EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 20.6.2023
SWD(2023) 331 final
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
Accompanying the document
Amended Proposal for a Council Decision
amending Decision (EU, Euratom) 2020/2053 on the system of own resources of the European Union
{COM(2023) 331 final}
Table of Contents
Executive Summary
Part 1. Overview of the own resources system and recent developments on the revenue side of the EU budget
1.1 Recent developments of the EU own resources system.
1.1.1. The own resources system: main elements of reform
1.1.2. Simplification of the own resources system: Value Added Tax own resource
1.1.3. Diversification of revenues: the plastics-based own resource
1.2 The increase in “other revenues”
Part 2. Potential New Own Resources – Types and Evaluation
2.1. Assessment framework for new own resources candidates
2.1.1. Political context
2.1.2. Selection of criteria
Revenue potential
Simplicity
Fast mobilisation of new revenue sources
2.2 Stakeholder and other institutions’ views
2.3. Evaluation of potential new own resources – individual factsheets
2.3.1. Corporate taxation (BEFIT), including financial sector
2.3.2. Statistical own resource based on company profits
2.3.3. Financial Sector - Financial Transaction Tax (FTT)
2.3.4. EU ‘fair border Mechanism’
2.3.5. Tax on crypto assets
2.3.6. Statistical own resource based on gender pay gap
2.3.7. Statistical own resource based on food waste
2.3.8. Statistical own resource based on e-waste
Part 3. The new own resources package
3.1.Emissions trading scheme (ETS) own resource
3.1.1. The 2021 proposal on ETS – an overview
3.1.2. Ensuring fairness – the Valuation Mechanism and Solidarity Adjustment Mechanisms
3.1.3. The evolution of the carbon market
3.2.The statistical own resource based on company profits
3.2.1. Characteristics of the statistical based own resource on company profits
3.2.2. How would it work?
Executive Summary
In 2020, the revenue side of the EU budget was significantly reformed. The Recovery plan for Europe put in place to address the economic and social damage brought about by the COVID-19 crisis and the empowerment to borrow up to around EUR 750 billion (2018 prices) on the markets to finance it was a step change for the EU. At the same time, adding a new own resource based on non-recycled plastic packaging waste, the first one since the introduction of the GNI-based own resource in 1988, was an important step in the direction of supporting EU policy priorities, such as the circular economy, and diversifying the revenue sources of the EU budget. Finally, the revenue side of the EU budget became less complex with the simplification of the VAT own resource and the budgetary rebates.
The commitment to repay the NextGenerationEU borrowing as from 2028 emphasises the urgent need for new own resources to protect EU budget expenditures for existing policies and new challenges. The Commission has proposed a first package in December 2021 with three new sources of revenues for the EU budget, i.e. contributions from the emissions trading system, from the EU Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism and from a share of residual profits from multinationals that will be re-allocated to EU Member States under the recent OECD/G20 agreement (“Pillar One”). The inter-institutional agreement of 16 December 2020 among the European Parliament, the Council, and the Commission foresees another package to be presented by the Commission.
Against this background, this document takes stock of the current situation and analyses a set of potential candidates for the Commission adjusted proposal on new own resources.
Three criteria are used to evaluate potential new own resources – revenue potential, simplicity, and fast mobilisation of revenues. As found in the literature, they summarise different considerations relevant to designing new own resources optimally, such as the ability to generate sufficient revenues, ease of administration in terms of revenue collection and compliance. They also reflect the political context and the need to act urgently. The ability to implement any new sources of revenues quickly is an important dimension which takes account of the needs of the EU budget.
The analysis covers eight potential new own resources, scoring each option on a qualitative and quantitative basis. The eight candidates are: corporate taxation (BEFIT), including the financial sector; a statistical own resource based on company profits; a tax on the financial sector with an assessment of a financial transaction tax (FTT); an EU ‘fair border mechanism’; a tax on cryptocurrencies; a statistical own resource based on gender pay gap; a statistical own resource based on food waste; and a statistical own resource based on e-waste. Having due consideration of the current economic environment, with high inflation creating pressures on the EU budget, the analysis shows that only few candidates would be suitable under the current circumstances; others could not be mobilised in the short run or are too complex to implement.
Part 1. Overview of the own resources system and recent developments on the revenue side of the EU budget
Until 2020, the EU own resources system has remained fairly stable, providing reliable revenue to the EU budget. Between 1988 and 2021, the main categories of own resources remained the same: traditional own resources (customs duties), contributions from the Member States based on value added tax (VAT) and on gross national income (GNI). This stable system has however increasingly relied on the own resource based on GNI, which had been introduced in 1988 as a residual item. Throughout the decades, various attempts have been undertaken to reform this system and to introduce new own resources(). The reform of 2020 introduced significant changes which pave the way for the modernisation of the own resources system.
In parallel, other streams of revenues (‘other revenues’) have increased their share in the revenue side of the EU budget. ‘Other revenues’ coming from various sources described in part 1.2 have also provided a stable revenue source. Since 2021, ‘other revenues’ also include the amounts for non-repayable support assigned to the European Recovery Instrument and borrowed for NextGenerationEU (NGEU), for which an exceptional and temporary authorisation was established in the Own Resources Decision(). Complemented with an increasing role of financial instruments, NGEU issuances explains recent increases in the share of ‘other revenues’.
1.1 Recent developments of the EU own resources system.
1.1.1. The own resources system: main elements of reform
In 2020, in response to the severe COVID-19 crisis, Member States agreed on far-reaching reforms, including on the system of own resources. The Recovery plan for Europe put in place to address the economic and social damage brought about by the Covid-19 crisis has introduced significant changes on the revenue side of the EU budget. To give the Union the means to achieve its objective, the Own Resource Decision() adopted in December 2020 empowers the Commission to borrow up to EUR 750 billion (2018 prices) on an exceptional and temporary basis. In order to do so, it also substantially increases the own resource ceiling, enabling such EU borrowing on an exceptional and temporary basis. In particular, the Own Resource Decision has added a separate and additional compartment in the own resource payment ceiling equal to 0.6% of EU GNI, to enable NextGenerationEU borrowing.
Although the 2020 reform introduced a new own resource (based on recycled plastic packaging waste), the balancing GNI-based own resource remains the dominant source of revenue for the EU budget. Broadly stable revenues from both Traditional Own Resources and the VAT-based, combined with a slowly rising total budget, have translated into a growing weight of the GNI-based own resource (Graph 1). The introduction of the new plastics-based own resource makes a small dent in the GNI dominance, without significantly altering the overall picture.
Graph 1. The evolution of own resources, 2000-2022
Source: Commission services, Expenditure and Revenue Tables 2000-2021 (
Spending and revenue (europa.eu)
); source Budget 2022: financing tables 2022, including Draft Amending Budget 5
A system of rebates is maintained for the period 2021-2027, but it is now simpler and more transparent. The system of rebates on national contributions, initially introduced in 1984, was meant to reduce the excessive net budgetary burden on some Member States, while at the same time adding complexity to the revenue system. With the withdrawal of the United Kingdom, the UK rebate ceased to apply. As from 2021, gross lump sums are deducted from the GNI-contributions of Austria, Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, and Sweden, and they are financed by all Member States, i.e. including the five beneficiaries, which reduces the net amount of their rebates. As these lump sums are indexed to inflation, they imply large windfall gains in the current inflationary environment. The retention rate for traditional own resources, also known as ‘collection costs’, increases from 20% to 25%.
1.1.2. Simplification of the own resources system: Value Added Tax own resource
The Value Added Tax-based own resource was simplified for the first time in 2020. The previous system used to rely on a notional harmonised value added tax base requiring complex calculations to adjust for the derogations and exemptions in the VAT Directive. Following the reform, the value added tax base is now calculated in a simpler way, by dividing the national receipts by a weighted average rate based on a reference year (
). The adjustment for derogations and exemptions have been removed, thus simplifying the calculations A uniform call rate of 0.3% applies to the value added tax bases of all Member States.
On average, the removal of complex calculations had a limited impact on Member States. The objective of corrections and compensations was to offset the potential exemptions and derogations foreseen in the value added tax Directive that were applied by some Member States (
). First, the VAT national receipts were corrected from non-VAT elements, leading to the so-called ‘net receipts’. Over the period 2016-2019, corrections represented on average 0.5% of total value added tax receipts in the EU27 as a whole. The difference between receipts and net receipts (representing the amounts of corrections) was limited in most Member States (Graph 2). Second, more complex, the compensations included a statistical treatment of derogations and exemptions for levying VAT, allowing the calculation of the final base. Compensations represented around 0.2% of the EU’s value added tax base on average. The difference between intermediate and final base (corresponding to the statistical compensation) was limited for most Member States (
Error! Reference source not found.
). Finally, as the annual weighted average rate did not fluctuate considerably over time, the reform proposed to remove the complex calculations of the annual weighted average rate, and to take the weighted average rate of 2016 (
Graph 4
) (
).
Graph 2. Corrections to VAT receipts, EUR billion, average 2016-2020
Note: Net receipts exclude corrections from receipts. Corrections aimed to take out non-VAT elements from VAT receipts and to add potential VAT receipts accounted for elsewhere or not at all. The small differences between receipts and net receipts show the small impact of removing the corrections.
Source: Commission services calculations based on national VAT statements.
Graph 3. Compensations to the VAT base, EUR billion, average 2016-2020
Note: Compensations were made until 2020 to harmonise the notional VAT base, as calculated from the VAT receipts reported by Member States. They correspond to the full application of the VAT Directive (no derogations, no exemption). VAT bases are displayed before capping at 50% of GNI.
Source: Commission services calculations based on national VAT statements.
Graph 4. Weighted Average VAT Rates, %, 2016-2020
Source: Commission services calculations based on national VAT statements.
Finally, to ensure fairness among Member States, the capping mechanism was maintained. The mechanism prevents Member States with high consumption shares and large value added tax bases from paying a disproportionate contribution, by capping the value added tax base for the VAT own resource at 50% of their GNI.
1.1.3. Diversification of revenues: the plastics-based own resource
The most notable novelty concerning own resources is the own resource based on non-recycled plastic packaging waste, entered into force in 2021. The introduction of this new own resource is not only historic, as it is the first new own resource since the introduction of the GNI-based own resource in 1988, but also an important step in the direction of supporting EU policy priorities, such as the circular economy, with the revenue side of the budget. The new own resource contributes some 3% of total EU revenues, which represents a small but important change in the mix of revenues.
As a statistical-based own resource, the plastics-own resource changes the contribution key of Member States, thereby encouraging them to implement or reinforce recycling policies. The own resource contribution is proportional to the quantity of plastic packaging waste that is not recycled. Member States contribute EUR 0.80 per kilogramme of plastics packaging waste that is generated in their territory and not recycled (i.e. is put in a landfill or incinerated with or without energy recovery). As such, it provides Member States with a direct financial incentive to reduce waste generation and recycle more. It however leaves them free to choose the appropriate way of achieving this, which may include a tax or other measures, such as deposit systems and communication campaigns to encourage recycling().
In the years before the Covid-19 crisis, both plastic packaging waste generation and recycling have risen in the EU. The quantity of plastic packaging waste that each Member State generates annually depends on its demographic and economic size. In the past, it has broadly evolved in sync with real GNI growth (Graph 5).
Graph 5. Plastic packaging waste (PPW) generated and recycled vs GNI, EU27
Source: Eurostat database (Tables: env_waspac & nama_10_gdp).
Note: Recycling rates series feature a break due to a change in measurement. This break explains the fall in the series in recent years, as measurement is stricter.
The proportion of plastic packaging waste that is recycled varies widely across the EU. Whereas in two Member States in 2020 it had already reached the 50% EU target() for 2025, in others it remained quite far below that level. Overall, recycling rates have also increased from an EU average of 31.4% in 2008 to 37.6% in 2020, although with wider fluctuations in several countries (Graph 6).
Graph 6. Recycling rate: plastic packaging waste recycled in % of total generated, 2020
Source: Eurostat database (Tables: env_waspac).
The plastics-own resource encourages decoupling non-recycled plastic waste from economic growth. The new own resource is expected to support Member States’ efforts to reduce the generation of plastic packaging waste and to increase its recycling. Both effects would contribute to decouple the dynamics of non-recycled waste from economic developments. However, the incentives become smaller over time as the “price” for the non-recycled plastic packing waste in the Own Resources Decision is fixed in current prices while the overall price levels increased substantially due to high inflation rates.
1.2 The increase in “other revenues”
In addition to own resources, “other revenues” present another income stream for the EU budget. These revenues come from various sources such as surpluses from the previous year or contributions from third countries. They can also be directly generated by the implementation of EU policy and the enforcement of common Union rules, such as fines in the context of competition policy or taxes paid by EU civil servants (see Box 1). By default, other revenues, provided they are not assigned, are budgeted as general revenues. Until 2020, other revenues have so far represented less than 10% of total own resource revenues, on average (Graph 7).
Graph 7. Evolution of the share of other revenues and own resources in total budget revenue, 2000-2022, %
Note: Light colour / green bars include revenue from own resources, i.e. traditional own resources (TOR), VAT, plastic packaging waste (PPW) and GNI. Dark colour / blue bars include other revenues as per Box 1, including the revenues from borrowing activities linked to non-repayable part of NGEU.
Source: Commission services, Expenditure and Revenue Tables 2000-2021 (
Spending and revenue (europa.eu)
), source Budget 2022: financing tables 2022, including Draft Amending Budget 5.
Components of other revenue (excluding NGEU) such as surplus, administrative revenues or fines have remained quite stable over time. They account for a small share of total revenues (i.e. 4.5% in 2016 and 3.1% in 2021) and depend to a large extent on the implementation of the EU budget and the revenues actually collected during the financial year. Income stemming from interests and fines or penalties due to infringement law are more difficult to predict and can vary from one year to another.
Compared to the last decade, the share of revenues from “budgetary guarantees, borrowing and lending operations” have increased to reach 23% of total revenues in 2021 (graph 8). This is solely related to the borrowing for the new NGEU instrument, where proceeds for the non-repayable expenditures are channelled to the budget via external assigned revenues. On the contrary, the increasing role of financial instruments over the past years, contributing to incentivising both private and public investment in the EU, or the increased support to some countries through facilities such as the balance of payment assistance or external lending related to the past economic and financial crisis do not feature prominently on the revenue side.
Graph 8. Budget revenue, 2016 (lhs) vs 2021 (rhs)
Source: Consolidated annual accounts of the European Union 2016 and 2021.
Box 1. Other revenues and assigned revenues
The annual budget includes the yearly general statement of revenues, including ‘other revenue’ described in Titles 2 to 6 below, which are subdivided further into Chapters, Articles, and Items.
‒Title 2 (Surpluses, balances, and adjustments) includes the surplus from the previous financial years as well as own resources balances, and other adjustments such as for the non-participation of certain Member States in specific policies.
‒Title 3 (Administrative revenue) comprises in particular revenues from taxes and levies on the remuneration of staff.
‒Title 4 (Financial revenue, default interests and fines) refers mainly to fines in the field of competition.
‒Title 5 (Budgetary guarantees, borrowing and lending operations) covers NextGenerationEU (NGEU) funds for the non-repayable support as well as guarantees and interest and repayments of loans granted.
‒Title 6 (Revenue, contributions and refunds related to Union policies) covers mainly revenue from financial corrections related to structural and agricultural funds and includes the participation of third countries in research programmes, the clearance of accounts in agricultural funds and other contributions and refunds to EU programmes/activities.
Expenditure can be financed by general revenue or revenue that is assigned to specific expenditures. Assigned revenues therefore represent an exception to the principle of universality. The complete list of items constituting assigned revenue is given in Article 21 of the Financial Regulation. The sums borrowed for NextGenerationEU are assigned to specific programme spending (in particular the Recovery and Resilience Facility).
The number of “Other revenue” sources are expected to increase in the near future. Recent policies generating other revenues for the EU Budget include EU policies such as the European Travel Information and Authorisation System - ETIAS (), the CO2 emission standards for cars and vans Regulation (), the CO2 emission standards for heavy duty vehicles ().
|
Part 2. Potential New Own Resources – Types and Evaluation
The own resource package is framed by a specific political context – the inter-institutional agreement signed in December 2020 where the three institutions agreed on a roadmap towards the introduction of new own resources.
This part explores criteria to assess new own resources, taking account of the current economic and political context, and applies these criteria to potential candidates, scoring them, to propose or discard new own resources in the short term.
2.1. Assessment framework for new own resources candidates
2.1.1. Political context
In December 2021, the Commission proposed three new sources of revenues for the EU budget with contributions from the Emissions Trading System (ETS), from the EU Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) and from a share of the residual profits of the largest multinational enterprises that would be reallocated to the EU under the OECD/G20 Pillar 1 agreement. This basket of own resources was consistent with the proposed sectorial legislation on both the revised ETS Directive and on the Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) proposed earlier in the same year. Since then, the discussions on own resources have made limited progress and the recent agreement on the underlying sectoral legislation – ETS Directive and CBAM Regulation – paves the way for relaunching the discussions (see part 3).
The inter-institutional agreement of 16 December 2020 among the European Parliament, the Council, and the Commission foresees another batch of own resources, mostly linked to the corporate and financial sectors. The European Parliament as well as other institutions have identified a large number of potential candidates, including in the field of corporate and financial taxation (see section 2.2).
The delays in the implementation of the December 2021 proposals increase the urgency of additional resources. Issues of both timing and sufficiency related to ETS, CBAM, and the OECD/G20 Pillar 1 make it now necessary to supplement this selection with additional new own resources. This document intends to provide Member States, the Parliament, and stakeholders at large with a full overview of the analysis underpinning the Commission’s proposal, so that all elements are available to resume and swiftly progress in the discussions on the proposed new own resources.
2.1.2. Selection of criteria
Against this political background, the assessment framework must account for the need to act quickly and provide the necessary means to the EU budget, but also of ways to design new own resources optimally. For this purpose, selection criteria are established according to the literature, but only own resource candidates able to generate significant resources quickly and without heavy implementation are considered, to respond to the challenges the EU budget is facing. Therefore, the assessment framework relies on three criteria related to (1) revenue potential, (2) simplicity in terms of compliance and administrative burden, and (3) fast mobilisation. These are in line with the economic literature, while taking account of the specificities of the EU budget at this juncture (Table 1 and Box 2).
Table 1. Assessment framework
Assessment framework
|
1.Revenue potential
|
2.Simplicity
|
3.Fast mobilisation of new revenue sources
|
Revenue potential
The revenue potential evaluates the amounts of money the own resource can generate. Linked to revenue potential are also the stability of these revenues over time and their predictability.
Simplicity
Simplicity refers to budget revenue collection and the ease of implementing new own resources, from an administrative angle, including the availability of statistics. It also contributes to improving transparency, which is particularly important to preserve accountability to citizens and stakeholders. In the past, the EU own resources system had grown increasingly complex and opaque due to factors such as the cumbersome calculations of the UK rebate, the “rebates on the rebate”, and heavy steps to calculate a notional harmonised value added tax base(
). The reforms of 2020 - simplifying the VAT base() and introducing a plainer system of lump-sum rebates led to a simpler revenue collection for both Member States and the Commission.
Fast mobilisation of new revenue sources
Box 2. Criteria: What does the literature tell us?
There is an extensive literature on tax and economists have been assessing taxation from various perspectives concerning for example policy, administration, and compliance. Comparatively, the literature on EU revenues is more limited, given the specificities of the EU budget compared to national budgets. The EU budget does not levy taxes and is financed by revenues from common policies (i.e. customs duties) and national contributions (see Part 1). These revenues are currently collected by Member States and transferred to the EU budget. Therefore, the application of criteria used in the tax literature would need to be further adjusted to reflect these specificities.
Equity, efficiency, and a practical/simple administration are three principles traditionally used to evaluate the rationale for raising revenue as done through national budgets. These objectives originate in the early economic theory of Adam Smith and continue to gather wide acceptance among modern theorists today. They reflect various aspects of governance, tax policy, and tax administration, including the extent to which the two main roles traditionally defined for taxes under national budgets - redistribution and revenue raising for the collective provision of goods and services, including insurance (Smith, 2015(
)) - are fulfilled.
Some key conceptual considerations are listed below and refer to the criteria for a good tax, as found in the literature(
).
- Effectiveness in raising revenues will determine revenue sufficiency. In the literature, effectiveness refers to a tax or revenue design which is dependable () and predictable from year to year; for instance, tax / revenue systems applying to a broad tax base at a low tax rate are known to be most effective in raising revenues.
- Efficiency is important as public authorities aim to avoid distortions often associated with the loss of economic activity (‘deadweight loss’) that may arise when taxes drive a wedge between economic agents. Economic distortions are behavioural changes which can occur when taxes change relative prices and consumers can turn to substitute products. Such distortions would prevent from concluding or supress a transaction which would have occurred in absence of the tax(
).
- Equity is a major issue in taxation and it can encompass several dimensions, such as the ability to pay, progressivity and redistribution from the better off to the worse off (vertical equity); equal treatment of agents in the same situation (horizontal equity), ‘the polluter pays’ principle and correction of other negative externalities (Smith, 2015).
- Simplicity or ease of administration refers to revenue collection, implementation, and compliance. This criterion, which also features among those qualifying `good' tax systems (Smith, 2015, Stiglitz, 2000(
)), De Mooij et al., 2014), essentially concerns administering a tax or revenue system at low collection costs (Begg and Grimwade, 1998; Heinemann et al., 2008; Schratzenstaller, 2014). Generally speaking, the proof of simplicity is whether revenues are reliably collected every year without excessive administrative burden or legal and procedural controversy.
- Transparency concerns the different stakeholders’ understanding and ease of access to information, including through clear calculation methods of different budget revenues. Stakeholders may include taxpayers / citizens, civil society, parliaments. Transparency is even more vital in multi-level governance systems (Begg et al., 2008).
|
2.2 Stakeholder and other institutions’ views
The European Parliament supports the proposal of new own resources. In its report adopted on the 10 May 2023(
), the European Parliament responded to the Commission’s proposal of 22 December 2021 on three additional sources of revenues for the EU budget based on carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM), emission trading scheme (ETS) and reallocated profits of multinationals. This report called on the Member States in the Council to adopt the new own resources from the first package of 14 December 2021. Moreover, concerned on the sufficiency of new own resources “to cover all NGEU repayments and borrowing costs”, to avoid cuts to existing EU programmes and policies, it “urged all actors to continue the efforts to identify fresh and new, preferably genuine, own resources and other revenue sources for the EU budget”.
This report discussed several possible measures as a basis for own resources, supporting, among others, corporate taxation (BEFIT), a tax on cryptocurrencies, a tax related to the digital economy, a financial transaction tax (FTT), an EU ‘fair border tax’, and saw high potential in all statistics-based own resources. On the latter, the European Parliament report proposes a bio-waste statistical own resource fostering the reuse of bio-waste() and an own resource on gender pay gap statistics.
Finally, the Parliament report also mentions revenue sources other than own resources, such as those in the form of levies, fees charged for visa waivers under the European Travel Information and Authorisation System (ETIAS) when it comes into operation, excess emission premiums, competition fines, infringement penalties or similar, which should be listed transparently in the annual budget documents, as well as proceeds generated in the context of criminal justice sentences and assets confiscated in the event of non-compliance with EU sanctions (e.g. Russian frozen assets).
The Council technically explored the Commission’s proposals since 2021, but little progress has been made concerning the adoption of new own resources. Further to the inter-institutional agreement of 16 December 2020, the Council monitored the Commission’s proposals of December 2021 on CBAM, ETS, and reallocated profits of multinationals, including their share in the ‘Fit-for-55’ package of July 2021, and the related implementing Regulations proposed in March 2022. In this context, in 2022, the Council reached a general approach and started negotiations with the European Parliament on the sectoral Regulations of CBAM and ETS. These took place mostly during the 2nd half of 2022, under the Czech Presidency(). Few delegations took a fully-fledged position on the own resources’ package, given that not all Commission proposals were on the table. Consequently, there was no substantial progress in their adoption so far.
The European Court of Auditors’ position is also broadly favourable. The latest European Court of Auditors opinion on the Commission’s proposal of December 2021 dates from July 2022(
). While the opinion recognised the progress made towards the introduction of new own resources, it saw a need for more consistency in the rules for managing own resources.
The European Economic and Social Committee (EESC) also supported the Commission’s December 2021 proposal for new own resources, but was concerned with the competitiveness of EU businesses and the subsistence of households. The Committee deemed new own resources were necessary to cover the debt repayment resulting from NextGenerationEU borrowing and acknowledged the higher flexibility of an extended own resources model, with funds reacting more effectively to economic shocks. It stressed the importance of equity and fairness, efficiency, transparency, simplicity, and stability in the new system, as well as of a focus on competitiveness and applying solidarity to support households and businesses, where necessary. A targeted impact assessment by country and sector (industry) was also mentioned, together with preserving a level playing field of EU businesses in the international tax system, avoiding competitive disadvantages().
The European Committee of the Regions (CoR) noted the Commission's proposal, with a nuanced position. In its opinion of 30 November – 1 December 2022(), the Committee noted that the introduction of a first basket of new own resources would send a positive message to investors on the financial markets and rating agencies; similarly to other institutions, it also stressed the need to establish new resources not only to repay the NGEU debt without jeopardizing EU programmes in the next MFF, but also to increase the EU budget's financial autonomy in a permanent, sustainable way for the Member States' budgets. The Committee also underlined that additional new own resources would be needed given that, overall, the three new own resources proposed in December 2021 would yield up to EUR 17 billion / year from 2026 to 2030 (European Commission estimates), an amount insufficient to cover both the costs of repaying the NGEU debt (EUR 15 billion / year) and finance the Social Climate Fund (EUR 9.7 billion / year). Furthermore, the Committee called upon the Commission to consider credible, territorial impact assessments regarding potential costs European companies and consumers may incur.
2.3. Evaluation of potential new own resources – individual factsheets
This section presents eight potential options for new own resources based on either Commission’s existing or forthcoming sectorial proposals – such as BEFIT – or the European Parliament’s own initiative report (see section 2.2). Each of the eight assessments elaborates on the three criteria – revenue potential, simplicity, and fast mobilisation of revenues – and scores each option on a qualitative basis and using expert judgement (for the methodology, see Box 3). A summary evaluation is presented in Table 2.
A tax on the digital economy is not part of this assessment, given the ongoing international discussions in the context of the OECD. The EU has always considered the OECD’s Two-pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy a paradigm-changing reform of the international corporate tax system. Its implementation remains a key priority in the area of corporate taxation for the EU and its Member States. Enormous progress has been made following the October 2021 agreement. Certain building blocks now remain to be completed to pave the way for the signature of the Multilateral Convention before the end of the year.. Against such backdrop, the EU will not consider further measures on the digital sector, as long as the OECD’s Pillar One is in preparation or in place.
The European Parliament called for the establishment of a bio-waste-based own resource. Since there are no specific statistics on bio-waste, but rather several statistical systems, the assessment considers two separate own resources based on the waste from electrical and electronic equipment – ‘e-waste’ – and on food waste.
The eight candidates are: corporate taxation (BEFIT), including the financial sector (section 2.3.1); a statistical own resource based on company profits (section 2.3.2); a tax on the financial sector with an assessment of a financial transaction tax (FTT) (section 2.3.3); an EU ‘fair border mechanism’ (section 2.3.4); a tax on cryptocurrencies (section 2.3.5); a statistical own resource based on gender pay gap (section 2.3.6); a statistical own resource based on food waste (section 2.3.7); and a statistical own resource based on e-waste (section 2.3.8).
Box 3. Evaluation and scoring of new own resources
Each potential new own resource is scored along the three criteria – 1) revenue potential, 2) simplicity of collection and implementation, and 3) fast mobilisation of new revenue sources to the EU budget.
Each criterion is marked from 0 to 4 points (quarters of a circle), with 0 standing for no compliance and 4 standing for full compliance of the new measure with the criterion considered. With a maximum of 4 points per criterion, any given new own resource proposal can score a maximum number of 12 points (3 criteria * number of points/criterion).
Scoring
|
None
|
Modest
|
Adequate
|
Good
|
Full
|
As in Monti et al., 2016 and Schratzenstaller et al., 2016, this scoring assessment is largely qualitative and reflects the expert judgment with each potential new measure.
|
2.3.1. Corporate taxation (BEFIT), including financial sector
Description: Rationale and design
The initiative Business in Europe: Framework for Income Taxation (BEFIT) would improve the functioning of the Single Market by simplifying corporate tax rules and tax compliance, and levelling the playing field for businesses, as well as stimulating growth and investment. BEFIT aims to address double taxation and reduce tax compliance costs that businesses, chiefly those with cross-border activity, currently face in the Single Market. This will help make the EU more attractive to investment and support growth. BEFIT will cover both the financial and non-financial sectors and will be mandatory for large groups, i.e. those with global combined annual revenues of EUR 750 million or more and therefore in scope of the Directive on ensuring a global minimum level of taxation for multinational groups in the Union (‘Pillar 2’) which will enter into force on 1 January 2024. It will remain an option for all other groups of companies that file consolidated financial statements and have a taxable presence in the EU.
The BEFIT-based own resource could levy e.g. a call rate on the share of the aggregated tax base, of all groups within the mandatory scope of BEFIT allocated to the Member States, using a formulary apportionment.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
A BEFIT-based own resource would link the financing of the EU budget to the benefits enjoyed by companies operating in the Single Market and make for a strong and stable resource over time. Under a BEFIT-based own resource, Member States would transfer part of their corporate income tax revenues to the EU budget. Applying even a potentially small call rate could raise substantial revenues.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
Member States would contribute based on a call rate that will be applied to the apportioned share of each member of a group within the mandatory BEFIT scope. Since the calculation of the apportioned shares is already part of the BEFIT system, only the aggregation of the tax base at Member State level would be required for the purpose of raising the own resource amount.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
The Commission will come forward with a proposal on BEFIT during the second half of 2023. The own resource element could be implemented only after the Directive on BEFIT comes into effect. Negotiations on the sectorial BEFIT proposal in Council requires Member States’ unanimous vote.
2.3.2. Statistical own resource based on company profits
DESCRIPTION: RATIONALE AND DESIGN
A statistical own resource based on company profits would not be a tax on companies, nor would it increase their compliance costs. It would be a national contribution linked to the corporate sector. A national contribution could be designed based on a “statistical proxy” of corporate income or corporate profits. The measure could apply to financial and non-financial corporations (see part 3, for more details). One such statistical indicator is gross operating surplus, as defined in the European System of Accounts 2010 (ESA 2010)(
).
This statistical indicator covers both profit generation due to the physical presence of companies and their related economic activities, and - at least partially - the shifting of profits for tax reasons. Member States attracting company profits that are in principle potentially taxable would in principle contribute more on this statistical own resource.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
The own resource base could comprise both financial and non-financial companies and would reflect the gross operating surplus of both sectors. The own resource base would be substantial and reach around EUR 3 000 billion in current prices on average for 2018-2020.
The call rate could be low: a call rate between 0.1% and 0.5% applied on the sum of gross operating surplus for the sectors of financial and non-financial corporations could bring revenues between EUR 3 billion and 16 billion per year on average over the period 2028-2030 (in 2018 prices).
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
In terms of implementation, the statistics on which this own resource would be levied already exist. As a matter of efficiency and effectiveness, the implementing measures for the supervision related to this own resource could take into account the existing obligations on Member States under the GNI control framework.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
This own resource could be implemented quickly. This statistical own resource could be temporary and cease to apply once Member States agree on both the forthcoming Directive related to the BEFIT initiative, and to draw a Union own resource from that tax base (e.g. as described in factsheet 2.3.1).
2.3.3. Financial Sector - Financial Transaction Tax (FTT)
Description: Rationale and design
The financial sector is perceived as being undertaxed. It faces different non-harmonised national taxes across the EU and is VAT exempt. To ensure a just and stable contribution of the financial sector to public finances, a contribution from the financial sector as a basis for an EU own resource could balance contributions from other sectors.
In the wake of the 2008-09 financial crisis and subsequent sovereign debt crisis, the introduction of a harmonised framework of national financial transaction taxes (FTTs) at EU level became part of the Commission’s political priorities in the field of taxation policy. The FTT was targeted at curbing excessive speculation and volatility, making the financial sector bear part of the costs of its rescue from the financial crisis and fostering harmonisation, as some Member States were considering introducing (or had already introduced) FTTs. The Commission put forward two FTT proposals, one in 2011 (for all Member States) and one in 2013 under enhanced cooperation. The latter proposal, still under discussion, is similar to a stamp duty and would apply only to purchases of shares issued by domestic listed companies with a market capitalisation higher than EUR 1 billion.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
It was estimated that the initial 2011 Commission proposal would have generated revenues up to EUR 57 billion per year. Design changes in the compromise FTT proposal that was put forward under enhanced cooperation would mean a much lower revenue potential. The significantly changed design and limited number of participating Member States would mean that, under the current design, the revenues to the EU budget would be rather limited.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
A uniform tax rate would be applied to transactions of financial assets in scope of an FTT in addition to the price and intermediary fees. The revenues would be collected by the financial intermediary and allocated to the relevant Member States. Part of that revenue would then accrue to the EU budget at a set call rate.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
After years of negotiation, no agreement has been found on the FTT proposal, progress has been very slow, the enhanced cooperation is reduced to ten Member States, and the prospects of reaching an agreement in the future are limited given that the last substantial discussions took place under the Portuguese Council Presidency in 2021. There is little expectation that any proposal would be agreed in the short term.
2.3.4. EU ‘fair border Mechanism’
Description: Rationale and design
The EP report on own resources ‘A new start for EU finances. A new start for Europe’ (2022/2172(INI)) suggested establishing an EU Fair Border ‘Mechanism’. It should help fight the social dumping of commodities made by underpaid people in developing countries and imported into the EU market. The companies importing products into the European Union would be required to pay a charge for any worker in their global supply chain who is paid a wage below the relevant poverty line of third countries.
The European Parliament refers to the example of textile production in Bangladesh. Bangladesh is a part of an EU programme that allows developing countries to export goods to the EU at lower or no tariffs, under the
Generalised Scheme of Preferences
(GSP). The GSP is one of the key EU trade instruments to assist developing countries to integrate into the world economy, reduce poverty, and support sustainable development through the promotion of core human and labour rights, environmental protection, and good governance. A specific salary level is not part of the EU’s GSP conditionality. Therefore, the contemplated idea of a fair border tax could not be implemented via the GSP, but only as an additional selective tariff.
Such mechanisms are uncommon in the world, and in particular do not include any trade measures. In California, for instance, a Garment Worker Protection Act is in place since January 2022 (). It foresees that employees engaged in garment manufacturing in California must be paid an hourly rate not less than the minimum wage and forbids pay per piece, except in specific cases. These conditions seem to concern domestically produced garments, with no specific reference to trade. In the EU, the Commission proposed in 2022 two pieces of legislation - a Regulation aiming to prohibit products made using forced labour and a Directive on corporate sustainability due diligence (CSDDD). The Regulation covers cases of systematic and deliberate withholding of wages, as well as working involuntarily because of very low or no wage; it will empower national authorities to withdraw from the EU market products made with forced labour or to stop such imports at EU borders. The Directive aims to foster sustainable and responsible corporate behaviour throughout global value chains, requiring companies to identify and, where necessary, prevent, end or mitigate adverse impacts of their activities on human rights, such as exploitation of workers.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
The EU Fair Border Mechanism would bring fresh money. If introduced, the duties paid on certain imported garments/goods will likely be classified as customs duties and thus Traditional Own Resources. Under the current own resources’ rules, the Member States would be able to retain 25% of the duties as collection costs.
The issue of how the charge would be determined and calculated across complex value chains should be considered – the production of garments has a fairly simple supply chain; however, more complex products have infinitely more complicated supply chains (e.g. a typical motor vehicle has over 20.000 parts and thousands of suppliers and suppliers to those suppliers). Therefore, the quantification of potential revenue is difficult to establish.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
The desired design of the charge is not clear – such as on what base the wage difference would need to be applied for a given assignment. Another question would be to know whether the importer would need to pay the difference in the wages on each piece of garment or would the difference be divided by the average daily output. Moreover, the effect of the tax or charge on increasing the salaries in third countries seems to be uncertain – the importer is usually not the producer and has limited control over the production part of the supply chain.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
The ‘Fair Border Mechanism’ would be a trade policy tool which would be introduced by the Commission as a legislative proposal under Article 207(1) and (2) TFEU. It would need to be compatible with the WTO Agreement and EU bilateral trade agreements. The tariff must be justified under an exception in the WTO’s General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) because it would exceed the EU’s scheduled tariff commitments (Article II GATT, i.e. the maximum permitted tariff which normally is already applied) and there would inevitably be discrimination between countries (most-favoured-nation obligation).
This justification could theoretically be Article XX of GATT which allows WTO Members to restrict trade when this is necessary to protect public morals or human life or health, provided they do not unjustifiably or arbitrarily discriminate between countries or use this as disguised restriction on trade. Using this article to justify a “Fair Border Mechanism” would be a major political and legal challenge. Properly designing and operating such a scheme would also create a high administrative burden on public authorities and the private sector, raising the question of whether poverty alleviation can be achieved more effectively and more efficiently through other means.
2.3.5. Tax on crypto assets
Description: Rationale and design
The global market in crypto assets has grown rapidly over the past years. Crypto assets are increasingly used and citizens are increasingly investing in the crypto market, while businesses intensify their investments – whether in the necessary infrastructure or in tradable assets. There are many kinds of crypto assets, including cryptocurrencies with fluctuating prices (e.g. Bitcoin), “stablecoins” pegged to a currency (e.g. Tether pegged 1:1 to the USD), and “non-fungible tokens” (NFTs) representing a unique digital item (e.g. a cyber artwork). While crypto assets also have a hybrid or dual nature as an investment product (similar to financial assets) and payment method (similar to currency), to date, at the level of the EU Member States, the main tax implication arising from them has been as speculative assets that can deliver capital gains (and losses).
In view of the constantly evolving nature of the crypto market and the importance of its future potential, as well as the risks it brings to bear, this market’s evolution will need to be continuously assessed and monitored. As a first step, the recent adoption of MiCA (Markets in Crypto-assets) Regulation in April 2023 has already improved the opaque nature of the market. Transparency will continue to improve with the entry into force of the DAC8 (Directive on Administrative Cooperation) proposal (
) on the automatic exchange of information, which will help boost crypto-asset related information sharing and tax compliance.
Most Member States already tax capital gains and other income related to crypto assets as part of their national tax systems; however, they do so in a heterogeneous way. The European Parliament has suggested several ideas, including a harmonised direct tax on capital gains arising from increases in the value of crypto assets, applying across the EU, and accruing to the EU budget. Any work at the EU level on this front should ensure that the taxation of crypto assets is coherent with national tax systems. It should, moreover, be considered only over the medium-term, based on further analysis and close coordination with Member States.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
According to a study of the European Parliament () and based on limited data availability, the value of the European cryptocurrency market had already reached EUR 4.3 billion in 2019 and it is expected to grow to EUR 12.9 billion by 2026.
The yield would fundamentally depend on the evolution in the price of crypto assets. It would also depend on what tax and call rates are ultimately applied. Although there are concerns about under-reporting of income from crypto-assets (which DAC8 will contribute to alleviate), it should be noted that the crypto-asset market is characterised by high levels of price volatility, which introduces uncertainty as to the stability of revenue generation over time.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
There are currently significant variations across the EU in the classification of crypto assets, what counts as a taxable event, tax rates and thresholds, how to value individual assets and gains on disposal, and the treatment of losses. What Member States already have in place varies greatly (); and is interlinked with the national tax treatment of capital gains on other asset classes. Such issues would, therefore, have to be explored in greater detail and best practices shared to inform appropriate decisions.
Irrespective of the DAC8 proposal, a possible change in the taxation of crypto assets into a mechanism for the taxation of gains harmonised at the EU level would entail significant resources to set up, in operating systems and collection mechanisms, all issues that would require careful consideration.
An EU own resource call rate could then be applied e.g. to the capital gains tax base, provided Member States apply a harmonised tax base across the EU.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
Given the policy design and administrative challenges, the innovative and evolving nature of the crypto market and tradable assets, as well as the precedent that the application of any measure at EU level would set, further work is required to map and explore solutions to a plethora of challenging questions.
2.3.6. Statistical own resource based on gender pay gap
Description: Rationale and design
The strict prohibition of any discrimination on grounds of sex and the right to equal treatment between men and women in all areas, including employment, work and pay is directly enshrined in article 157 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, according to which “Member States shall ensure that the principle of equal pay for male and female workers for equal work or work of equal value” and in Directive 2006/54/EC.
Although these provisions have direct effect and can be enforced by national courts, currently, the gender pay gap in the EU stands at 12.7 % in 2021 and has only changed minimally over the last decade. It means that women earn 12.7 % on average less per hour than men ().
In principle, an own resource based on the difference between the hourly earnings of women and men could incentivise Member States to take more action.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
The relevant data are submitted to the Commission every year. The gender pay gap indicator is the relative difference between the average earnings of women and men:
This indicator takes account of the fact that the two groups do not work the same number of hours on average. However, it does not take into account other characteristics of male and female employees, i.e. the difference in terms of qualifications, which is higher for women in most of the Member States, and occupation as well as the concentration of one sex in certain economic activity and sectors.
Although the exact design of a related own resource would need to be developed, it seems that an own resource would generate a relatively limited amount of revenue.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
Although the quality of statistics is considered as satisfactory, the gender pay gap statistics published on a yearly basis by the Commission do not measure discrimination as such. Indeed, differences in pay between males and females can be explained by other dimensions such as the differences in the overall structure of male versus female employment. Statistical work is ongoing to adjust the pay gap and compare the returns paid to women versus those paid to men with the same average characteristics().
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
Though work to improve the related statistics is ongoing, it is not sufficiently developed, nor tested, to propose a gender pay gap own resource within a reasonable timeframe.
2.3.7. Statistical own resource based on food waste
Description: Rationale and design
Food waste is a part of bio-waste, but there are two separate reporting obligations. According to Eurostat estimates, around 10% of food made available to EU consumers (at retail, food services and households) are wasted. Reducing food waste would consequently provide many economic and environmental benefits as it would lower the carbon and overall environmental footprint of food production and consumption. It would also increase food security.
In June 2023, the Commission [will propose/proposed] an amendment to the Waste Directive and [will introduce/introduced] binding reduction targets for food waste (a percentage as from the reference year). An own resource proportional to the annual quantity of food waste in every Member State would complement this sectorial legislative proposal.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
This new own resource would also apply to a statistical base, which is the quantity of food wasted in a year, valued in euro, as reported by Eurostat. In 2022, there were nearly 59 million tonnes of food waste (131 kg / inhabitant / year, around 10% of the food produced in the EU)(
). This had an associated market value estimated at EUR132 billion / year (2020).
Under the new own resource, the national contribution would be directly proportional to the quantity of food waste generated in each Member State (statistical base). Concretely, a call rate between EUR 0.05 – 0.20 per kg could apply to this base and could generate between EUR 3 and 12 billion/year. ()
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
The waste framework Directive (
) imposes on Member States an obligation to submit data to the Commission on the amount of food waste generated. The measurement of waste is harmonised throughout the EU by a Commission Delegated Act (
).
A food waste own resource could make use of this existing statistical system. It should however be noted that the statistical system was just set up, and the results are still regarded as estimates rather than solid data, due to lack of data series(
). The collection of the own resource could be similar to the plastic based own resource, however the system for food waste will be much more complex, less precise and require longer time to establish quality data series.
In particular, waste is generated throughout the whole food supply chain from production until consumption and the types of food waste and factors contributing to its generation. Moreover, important amounts of food waste are currently not measured due to lack of methods for measuring which would ensure sufficient levels of confidence and comparability – e.g. food waste which is usually discarded with wastewater or food waste recycled by home composting.
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
As announced in the Commission Work Programme for 2023(), the Commission proposes a revision of food waste and textiles aspects of the EU waste framework Directive. As regards the statistics, the complexity of the issue may require significant further work.
2.3.8. Statistical own resource based on e-waste
Description: Rationale and design
A new own resource based on waste from electrical and electronic equipment could support the EU priorities on the circular economy and the recent proposal of the Commission on Critical Raw Materials (CRM)(
) which aims to ensure EU access to a secure and sustainable supply of critical raw materials. This initiative underlines the necessary contribution of waste from electrical and electronic equipment to the efficient use of resources and to the retrieval of secondary raw materials, including critical ones.
The EU faces the challenge of further increasing e-waste collection, recycling, and reuse in Member States. An own resource based on the collection of e-waste could incentivise Member States to put in place measures to incentivise consumers to discard electrical and electronic equipment that it is hoarded in households in several ways. A call rate could be applied on the quantity of waste electrical and electronic equipment not collected, calculated by subtracting waste collected from waste generated. The use of waste generated compared to what is placed on the market has an important advantage, as it accounts for the lifespan of EEE products. This is particularly important in the current context of the energy crisis.
Assessment
1.Revenue potential
The base to which such measure could apply, the quantity of e-waste not collected, would represent approximately 4 million tonnes per year (2016-2018). This statistical base would be calculated by subtracting e-waste collected from e-waste generated and would be based on the existing EU Directive on Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE Directive (
)).
A call rate in the range of EUR 1 to EUR 2 / kg could be applied on the difference between the generation and the collection of waste of electric and electronic equipment. It would lead to a range of revenues between EUR 4-8 billion / year (average 2016-2018).
While the quality of e-waste statistics, including e-waste trade, are still being improved, economic efficiency distortions linked to the firms’ incentives to report e-waste, including exports/imports as such cannot be excluded. These could affect the base of this potential new own resource, warping the related revenues across EU countries. Therefore, particular attention should be paid to the reporting of companies when importing or exporting e-waste.
2.Simplicity of collection and implementation
In terms of implementation, Member States already have the obligation to provide data necessary to calculate the own resource to Eurostat in the context of the electronic and electric equipment waste Directive (WEEE Directive(
)).The quality of statistics would need to be further improved on several levels. First, it needs to be ensured that waste generation data is available for all Member States. Second, internet trade - in cases where producers outside the EU or importers of used goods do not report on the whole amount of electrical and electronic equipment placed on the market – needs to be taken into account. Third, specific issues relate to second hand articles sold to another Member State, which are currently not reported (no tracking system of trade of electronic appliances between physical or legal persons after placing on the market or their storage before being wasted), and the treatment of electronic and electric equipment waste as metal scrap under sub-standard conditions. Fourth, the quality of statistics for e-waste generated and not collected also reflects country-specific coefficients for the lifespan of products. Not least, addressing illegal and sub-standard activities such as illegal exports and scavenging of electronic and electric equipment waste constitute key challenges to implementing this measure / electronic and electric equipment waste Directive(
).
3.Fast mobilisation of new sources of revenue to the EU budget
This own resource could generate revenues from the start. As announced in the Critical Raw Materials communication(
), the Commission will review the electronic and electric equipment waste Directive to, inter alia, address critical raw materials-rich equipment in provisions relating to information requirements and recovery targets. The evaluation of the electronic and electric equipment waste Directive is already ongoing and should be available in 2024. Furthermore, significant work on the quality and comparability of statistics would need to be done.
In conclusion, the analysis shows that, in principle, all candidates could become an own resource, but not all could be mobilised in the short run. Indeed, candidates display different features and some could be too complex to propose from a technical and/or political perspective. The table below presents the scoring of the own resource candidates according to the three criteria.
It shows that statistical based own resources are in general easier to implement and to mobilise quickly. Depending on the call rates, they can generate substantial revenues. However, the quality of statistics differs among them, in particular when it comes to environmental own resources. As for the statistical own resource on company profits, this relies on a harmonised system of European statistics and therefore does not raise any major comparability issues.
Tax candidates can be attractive as they can generate significant amounts of revenues. However, they would require unanimous agreement on the underlying sectoral legislation, which may take time. Experience on some existing proposals such as the Financial Transaction Tax shows the difficulties to reach swift political consensus on that matter.
The EU fair border mechanism seems to raise substantial challenges at international level and would certainly need to be further explored and analysed.
Table 2: Evaluation of the own resources examined
|
Revenue potential
|
Simplicity
|
Fast mobilisation
|
1.Corporate taxation (BEFIT)
|
Good
|
Good
|
Modest
|
2.Statistical own resource based on Company profits
|
Good
|
Good
|
Full
|
3.Financial sector - Financial Transaction Tax (FTT)
|
Adequate
|
Adequate
|
Modest
|
4.EU ‘fair border mechanism’
|
Modest
|
Modest
|
Modest
|
5.Tax on cryptocurrencies
|
Modest
|
Adequate
|
Modest
|
6.Statistical own resource based on Gender pay gap
|
Adequate
|
Adequate
|
Modest
|
7.Statistical own resource based on Food waste
|
Adequate
|
Adequate
|
Good
|
8.Statistical own resource based on E – waste
|
Adequate
|
Adequate
|
Good
|
Scoring:
|
None
|
Modest
|
Adequate
|
Good
|
Full
|
Notes: (1) for more information about the scoring system, see Box 3.
Source: European Commission.
Part 3. The new own resources package
Following the agreement on the Fit for 55 package, the Commission proposes to adjust the first basket of new own resources proposed in December 2021. In line with the inter-institutional agreement, the Commissions proposes to adjust its proposal and puts forward a corporate-related own resource. The assessment made in part 2 shows that the statistical own resource based on company profits could generate revenues and be implemented quickly and has therefore been assessed to be a good candidate.