This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52011SC0892
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT /* SEC/2011/0892 final */
1.
Problem definition
1.1.
The CFP has failed to perform
The current CFP has failed to ensure
sustainable exploitation of living aquatic resources despite the new management
tools introduced in 2002: Long Term Management Plans intended to exploit fish
stocks at sustainable levels and to rebuild overfished stocks, and Regional Advisory Councils, intended to foster dialogue among stakeholders
and with the Commission. The problems underlying this failure are
interdependent. Overcapacity is the main driver for overfishing. However, the
reduction of quotas, intended to curb overfishing, has increased overcapacity
still further. Similarly, overcapacity implies the poor economic performance of
the catching sector — but poor economic performance incentivises overfishing as
a short-term fix for diminishing revenues. It also results in the industry's
repeated calls for public financial support, which maintains overcapacity, and
encourages deviation from scientific advice when setting TACs. With these links
in mind, the problems can be ranked as follows: ·
The main problem of the CFP is the lack of
environmental sustainability due to overfishing. All other problems
contribute to this. Fleet overcapacity, deviation from scientific advice while
setting TACs, and a lack of prioritisation when setting objectives are the main
drivers for overfishing. Relative stability, the high level of discards, poor
compliance and the lack of sufficient scientific advice are additional drivers. · The second problem is poor economic sustainability, particularly
for the catching sector. Many fleets are unprofitable and vulnerable to
external shocks (eg high fuel prices). · The third problem is the lack of social sustainability, which
primarily affects the catching sector and areas dependent on fishing. Low wages
and serious safety hazards mean that the catching sector is not a source of
attractive jobs to potential new generations of fishermen. As a result,
employment, particularly in the catching sector, has been declining for the
last 15 years in many areas dependent on fisheries. · Fourth, the CFP has a very complex legal framework, which
fosters micromanagement and impedes achieving environmental sustainability. · The external dimension of the CFP has also performed worse
than expected, particularly as regards environmental sustainability, but also
in terms of international governance.
1.2.
Who is affected by the CFP and how?
Stakeholder || Description || Key interests Catching sector in the EU || EC vessel owners and crew || Maintaining profitability and livelihoods Dependent businesses & communities || Business and communities dependent upon fisheries || Maintaining profitability and livelihoods Processing sector || Those processing raw material both imported and caught within EC waters || Maintaining profitability and livelihoods, stable supplies Sector regulators || National, regional and local bodies regulating fishing || Ensuring an efficient, effective and practical management framework that balances a wide range of stakeholder needs Sector research || Scientific research bodies contributing to the conservation and management of stocks || Contribution to an effective fisheries management regime through timely access to high quality, robust data || Consumers || Those consuming fisheries products || Availability, cost, quality and nutritional values of fisheries products with varying degrees of environmental scrutiny || Non-EU countries || Fishing sector in competition with EU fleets. Aquaculture producers, exporters to the EU. Authorities in non-EU countries getting payments under FPA || Conflicting interest between those who see the EU as a very important export market and as a source of revenue, and small local fishing communities that face competition from EU fleets in non-EU fisheries over access to local resources || NGOs, civil society and EU citizens || NGOs advocating sustainable management of fisheries The wider public with an interest in and concern for fisheries and the marine environment || To maintain fish populations, marine bio-diversity, and the amenity value of oceans, rivers and lakes ||
1.3.
Why is public intervention necessary?
Fisheries are characterised by the ‘Tragedy
of the Commons’: Individuals operating in their own interests tend to
overexploit a common pool resource, rivalling others as they capture 'their'
share. What one fisherman takes today cannot be caught tomorrow by another. The
harvesting costs imposed on others (fewer fish to catch, damage to the habitat,
etc) are not taken into account by fishermen when they make their fishing
decisions. In the absence of regulatory intervention regarding access, stocks
will be exploited at levels which will lead to their decline and commercial
extinction. That justifies regulatory intervention and implies discarding the ‘No
EU action’ option.
2.
The right for the EU to act
According to Article 3 (d) of the Treaty
of the Functioning of the EU (TFEU), the Union shall have exclusive competence
in the conservation of marine biological resources under the CFP. According to
Article 4 (2d) the Union has shared competences for the rest of the CFP. The last reform of the CFP took place in
2002. It was implemented by Council Regulation (EC) No 2371/2002 of 20 December
2002. Article 35 thereof contains a specific provision for a review by end of
2012 with respect to Chapters II [Conservation and sustainability] and III
[Adjustment of Fishing Capacity]. However, the conclusions of the 2007
Court of Auditors’ special report on the CFP as well as the Commission’s own
assessment of the current CFP, led it to go beyond that obligation and propose
a thorough reform of the CFP.
3.
The objectives of the CFP
3.1.
The objectives of the CFP according to the
Treaty
The objectives of the CFP are set out
in articles 3(d) and 4 (d) and 38 and 39 of the TFEU. Article 11 is also relevant, as it stipulates that
environmental protection requirements must be integrated into the definition
and implementation of the Union’s policies and activities, particularly with a
view to promoting sustainable development. According to
Article 39, the CFP’s objectives, which are the same as for agriculture, are: ·
to increase agricultural productivity by
promoting technical progress and by ensuring the rational development of
agricultural production and the optimum utilisation of the factors of
production, particularly labour; ·
to ensure a fair standard of living for the
agricultural community, in particular by increasing the individual earnings of
persons engaged in agriculture; ·
to stabilise markets; ·
to assure the availability of supplies; ·
to ensure that supplies reach consumers at
reasonable prices. These objectives are the same as those for
the Common Agriculture Policy but have to be seen in the specific context of
the fisheries sector.
3.2.
The general objectives of the reform
The reformed CFP will achieve
environmental, economic and social sustainability as regards exploiting fisheries
resources. From a legal perspective, these objectives are all equally
important, and none can be achieved in isolation. However, environmental sustainability is
the keystone for the success of the CFP. The
analysis in the impact assessment confirmed that ‘without more marked
improvements in stock status, economic and social sustainability will remain
limited’. The problem definition outlined the poor situation of many
stocks. Solving the problem will require aligning fishing pressure with
environmental sustainability.
3.2.1.
Environmental sustainability
Environmental sustainability is understood
as the exploitation of stocks in a way that does not prejudice their future
exploitation. This amounts to applying fishing pressure consistent with their
maximum sustainable yield (MSY), ‘with the aim of achieving these goals for
depleted stocks on an urgent basis, and where possible not later than 2015’. Achieving
environmental sustainability will also ensure compliance with the obligation
that marine environments attain good environmental status by 2020, as set out in
the Marine Strategy Framework Directive. Achieving environmental sustainability
implies: (a) Eliminating overfishing in the short
term; (b) Reducing overcapacity and discards as
much as possible; (c) Putting in place a decision-making
system consistent with long-term sustainability, flexible and adaptable to
local conditions; (d) Encouraging industry to take more responsibility
for outcomes and to comply with legislation; (e) Improving the availability of
scientific advice and economic data.
3.2.2.
Economic sustainability
Economic sustainability means having profitable
fleets that are economically viable over the long term. The same applies to related
processing, ancillary and aquaculture activities, acting within the limits set
by environmental sustainability, operating in the context of the competitive
global market and evolving consumption patterns.
3.2.3.
Social sustainability
Social sustainability means transforming
fisheries and related activities into a source of attractive jobs that enable a
fair standard of living for those who depend on them and ensure the viability
of fishing communities. Social sustainability in these areas must rely on
economic diversification into related maritime activities as well as fishing
itself.
3.2.4.
Other objectives: simplification and reduction
of administrative burden
The reform of
the CFP will need to contribute to the general objectives of the EU as regards
cutting red tape. Simplification implies reducing the number of
regulations and their complexity, and integrating public funding into one
financial instrument. As regards the administrative burden, the reform
does not include any quantifiable macro-objective because the current
Commission’s policy in that field is due to expire by the end of 2012.
4.
The Policy Options
Option Status Quo (SQ) is continuing the current CFP, but taking into account recent
legislation, in particular LTMPs in the pipeline, the Control Regulation and
the IUU Regulation. The SQ amounts to the CFP as it will be in January 2013.
This serves as a benchmark for all reform options. Option 1 seeks to achieve environmental
sustainability within a flexible time horizon while limiting short-term
negative economic and social impacts. Its main components are: a) achieving Fmsy as soon as possible, but
with a maximum inter-annual TAC reduction of -25 % (as in current LTMPs).
As a result, some stocks will reach Fmsy after 2015 (but no later than 2020). b) use of the ‘most valuable’ rule for
mixed fisheries; c) use of Individual Transferable Rights
(ITRs) to eliminate overcapacity. ITR would be compulsory for industrial fleets
and voluntary for small-scale fleets, and will be implemented over four years.
Transferability will be limited to within MS; d) public financial support focused on the
reform; fleet subsidies (Axis 1 of the current EFF) will be discontinued; e) the CMO focused on marketing, promotion
and local product market differentiation; f) costs of fishing licences under the
Fishery Partnership Agreements (FPA) will be gradually borne by ship-owners. Option 2 seeks to
achieve environmental sustainability without any flexibility regarding time
horizon. This option aims to achieve environmental
sustainability by the end of 2015, irrespective of the short-term economic and
social impacts. It includes the very strong assumption that sufficient
scientific advice will be available within this very short time frame. Its main components
are: a) Fmsy to be
achieved within four years from the start of the reform. b) use of the ‘most
sensitive’ rule for mixed-fisheries; c) use of ITR to
eliminate overcapacity, but with intra-MS transferability; d) public financial
support and CMO discontinued and e) FPAs to be
gradually terminated. Option 3 seeks to achieve environmental
sustainability within a time framework while minimising negative social
impacts. This option minimises short-term economic
and social impacts by allowing the sector extra time to reach Fmsy and to
implement ITR. Its main components are: a) achieving Fmsy as soon as possible but
with a maximum inter-annual TAC reduction of -15 %, so that more stocks
would reach Fmsy levels only towards the end of the period. b) use of ‘most valuable’ rule for mixed
fisheries; c) use of ITR as in Option 1, but with a
longer implementation period; d) public financial support focused on the
reform but with more attention given to social issues; e) limited overhaul of the CMO, leaving
some forms of market intervention. Option 4 seeks to achieve environmental
sustainability within a flexible time horizon while limiting short-term
negative economic and social impacts but without EU-led ITR. This option is equivalent to Option 1, but without ITRs addressing
overcapacity. MS are free to decide whether to implement the ITR. Two further options were also analysed: Option 1a amounts to Option 1, but uses Option 2’s ‘most sensitive’ rule for
mixed fisheries. Option 2a amounts to Option 2, but uses
the -25 % maximum inter-annual TAC reduction as in Option 1.
5.
Assessment of options
The methodology used defined: a) measurable targets for the objectives
and b) a set of impact indicators to capture
progress towards the objectives. Additional indicators address governance,
administrative burden and simplification. The value of indicators is measured
and compared for 2012, 2017 and 2022 (2020 for environmental performance). The impact
assessment combines quantitative and qualitative analysis.
5.1.
Environmental sustainability
All reform options dramatically outperform
the SQ Option in terms of environmental sustainability. Option 2 appears to
perform best both in the short and the long term. However, its environmental
component is unfeasible, due to the very short time remaining in which to
develop the necessary scientific advice. Option 1a performs best.
Options 1, 2a and 3 result in a very good performance, although below that of
Option 1a, particularly by 2020. The maintenance of overcapacity in Option 4
significantly reduces its environmental performance. Option 1a has the largest potential for
reducing unwanted catch by combining the best environmental performance, the ‘most
sensitive’ mixed fisheries rule, ITRs and the regionalisation component. The ‘most
valuable’ rule in Option 1 limits its potential for discard reduction. The SQ Option and Option 4 result in the
largest fleets, short- and long-term. Options 1 and 3 show the largest
reductions in fleets.
5.2.
Economic sustainability
The SQ Option does not achieve economic
sustainability. Options 1 (and 1a) perform best both short- and long-term.
Option 2 performs somewhat better than Option 2a and 3. Option 4 performs
significantly worse, due to the maintenance of overcapacity. The processing sector dependent on imported
raw material would be unaffected. For processing local landings, Options 1 and
1a give the best short and long-term results. For ancillary services, dependent
on fleet size, the best performance would be under the SQ Option, followed by
that of Option 4.
5.3.
Social sustainability
All options imply a substantial decline in employment
for the catching sector. Given a smaller fleet reduction, this decline under
the SQ Option is relatively lowest, closely followed by Option 4. However, in
term of wages, the performance of the SQ Option is very poor and that of Option
1 (and 1a) is very good. The combination of employment and wages shows that Options
1 (and 1a) would yield the best performance.
5.4.
Simplification and administrative burden
In terms of simplification, any
option will outperform the SQ. The regional approaches under options 1 (and
1a), 2 (and 2a) and 4 should also further simplify the CFP. In terms of management costs,
getting scientific advice and economic data would be a major addition. The
introduction of ITRs would imply some administrative burden for MS and
the EU; part of these costs might be passed on to the sector. Finally, the
elimination of FPAs or the payment of access costs by vessel owners would
reduce management costs at EU level. In sum, the SQ Option would be the
cheapest, followed by Option 4, as there would be no costs associated with
ITRs. Option 1a would be most costly, due to the need to obtain scientific
advice about the most sensitive stocks.
5.5.
External dimension
The best performance corresponds to Option
1 (and 1a).
6.
Comparison of Options: the preferred option(s)
Figure 1 —
Comparison of Options. EU level 2017 Figure 2 —
Comparison of Options. EU level 2022 Overall Options 1 and 1a offer the best combined
results. A study of four regions dependent on fishing (Brittany, Galicia,
Sicily and Scotland) confirms these results at regional level. Option 1 (and
1a) also performs best in terms of the external dimension.
7.
Monitoring and evaluation
Yearly progress will be monitored on the
basis of scientific advice, for the Fmsy objective, and of economic/social data
received from MS for economic and social sustainability. Regarding evaluation, it will take some
time for the reformed CFP to bear fruit, so a mid-term review should potentially
be carried out for 2017, for which the modelling has been done. The review
should compare the projected and actual values of the following indicators: · Environmental impacts: stocks at Fmsy,
fleet size and progress in ITR · Economic impacts: income, GVA,
revenue/break-even revenue and net profit margin · Social impacts: Employment (FTE) and
crew wage per FTE Figures for 2017 would be available in
2019. The evaluation should therefore be carried out in 2019.