This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52013SC0012
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2012/34/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, as regards the opening of the market for domestic passenger transport services by rail and the governance of the railway infrastructure
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2012/34/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, as regards the opening of the market for domestic passenger transport services by rail and the governance of the railway infrastructure
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2012/34/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, as regards the opening of the market for domestic passenger transport services by rail and the governance of the railway infrastructure
/* SWD/2013/012 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2012/34/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, as regards the opening of the market for domestic passenger transport services by rail and the governance of the railway infrastructure /* SWD/2013/012 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the
European Parliament and of the Council amending
Directive 2012/34/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21
November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, as regards the
opening of the market for domestic passenger transport services by rail and the
governance of the railway
infrastructure Disclaimer: This impact assessment commits only the
Commission's services involved in its preparation and does not prejudge the
final form of any decision to be taken by the Commission TABLE OF
CONTENT 1.
Introduction........................................................................................................................... 5 2.
Procedural
issues and consultation of interested parties........................................................... 6 3.
Problem
definition.................................................................................................................. 9 4.
Objectives........................................................................................................................... 31 5.
Policy
options...................................................................................................................... 34 6.
Analysis
of impacts.............................................................................................................. 39 7.
Comparing
the options......................................................................................................... 59 8.
Monitoring
and evaluation.................................................................................................... 61 Annexes Annex I – The
4th Package – The 'Big' Picture.................................................................... 63 Annex II – Consultation
analysis........................................................................................... 72 Annex III – Evidence
of discriminatory practices.................................................................... 85 Annex IV – Options
analysis.................................................................................................. 92 Annex V – Analysis
of the costs and benefits of further separation requirements................... 108 Annex VI – Analysis
of social impact.................................................................................... 126 Annex VII – Governance
and access conditions to rail related facilities................................... 127 Annex VIII – Summary
of the conference “The Last Mile towards
the 4th Railway Package”.................................................................................. 133 Annex IX – Glossary and Acronyms..................................................................................... 157
1.
Introduction
1.1
Background In
its 2011 White Paper on transport policy adopted on 28 March 2011 (hereinafter
the 2011 White Paper), the Commission announced its vision to establish a Single
European Railway Area and clarified that this objective implies creating an
internal railway market where European railway undertakings can provide
services without unnecessary technical and administrative barriers. [1] Several
policy initiatives have recognised the potential of rail infrastructure as a
sustainable backbone for the internal market and a driver of sustainable
growth. The European Council conclusions of January 2012 highlight the
importance of unleashing the growth-creating potential of a fully integrated
Single Market, including measures with regard to network industries.[2]
Furthermore, the Commission Communication on Action for Stability, Growth and
Jobs adopted on 30 May 2012 stresses the importance of further reducing the
regulatory burden and barriers to entry in the rail sector, making
country-specific recommendations to that aim.[3]
In the same manner, on 6th June 2012 the Commission adopted the
Communication on strengthening the governance of the single market, which also
stresses the importance of the transport sector.[4] At
the same time, important financial means have been made available for
investment in rail infrastructure by Member States as well as through EU
structural funds. In addition, the Commission has proposed for the next 2014-2020
multi-annual financial framework the creation of a new infrastructure
instrument supporting the priorities in Transport, Energy and
Telecommunications: the "Connecting Europe Facility" (CEF)[5]. Of the total €50-billion
envelope €31.7 billion are allocated to transport infrastructure. The
EU railway market has seen important changes in the recent decade. They were
gradually introduced by three legislative "railway packages" (with
some accompanying acts) intended to open up national markets and make railways
more competitive and interoperable at the EU level, while maintaining a high
level of safety. The most recent development is the adoption (passed 2nd
reading in Parliament in July, to be adopted by the Council before the end of
2012) of the recast of the 1st Railway Package, which, in addition
to legislative simplification and consolidation, reinforces existing provisions
on competition issues, regulatory oversight and financial architecture of the
railway sector[6]. Despite the
considerable development of the 'EU acquis' establishing an internal market for
rail transport services, the modal share of rail in intra-EU transport has
remained modest. Therefore the Commission has planned to put forward the 4th
Railway Package (cf. Annex I for further details) in order to enhance the
quality and efficiency of rail transport services by removing the remaining
identified obstacles of different types, and by thereby fostering the
performance and competitiveness of the railway sector. As announced by the 2011
White Paper, these issues will be addressed by different initiatives: ·
Removing
remaining administrative and technical barriers, in particular by
establishing a common approach to safety and interoperability rules to increase
economies of scale for railway undertakings active across the EU, decreasing
administrative costs and accelerating common administrative procedures, as well
removing disguised discrimination; ·
Opening
the domestic rail passenger market, granting open access rights but also
addressing competition for public service contracts (PSCs)[7]
award process, in order to complete the process of rail passenger market
opening; accompanying measures will facilitate Member States' retaining
integrated timetabling and ticketing systems where this benefits the passenger; ·
Optimising
the governance of infrastructure management, in particular by
ensuring that the infrastructure manager performs a consistent set of functions
that optimises the efficient use of infrastructure capacity and ensuring
effective non-discriminatory access to the infrastructure. 1.2
Scope of the impact assessment This
impact assessment focuses on the third point mentioned above. It draws in
particular on the experience gained in all 25[8]
Member States which have opened the rail freight and international passenger
markets under EU law as well as those that have already chosen to take measures
to open their domestic rail passenger markets to competition. This
impact assessment will not deal with the issue of access and governance of
rail-related services (such as passenger stations, freight terminals,
maintenance facilities) as this has been already been addressed recently by the
Recast of the First Railway Package. However, since this issue is directly
linked with the governance and the conditions of access to the railway
networks, this question is presented under Annex VII of the present document.
2.
Procedural issues and consultation of interested
parties
2.1
Organisation and Planning This
IA is prepared by DG MOVE to support the legislative initiative on the
governance of railway infrastructure in the Single European Railway Area
(Agenda Planning number 2011/MOVE/…). The Commission proposal in this regard
will include amendments to the Directive of the European Parliament and of the
Council establishing a single European railway area[9]. An
Impact Assessment Steering Group was created in December 2011 and has been
actively consulted during the IA process. This Steering Group has counted on
the membership of DG CLIMA, COMP, ECFIN, EMPL, ENER, ENV, ENTR, LS, MARKT,
REGIO, SANCO, EEAS, TRADE ELARG and SG and met 8 times, with the last meeting
being held on 4 October of 2012. The IASG has been re-consulted in writing on
the final draft on 8 October 2012. 2.2
Consultation and Expertise Expertise In
order to support the Commission in the impact assessment process, an external
consultant was tasked to prepare a support study[10]
and to undertake a targeted consultation. The study started in December 2011
and the final report was delivered in November 2012. Consultation of stakeholders To
gather the views of the different stakeholders, a comprehensive mix of targeted
consultation methods completed by a Eurobarometer survey was preferred to an
open consultation for two main reasons: (1) The technical
nature of some of the questions: not all stakeholders could have been expected
to have a knowledge of the subject-matter, in particular passengers. (2) Representativeness
of passengers' responses would have not been ensured without a structured
sampling of responses, and in particular the Eurobarometer offered the
possibility to interview a carefully structured sample of 25.000 respondents in
their own language. Within
the main consultation organised by the external consultant (from 1 March 'til
16 April, responses obtained up to mid-June were accepted), tailored
questionnaires were sent to each group of main stakeholders - railway
undertakings, infrastructure managers, public transport ministries, safety
authorities, ministries, representative bodies, social partners etc. The
consultation reached out to 427 rail stakeholders and had a 40% response rate.
The consultant and/or the Commission services also held face-to-face interviews
in 10 Member States - Austria, Czech Republic, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Netherlands, Sweden, Poland and the United Kingdom. The
views of passengers were collected through a Eurobarometer survey, which
reached out to more than 25.000 respondents, with a representative sample
(circa 1000 per Member State) of respondents in each of the 25 Member States
with railways. A
stakeholder hearing was held on the 29 May 2012 (with some 85 participants).
Commission services have also met with sector representatives on an on-going
basis throughout 2012 to listen to their views, including organisations such as
CER (incumbent railway undertakings), EPTO (private passenger transport
operators), ERFA (private rail freight operators), ETF (transport workers), EPF
(passenger federations), EIM (independent infrastructure managers) and UITP
(urban transport operators). The consultation process was concluded by a large
conference “Last Mile towards the 4th Railway Package” with 420 participants
representing the entire sector in September 2012. The
majority of stakeholders agreed during the targeted consultation that the
quality of rail services and the competitiveness of the sector in the EU were
affected by different access barriers for RUs. 69% found different
interpretation of legislation to be an issue. Infrastructure capacity
constraints were considered to be the main access barrier for RUs (quoted by
83%). The
result of the consultation shows that views are highly polarised regarding the
appropriateness of solutions to these problems (e.g. how to ensure independent
and efficient governance of railway infrastructure). Some stakeholders - a
large majority of transport ministries, competition authorities, regulatory
bodies, independent infrastructure managers and RUs, passengers and freight
forwarders associations - advocated a complete separation which would ensure
full transparency and a level playing field for all operators. Other
stakeholders, in particular holding companies, infrastructure managers
depending on such holdings and workers' representatives, argued that there is
no empirical evidence about the benefits of complete separation and that some
scientific literature indicates that it could lead to higher transaction costs.
These stakeholders think that a stronger role of regulatory oversight could be
sufficient to solve the issues. 64% of respondents support the idea of creating
of a specific body of representatives from all infrastructure users to ensure
interests are taken into account in a non-discriminatory way. In
line with the IA Guidelines on the consultation of social partners, the
Sectoral Social Dialogue Committee was consulted on 26 March and 19 June 2012,
in particular with regard to the options and social impacts. However, during
the meetings worker organisations did not wish to position themselves on any of
the options related to the IM governance, as they considered them as supporting
measures in favour of market opening, a principle to which they were
fundamentally opposed. Finally the network of the Committee of Regions was used
to reach local and regional passenger transport authorities. Such consultation
was open from 14 May till 21 June. Throughout
the consultation process the Commission has taken a proactive approach to
prompt stakeholders to participate. Given that all relevant parties have been
given an opportunity to express their opinions the minimum consultation
standards of Commission have been met. More detailed overview of the
consultation process, representativeness and content of responses is provided
in Annex II. 2.3
Impact assessment Board This
impact assessment was reviewed by the Commission's Impact Assessment Board on
7 November and 30 November 2012. Based on the Board's recommendations, the
impact assessment has been revised as follows: The
problem definition has been revised to make it more robust. Additional
anecdotal evidence, benchmarks between comparable Member States, in particular
to examine to which extent the institutional setting in place can influence the
success of liberalisation and improve the intensity of infrastructure use have
been added. Where relevant, analogies with other network industries have been
made. The context of the initiative has been further clarified with a
presentation of the current approach and on-going reforms in Member States, as
well as with additional explanations on its relation with the Recast and with
on-going infringement procedures. The content of each possible policy option,
their differences and their implications, as well as the criteria for screening
them have been further explained. The definition, analysis and comparison of alternative
policy scenarios presenting (a) only efficiency measures and (b) efficiency
measures in combination with 2 different separation modes, have been
strengthened with further discussion. Where possible, a quantification of the
costs and benefits related to each policy scenario has been added. Furthermore
quantitative estimates of the impact of this initiative, when combined with the
other initiatives of the 4th Railway Package aimed at opening the
domestic rail passenger markets, have been added. The methodology retained for
the calculation of both costs and benefits has been more clearly explained. Stakeholders'
views have been further detailed throughout the report and the choice of a mix
of targeted consultations completed by a Eurobarometer survey justified.
Finally the presentation of the report has been improved with the provision of
references of the studies, reports and decisions quoted as well as web links,
where available. Graphs and figures have been revised and further explained, referencing
of stakeholders opinion and studies improved, and the map demonstrating the
structural models of Member States has been incorporated. Notwithstanding,
where relevant the limits of available quantification have also been
stipulated.
3.
Problem definition
3.1
Description of the current framework for the
governance of railway infrastructure 3.1.1
Rail infrastructure as
natural monopoly Railway
infrastructure is a natural monopoly[11].
Its construction is very expensive and consequently it is not economically
justified that each railway undertaking builds its own tracks. Therefore there
is a need for specific rules in order to ensure optimal management and
utilisation of the shared infrastructure by different railway undertakings. Even
then the construction and maintenance of railway infrastructure is mostly not
commercially viable and relies on public support. Revenues collected by
infrastructure charges are typically absorbed by maintenance needs. Against the
background of growing pressure on public finances, improving the efficiency of
railways is more crucial than ever. This
intrinsically raises two challenges from an economic and regulatory point of
view: -
Efficient
management challenge: the current governance does not provide sufficient
incentives and means for infrastructure managers (hereinafter IM) to respond to
the needs of the transport services market and to contribute to the
optimisation of the performance of the sector taken as a whole; -
Equal
access challenge: Given that historically infrastructure was
owned by incumbent rail operators, conflicts of interest naturally lead to
discriminatory/protectionist practices of incumbents which impair competition
in rail services. Eliminating the incentives for the incumbent to discriminate
against its competitors via different infrastructure management functions is
arguably even more necessary in the rail sector than in the electricity or
telecom grids, as the rail IMs have a wider range of services and therefore
more means for discrimination. 3.1.2
Infrastructure
management functions Infrastructure management relates to
different activities which can be categorised in different manners but
correspond basically to the four following elements: a)
Infrastructure
development. This includes responsibilities for the ultimate network
planning, financial and investment planning and building on the basis of market
analysis, business plans, fund raising from public authorities and financial
markets. Simplistically, this means building new tracks, depots and stations to
increase the size of the rail network. b)
Track
access charging. This includes the determination and collection of charges
but also more generally infrastructure marketing – i.e. relations with
customers (railway undertakings and other categories of applicants for
infrastructure capacity), public authorities and regulators. In practice, this
means that the IM markets access to the network. c)
Infrastructure
operations, including path allocation and traffic management. This
includes the provision of services necessary for infrastructure access on a
long or short term basis through assessment of availability and allocation of
individual train paths, timetabling, traffic management, control command and
signalling as well as traffic information services. In short, this means that
the IM is responsible for the organisation of the traffic on its network,
including in case of traffic disturbances. d)
Infrastructure
maintenance. This includes infrastructure upgrade and renewal and is
linked to asset management activities. The IM is thus responsible for
organising and conducting the maintenance of the network assets. According
to current legislation, the functions of the IM may be allocated to different
bodies or firms. On the one hand, the two "essential functions" of IM
- path allocation and track access charging - may be assigned to an allocation
body and charging body (See under Section 3.2.1.2). 3.1.3
The current European
regulatory framework for the governance of the railway infrastructure The
Commission has long considered that the improvement of the functioning of the
internal market should stimulate the rail industry to become more efficient and
responsive to customers’ needs. Thus the development of EU rail market access
legislation has progressively encouraged market opening. Within
this framework, certain degree of separation between infrastructure management
and transport operations have been introduced under EU law with the aim to
thereby prevent discriminatory practices distorting competition in integrated
structures[12].
This policy is in line with the general Commission policy for the regulation of
network industries (see Box 1 below). Box 1 - Analogies with other network
industries: link between market opening and separation As highlighted in the report
on the market functioning of network industries (Electronic Communications,
Energy and Transport) produced for the Economic Policy Committee and published
by the Commission on 16 November 2012, network industries share common
characteristics. On the one hand, the infrastructure segment displays features
of natural monopoly (high sunk costs and non-duplicable network) and is subject
to regulation on pricing and access to the network. This applies to the
transmission and distribution networks in e-communications (backbone, backhaul
and last mile) energy and transport infrastructures (road, rail, ports and
airports). On the other hand, competition needs to be ensured in network
services, as long as each operator gets a fair and transparent access to the
infrastructure. These industries are intrinsically
characterized by the co-existence of competitive and regulated segments with
natural monopolies, sunk costs, and economies of scale due to the crucial role
played by the underlying infrastructure. Given the economic costs associated
with monopolistic rents, these sectors have thus been reshaped by major
regulatory reforms over the past two decades, mainly in order to promote
competition and safeguard consumers' rights. In the case of companies which
integrate infrastructure and the related upstream or downstream services, it is
difficult for other operators on these related markets to compete against such
a company, since the control over the infrastructure confers a number of
competitive advantages to the integrated company: not only does it have
exclusive information about costs and other items of the infrastructure which
are relevant for competitors, but it also has the possibility to exploit the
control over the infrastructure in order to limit the actions of the competitors.
Therefore on the one hand market opening of such network industries requires a
separation of accounts which allows a transparency of costs of and charges for
the infrastructure and on the other it must be ensured that the decisions
related to the management of the infrastructure are taken in an independent
way. European legislation in all the network industries mentioned above has
opted for the unbundling of infrastructure and related services as a preferred
means to guarantee non-discriminatory access to the infrastructure, and to make
market-opening a success. This was done in the air
transport sector. After the three liberalisation packages adopted between
1987 and 1993, separation measures were introduced to ensure access of airlines
to the necessary resources and services in airports: Council Regulation (EEC)
No 95/93 on common rules for the allocation of slots at Community airports and Regulation
(EC) No 793/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 April 2004
amending this Regulation introduced slot allocation bodies and ground handling
services which had to be independent from air carriers. The aim was to prevent
dominant air carriers from controlling these functions of the
infrastructure manager and services with a view to discriminate their
competitors. Market opening in the
telecom sector followed the same principles. Regulation (EC) No 2887/2000 of 18 December 2000 provided for an
unbundled access to the local loop. The Regulation addresses the problem of the lack of
competition on the local network where incumbent operators dominated the market
for voice telephony services and high-speed Internet access. Allowing new
entrants access to the local loop has led to increased competition and
stimulated technological innovation on the local access market. It has not only
produced much lower charges for telecom users, but also encouraged the
provision of a large range of competitive electronic communications services. In the energy sector,
the process of market opening has been launched in the mid-90s to enable all
consumers to benefit fully from competition and fair prices. The Second energy
Package of 2003 introduced some limited unbundling provisions, with the
requirement that network operations be legally and functionally separated from
supply and generation or production activities. The functional independence was
described with some limited safeguards concerning the structure, but
essentially it was only about legal separation. However, the Commission’s
Energy Sector Inquiry, launched in June 2005, identified a number of areas
where the market was not working properly. This concerned in particular the
continuing market power of incumbents in many Member States, stemming from an
inadequate separation of network and supply companies and leading to
foreclosure of new entrants and investments. The integration of network and
energy generation in the same companies also caused an unwillingness of
integrated national incumbents to make investments in cross-border
infrastructure, since integrated companies have an incentive to protect their
own home markets from competing energy producers from other EU countries. This
has undermined cross border integration of networks. That is why the Commission
proposed in 2007, in its Third Energy Package, an ownership unbundling of the
network from energy supply and generation activities. In addition to the
ownership unbundling, the option of an independent system operator (ISO) was
proposed, giving the member states also the opportunity to let the transmission
networks remain under the ownership of energy groups, but transferring
operation and control of their day-to-day business to an independent body. A
third possibility was added at the request of a number of Member States during
inter-institutional debates: the ITO model. This model, the Independent
Transmission Operator (ITO), envisages energy companies retaining ownership of
their transmission networks, but the transmission subsidiaries would be legally
independent joint stock companies operating under their own brand name and with
a number of very strict structural safeguards ensuring the autonomy of the ITO
from the holding company. These safeguards contain the appointment and
supervision of board members, the prohibition of financial flows between ITO
and the holding, the decisions on investments and many other strict
"Chinese walls" which practically prevent the holding company from
influencing the day-to-day management of the ITO. The addition of the ITO model
to the package allowed a compromise and the adoption of the Third Energy
Package in 2009. Because Chinese walls under the ITO model are very burdensome,
one can observe that Member States tend to prefer the full ownership
unbundling. For the same reasons, in a Member State where the ITO model was
retained, such as Germany, the two biggest infrastructures (out of four) were
sold by energy holdings to third parties. For
more than twenty years, Directive 91/440/EEC[13]
has provided for the separation of accounts between rail infrastructure and
transport operation to ensure financial transparency and avoid
cross-subsidisation between infrastructure and operation management. Following
the First Railway Package adopted in 2001, additional separation requirements
were introduced through Directive 2001/12/EC[14]
and Directive 2001/14/EC[15].
The latter stipulates that the "essential functions" of IMs – train
path allocation and infrastructure charging - must be separated from transport
operations in legal, organisational and decision making terms. In addition, the
same Directive foresees that Member States have independent Regulatory Bodies
in place to oversee railway markets and to act as an appeal body for rail
companies. The
Recast of the First Railway Package (hereinafter 'the Recast') merging nine
previous legislative texts was proposed by the Commission in September 2010
with the
objective to strengthen
the power of regulatory bodies, improve the framework for investment in rail,
and ensure fairer access to rail infrastructure as well as rail related
facilities and services. Following a final vote of approval in the
European Parliament on 3 July 2012 and adoption by Council on 29 October 2012,
these new EU rules will be transposed by 2015. Despite
requests from some Members of the European Parliament and specific Member States during inter-institutional negotiations, issues related to the separation
between infrastructure management and transport operations were finally not
directly addressed by the Recast. The Commission argued in particular that
further stakeholder consultation and a robust impact analysis was required. As
a final compromise, the Recast calls on the Commission to act by December 2012:
"the Commission shall, if appropriate, propose legislative measures […]
to develop appropriate conditions to ensure non-discriminatory access to
infrastructure, building on the existing separation requirements between
infrastructure management and transport operations, and shall assess the impact
of any such measures". Further
details on the current legal framework are provided in section 3.2 as part of
the baseline developments. 3.1.4
The implementation of
the EU regulatory framework by the Member States Member
States have chosen different models of governance to implement this
legislation. More than half of the Member States with a rail transport system
(13 out of 25) went beyond what is required by EU law and opted for an
institutional separation between (a) a fully-fledged IM in charge of all the IM
functions described under section 3.1.2 and (b) the transport operators. These
Member States are listed in category 1 in Table 1. Others have chosen to
establish more complicated structures. Four Member States in category 3 kept a
fully integrated structure (with only separation of accounts between
infrastructure management and transport operations) but delegated the two
essential IM functions to external bodies (called charging and capacity
allocation bodies). Some Member States established a holding structure with a
legally separated subsidiary in charge of infrastructure management (categories
2 and 5). Ireland and the United Kingdom (in respect of Northern Ireland) benefit from an exemption from separation requirements until 15 March
2013 and have until now maintained a fully integrated structure in charge of
both transport operations and infrastructure management, including IM essential
functions. Table 1 –
Institutional settings in the Member States Category || IM responsibilities || Level of independence || Member States 1 || IM in charge of all IM functions (incl. capacity allocation and charging) || IM institutionally independent from any railway undertaking || Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Denmark, UK (for the part of Great Britain), Estonia, Finland, Greece, Netherlands, Portugal, Romania, Spain, Sweden and Slovakia 2 || IM in charge of all IM functions (incl. capacity allocation and charging) || Legally independent IM owned by a holding company which also owns and controls a railway undertaking but with strong guarantees of organisational and decision-making independence in relation to the railway undertaking || Belgium and Latvia 3 || IM in charge of IM functions with the exception of the essential functions (capacity allocation and charging) under the responsibility of a separate body || IM integrated in a structure responsible for transport operations Separate body in charge of essential functions institutionally independent || Hungary, Lithuania, Luxembourg and Slovenia 4 || IM in charge of the essential functions (capacity allocation and charging) but having delegated specific parts of the essential function capacity allocation and other IM functions (e.g. maintenance) to a railway undertaking || IM institutionally independent from any railway undertaking || France 5 || IM in charge of all IM functions (incl. capacity allocation and charging) || Legally independent IM owned by a holding company which also owns and controls one of the operators with limited guarantees of organisational and decision-making independence in relation to the railway undertaking || Austria, Germany, Italy and Poland 6 || IM in charge of all IM functions (incl. capacity allocation and charging || IM integrated in a structure responsible for transport operations and || Ireland and the United Kingdom (for the part of Northern Ireland) The
Commission is, however, of the opinion that not all Member States have
implemented the legislation properly and has accordingly launched a number of
infringement procedures concerning in particular three groups: ·
Category
3 Member States having integrated IMs working alongside an independent charging
and path allocation body, in so far as in cases of disruption on the network
the path allocation is performed via traffic management by the incumbent rail
operator. ·
Category
5 Member States, with holding companies in which the IM is a controlled
subsidiary and where the guarantees of decision-making independence from the
railway holding are missing or insufficient in the view of the Commission. ·
Category
4 - France, where parts of the essential function of path allocation and
traffic management have been delegated by the independent IM to the incumbent
railway undertaking. 3.1.5
On-going reforms in
Member States As
a consequence of these infringement procedures, because of the termination of
the on-going derogation as well as national debates on the benefits of
separation, six Members States are in the process of reforming the
institutional structure of their national rail sector: Belgium is currently
in the process of reviewing its legislation to ensure institutional separation
between the IM and the incumbent. The national government indicated that it
intends to submit such reform to the national Parliament by the end of the
year. The Polish government has also indicated at several occasions its
intention to dissolve the existing holding and separate institutionally the IM
and the incumbent. However it has recently announced that such reform would be
postponed to focus efforts on the absorption of EU funds for rail
infrastructure projects. In Hungary, public authorities have also indicated
that preparations for further separation are on-going but the exact timing and
content of such reform remains uncertain. In Italy the newly created independent
transport authority has been tasked to issue recommendations to the national
government on separation between the IM and the incumbent. The issuance of such
recommendations is due by 30 June 2013. The
termination of the derogation applicable to Ireland until 15 March 2013 will
also lead to a reform of the national rail sector. Irish authorities appear
inclined to establish a legally independent IM owned by a holding company but with
strong guarantees of organisational and decision-making independence in
relation to the incumbent railway undertaking. France announced on
30 October 2012 the creation a new fully fledged infrastructure manager
grouping RFF with the SNCF services active in infrastructure management (DCF
for traffic management and SNCF Infra for maintenance). This new infrastructure
manager should be attached to the incumbent operator SNCF in a new grouping
called "Pole ferroviaire public unifié". However the legal form of
this grouping will only be decided next year. French authorities indicated publicly,
that they are willing to put in place all the necessary safeguards to ensure
the absence of conflicts of interest between the infrastructure manager and the
incumbent and to prevent discriminatory practices. No
other Member State has indicated so far its intention to review its
institutional settings. Germany and Austria do not appear to be willing to
abandon their holding model. However German regional authorities awarding
public service contracts and new entrants active on the German market
repeatedly requested the introduction of institutional separation. The
coalition agreement concluded in 2009 by the political parties of the current
majority in the Bundestag foresaw that the independence of infrastructure
management should be guaranteed, profit transfers excluded and infrastructure
revenues used exclusively in favour of infrastructure. In
Member States such as Finland, Romania, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom, the current institutional separation is largely supported, including so far
by national incumbents. In the United Kingdom, the McNulty study commissioned
by the previous government proposed to test "alliancing" as a way to
ensure better alignment between the infrastructure manager and the railway
undertakings in charge of franchises. However, even in the most advanced type
of alliances to be tested, the current institutional separation would not be
questioned. Similarly the national governments in the Netherland and Czech Republic have not indicated so far their intention to modify the current
institutional settings in absence of EU reform, despite calls from their
national incumbent (respectively NS and CD) to reintegrate. The
current situation in all 25 Member States with a rail transport system and the
possible reforms mentioned above are illustrated by Map 1. Map 1 - Current institutional settings and announced reforms
in Member States 3.2
Description of the problem In
its 2010 Communication concerning the development of a Single European Railway
Area[16],
the Commission explained that "competition between railway undertakings is
still limited by various factors stemming from the protectionist behaviours of
historical incumbent operators and the collusive management of rail
infrastructure, which, being a natural monopoly, should be accessible to all
applicants in a fair and non-discriminatory manner. Insufficient transparency
of market conditions and ineffective functioning of the institutional framework
in most Member States continue to make the provision of competitive rail services
difficult. Operators entering a new market continue to face discrimination in
obtaining access to the infrastructure and rail-related services, which are
often owned and operated by the incumbent rail undertaking. Member States’
regulatory bodies encounter difficulties in carrying out their supervision
duties over IMs, in particular to ensure non-discriminatory treatment of new
entrants and to check whether charging principles and accounting separation are
properly applied." The
key issue addressed by this IA is that, despite regulatory developments in
recent years, the current governance of railway infrastructure in the EU still
causes problems of (1) network inefficiencies and (2) discrimination
in infrastructure access, preventing the smooth functioning of the Single
European Railway area. Accordingly, the analysis of problems has been grouped
under efficient management and equal access challenges. Box 2: Key issue
of availability of data Key issue of availability of
data Evidence used to support the
problem definition is mostly anecdotal for a number of reasons. ·
Given the
very different models of IM governance, regulatory practices and level
of competition on domestic rail markets, comparisons between Member States are
often difficult. For this reason, the statistical comparisons provided under
this report for benchmarking purposes exclude Member States whose performances
are overly determined by geographical and technical factors (peripheral Member
States with an isolated rail network and/or with track gauge different from the
main network: Baltic States, Finland, Spain, Portugal and Greece). As far as
IM efficiency is concerned, statistical benchmarking remains problematic
and inconclusive as efficiency very much depends on the national cost structures,
characteristics of the network, management practices or commodities transported
but also on the level of public support and business climate. ·
Furthermore,
studies prepared on functioning of rail models in other major economies outside
Europe (e.g. in USA, Canada, Russia, Japan, China) should be interpreted with
care. They do not allow comparison between separated and integrated structures
and can only evaluate whether performance of an integrated company has evolved
positively over time. But these countries are organised with a single RU
enjoying a monopoly and do not provide indications on the best possible model
for the EU rail system which is already characterised by a single market with
competition between different operators. ·
The same
type of concerns exist regarding evidence on discrimination in terms of
access to infrastructure. A low number of complaints can be, on the one hand,
an indication of a well-functioning open market where conflicts are prevented
by structural measures. On the other hand, there might be no complaints in a
closed market where new entrants have no trust on regulatory interventions.
When markets are only formally open to competition and there is no entrant to
submit complains, discriminatory practices are particularly hard to detect. ·
By
definition, the lack of financial transparency is an element which is
difficult to assess and quantify. Therefore, assessment of the various impacts
of distortions of competition caused by possible cross-financing between
infrastructure and rail operations can be made only on a case by case basis. However, all the evidence and
information collected from stakeholders is convergent and indicates that the
problems discussed below could significantly affect the benefits of the Single
European Railway Area and, in particular limit the impact of rail market
opening initiatives. Anecdotal evidence is referred to under this Section 3.2.
This evidence is further substantiated and completed in Annex III. 3.2.1
Efficient management
challenge 3.2.1.1
IMs are not sufficiently
market oriented Since
railway infrastructure is a natural monopoly and its construction and
maintenance relies heavily on public funding, IMs tend to
manage the infrastructure giving priority to the instructions received from the
public authorities and to neglect the needs expressed by users – railway
undertakings.
In this context, construction of new lines but also maintenance and closure of
existing ones may be dictated by political considerations rather than an
in-depth assessment of potential market developments. According to the Everis study[17],
path allocation management shows that IMs tend to be reactive rather than
proactive. They respond to applications for paths rather than trying to
optimize the use made of infrastructure. . IMs may fail to have a sufficient knowledge of
the market, the needs and the business environment in which the infrastructure
users operate. They may not be in a position to respond adequately and
comprehensively to the operational constraints faced by their users. In some cases,
IMs may neglect in particular the needs expressed by small operators and new
entrants. This could lead to suboptimal use of resources and limit the
development of rail operators. Politically, driven rather than market-oriented
priority rules for traffic management (e.g. between freight and passenger
traffic) illustrates this situation. IMs generally acknowledge the "need to
better meet their customers' and funders' needs"[18]
and require tools necessary to fulfil such responsibilities, while, infrastructure
users, in particular railway undertakings, claim that their interests are not
sufficiently taken into account in both operational and investment decisions
taken by the IMs and request to be better associated to such decisions. Box 3 – Cases of non-market-oriented
decisions of IMs in the UK and Austria McNulty Report[19] (2011) points out that the UK still suffers from a lack of
coordination between IM Network Rail and railway undertakings, having different
goals and objectives. It recommends closer co-operation and alignment between
organisations and the establishment of stronger incentives to focus on cost
reduction and the delivery of high-quality services. The Austrian IM
ÖBB Infrastruktur AG instructed all railway undertakings in its network
statement 2012/13 to use the new Inn Valley route only with locomotives which
are equipped with the signalling system ETCS. At this moment only ÖBB’s own
subsidiaries and DB have the necessary locomotives. All the other (private)
rail freight operators will only be able to use such locomotives in about two
years, since the rail industry is not able to supply these locomotives before.
ÖBB refuses to grant a transition period to the new entrants, in which they
could use either ETCS or the national PZB system, although, according to the
private operators, there are no technical reasons for this refusal. Both ETCS
and PZB can run on the new route, and PZB fulfils the environmental/noise
reduction requirements. The new route is part of an important trans-European
corridor. Therefore the behaviour of the IM could mean that other operators
cannot offer services, in addition to the Inn Valley route, on the entire
trans-European corridor. There is a risk that the positive environmental effect
brought to the sensitive alpine eco-system by enhancing quality of
infrastructure and moving goods from road to rail will be annihilated by this
measure. Baseline
developments The
Recast reinforces the obligations of IMs to consult infrastructure users on
important decisions, including the content of the IMs business plan and network
statement detailing the conditions for access to the infrastructure. The
Recast also foresees that performance targets which are defined in
contractual agreements between Member States and IMs shall be user-oriented.
The Railway Directives also require Member States to set incentives for IMs to
reduce both infrastructure costs and the levels of access charges. However, the
performance targets will be set by IMs and public authorities with little or no
involvement of rail operators and do not therefore guarantee that users' needs
will be adequately addressed. The
Recast also details the content of the performance scheme which IMs must
introduce as part of their infrastructure charging scheme. In this framework,
penalties for IM actions disrupting the operation of the network, compensation
for undertakings suffering from disruption and bonuses rewarding
better-than-planned performance are foreseen. However performance schemes focus
only on cases of disruption of traffic and delays and do not provide incentives
in relation to other aspects of performance such as line speed, operational
costs or capacity under normal conditions. In
conclusion, these ad hoc consultations of infrastructure users will not allow a
structured, transparent and continuous exchange of information between IMs and
users. They will not address specific operational problems that may emerge
during infrastructure usage. Some Member States, such as France, the UK and Sweden, have already taken the initiative to create formal structures of
coordination between IM and its infrastructure users 3.2.1.2
Inconsistencies in the
management of infrastructure and increased coordination costs The
capacity of an IM to develop and optimise transport infrastructure and ensure
quality, reliability, flexibility and customer orientation, depends on its
control over the functions listed in section 3.1.2. According
to current legislation, the functions of the IM may be allocated to different
bodies or firms, e.g. the two "essential functions" (path allocation
and track access charging) may be assigned to an allocation body and charging
body. Accordingly, several Member States (Hungary, Estonia, Luxembourg, Slovenia, and Lithuania) have externalised these two essential functions to independent
bodies, while the rest of functions have been kept within an integrated
incumbent structure. The allocation of the essential functions to entities
outside the IM has certainly brought great advantages for a more equal access
to infrastructure and thereby helped market access of new entrants. However,
These governance models and the model adopted by France (which is splitting the
different functions further), do not allow the IM to have effective control on
all the activities required to manage the infrastructure, as it is dependent on
decisions of other bodies with specific and possibly diverging interests.
Infrastructure managers consider on the contrary that they should have all the
levers of control over their business. This position is largely shared within
the rail sector. Box 4 - Example: Conclusions of the
"Assises du ferroviaire" in France In September 2011 the French
government launched the "Assises nationales du ferroviaire"[20]
to involve all French stakeholders in the preparation of a new reform of the
rail sector, focussing on market opening, financing and governance issues. The
conclusions of this process were adopted in December 2011. They demonstrated a
large consensus on the inefficiency of a system based on the allocation of
infrastructure management functions in two separate entities: on the one hand
the IM RFF in charge of infrastructure development, capacity allocation and
charging and on the other hand, SCNF in charge of maintenance works as well as
traffic management. RFF transfers to SNCF each
year a network management fixed fee of around €3bn. RFF is responsible to
oversee SNCF’s efficient use of the network management fee. However, at the
moment, there is a relatively small technical team available to RFF to oversee
the efficiency and effectiveness of SNCF’s management of the IM contract. This
means that some of SNCF’s actions might not be fully observed, or properly
monitored. This structure would lead to a lack of coordination with a negative
impact on operations and to the absence of costs optimisation. It was therefore
recommended to unify all infrastructure management functions in the same entity
soon. There
are substantial interactions between the functions currently defined by EU law
as essential and the other IM functions described under section 3.1.2, such as
infrastructure development, traffic management and infrastructure maintenance.
As illustrated below, their distribution among different market players can
lead to inconsistencies in the management of infrastructure and increase
coordination costs. ·
Charging
and maintenance - if the body responsible for the charging cannot control
the costs of the infrastructure (i.e. investment and maintenance activities),
the charges may not be set at the right level to reflect these costs. It also
means that possible cost savings or scale effects may not be passed on to the
infrastructure users in terms of lower charges, even though this is a
requirement under EU law. It may also lead to a situation where the IM does not
charge railway undertakings for maintenance costs, thereby ultimately leading
to a decrease in maintenance services and to the degradation of the rail
infrastructure. ·
Charging
and development - under a charging system designed to obtain full
cost recovery, control over the charging is important for being able to fund
projects under the best possible conditions. The price signals sent out by the
different charging levels of various parts of the network should be correctly
set to prompt the best possible use of the network as a whole (new sections and
existing network). ·
Path
allocation and traffic management - the re-allocation of
pre-assigned train paths in cases of delays and disruption of traffic is one of
the core activities of traffic management, and at the same time it is part of
the essential function path allocation. In addition an adequate path allocation
process implies an in-depth knowledge of traffic management practices and
constraints and some return on experience which cannot occur when these
functions are assigned to separate entities. ·
Path
allocation/traffic management and maintenance - if the body
responsible for path allocation and traffic management does not have full
control over the actual availability of the allocated slots (which depends
inter alia on maintenance works planned and executed by another body) this
could create problems in traffic management. Furthermore, regarding the
planning of works, only the allocating body knows, on the basis of path
requests received, which are the most intensely used parts of the network and
therefore could need maintenance most urgently in order to ensure safety levels
and to avoid disruption of operations. ·
Path
allocation/traffic management and development - infrastructure
development has a direct impact on travel time, the number of paths available,
potential traffic types (platform length, etc.) and the quality of operations
on lines. Therefore splitting control functions over path allocation and
infrastructure development decisions will, in the best case scenario, create
coordination problems. ·
Development
and maintenance - where the functions of development and maintenance are
split, there is a threat that suboptimal trade-offs could be made between the
network “maintenance" and “development” works. It is necessary to
coordinate “development” and “renewal” in order to avoid having too many
renewal and development operations going on at the same time, as these
activities reduce the number of available train paths. ·
Path
allocation and charging - charges are a price signal to infrastructure
users and a tool to optimise the use of the infrastructure. If the entity in
charge of path allocation has no control over track access charges, they miss
such optimisation and only face the costs of infrastructure (development and maintenance).
Without the possibility to manage revenues, the IMs' financial management is
limited to the channelling of subsidies without any consideration of
profitability. Box 5 - Analogies with other network
industries concerning infrastructure managers functions Air transport: Airports are responsible for their own investment
planning and maintenance, they also collect airport charges, while slot
allocation is the responsibility of a "coordinator" which is
independent from the Member State, the airport managing body, service providers
and the airlines operating from the airport in question. Electricity and gas: Transmission system operators are by
definition responsible for infrastructure development and maintenance. They
collect congestion charges and allocate transmission capacity. In both cases, the entities in charge of
infrastructure management have a direct responsibility for infrastructure
development, charging, operations and maintenance. Baseline
developments While
the definition of essential functions and the separation requirements
applicable to them have not been changed by the Recast, the latter provides for
a new definition of IM which refers to a "body or firm responsible in
particular for establishing, managing and maintaining railway infrastructure,
including traffic management and control-command and signalling". However
this does not ensure that all the functions listed are in the hands of the same
entity as the text foresees explicitly that "the functions of the IM on a
network or part of a network may be allocated to different bodies or
firms". It
cannot be excluded that Member States which have allocated IM functions in
different entities will adjust the governance of their infrastructure on their
own to reunify them. This should be the case in France where there is large
consensus on the unification of all IM functions in the same structure (see Box 5 above) and in Hungary where the government announced a reform of the national
institutional settings (see Section 1.3.5). However other Member States, in
particular Lithuania, Luxembourg or Slovenia (which finalised in 2011 a reform
maintaining the fragmentation of IM functions) suggest otherwise. 3.2.1.3
Cross-border
cooperation between IMs is insufficient An
important condition for completing the Single European Rail Area is well
functioning cross-border cooperation of IMs. With this regard, the problems
mentioned hereunder, and illustrated by examples in Box 6, are still
widespread. IMs
do not efficiently cooperate to cope with traffic disruptions and temporary
traffic restrictions, especially when more than two IMs are concerned. They may
neglect the impact of their decisions on the business situation of
international traffic and traffic beyond their network. There is a lack of
integrated and proactive cross-border communication with users, such as railway
undertakings, terminal operators and shippers. As
regards investment, national infrastructure management often neglects
interoperability and cross-border infrastructure (in particular port terminals
and hinterland connections by rail) in favour of the needs of domestic
passenger and freight traffic. Where the investment decisions of national
infrastructure management are biased towards the needs of the incumbent,
international trains suffer most because they have to be configured and/or
routed according to the "weakest link" in the infrastructure chain
(in terms of ERTMS deployment[21],
axle loads, loading gauge, electric supply, train length, train mass etc.). National
infrastructure funding priorities may not necessarily consider future
pan-European demand despite the incentives to do so which is provided through
EU co-financing instruments such as the TEN-T programme. The long lifetime of
assets, conservatism of the sector and a preference to maintain national or
regional specifications curb the benefits for investment. Obligations imposed
by Member States to keep unprofitable infrastructure open results in funds
trickling away, and not being focused on main international corridors.
Considerations of available approvals prevail over traffic needs when it comes
to project selection. Freight
trains run at low speeds (18 km/h) on many international routes. This results
from time-consuming operations at borders for railway undertakings. Operations
at borders have not yet been streamlined to exploit the advantages of the
internal market and the Schengen rules. As a result, rail fails to capture
certain commodity groups who prefer the higher speeds of road transport. Box 6 – Examples of IMs coordination problems IMs
along the corridor Rotterdam-Genoa made substantial investments to enhance
capacity and establish the interoperability of train control and command
systems on the basis of ERTMS. In doing so, they expected that all participants
would stick to the agreed time tables. However the corresponding investments on
the German stretches of this corridor will only be made several years later,
which means that benefits will be delayed for other IMs as well as for the
users. Rail freight
undertakings operating in France and the UK enjoy moderate levels of
infrastructure charges that are by and large competitive with road. Whereas
this allowed rail freight to grow in England, the number of freight trains
through the Channel tunnel to and from London did not grow or even dropped
though the link accommodates trains with the main continental (UIC) gauge and
has capacity available. Infrastructure charges in the tunnel and on the link to
London are high such that freight trains are not attractive and shippers
prefer trucks. A better coordination of charging policy between the four
different IMs involved might open the opportunity to attract more trains and at
the same time safeguard the financial interest of all companies involved. Freight trains
operating on the South East Axis to and from Greece/Turkey suffer from
important delays at borders. On such axis two TEN-T corridors (IV and X,
passing respectively via Belgrade and Budapest) compete on the basis of
different infrastructure charges. A better coordination between IMs could curb
delays and allow more balanced use of capacity. This situation contributes to an
imbalance between international and domestic traffic for passengers but also
the negative trend observed in the development of international freight traffic,
as illustrated by the Figure 1 below. Figure 1 Evolution of domestic and international traffic in the EU
(in Mton/km for freight traffic and Mpassenger/km for passenger traffic)[22] Figure 1 shows in particular that international
passenger traffic remains very marginal when compared to domestic passenger
traffic. It also shows that, despite the potentially higher competitiveness of
rail freight vis-à-vis other transport modes over medium to long distances, international
freight continues to decline, both in absolute and in relative terms when
compared to domestic freight traffic.[23] Baseline
developments Some
on-going actions are already heading in the direction of increased integration
of national infrastructure management at the European level, with a specific
emphasis being put on EU freight corridors. The
Rail Freight Regulation[24]
provides a cooperation framework for freight. Corridor structures involving Member States and IMs are set up to cooperate on specific aspects. The Rail Freight
Regulation requires coordination of infrastructure management in aspects such
as maintenance work, upgrades and renewals, the allocation of international
paths and in the supervision of international traffic. The activities of the
Corridors in the field of allocation of paths and traffic supervision are based
on the work done by RailNetEurope (RNE), a partnership of IMs and allocation
bodies which strives to simplify, harmonise and optimise international rail
processes such as Europe-wide timetabling, co-operation between IMs in the
field of operations, train information exchange in real time across borders and
reporting. The
obligations of national IMs to cooperate in the allocation of infrastructure
capacity and in the charging for the operation of train services crossing more
than one infrastructure network will be extended from the corridor approach to
all networks and types of traffic with the Recast. It will actually oblige IMs
to formalise their cooperation with the establishment of IMs' associations
which can charge and/or allocate capacity at an international. The Recast also
foresees that regulatory bodies will have to increase their cooperation in
order to supervise the IM's joint activities. The Commission will be invited to
participate in IMs' deliberations on common principles and practices. While
the cooperation activities under the Rail Freight Regulation are comprehensive
(addressing path allocation and charging but also development, maintenance and
operations) they are limited to specific rail freight corridors. At the same
time, the obligations under the Recast apply to all networks and types of
traffic, but relate only to path allocation and charging. Therefore there is
still a need to address coordination problems related to development,
maintenance and operations beyond EU rail freight corridors and to ensure
consistency between the existing approaches. 3.2.2
Equal access challenge The
level of entry into freight markets has progressively increased as a result of
the various market opening measures implemented on the basis of national
initiatives before 2000 and at the EU-level since 2000. As indicated in Figure
2 below, progress can be observed over the last 5 years in almost all
countries. However
there are marked differences in the level of entry reached as well as in the
growth of new entrants' market shares. The share taken by non-incumbents
reached 40% in only four Member States in 2010 (NL, SE, UK and RO), all of them with separated structures. For the period 2006-2010 examined in Figure 2,
new entrants' market shares have grown by 13.8% on average in Member States
with separated structures while it has increased by only 8.9 % in Member States
with integrated structures. Figure
2 Market share of non-incumbent freight operators Source:
Rail Market Monitoring Scheme 2007, 2009 and 2012 and SDG report Comparison of entry levels in passenger
markets remains difficult at this stage as market opening for domestic services
has only been introduced by a very limited number of Member States, from
different dates and under conditions which are not harmonised by EU law (see
for further details the IA report on market opening of domestic passenger
services). However
it can be noted that the pace of market entry in those few Member States which
have already allowed the provision of domestic passenger services in open
access differs substantially. Such differences seem somehow correlated with the
separation model in place in those Member States: in the case of Germany,
Austria and Italy which formally opened their domestic passenger market more
than a decade ago, the number of new entrant remains very limited and market
entry took place only very recently (only Westbahn since 2011 in Austria, only
NTV since 2012 in Italy, only HKX since 2012 and InterConnex in Germany). In
the case of the Czech Republic, the UK and Sweden, the number of new entrants
is higher and market entry of open access operators came faster after formal
market opening (in the UK Grand Central and First Hull, in Sweden both Veolia
and Blataget, in Czech Republic both RegioJet and LEO-Express). 3.2.2.1 Persistent conflicts of interests of IMs Experience
over the last decade has demonstrated that the implementation of current
separation requirements did not completely prevent the conflicts of interest
and discriminatory practices in respect of access to rail infrastructure and
related services. In addition, the existing legal framework has proven to be
insufficient to allow detection and prevention of cross-subsidisation from IMs
to incumbents. Even reinforced regulators' powers as already foreseen under the
Recast cannot prevent this, as the risk is inherent in some of the existing
institutional settings. 3.2.2.1.1
Diverging
interpretation of existing rules The current
EU legislation requires legal, organisational and decision-making independence
for the essential functions, but it does not provide for concrete criteria as
to how the IM needs to be organised in order to meet these basic requirements.
While there is broad agreement about the definition of legal independence
(meaning that the relevant body must have a separate legal personality),
definition of organisational and decision-making independence must be
interpreted on the basis of existing case-law of the European Court of Justice
(ECJ). Consequently there are problems with the transposition and enforcement
of these requirements and The Commission has initiated several infringement
procedures. According
to the Commission, to fulfil their objective of absence of conflict of
interest, separation requirements should at least imply restrictions in the
composition and nomination of the management boards, cooling-off periods for
managers, the existence of separate staff, facilities and information systems
and new powers to national regulators, as explained in Annex V of the Communication on the implementation of the First railway Package[25]. The interactions between railway undertakings and IMs, where these
independence rules have not been implemented properly, have created conflicts
of interest and still result in access barriers and market distortions, such as
access denials and discriminatory charges. Discriminatory
practices in Member States with vertically integrated undertakings are
illustrated by a high number of examples which are detailed under Annex III.
These discriminations relate in particular to charging and path allocation
practices but also to asymmetries in access to information. While such
practices are illegal under the current regulatory framework, it generally
takes time for the regulator to investigate and decide on the legality of such
practices, at the expense of new entrants who are accumulating costs during the
investigation period (which could take years). The absence
of independence between IM and incumbent railway undertakings can also distort
competitive tendering procedures, given that the incumbent may have access to
information on the technical characteristics of the network and their
implication for transport operations which are not available for new entrants.
Integrated structures may also be in a position to include in their offer
infrastructure related improvements. And the possibility to prioritise
infrastructure investments may give a decisive advantage to the bid submitted
by an integrated structure[26].
Discriminatory practices may lead to distortions of competition in the award of
public service contracts but also to a lower number of bidders since some of
the latter are deterred from participating in tendering procedures. The
progressive reduction in the number of bidders in competitive tenders observed
since 1997 in Germany, illustrated by Figure 3 below, can be explained by
various factors such as a consolidation of the sector, the increased
competitiveness of the incumbent but also by the deterrent effect of discriminatory
practices which German public transport authorities complained about. Figure 3 Number of bidders in
competitive tenders for public service contracts (PSC) in Germany Source: Holzhey, M.,
Berschin, F., Kühl, I. and Naumann, R. (2011) Wettbewerber-Report Eisenbahn
2010/2011 quoted in Appendix K of the IA support study. Baseline
developments The
Commission has provided some interpretation of the practical implications of
existing independence requirements in Annex V of the Communication on the
implementation of the First railway Package. However, some Member States do not
consider that such interpretation derives necessarily from existing law. ECJ is
expected to express its view on on-going infringement procedures and address
this specific issue before spring 2013. The ECJ ruling early next year will
pave the way for a timely and well-informed inter-institutional debate on the
need for new measures. While the
ECJ will decide on whether specific national transposition measures can be
considered sufficient to comply with the existing independence requirements, it
is not expected to provide detailed guidance on how to ensure uniform and
effective implementation. If the ECJ supports the Commission interpretation and
considers national transposition measures insufficient, there would be a need
to clarify in law which are the necessary safeguards to implement existing
independence principles. If, on the contrary, the ECJ considers national
transposition measures compliant with existing EU requirements, it would prove
that EU law currently in force is inadequate to prevent discriminations. This
would represent an additional incentive to further detail and strengthen
separation requirements. Some Member
States are currently taking new national measures on separation of
infrastructure management from transport operations. However, as indicated
under Section 3.1.4., the outcome of these initiatives is still uncertain. And
in other Member States the conflicts of interest are likely to persist without
modification of EU law and these issues would thus continue to hinder
competition in the railway markets and the development of the Single European
Railway Area. Some Member States are still caught up by their multiple roles as
national policy decision makers, owners of rail assets, shareholders of railway
undertakings and contractors of rail services – and find it difficult to
distinguish between their different responsibilities in their different roles.
This situation results in very conservative and defensive positions aimed at
protecting the incumbent which they perceive as their national champions. While a
majority of interested parties, including national regulatory bodies, favours
institutional separation (see Annex II stakeholders consultation, section
2.4.3), several incumbents are actively lobbying national authorities to
maintain regulatory status quo or even to weaken existing separation
requirements. DB and SNCF claimed, during bilateral consultations with the
Commission services, that, as dominant operators, they can defend the interest
of all railway undertakings in their relation with IMs and should therefore act
as "system integrator". The complexity of interfaces would be lower,
operational co-ordination and dispute resolution easier within such "system
integrator". As part of an integrated company, IMs would be more
"customer-driven". In addition, DB argues that the persistence of an
integrated structure has clear advantages in terms of fiscal consolidation. 3.2.2.1.2
Persistent risks of
cross-subsidisation due to lack of financial transparency The
enforcement of existing account separation requirements[27]
has proven to be difficult and insufficient for various reasons: a)
These requirements can be circumvented, for
instance via accountancy tools (evaluation of certain assets belonging to the
different subsidiaries, grants given between subsidiaries and holdings which
have an effect of reducing or increasing results of the respective entities,
profit transfer agreements, asset sharing, etc.); b)
Monitoring by regulatory bodies is very complex,
lengthy and resource consuming process requiring specific expertise. In many
cases incumbents show little willingness to fully comply with information
requests. Even the most powerful and well-equipped national regulators, such as
BNetzA in Germany and ARAF in France, have indicated difficulties in fulfilling
this task[28]
and may therefore tend to prioritise other actions; c)
Any results of ad hoc investigations and
conclusions by national regulators can be contested and experience shows that
such fairly systematic contestations related to account separation. Judicial
appeal procedures against regulators' decisions lead to particularly long
delays (up to five years[29])
in the implementation of corrective actions which may create irretrievable
damage to the market; d)
Existing account separation requirements do not
prevent the distortion of competition resulting from the potentially more
favourable conditions of financing that the holding can obtain due to its
larger scope of activity benefitting both rail transport undertakings and the
IM. Box 7 – Examples: Competitive
advantages of (semi)integrated structures in terms of cross-financing The RGL-AECOM-Frontier
Economics study on account separation (2009) shows that the provision of
regulatory accounts by integrated structures upon requests by regulators is
unlikely to correctly identify if cross-subsidisation is taking place or not.
For instance, depreciation of fixed assets is one of the main costs for railway
undertakings. However, changes in valuation methods for depreciation can
significantly affect both profitability and charges. Financial accounts
typically do not calculate marginal costs and, as a result, statutory accounts
are unable to provide clear insight on this key variable necessary for cross-subsidisation
calculations. Therefore it would remain feasible for the profit-making
subsidiaries of holding structures to offset the losses of the other
subsidiaries. The study indicates that the Deutsche Bahn considers that its
structure is compatible with the accounting separation requirements of
Directive 2001/12/EC. However, at the same time Deutsche Bahn acknowledges the
existence of a control and profit agreement between each subsidiary of the DB
Group. This agreement does not contain any limitations as to the use of
revenues from one subsidiary (including the infrastructure) for the purposes of
subsidisation of another (including train operating subsidiaries). As a result,
profits generated by one of the entities can be transferred to the other, without
possibility for monitoring of cross-subsidies. The study shows that the efforts
of regulators cannot prevent cross-subsidisation alone. In its investigation on
Ferrovie dello Stato (FS) practices, the Italian Competition Authority (ICA)
ascertained that the “complex and unified strategy” developed by FS to keep
Arenaways out of the profitable route between Milan and Turin between 2008 and
2011 included Trenitalia providing a misleading representation of its costs
when the Regulator (URSF) asked the data necessary for the assessment of
economic equilibrium of PSCs, so as to deceive it. DB Holding concluded profit
transfer agreements with all its subsidiaries, including the infrastructure
companies DB Netz (for rail network), DB Station and Service (for passenger
stations) and DB Energie (Energy supply). On the basis of these agreements,
profits of subsidiaries are transferred to the holding, which in turn
compensates losses of these subsidiaries. In the last years the infrastructure
subsidiaries DB Netz and DB Stations and also the subsidised regional passenger
branch DB REGIO have transferred "profits" to the holding, which were
only possible due to the State financing of these companies, and would
otherwise not exist. At the same time DB Holding compensated losses of
transport operators under competition. This mechanism makes it possible to
increase track access charges to the detriment of only the competitors, while
the DB railway operators may be compensated for losses resulting from higher
access charges. This does not formally represent a discrimination, since
formally all pay the same access charges, but it has the same effect. Since
track access charges constitute about 45% of the total costs of a railway
undertaking[30], the effect of increasing track access
charges is significant for competition[31]. In Germany, DB Regio has been
subject to allegations that its services are cross-subsidised from
infrastructure access charges, which is possible because of the existence of
profit transfer agreements between DB Holding and its subsidiaries. The
practice of "profit" transfer to the holding and redistribution among
subsidiaries is said to have a number of anti-competitive consequences. E.g.,
DB is able to present offers for transport services which are only possible on
the basis of such a cross-subsidising mechanism between the sectors transport
and infrastructure. E.g., in the contract attributed for the "Elektronetz
Nord" in Saxony-Anhalt, DB REGIO took over the risk of increases of track
access charges for a period of 15 years. Such an offer is only possible when it
is irrelevant for DB whether the revenues come from the infrastructure or from
transport operators, since profits and losses are balanced out at the level of
the holding. If the track access charges are increased, DB REGIO will make a
loss, however this will be compensated by a corresponding profit of DB Netz
from the increased track access charges. DB's competitors for transport
services, which are not able to use such a mechanism of profit transfer, are
obviously unable to make offers in which they would commit to compensate all
possible increases of track access charges for such a long period[32]. Baseline
developments The Recast
provides for clear competences and additional means to regulatory bodies to
monitor the existing obligations in terms of account separation. With its
implementation, regulators will have in particular the power to carry out
audits or initiate external audits to verify compliance with accounting
separation requirements. It stipulates that the accounts for the different
areas of activity must be kept in a way that allows detection of transfer of
public funds and of the use of incomes from infrastructure charges. But,
despite these improvements, monitoring of the use of public finances within
integrated structures and identification of cross-subsidisation practices will
remain a specifically complex and difficult exercise because of the great
variety of accountancy tools which can be used to circumvent account separation
and the very high number of financial transactions to be controlled.
Furthermore, adoption of ex-post corrective would continue to take years while
irretrievable damage would be caused to the functioning of the rail market (with in some cases the bankruptcy of the new
entrants which suffered from the anti-competitive practices of the integrated
structure). 3.2.2.2
Wide range of IM
functions being the source of discrimination. Beyond
the essential functions, the absence of separation for other IM activities
(development, infrastructure operation and maintenance) in integrated structure
causes potential conflicts of interest. Development decisions on infrastructure may
lead to discrimination as an incumbent in control will be able to prioritise
them to the advantage of its own subsidiaries. When
the entity in charge of traffic management remains under the control of
the incumbent, the latter can interfere to ensure that it is better served in
the daily re-allocation of train paths in case of delays or disruptions
(incidents, accidents, strikes, climate-related problems, etc). In such cases,
there is also an element of urgency which makes traceability and opportunities
of appeal extremely difficult and creates more room for discriminatory
practices. In
relation to maintenance (as for infrastructure development), there are
clear risks in integrated structures that IM decisions are prioritised in
favour of the transport operation subsidiary as illustrated by the examples
presented in Annex III. An integrated IM may disinvest in lines used
essentially by competitors and conversely may continue to maintain
under-utilised lines used by the incumbent. The planning of maintenance works
may also be used by an IM in an anti-competitive way if it schedules
maintenance work to affect the transport operations of new entrants more
severely than those of its own transport companies. Furthermore,
as discussed in Section 3.2.1.2, there is substantial interaction between the
essential functions (capacity allocation and infrastructure charging) and other
infrastructure functions (maintenance and development). Anecdotal
evidence proving the existence of discriminations rising from the absence of
separation requirements for traffic management, infrastructure maintenance and
infrastructure development functions are provided under Annex III. Baseline
developments The
Recast extends part of the existing separation requirements (accounting
separation, organisational and decision-making independence) to access to those
rail-related facilities which are considered essential (such as passenger
stations, freight terminals, maintenance facilities and port facilities). These
new rules apply to transport operators holding a dominant position in national
rail transport markets and operators of specific service facilities. However
these legislative changes preserve the concept of essential functions of
infrastructure management and do not extend the IM functions covered by the
separation requirements. As such they do not prevent discrimination in
infrastructure maintenance and development decisions or in traffic management. Table 2 – Mapping between Problems, Problems drivers and
their root causes 3.2.3
Who is affected The problems described above and the measures to
be proposed to address them will affect a large number of players in the rail
market. They affect in particular national authorities which are responsible
for establishing the IM and assigning infrastructure management functions but
also which finance the infrastructure and award public service contracts. They
affect the regulatory bodies which oversee railway markets and act as an appeal
body for rail companies if they believe they have been unfairly treated, IMs
which are responsible for infrastructure management functions and are subject
to separation requirements, railway undertakings operating freight and
passenger rail transport services and other authorised applicants which are
infrastructure users. They will also affect indirectly passengers and
potentially those using rail freight transport services, as well as
operators of rail service facilities whose activities depend on the volume and
nature of rail traffic. 3.2.4
Aggregated baseline
scenario The
detailed elements of the baseline scenario were provided while different root
causes were discussed. The overall conclusion is that while the Recast and the
Rail Freight Regulation already contain some obligations for IMs to cooperate
with their counterparts and to consult infrastructure users on specific issues,
a more systematic and consistent approach would be necessary to address the
problems mentioned above and their root causes. The Recast foresees explicitly
that Member States can allocate IM functions to distinct entities, but it does
not modify the scope of the IM functions subject to independence requirements
nor the content of these requirements. In this context, the models of IM
governance in place in Europe will not ensure the optimisation of
infrastructure management and a level playing field for infrastructure access.
Existing distortions of competition are likely to persist despite the
reinforcement of regulatory activities. 3.3
Subsidiarity 3.3.1
Legal basis EU action in the field
of rail transport infrastructure is grounded in the Treaty on the Functioning
of the European Union, in particular in its Articles 58, 90 and 100 setting the
basis for internal market in the context of an EU Common Transport Policy. 3.3.2
Subsidiarity The
rationale for a European action in the field of railway infrastructure stems
from the trans-national nature of the Single European Railway Area. Actions by
Member States alone cannot ensure the coherence of market access and
competition rules needed for the emergence of a genuine internal market for
rail transport. The absence of a clear and comprehensive system of governance
of infrastructure hinders the cross-border operations of rail service
providers. Rules
to improve the governance of infrastructure should be developed so that they
can be adapted to the existing institutional setup in each Member State. However, this should be done following common general principles and requirements
in order to ensure the coherence of the single market. Therefore, to ensure the
viability of a Single European Railway Area, EU railway acquis should be
developed further, allowing the railway operators to benefit from a single
consolidated legislative framework and to face predictable business conditions
throughout the EU.
4.
Objectives
4.1
General objectives: The
2011 White Paper foresaw a progressive modal shift from airplane and road
vehicles, so that by 2050 the majority of medium-distance passenger transport
should go by rail. This modal shift will contribute to the 20% reduction of GHG
emissions foreseen in the Europe 2020 Agenda for smart, sustainable and
innovative growth. More specifically, the White Paper concluded that no major
change in transport will be possible without the support of an adequate
infrastructure and a smarter approach to using it. The
overall objective of the Fourth Railway Package is to enhance the
quality and efficiency of rail services by removing remaining legal,
institutional and technical obstacles, fostering the performance of the railway
sector and its competitiveness, in order to further develop the Single European
Railway Area. The initiative on infrastructure governance aims to improve the
management of rail infrastructure, where necessary, through revisiting
remaining institutional obstacles: GO: Strengthen further the
governance of railway infrastructure, thereby enhancing the competitiveness of
rail sector vis-à-vis other modes and developing further the Single European
Rail Area. Overall,
the stakeholders have supported, during stakeholder consultations, the general
problem and the problem drivers as identified by the Commission, as well as the
general direction of EU action - 69% agreed with the objective of improving
access to infrastructure (see Annex 2). Others considered that the availability
of rail-related facilities or the lack of adequate regulatory oversight
constitute the most important access barrier for railway undertakings. 4.2
Specific objectives: The
general objective has been translated into specific and operational objectives
attributed to the two challenges of efficient management and equal access
challenges: EFFICIENT MANAGEMENT CHALLENGE SO1: Improve the IM ability
to manage efficiently the infrastructure in favour of users EQUAL ACCESS CHALLENGE SO2: Eliminate
conflict of interest and distortions of competition in infrastructure access 4.3
Operational objectives: The
following operational objectives have been identified in order to address the
drivers identified in the previous section. EFFICIENCY CHALLENGE OO1: Ensure better
coordination/alignment between the IMs and rail operators OO2: Ensure coherence in
the management of the different IM functions OO3: Ensure that the
cross-border and pan-European dimension of rail infrastructure is adequately
addressed EQUAL ACCESS CHALLENGE OO4: Extend the scope of
"essential functions" to all IM activities which are potential
sources of conflict of interest and distortion of competition OO5: Apply
appropriate safeguard measure(s) preventing conflicts of interest and
distortions of competition to all the "essential functions" of IMs Given
the nature of the initiative, which is to identify the optimal governance
structure of IMs, the operational objectives remain rather generic indicating
the scope and direction of intended change. Targets cannot be set for these
objectives; however the progress will be measured according to the monitoring
indicators outlined in Section 8. Table 3 – Mapping
between problem drivers, root causes and objectives 4.4
Coherence with other horizontal policies The
proposed initiatives aim to meet the objectives of the renewed policy agenda
outlined in the Europe 2020 Strategy, the 2011 White Paper for transport and
the Strategy for Growth and jobs. Transport infrastructure is being considered
as the backbone of the internal market and this objective has been retained as
one of the "Twelve levers to boost growth and strengthen confidence"
in the recently adopted Single Market Act[33]. Additionally,
this initiative is consistent with EU competition policy and legislation in the
transport sector, which aims to ensure that transport markets operate
efficiently, as has been seen in the aviation sector. The equal access
challenge identified in the previous sections is in line with this horizontal
objective.
5.
Policy Options/Policy Scenarios
5.1
Identification of possible policy options The
problem definition identified two main challenges to be addressed in order to
find an optimal governance structure of IMs – efficiency challenge and equal
access challenge. Section 2 above identified for each challenge a series of
root causes. In order to solve the identified problem, five groups of options
are considered, each of them proposing options to remedy the different problem
elements. For each group, two to four options are identified in addition to the
baseline options which are presented under Annex IV. Efficiency challenge: ·
C
options: Coordination
between IM and RUs (linked to operational objective 1) Option C1: RUs participating in the administrative board or
supervisory board of the IM. While EU law currently in force implies that
RUs do not control the decision making process of IMs in relation with
essential functions, this option would foresee that all RUs active on a network
would be entitled to a seat in the supervisory board or management of the IM
responsible for this network. RUs would therefore take a direct and active part
in the management of the infrastructure. This Option C1 corresponds to the
arrangements in place in Switzerland for the company in charge of capacity
allocation, Sillon Suisse SA - Trasse Schweiz AG which is owned by four Swiss
operators CFF, BLS, SOB and UTP which seat in its administrative board. Option C2: Coordination bodies. This option foresees a
creation of coordination bodies representing all RUs and providing opinions to
IMs. RUs would not participate in the administrative board or supervisory board
of the IM, preserving the existing principle of decision-making independence.
However, in order to align strategies and to jointly address
issues which cannot be solved by the implementation of the charging principles,
performance regimes foreseen by the Recast (such as operational costs or capacity
under normal conditions), would be part of a consultative body allowing a
constant exchange of information between IMs and RUs. Such arrangements are
already in place in a limited number of Member States (such as the United Kingdom and France). Option C3: Financial incentives alignment. Under this
option financial incentives are introduced for both RUs and IMs to ensure that
they contribute to the jointly established efficiency targets. Such type of
arrangements is recommended by the McNulty report for the UK (see Box 3). ·
F
options: Consistent
management of key functions (linked to operational objective 2) Option F1: New coordination mechanism. This option
would maintain the current possibility to allocate IM functions to different
entities and foresee the establishment of a mechanism to oblige these entities
to better coordinate the management of IM functions to ensure consistency of
their decisions. Option F2: Unified IM. Under this option, all
IM functions – path allocation and track access charging, but also traffic
management, infrastructure maintenance and development are put under the
responsibility of a single entity, the unified IM. ·
CB
options:
Cross-border infrastructure management (linked to operational objective 3) Option CB1: Establishment of a EU network of IMs. This option
consists in the institutionalisation of a network of national IMs to exchange
best practices, in particular on operational and infrastructure development
issues. A pan-European organisation such as RailNetEurope already constitutes a
coordination forum gathering the vast majority of IMs on specific technical
projects, such as the development of common IT tools. Option CB2: Creation of an EU structure integrating IMs. This option
foresees the establishment of a structure, such as a European Economic Interest
Grouping (EEIG) integrating the existing national Infrastructure Managers into
a single European Infrastructure Manager. Such type of structure is already
foreseen for the management of specific European rail freight corridors. Equal access challenge: ·
SF
options: Functions
subject to the separation requirements (linked to operational
objective 4) Option SF1: Traffic management also covered by separation
requirement. Traffic management - a function which cannot be dissociated
from path allocation and has a very important potential for discrimination - is
added to the list of essential functions subject to separation requirements. Option SF2: Traffic management and maintenance also covered
by separation requirement. Essential functions subject to separation
requirements are extended to include both traffic management and the
maintenance of new infrastructure considering the inter-relation between the
two and their high potential for discrimination. Option SF3: All IM functions subject to the same separation
requirements. This would mean that path allocation and track access
charging as well as traffic management, infrastructure maintenance and
development are subject to the same separation requirements, independent of the
fact that these functions are performed by the same entity or by different
ones. ·
S
options:
Way of separation between IMs and RUs (linked to operational objective 5) Option S1: New competences for regulatory bodies. This option
foresees that regulatory bodies are tasked with controlling that existing
independence requirements in organisational and decision-making terms are
respected. In this framework any RU would have the right to appeal to the
national rail regulator if it believes that these independence requirements are
not respected. In line with this option, the German rail regulator today has
competences to control the implementation of the German rules related to
separation. Option S2: Clarify existing EU law. This would
mean revision of the existing provisions in the Directive so that the
interpretations provided by Annex V of the Communication on the implementation
of the First Railway Package would become indisputable. This would clarify in
particular that the existing independence requirements in organisational and
decision-making terms require in particular strict separation between the
holding and IM supervisory/management board, cooling off periods for IM board
members, own staff, IT tools and premises. In this option, the competences for
regulatory bodies are also extended as foreseen under Option S1. Such option
corresponds to the measures developed in Belgium and Latvia (see Section
3.1.4). Option S3: Institutional separation between IM and RUs. Under this
option, the same persons are not entitled to control, hold any interest or
exercise any right over an IM and a RU. When both IM and RU are public
entities, distinct public authorities must exercise such control over them.
This option corresponds to the institutional settings in place today in 14 out
of 25 Member States (see categories 1 and 4 in Table 1 under Section 3.1.4). Option S4: Compliance officers in integrated structures. The
supervisory board of integrated IM would appoint a compliance officer
responsible for monitoring the implementation of any specific measures taken
within the integrated structure to ensure non-discriminatory behaviour. The
compliance officer would also issue recommendations and report on these
measures to the supervisory board and to the regulatory body. Such arrangement
is in place today within the Deutsche Bahn group. 5.2
Screening of policy options In
total, 19 possible policy options (including baseline options) related to the
five problem elements have been identified. The combination of all these
options could create theoretically 576 scenarios which would evidently be
impracticable to assess. To reduce complexity, these 19 policy options have
been pre-screened for each problem element as per Annex IV. Such screening is
based on (1) stakeholder views, (2) compliance with
subsidiarity/proportionality principles, (3) effectiveness in terms of policy
objectives as well as (4) overall feasibility. Where relevant, the implementing
measures are also discussed in Annex IV. The table below summarises the results
of the screening. Table 4 – Result of policy option screening Problem element || Respective category of options || Policy options considered || Retained Insufficient market orientation of IMs || C options: Coordination between IM and RUs || Option C0: Baseline – improvements as foreseen by the Recast || √ Option C1: RUs participation to IMs' board || Option C2: IMs-RUs coordination bodies || √ Option C3: Alignment through new financial incentives || IM functions managed in an inconsistent manner || F options: Consistent management of key functions || Option F0: Baseline – the content of existing essential functions is clarified by the ECJ || √ Option F1: New coordination mechanism between the various entities in charge of IM functions || Option F2: Unified IMs (all IM functions under IM responsibilities) || √ Cross-border cooperation between IM not sufficient || CB options: Cross-border IM management || Option CB0: Baseline - implementation of existing EU law (the Recast, regulation of rail freight corridors, etc.) || √ Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs || √ Option CB2: Creation of an EU structure integrating national IMs || Equal access needs to be assured to all key functions || SF options: Functions subject to the separation requirements || Option SF0: Baseline – separation requirements applying only to path allocation and track access charging || √ Option SF1: Current essential functions+ traffic management separated || Option SF2: Current essential functions +traffic management + maintenance separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || √ Conflicts of interests in the management of IM functions management || S options: Way of separation of IMs from RUs || Option S0: Baseline - existing separation requirements for the essential functions as interpreted in the forthcoming ECJ ruling || √ Option S1: Additional competences for regulatory bodies || Option S2: Clarify in EU law the concrete implications of existing separation obligations || √ Option S3: Institutional separation || √ Option S4: Compliance officer in integrated structures || 5.3
Construction of policy scenarios The
table 4 above identifies the 11 options that have been retained
(including 5 baseline options) out of the 19 options screened. Of these, three
policy scenarios combining policy options in the five areas highlighted above
(in addition to the baseline) have been designed for the assessment of impacts.
The rationale of the choice is explained in Annex IV. ·
Scenario
0 – Baseline: this Scenario includes only baseline options and is used for
comparison purposes only. ·
Scenario
1 – focussing only on the efficiency measures – this Scenario includes
all three retained options related to the efficiency challenge (an IM-users
coordination body is created, IM functions are unified, an EU network of IMs is
created and all IMs functions are subject to the existing separation
requirements) but only the baseline options related to the equal access
challenge; ·
Scenario
2
– efficiency measures and better enforcement of existing separation
requirements – this Scenario combines efficiency measures (an
IM-users coordination body is created, IM functions are unified, an EU network
of IMs is created) with a first set of equal access measures (all IM functions
are subject to the existing separation requirements with their concrete
implications according to the Commission clarified in EU law); ·
Scenario
3
– efficiency measures and new institutional separation requirements –
this Scenario combines efficiency measures (an IM-users coordination body is
created, IM functions are unified, an EU network of IMs is created) with a
second set of equal access measures (all IM functions are subject to
institutional separation requirements). The
composition of these Scenarios is summarised in the Table 5 below: Table 5 –
Detailed content of Policy Scenarios Category of options || Baseline Scenario || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Coordination between IM and RUs || Option C0: Improvements as in the Recast || Option C2: Coordination bodies || Option C2: Coordination bodies || Option C2: Coordination bodies Consistent management of key functions || Option F0: Existing essential functions are clarified by the ECJ, but scope remains limited || Option F2: Unified IMs || Option F2: Unified IMs || Option F2: Unified IMs Cross-border IM management || Option SC0: Implementation of existing EU law - the Recast, regulation of rail freight corridors. || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs Functions subject to the separation requirements || SF0: Only path allocation and track access charging separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated Way of separation || Option S0: Existing separation requirements || Option S0: Existing separation requirements || Option S2: Clarify in EU law the concrete implications of existing separation obligations || Option S3: Institutional separation
6.
Analysis of impacts
The
analysis below details the economic impacts of the baseline scenario and the
comparative outcomes of the three policy scenarios. Section 6.1 focuses on
direct impacts on the railway sector in terms of enforcement costs, transaction
costs, regulatory costs, the costs of discriminatory practises, that of the
cross-subsidisation, but also the impacts of separation on the efficiency of
infrastructure usage (including assessment of misalignment costs). Assessment
of these impacts is most detailed and supported with further details in Annex
V. Section 6.2 looks in addition at the induced impacts of the initiative, such
as level of competition, level of activity, investments, service quality,
safety and SME impacts. The rest of this chapter covers the indirect impacts on
transport sector and wider economy including range of economic, social and environmental
impacts. This
section provides an assessment of the main economic, social and environmental
impacts. The analysis is mostly derived from a qualitative assessment of the
policy options which is supported where possible by quantitative elements. To
the extent such an approach provides sufficient basis for comparative analysis,
it is considered being proportionate to the nature and purpose of the policy
measures under consideration. The overall results of the analysis of impacts
are summarised in the table in section 6.4. 6.1
Direct impacts on the railway sector 6.1.1
Enforcement costs While,
by definition, there are no enforcement costs under the baseline scenario,
creation of IM-users coordination bodies under Scenario 1 will imply limited
administrative burden for IMs and infrastructure users which are already
involved in ad hoc consultations. In the same manner, without any permanent
secretariat and only few meetings per year under the auspices of the
Commission, the establishment of a European IMs' network is not expected to
create important enforcement costs. In a limited number of Member States, the
unification of IM functions will require merging the IM with allocation and
charging bodies or specific departments of the incumbent. This reorganisation will
necessitate transfer of staff and reorganisation of the IM management chain. Scenario
2 implies the generalised establishment of safeguards capable of ensuring the
decision-making independence of IMs. Such "Chinese walls" may
increase moderately the cost of IM infrastructure management, for instance
through the recruitment of distinct board members and development of new staff
policies, IT systems. However these restructuring costs, affecting only those
Member States which have not opted for institutional separation, are expected
to remain moderate (costs associated to legal separation but also some costs
resulting from decision-making and organisational separation are supposed to be
part of the baseline scenario). Institutional
separation under Scenario 3 is also expected to bring enforcement costs.
However such costs are expected to be limited and not necessarily higher than
those of the "Chinese wall" under Scenario 2 and, as for Scenario 2,
to be concentrated on those Member States which have not opted for
institutional separation. Implementation of Scenario 3 essentially requires
changes in the ownership structure without a need to shift personnel or assets
from one part to another. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Enforcement costs || 0/- || -- || -- Here and afterwards, comparison
tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not the relative
importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-' negative
impacts. Evidence provided under Annex V indicate that Member States
currently without institutional separation (categories 2-6 in Table 1) could be
expected to incur potential one-off costs equivalent to 0.7% of annual
operating costs (the 0.5% mid-point estimate for implementing Scenario 2 plus
the 0.2% arising from Scenario 3). This would imply EU level expenditure of
€0.24 billion. 6.1.2.
Transaction costs Under
the baseline scenario, transaction costs exist as a result of the interaction
between the IM, the incumbent and new entrants. But while transaction costs
between the IMs and new entrants can be easily identified, those between IMs
and incumbents are less transparent but equally existent within integrated
structures. Such costs derive for example from the level of contractualisation
and negotiation, the process of capacity allocation, timetabling and traffic
management, performance monitoring and alignment of incentives, delay
attribution, capacity planning and dispute resolution. All these activities
have to be undertaken, in the framework of the EU railway Directives,
independently of the governance model retained, and of whether the railway
undertakings belong to an integrated group or not. Their cost may vary with the
number of transport operators (depending from the level of market opening), but
not with the level of separation. In the case of rail infrastructure management
there is no possibility to have double marginalisation with integrated
structures because the prices of the infrastructure is regulated and its
profits are constrained by charging principles applicable under EU law. In some
Member States additional transaction costs derive from the fact that IM
functions are spread between different operational bodies. Scenario
1 reduces transaction costs in two different ways: (1) with the unification of
IM functions, those costs resulting from interfaces between the different
entities in charge of IM functions will be removed; (2) better coordination
between IMs and infrastructure users will ensure alignment of strategies and
objectives. As a consequence, contractualisation and negotiation costs should
be minimised, performance monitoring simplified and potential for disputes
partly removed. Under
Scenarios 2 and 3, some transaction costs are likely to increase together with
the number of infrastructure users and volume of traffic. However the benefits
resulting from an increase in the offer of rail transport services, such as
higher track access charges revenues will more than outweigh such costs. In
addition, the efficiency measures implemented under Scenario 1 (as well as the
implementation of the Recast under the baseline scenario) will act as
mitigating measures under these Scenarios. Compared
with Scenario 2, transaction costs under Scenario 3 are expected to vary
essentially as a result of the increasing number of new entrants and higher
traffic volumes. However such increase will impact exclusively those Member
States which have not yet opted for a separated model (see Graph 2 in Section
3.1.4). In addition, under Scenario 3 specific transaction costs, in particular
those resulting from dispute resolution, are expected to decrease compared to
Scenario 2, as illustrated by UK, Sweden and Germany examples in Box 9. Box 9 – Example of dispute
resolution costs in UK, Sweden and Germany Merkert et al. (2008) compared
the railway systems in the UK, Sweden and Germany in terms of complexity of its
transaction processes at interfaces and the related costs. The authors found
that the partially integrated holding model adopted in Germany clearly reduces uncertainty for the integrated DB group and thus for a large part
of all transactions in the German market. It does, however, increase
uncertainty for non-DB operators significantly. This is because most disputes
between non-DB operators and the IM require ex post intervention from the
Regulatory Body and many of them end up in court, thereby lengthening the time
required to resolve them. In the light of an expected increase in the number of
new entrants, the dispute resolution system currently in operation in Germany may lead to substantial cost increases. In contrast, most of the disputes in Britain and Sweden, which are anyway fewer in number, can be resolved between the RUs and the IMs.
Merkert et al. conclude that the British and Swedish systems "provide
competition at not unusually high transaction costs" and work at least as
well as the German system Box 10 – the "PRIMON" study[34] on synergy
costs in Germany In 2006, the PRIMON report was commissioned by
the German government with the aim of evaluating different options with respect
to the privatisation of Deutsche Bahn. The report estimated synergies benefits
from an integrated structure to be up to €1.1 billion for the first four years
after separation. However, according to PRIMON, these costs of separation are
not transaction costs but rather those resulting from the abandon of single
wagon load activities by DB Schenker – 298 m€), cancelled internal efficiency
programs (195 m€), misallocation of investments (164 m€) and distinct
procurement and other central administrative services (432 m€). However it can
be argued that some synergy benefits are not necessarily eliminated in the case
of institutional separation. In particular charging policies supporting single
wagon load activities, joint efficiency programs and alignment of investments
can be developed through IMs-users coordination, benefitting thereby new
entrants in addition to the incumbent. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Transaction costs || 0 || - || -- Here and afterwards, comparison
tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not the relative
importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-' negative
impacts. According to the evidence collected
under Annex V, the potential transaction costs range between 0.05 and 0.16 bn
euro per annum with Scenario 2 and 3. They should impact only Member States
with integrated structures and represent at least 0.15% of operating costs
under Scenario 2 and nearly 0/3% of operating costs under Scenario 3. 6.1.3.
Regulatory costs Under
the baseline scenario as well as Scenarios 1 and 2, the persistence of
integrated structures will oblige regulatory bodies to deploy important
administrative resources to effectively control and detect discriminatory
behaviour of and cross-subsidisation within the integrated railway undertaking. Under
the baseline and Scenario 1, discriminatory practices are already prohibited
and regulatory bodies are competent to act following an appeal from a party
which considers itself discriminated or on their own initiative. While the
scope of separation requirements varies between these two scenarios, there is
no evidence that regulatory costs will change significantly. With
Scenario 2, regulatory bodies are tasked with a new competence requiring
additional resources: controlling that independence requirements in
organisational and decision-making terms are respected. However the related
increase in regulatory costs should be at least compensated by a reduction in
the number of appeals resulting from the absence of conflicts of interest. Finally,
transparency resulting from institutional separation under Scenario 3 will
greatly facilitate and make more effective regulation. As conflicts of interest
are prevented but also financial transparency ensured, the cost of regulation
will substantially decrease under this Scenario. According to the evidence
collected under Annex V, regulatory costs per train-kilometre could decline up
to 75% as a result of institutional separation. Such positive impact would be
concentrated in Member States with integrated structures. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Regulatory costs || 0 || 0 || + * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.1.4
Costs of
discriminatory practices By reducing or even
eliminating the scope for discriminatory behaviour, all three policy scenarios
would evade opportunity costs of potential operations of new entrants omitted
due to discrimination in gaining access to infrastructure. Equal access to
infrastructure would also provide for the development of competition for, and
in, the market, in particular if coupled with market opening initiative. Already in the Baseline
Scenario, any discriminatory practices are prohibited by existing EU law and
regulatory bodies are competent to act following an appeal or on their own
initiative. However, as presented in the problem definition of the IA, the
discrimination in infrastructure access, preventing the smooth functioning of
Single European Railway area, still occurs. Under Scenario 1, measures
ensuring better coordination between Ims and infrastructure users will provide
an opportunity for new entrants to have their interests taken into account by
IMs and thereby to reduce the scope for discrimination. In case of Scenario 2
independence requirements in organisational and decision-making terms are
further detailed and the scope of oversight of regulatory bodies is extended to
verify that these requirements are respected. However, without full
institutional separation and full financial trasparency, an opportunity and
motivation for discrimination remain. Damages caused by discriminations could
be illustrated in terms of 'opportunity costs' expressed as loss from
non-running of services as well as lost return on investments. Whilst such
costs can be significant, quantification is challenging being each time
dependent on the circumstances and the nature of services involved. For
instance, one of the discrimination cases quoted in Annex III refers to hurdles
the Italian new entrant NTV experienced during the homologation procedure for
its HS trains. The process took 45 months between July 2008 and March 2012 main
reason for delays being the infrastructure manager's RFI (subsidiary of the
Ferrovie dello Stato) refusal to grant the train paths necessary for testing
purposes. The excessive duration of the procedure led to a lost return on its
€1 billion investment for the development of its new rail transport services. Scenario 3
would imply a structural change by introducing full institutional separation
and thus prevent (rather than correct) occurrence of discriminatory behaviour.
Therefore this Scenario is much more efficient in terms of evading discrimination
related opportunity costs. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Costs of discriminatory practices || 0 || 0/+ || ++ Here and afterwards, comparison
tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not the relative importance
of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-' negative impacts. 6.1.5.
Costs of
cross-subsidisation Separation would also reduce
the risk of cross-subsidisation embedded in integrated and holding structures.
Complex bundle of services offered over the same network and potentially by the
same or closely linked companies has inherently implications for
cost-accountancy and transparency even if account separation requirements are
in place. In these terms only full institutional separation, as foreseen under Scenario
3, would reduce and ultimately eliminate the risk of cross-subsidisation
between different rail services. Improved transparency would provide the
decision-makers within the relevant competent authorities with more transparent
financial information about asset values and cost structure, allowing improving
the allocation of public funds to, and within, the rail sector. However,
likewise the opportunity costs, transparency linked benefits would not be easy
to quantify. In any terms Scenario 3 is considered much more effective,
given that institutional separation would structurally prevent the case for
cross-subsidisation, while Scenario 2 would still allow
the persistence of cross-subsidisation through the use of complex accountancy
tools which are difficult for regulators to monitor and control. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Costs of cross-subsidisation || 0 || 0/+ || ++ Here and afterwards, comparison
tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not the relative
importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-' negative
impacts. 6.1.6.
Efficiency of
infrastructure usage Under
the baseline scenario, efficiency improvements measured by the passenger-km and
tonne-km per kilometre of rail network and per unit of rolling stock will
continue to be largely determined by technological evolutions and by the
managerial independence of market players (i.e. the ability of railway
undertakings to manage their business on a commercial basis and for the IM, its
responsibility over its own management, administration and internal control).
In this context, it can be expected that efficiency will continue to improve to
some extent. However, a low competitive pressure on transport operators,
sub-optimal asset management and biased investment allocation of some IMs would
limit efficiency gains. The
measures to be implemented under Scenario 1 are specifically designed to
increase efficiency. They will allow IMs to better assess market needs at both
domestic and EU level and to develop infrastructure capacity responding to
these needs, thanks to their ability to control the various activities which
determine it. Under Scenarios
2 and 3, increasing competitive pressure and specialisation of the market
players will have an additional positive effect on their productivity and
efficiency. At the same time, as further explained under Annex V, there are
risks of loss of synergies and economies of scope which can appear in cases of
separation between IMs and a dominant RU (the so called 'misalignment costs').
However, this is inherent in order to ensure a level playing field for all
operators. These risks will be mitigated by the enhanced coordination between
IMs and infrastructure users as well as full implementation of the financial
incentives foreseen by the Recast (modulation of charges, incentive scheme and
performance regime). Such measures will ensure adequate alignment of strategies
and investments leading essentially to long term efficiency gains. Box 8 – Example of impacts on efficiency in
Australia Evidence of efficiency gains as a result of unbundling has been
found in Australia (OECD (2005), where an inter-state IM was created, whose aim
was to provide the infrastructure on a non-discriminatory basis to several,
mostly freight, RUs. The IM was able to decrease infrastructure charges by 25%
compared to the situation under mutual agreements between vertically integrated
companies in place hitherto. Figure 6
below illustrates the findings of a study of 16 European railway networks
conducted by Sanchez and Monsalvez (2008). They found that structural reforms
and market opening have a positive effect on productivity and efficiency of the
railway industry measured by the passenger-kilometre and tonne-kilometre and
per unit of rolling stock. The authors found in particular that horizontal
separation (i.e. opening up of the rail transport services market) without
vertical separation (as in Austria, Germany or Italy) had a limited impact on
the efficiency. On the other hand, efficiency gains in vertical separated
countries were significantly higher compared to those countries where
industries remained vertically integrated only where vertical separation was
introduced with some degree of horizontal separation (as in the UK and Sweden).
Vertical separation without market opening (as in Spain and in France) had a negative impact on efficiency. Figure 6 Productivity
and efficiency changes on European railways[35] Source:
Sanchez P., Monsalvez J., Martinez L. (2008) quoted in
Appendix E (E2.4) of the SDG report. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Operational efficiency || + || ++ || +++ Scope efficiencies between IM and incumbent || 0 || - || - Overall level of efficiency || + || + || ++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.
Induced impacts on the railway sector 6.2.1.
Level of competition Under
the Baseline scenario as well as under Scenario 1, changes in the level of
competition are likely to remain limited. However the efficiency measures
adopted under Scenario 1 may, in comparison to the baseline, have an additional
impact on competition: the new IM-users coordination mechanisms will address
the problem of asymmetries of information in the dialogue between IMs and
infrastructure users, including new entrants. In addition, by extending
existing independence requirements to all IM functions, Scenario 1 may also
address some potential discriminatory practices arising for functions which are
not defined today as being 'essential'. However distortions of competition are
expected to persist because of the weaknesses of these independence
requirements explained under Section 3.2.2.1.1. Identifying and correcting
anti-competitive practices will remain particularly difficult for regulatory
bodies and will continue to be a long process with important opportunity costs
for the victims of discrimination. New entrants would therefore continue to face
difficulties in developing alternative transport offers. Under
Scenarios 2 and 3 strengthening of the separation between the IM and the
railway undertakings is expected to address anti-competitiveness concerns by
eliminating conflicts of interest between IMs and incumbent operators. Under
Scenario 2, competition will increase compared to the baseline as the
decision-making independence of the IM would be ensured. However its impact in
terms of competitive pressure vis-à-vis railway incumbents will not be as
strong as in Scenario 3. In fact, the existence of integrated structures and
the associated persisting risks of cross-subsidisation explained under Section
3.2.2.1.2 will continue to slow down new entrants' development – in freight and
in passenger transport. Integrated structures will find possibilities to
continue using public infrastructure subsidies to gain competitive advantages
for their commercial operations. In addition, under Scenario 2, competitive
advantages of incumbents in access to resulting from infrastructure ownership
will not be addressed. Full
institutional separation under Scenario 3 will guarantee financial
transparency, absence of cross-subsidisation and fair financing conditions,
reduce further the risks of conflicts of interest and ultimately create the
conditions for increased competition. However it must be
acknowledged that institutional separation and non-discriminatory coordination
between IMs and users will not directly affect the dominance of incumbents. The
latter will continue to use their market power to claim favourable
infrastructure access conditions from independent IMs. Figure
2 under section 3.2.2 has shown the evolution of the market shares of new
entrants in freight markets. It indicates that the share taken by new entrants
has been generally greater and has grown faster in countries adopting full
institutional separation than in those with an integrated structure: in 2012,
the market share of new entrants was above 21% in 6 out of 8 countries in the
separated sample while it was above this same figure only in 2 out of the 8
countries in the integrated sample. It can be concluded that combining IM and
RU functions within a single organisation is likely to prevent or discourage
new entry. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Level of competition || +* || ++ || +++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.2.
Level of activity of
railway operators (traffic) Under
the baseline scenario, the level of activity, linked to infrastructure usage
and the level of traffic, is likely to remain constrained by the difficulties
faced by new entrants in accessing the rail market. However some access
barriers will already be removed by the development of common technical
standards (for both safety and operability) and by the implementation of the
Recast which will in particular facilitate access to rail-related services for
new entrants. Other initiatives under the Fourth railway package (single
certification and homologation procedures, opening of the domestic passenger
markets) will have an important impact on the evolution of rail traffic. Implementation
of the efficiency measures foreseen under Scenario 1 will have a positive
impact on the level of traffic: IMs coordination, improved consultations
between IMs and infrastructure users as well as the unification of IM functions
will ensure that the availability of existing infrastructure capacity is
maximised (through better maintenance planning and operational practices) and
that investments in infrastructure development are optimised to respond to
transport operators' demand. In
addition to the positive impact of the efficiency measures mentioned above,
Scenarios 2 and 3 will facilitate market access and the increasing number of
operators will ultimately generate new business activity and additional
traffic. For freight and passenger rail in open access, this will lead to an
increase of traffic generated by additional transport supply. For
competitively-tendered passenger rail services, new bidders bringing additional
competitive pressure will lead to additional savings for competent authorities and
improvements in service quality for passengers. These benefits will ultimately
increase the possibility for awarding authorities to purchase additional
train-km or passenger-km of train services for the same amount of subsidies. As
the level of competition will be higher under Scenario 3 than under Scenario 2
(see section a) above) these effects will be respectively stronger under
Scenario 3 than under Scenario 2. Empirical
evidence shows that there is a correlation between the level of separation and
the intensity of infrastructure use. Figure 4 below shows that rail
infrastructure tends to be most intensively used in those countries that have
adopted institutional separation and liberalised their respective rail markets.
Sweden is a notable exception, with the relatively low intensity of use
reflecting geography and network configuration. Such correlation appears even
more obvious when changes to the intensity of use are observed: While intensity
of use of rail infrastructure in the UK and the NL, which had reached an
already remarkably high level in 2006, remained fairly stable, such intensity
increased particularly rapidly in other Member States with separated
structures, such as the Czech Republic, Sweden, Denmark and Romania. Among
Member States with integrated structures, the intensity of use reached
relatively important levels in Italy, Austria, Germany, Belgium and Luxembourg. However, with the exception of Austria and France, such intensity
deteriorated or remained fairly stable during the reference period 2006-2009. Figure 4 Intensity of use of infrastructure and variation 2006-2009
(passenger train-km / km of line) Source: Rail Market
Monitoring Scheme (RMMS) 2012 and Eurostat data. Change of use of
infrastructure in selected countries in 2006-2009, % Source: Rail Market
Monitoring Scheme (RMMS) 2012 and Eurostat data. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Level of activity of railway operators || + || ++ || +++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.3.
Investments in
infrastructure and transport operations Under
the baseline scenario, investments by new entrants in transport operations will
be constrained by the fear of distortions of competition (discriminatory
practices and cross-subsidisations) but also by the persistence of
inefficiencies in infrastructure management. In addition the variety of
governance structures will continue to affect the transparency of market access
conditions making cross-border investments of rail undertakings more difficult.
Public authorities may ultimately decide to limit their funding to the rail
infrastructure due to the sub-optimal management of the rail infrastructure as
well as the persistent risk of transfer of public funding for the
infrastructure to other activities. Improving
the efficiency of infrastructure management, Scenario 1 is expected to reduce
its costs. This may result in IMs requesting lower public funding for specific
infrastructure development projects and ultimately making rail more attractive
for both public and private investments. Investments in favour of competing
modes could be re-allocated in favour of rail in the future. Under
both Scenario 2 and Scenario 3, independent decision-making processes in
relation to infrastructure development and maintenance will optimise further
usage of available funding and should lead to higher public and private
investments. However, with persistent risks of reallocation of public funds for
infrastructure development to transport operations under Scenario 2, the
increase of public and private investments is likely to remain lower than under
Scenario 3. Experiences
in both the UK and Sweden have shown that public contributions to the rail
sector in general have increased significantly after institutional separation.
Such increase is illustrated by the Figure 5. Figure 5 UK
Government Support to the rail industry in Great Britain[36] * Source: UK Department for Transport, Transport Scotland and Welsh Assembly As
highlighted in the IA report on market opening in domestic passenger services,
such increases in the level of investment has led to an higher offer of rail
transport services and the investment efficiency has improved. According to
this report, the increase of passenger-kilometre per subsidies between 2003 and
2008 is the highest in the UK and Sweden. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Level of investment || + || ++ || ++ * Here and afterwards,
comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not the
relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.4.
Service
quality Under
the baseline scenario, low competitive pressure as well as the absence of
proper coordination between IMs and infrastructure users may lead to
investments not focussed on users' needs in terms of service quality and
sub-optimal traffic management decisions creating recurrent problems of
punctuality in a context of traffic growth. With
the efficiency measures implemented under Scenario 1, service quality will be
improved as IM having full control over the all key functions should result in
more effective and coordination with railway undertakings will make them more
aware of the needs of passengers and freight forwarders. Under
Scenario 2 and Scenario3, higher competitive pressure will bring market players
to become even more customer-oriented and focus their investments on service
quality (in terms of comfort, reliability, speed, etc.). Box 11 below
illustrates such impact. Box 11 – Example
of impacts on service quality in the Netherlands A study by Mulder (2005) looks at the
institutional change process of the Dutch railways, and its effect on passenger
welfare. While there were many transitional problems evident, the report
concludes that, following initial problems with performance and punctuality,
there has been an improvement in the quality of passenger transport, arising
through the institutional separation of different railway entities and the
formalisation of the relationships between them. Impacts compared to the baseline e || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Level of service quality and punctuality || += || + || ++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.5.
Rail safety Under
the baseline scenario, the level of safety is expected to continue to increase
as a consequence of the continuous development of safety and interoperability
standards as well as the improvement to certification and homologation
procedures foreseen under the Fourth Railway Package. With
Scenario 1, coordination between IMs and infrastructure users and among IMs
will cover safety aspects (investments in new technologies, operational
practices) and should improve further safety levels. Scenarios 2 and 3
scores are expected to be identical to Scenario 1 in relation to safety as the
latter is not influenced by the degree of separation. There is no evidence that
competition in general and the increasing competitive pressure resulting from
separation may affect safety. On the contrary, there is evidence that safety
levels improved in countries which have separated their systems as illustrated
by examples in Box 12. It can actually be argued that specialisation and
clearer responsibilities of the different market players creates a more
favourable institutional framework. Interestingly, less than 20% of the
respondents to the Eurobarometer survey think that competition is expected to
have a negative influence on the safety of the network and 55% think that there
will be an improvement. Box 12 – Example of
safety impact in UK A study by OECD (2010) found that there has been
no decrease in safety (measured in terms of fatalities) as a result of
unbundling in the UK and in Japan. Accident levels in the UK have fallen at a faster rate after market opening and separation rather than before it.
Steer Davies Gleave (2011) and Thompson (2004) agree that safety in the UK did not suffer from the unbundling and privatisation process. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Level of safety || 0 || 0 || 0 * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.2.6.
Impact on SMEs New
entrants in the railway freight and passenger markets as well as services
providers such as maintenance operators are partly SMEs. There are no obvious
differences in the impact of each Scenario on these SMEs compared to large
railway operators. It may be argued that Scenarios 1, 2 and 3 are increasingly
likely to create new business opportunities for these SMEs as these business
opportunities very much depend on the variations in the level of traffic. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Impact on SMEs || 0 || + || ++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.3.
Indirect impacts on the transport sector Taken
in isolation, the impact of this initiative will be rather limited at the
transport sector and EU economy levels. However, with the development of the
European Single Railway Area, it will contribute to fostering modal shift and
the efficiency of the transport system (see below). It will also improve the
environmental impact of the transport systems, but these impacts are minor
compared to the impact of better resource efficiency and cleaner energy use of
the transport systems, rail included. For example, the electrification of the
rail network as well as the increased share of low-carbon electricity would
have a much more pronounced impact on the environment. However the increases of
competition and activity in the railway sector under the different options will
impact the European transport system as a whole. 6.3.1.
Modal shift Under
the baseline scenario, in terms of modal split, the various modes are in
general expected to maintain their relative importance at EU level. Road is
expected to remain the largest mode. Aviation is expected to continue to grow
consolidating its position as the second most important passenger mode (in
terms of passenger*kilometres). While the total rail passenger transport
volumes should continue to grow, rails modal share is expected to increase only
modestly. As regards freight, total transport volumes are expected to grow at
rates comparable to the ones of road and maritime transport. Rail is expected
to grow faster aided by an expected slower increase in fuel costs[37]. The
impact on modal shift is likely to be proportionate to the impact on the level
of competition and the level of activity in the railway sector. Increased
competition under Scenarios 2 and 3 will lower the cost of rail and will make
the sector more responsive to customers' needs, allowing railway operators to
compete with other modes, therefore increasing modal share compared to the
Baseline and Scenario 1. Passenger high speed services will improve the
competitive situation with airlines and rail freight will increase its market
share. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Modal shift || 0/+ || + || + * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.3.2.
Efficiency of the
transport system (congestion and travel times) In
the Baseline scenario, efficiency improvements will result from market opening
initiatives, increased investments in infrastructure in line with the TEN-T
Guidelines and the Connecting Europe Facility, favouring intermodal connections
and reductions of missing links at cross-border sections and bottlenecks. The
expected modal shift under Scenarios 1, 2 and 3 would have an increasingly
positive effect on congestion levels of roads and is likely to reduce societal
costs compared to the baseline. Additionally, the more favourable climate for
public and private investments under Scenario 3 will allow investing in the
rail infrastructure to reduce bottlenecks and missing links, therefore
improving the efficiency of the rail network. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Efficiency of the transport system (congestion and travel times) || + || + || ++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.4.
Indirect impact on the European economy Studies
by the World Bank on countries logistics performance show the correlation
between economic growth and freight transport logistics effectiveness and
efficiency.[38]
Therefore as explained above, the improved conditions for competition and the
improved efficiency of the railway system will affect economic growth. A more
integrated and efficient transport system enabling the free movement of people
and goods across the EU and with its neighbours is expected to contribute to
economic growth, as it would allow for a more efficient use of resources. The
EU economy should also benefit from the increase in the capacity and
performance of the infrastructure resulting from its improved management of the
infrastructure. Additionally, the improvement of the efficiency of the
transport system and the reduction of related obstacles would improve the
economic conditions for both transport businesses and enterprises heavily
depending on transport for their activity. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Impact on the European economy || + || + || + * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.5.
Environmental impacts 6.5.1.
Impact on climate
change According
to the business-as-usual scenario of the Commission Communication "A
Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050", EU
transport's GHG emissions will increase by 60% to 70% in 2050 in comparison to
the 1990 levels. In addition, a 50% reduction of emissions in other sectors
compared to 1990 would increase transport's share in total emissions from 20%
(current state) to 50% by 2050. Improved
efficiency of the rail transport system and modal shift will reduce the
greenhouse gases emissions. However, the level of impact of the policy
scenarios will very much depend on the energy supply for trains (i.e. energy
mix for electricity used by electric trains and share of trains running on
diesel). Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Impact on climate change || 0/+ || + || + * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.5.2.
Impact on pollution Air
pollution levels, as defined by the Directive 2008/50/EC of the European
Parliament and the Council on ambient air quality and cleaner air for Europe, freight transport logistics effectiveness and efficiency mostly depend on the
vehicles' (including ship's) pollutant emissions performance and road traffic
congestion in urban areas. Compared
to the baseline, Scenarios 1, 2 and 3 would increasingly contribute to further
reduction in emissions thanks to their positive impact on congestion reduction,
as a result of induced modal shift. The level of the impact will partly depend
on the extent to which cleaner rail transport is introduced, for example by
fostering the replacement of diesel locomotives by electric ones (with a
cleaner electricity mix). Since rail transport is the second most energy
efficient mode, larger volumes of rail transport traffic flows should lead to a
reduction of the overall energy and fuel consumption. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 impact on pollution || 0/+ || + || + * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.5.3.
Impact on noise According
to one study,[39]
road generally accounts for approximately 70% of total noise emissions by
transport, rail for 10% and air transport for 20%. The reference scenario of
the Impact Assessment of the White Paper highlights that the forecasted
increase in traffic would lead to roughly €20bn increase of noise related
external costs by 2050. All scenarios will stimulate traffic growth and therefore
have a negative impact on noise emission. However such rail noise increase may
be partly compensated by specific measures (such a track access modulation
based on the noise performance of trains foreseen in the Recast, implementation
of new interoperability standards as well as noise bans). In addition benefits
should accrue through modal shift from road to rail for freight transport, and
from road and aviation to rail for passenger traffic as, in relative terms,
road and air transport noise will decrease. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 impact on rail noise || 0/+ || 0/+ || 0/+ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.6.
Social impacts 6.6.1.
Impact on employment
levels and working conditions, including wages, in the railway sector As
to the direct employment deriving from organisational changes, separation will
reduce the economies of scope of carrying out the infrastructure and operation
tasks within a single organisation. Therefore, in the short term, it will imply
that more people will be required to do complementary tasks in the IM and in
railway undertakings. The
growth of railway activity stimulated by the improved governance of the
infrastructure will increase the demand for qualified rail workers in railway
undertakings, operators of rail services facilities but also for rolling stock,
therefore creating new jobs in railway manufacturing. Such positive impact will
be partly mitigated by the productivity gains called by competitive pressure,
resulting in lay-offs in some incumbent railway undertakings. Changes
in the governance of the infrastructure will not impact directly working conditions.
The continuous applicability of existing rail worker status to the whole rail
sector is not linked to the efficiency measures or the level of separation
between IMs and incumbent. Wages are likely to evolve based on market
conditions such as specialisation, skills or scarcity. Higher-skilled
professions (traffic controllers, train drivers, train technicians) are most
likely to experience an increase in wages. As a result of increasing
competition, railway undertakings and IMs may be inclined to outsource the
provision of specific services like maintenance works or clerical functions. In
the medium term, this would lead to some job losses in rail sector but to new
business opportunities of other sectors. Lower
costs of transport resulting from efficiency measures and increasing
competition will have an induced impact on employment in the EU, as it will
free resources to carry out other activities thus increasing the
competitiveness of the EU and its production and employment. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 impact on employment and working conditions in the railway sector || + || + || ++ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.6.2.
Impact on transport
safety: As
rail is the safest transport mode, the potential increase of rail travel will
result in overall safer transport. This impact could be important in specific
regions, such as South-East Europe, where road traffic modal share is currently
increasing and where fatalities are highest. Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Impact on transport safety || 0/+ || 0/+ || 0/+ * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. 6.7.
Summary of assessment of direct and induced impacts Table 6
- Assessment of direct impacts (as per Annex V) Impacts compared to the Baseline || Scenario 1 (only efficiency measures) || Scenario 2 (efficiency and enforcement of separation) || Scenario 3 (efficiency and institutional separation) Enforcement costs (one off) || 0/– || – – Potential scale of costs €0.17 billion || – Potential scale of cost €0.24 billion – Limited costs related to establishment of coordination bodies in many MSs and unifying IM functions in some MS. || Related to the costs of internal reorganisation necessary to put in place "Chinese walls". Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. || ~0.9% of yearly operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Transaction costs || + || – Potential cost range €0.05 bn and €0.16 bn per annum || – – Potential cost range €0.05 bn and €0.16 bn per annum Some improvement due to better coordination. Impacts to all MSs. || At least 0.15% of operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. || ~0.3% of operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Regulatory costs || 0 || 0 || + It is not expected the costs of regulatory enforcement under Scenario 1 to be materially lower than those arising in the Baseline. || It is not expected the costs of regulatory enforcement under Scenario 2 to be materially lower than those arising in the Baseline. || Regulatory costs per train-kilometre could decline by up to 75% as a result of institutional separation. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Other costs and benefits, linked to: || || || || || Discrimination || 0 || 0/+ || ++ No impact || The scope of oversight of regulatory bodies is extended, but remains mostly reactive thus only partly evading discrimination related opportunity costs. || Full institutional separation would eliminate opportunity and motivation for discrimination. Cross-subsidisation || 0 || 0/+ || ++ No impact || Transparency issues and cross-subsidisation risks remain inherent in integrated and holding structures even if account separation requirements are in place. || Full institutional separation would provide necessary transparency and eliminate opportunity for cross-subsidisation. Efficiency || + || + || ++ Increasing competitive pressure and specialisation of the market players will have an additional positive effect on their productivity and efficiency. At the same time, as further explained under Annex V, there are risks of loss of synergies and economies of scope which can appear in cases of separation between IMs and a dominant RU. However, this is inherent in order to ensure a level playing field for all operators. These risks will be mitigated by the enhanced coordination between IMs and infrastructure users as well as full implementation of the financial incentives foreseen by the Recast (modulation of charges, incentive scheme and performance regime). Such measures will ensure adequate alignment of strategies and investments leading essentially to long term efficiency gains. In terms of scale, the implementation, transaction and regulatory
costs are relatively less significant than costs linked to discrimination and
lack of financial transparency. Misalignment costs could also be significant.
However, increasing competitive pressure and specialisation of the market
players will have an additional positive effect on productivity and efficiency.
In these terms Scenario 3 seems to be the preferred way forward. Table 7 –
Assessment of induced and indirect impacts Impacts compared to the baseline || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Economic impacts - Impact on railway business || || || Level of competition || + || ++ || +++ Level of activity of railway operators || + || ++ || +++ Level of investment || + || ++ || ++ Level of service quality and punctuality || 0/+ || + || ++ Level of rail safety || 0 || 0 || 0 Impact on SMEs || 0 || + || ++ - Impact on the transport sector || || || Modal shift || 0/+ || + || + Efficiency of the transport system (congestion and travel times) || + || + || ++ - Impact on the European economy || + || + || + Environmental impacts Climate change || 0/+ || + || + Pollution || 0/+ || + || + Rail noise || 0/+ || 0/+ || 0/+ Social impacts Employment and working conditions in the railway sector || + || + || ++ Transport safety || 0/+ || 0/+ || 0/+ Comparison of induced and indirect impacts confirms that Scenario 3
should be the preferred way forward as it performs in the same manner (in
relation to investment, safety, modal shift, European economy, environmental
impacts and transport safety) or better (competition, rail activity, service
quality, SMEs, transport efficiency, employment) than any other Scenario. 6.8.
Synergies between the IM governance and domestic
passenger market opening initiatives The ultimate goal of separation is to create a more competitive
and efficient rail sector and thus encourage a better service offer, while
improving the use of public funds fed via subsidises into railways. The
institutional separation envisaged under Scenario 3 is an important precursor
to the delivery of the full benefits of market opening, as already implemented
for rail freight market and international passenger rail market and further
proposed by the 4th Railway package for domestic passenger market. This can be
demonstrated by comparing the estimated outcomes of a specific form of market
opening with and without separation, which has been developed by the IA support
study[40]. The projections were carried out by the consultant in cooperation
with the Commission. There are high uncertainties linked to calculations of
aggregated impacts, because of (1) limited empirical evidence, (2) any effects
are dependent on baseline situations in Member States and (3) other principal
uncertainties in the baseline developments and exogenous factors. Therefore the quantification results were not used for comparison
of options. However, scenario analysis accompanied with sensitivity tests, as
presented below, should give a relatively sound idea of potential outcomes of
the proposed policy in different situations, based on the most credible
information available as of the date. Assumptions are provided in Annex V of
this IA, for detailed information on the assessment methodology see Annex 8 of
the IA on Access to Domestic Passenger Rail Markets[41]. Table 8 below summarises the financial benefits for: ·
the separation initiative only (column 1) ·
the domestic passenger market opening only for two scenarios: ─
Market opening Scenario 1
- Focus on savings (column 2) - In this scenario it is assumed that competent
authorities would focus on cost savings, taking all the reductions in PSC
tender costs as cash savings and not reinvesting any of these in higher rail
quality or capacity. ─
Market opening Scenario 2 - Reinvestment (column 3)- In
this scenario it is assumed that competent authorities would not focus on cost
savings but would instead implicitly “reinvest” half the potential reductions
in PSC tender costs by specifying higher quality or capacity in PSCs. In terms
of monetary impacts this implies reduction in NPV, while the benefits appear in
terms of increase in passenger km-s. ·
combined impacts of both initiatives separating two different
outcome scenarios: ─
Combined impacts Scenario 1 – Focus on
savings (column 4) ─
Combined impacts Scenario 2 – Focus on reinvestments
(column 5) Table
8 Combined impacts of market opening and infrastructure governance
policies – Summary of core financial estimates All changes are illustrative estimates NPVs (bil €) to 2035, discounted at 4% to 2019 || Separation Scenario 3 || Market opening: Scenario 1 - Savings || Market opening: Scenario 2 - Reinvestment || Combined impacts: Scenario 1 - Savings || Combined impacts: Scenario 2 - Reinvestment || 1 || 2 || 3 || 4 || 5 Transaction costs (mean estimate) || -1.37 || -0.42 || -0.42 || -1.77 || -1.77 Domestic service benefits* || 5.86 || 29.85 || 21.46 || 43.07 || 33.71 International service benefits || 1.07 || || || 1.05 || 0.89 Freight benefits || 1.00 || 1.00 || 1.00 Total NPV || 6.56 || 29.44 || 21.04 || 43.35 || 33.83 Table 9 below presents a wider range
of indicators for individual and combined policies. Table
9 Combined impacts of market opening and infrastructure governance
policies - Range of expected outcomes (in euros per annum) All changes are illustrative estimates || Financial benefits (NPV*, € bn) || Increase in annual revenue (€ bn) || Increase in annual CAPEX (€ bn) || Additional passenger-km (bn by 2035) || Increase in new entry market share (% points) Scenario 1 –Focus on saving Vertical separation[42] || 6.56 || 0.1 || 0.01 || 0.8 || 0.5% Domestic passenger market opening || 29.44 || 0.3 || 0.03 || 2 || 3.8% Combination of market opening and vertical separation || 43.35 || 0.5 || 0.1 || 3.8 || 6.4% Scenario 2 – Reinvestment Vertical separation alone || 4.42 || 0.1 || 0.01 || 1.1 || 0.5% Domestic passenger market opening || 21.04 || 0.9 || 0.13 || 8.4 || 3.7% Combination of market opening and vertical separation || 33.83 || 1.7 || 0.2 || 16.4 || 6.2% * NPVs to 2035, discounted at 4% to 2019, the benefits encompass mainly savings for competent authorities, but also profits of operators. The result for both scenarios demonstrates the existence of
significant synergies between the separation and market access measures as
proposed in the 4th package. 16 billion passenger-km potentially
made available by implementing market opening and separation polices, while
re-investing half of efficiency savings back to railways, would result in 6%
increase of passenger-km on top of the baseline developments. In addition a
more level playing field in access to infrastructure, as provided by vertical
separation measures, would enable to increase the market share of new entrants
from 19% in the baseline to 25%. Further value will be achieved by quicker time and cost to market
for rail undertakings, as provided by the revised scope of the European Railway
Agency, also being the part of the 4th Package.
7.
Comparison of Policy Scenarios
See table 10 below. Table 10 Comparison of Policy Scenarios || Effectiveness || Efficiency || Coherence || Motivation SO1: Improve the IM ability to manage the infrastructure || SO2: Eliminate distortion of competition in infrastructure access || Operational IM efficiency || Enforcement cost || Regulatory costs || Transaction costs || Employment and working conditions || Environmental sustainability Scenario 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || Scenario 1 || ++ || +/0 || + || 0/- || 0 || + || + || 0/+ || Scenario 1 is expected to already have a substantial positive impact on IM efficiency. However, in terms of reduction of conflicts of interest, it will have only a limited resulting from the extension of the existing independence requirement to all IM functions. While existing transaction costs are impacted in a positive but limited manner by better alignment between IM and RUs, regulatory costs and enforcement costs increased moderately as efficiency measures imply a limited administrative burden. Social and environmental impacts are moderate but positive. Scenario 2 || ++ || ++ || ++ || -- || 0 || - || + || + || Scenario 2 will have the same positive impact than Scenario 1 on the IM ability to manage the infrastructure. However its operational efficiency will improve further with increasing competitive pressure on RUs. Scenario 2 removes conflicts of interest in infrastructure access but does not ensure optimal financial transparency and the absence of distortion of competition. Transaction costs increase with the number of new entrants and traffic growth. Both enforcement and regulatory costs are higher due respectively to the implementation of "Chinese walls" and the absence of financial transparency. Social and environmental impacts are moderate but positive. Scenario 3 || ++ || +++ || ++ || - || + || -- || ++ || + || Scenario 3 improves further the IM ability to manage the infrastructure thanks to the specialisation benefits on institutional separation. With full financial transparency, it eliminates completely risks of distortion of competition at a relatively low enforcement and regulatory cost. Transaction costs increase further despite the mitigating effect of better alignment between IMs and RUs. Traffic growth and efficiency generate the highest positive social and environmental impacts. * Here and
afterwards, comparison tables compare the relative impacts within a row but not
the relative importance of different rows. '+' indicates positive impacts, '-'
negative impacts. Considering
this comparison of the three policy scenarios, it appears that Scenario 1 can
be discarded. While it has a significant impact on IM efficiency and positive
influence on transaction costs, it does not provide an effective answer to the
second challenge in terms of equal access. Scenarios 2 and 3 have different
advantages and disadvantages which have been highlighted by stakeholders. Both
perform well in relation to the IM ability to optimise infrastructure
management (as they include the efficiency measures of Scenario 1) and to
remove risks of discriminatory practices. However Scenario 3 is considered as
the most effective and efficient to eliminate distortions of competition, as,
contrary to Scenario 2, it ensures financial transparency and reduces the cost
of regulation with limited enforcement costs. Despite the fact that Scenario 3
implies higher transaction costs, this option must be retained as such costs
deriving from market entries and traffic growth will be outweighed by their
benefits.
8.
Monitoring and evaluation
The
Commission will monitor and evaluate the implementation of the specific
objectives of this legislation and its impacts through a set of indicators. In
order for these indicators to be consistent throughout EU legislation and not
to increase the burden on bodies responsible for providing the data to compile
the indicators, these indicators are aligned with those provided to the Commission
as part of the implementation of existing EU law: enhanced Rail Market
Monitoring Scheme (RMMS) and network of regulatory bodies under the Recast as
well as European Railway Agency (ERA) reporting on safety and interoperability. Specific objectives || Indicators EFFICIENCY CHALLENGE SO1: Improve the IM ability to manage efficiently the infrastructure to the benefit of the users || Infrastructure utilisation rate/Trafic Volumes EQUAL ACCESS CHALLENGE SO2: Eliminate conflict of interest and distortions of competition in infrastructure access || Number of new entrants Market share of new entrants Complaints to regulators 8.2.
Monitoring and evaluation arrangements Information
is already available by way of the existing rail market monitoring scheme which
involves all relevant stakeholders (representatives of the Member States,
including representatives of the regulatory bodies, representatives of railways
sector, including, social partners, users and local and regional authorities
representatives and, where appropriate, the European Railway Agency). The
Recast already foresees enhancing such market monitoring in relation to the use
of the networks and the evolution of framework conditions in the rail sector,
in particular infrastructure charging, capacity allocation, investments made in
railway infrastructure, developments as regards prices and the quality of rail
transport services, rail transport services covered by public service
contracts, licensing and the degree of market opening and harmonisation between
Member States, development of employment and the related social conditions in
the rail sector. The Commission will continue to collect data and to report
every two years to the European Parliament and the Council on the following
elements: (a) the evolution of
the internal market in rail services and services to be supplied to railway
undertakings; (b) the framework
conditions mentioned above, including for public passenger transport services
by rail; (c) the state of the
Union railway network; (d) the utilisation of
access rights; (e) barriers to more
effective rail services; (f) infrastructure
limitations; (g) the need for
legislation. In
addition the Recast will create a Network of Regulatory Bodies, with a
coordination role attributed to the Commission in this Network, which will exchange
information about regulatory bodies' activities (decisions but also on-going
complaints and investigations). Finally Regulation (EC) 881/2004 (so-called ERA
Regulation) foresees that the European Railway Agency reports on a regular
basis on safety and interoperability issues. The
potential indicators mentioned in the above table are addressed by these
monitoring and reporting activities already in place under EU law. In this
context, it is considered that there is no need to create any new arrangement
and obligation. ANNEX I
THE FOURTH RAILWAY PACKAGE – THE 'BIG PICTURE' Caveat:
The content of this Annex will be further refined and updated as the policy
preparation processes for the different initiatives within the Fourth Package progress 1.
Introduction In
its White Paper "Roadmap to a Single European Transport Area - Towards a
competitive and resource efficient transport system" adopted on 28 March
2011 ('2011 White Paper'), the Commission unveiled its vision to establish a
genuine Single European Transport Area and it clarified that this objective
implies creating the true Single European railway Area. A crucial condition to
meet this goal is the removal of all obstacles of administrative, technical or
regulatory nature still holding back the rail sector. As announced in the 2011
White Paper, the Commission has prepared a set of proposals, to be adopted
sequentially within the Fourth Railway Package. Additionally,
the European Council conclusions of January 2012 highlight the importance of
releasing the growth-creating potential of a fully integrated Single Market,
including as regards network industries.[43]
More precisely, the Commission Communication on Action for Stability, Growth
and Jobs adopted on 30 May 2012[44]
stresses the importance of reducing further the regulatory burden and barriers
to entry in the rail sector, making therefore country specific recommendations
in that direction. In the same vein, the Commission adopted on 6 June 2012 the
Communication on strengthening the governance of the single market, which
stresses the importance of the transport sector with a special attention to
rail.[45] This
Annex gives a brief background of the development of EU railway acquis
and clarifies the necessity and objectives of the Fourth Railway Package within
this context. It presents all the elements included in the Package (a chapeau
communication and seven legislative proposals accompanied by three impact
assessments) and explains how different pieces fit together.[46] 2.
Development of EU railways acquis In
the past decade, the European legislator has considerably developed the EU acquis
encouraging competitiveness and market opening. The overarching
idea has been that greater competition makes for a more efficient and
customer-responsive industry. In parallel measures have been taken to improve
the interoperability and safety of national networks; and
encourage the development of well integrated rail system leading to 'European',
rather than 'national', railways. Rail
legislation in the early nineties introduced some limited degree of market
opening and prompted the railways to improve efficiency by introducing
management independence of railway undertakings from the state and separation
of accounts between infrastructure management and transport operations. Since
2000, however, the European Commission has put forward further initiatives in
the shape of packages of legislative measures. The
First Railway Package, adopted in 2001, was designed to: ·
open
the international rail freight market, ·
establish
a general framework for the development of European railways, and clarify the
relationship between (a) the state and the infrastructure manager; (b) the
state and railway undertakings and (c) the infrastructure manager and railway
undertakings (Directive 2001/12/EC); ·
set
out the conditions that freight operators must meet in order to be granted a
licence to operate services on the European rail network (Directive 2001/13/EC); and ·
define
policy for capacity allocation and infrastructure charging (Directive 2001/14/EC). The
Second Railway Package was adopted in 2004. Its aim was to determine: ·
a
common approach to rail safety (Directive 2004/49/EC) ·
requirements
for interoperability of the European high speed and conventional rail systems
(Directive 2004/50/EC) ·
the
opening of national and international rail freight markets on the entire
European network (Directive 2004/51/EC) ·
the
establishment of the European Railway Agency (Regulation (EC) 881/2004, amended by Regulation 1335/2008). The
Third Railway Package was adopted in 2007, to open up international
passenger services to competition. The objective of the package was: ·
opening
the market for international passenger services to competition (Directive 2007/58/EC) ·
setting
the conditions and procedures for the certification of train crews operating
locomotives and trains (Directive 2007/59/EC); and ·
ensuring
basic rights for rail passengers (Regulation 1371/2007), for example, with
regard to insurance, ticketing, and for passengers with reduced mobility. The
Recast of the First Railway Package was proposed by the
Commission in 2010. Following a final vote of approval in the European
Parliament on 3 July 2012, the new EU rules should come into force by the end
of 2012. The recast aims to simplify and consolidate the rules by merging three
directives and their amendments into a single text. Importantly, the Recast
also seeks to clarify existing provisions and tackle key problem areas which
have been identified in the market over the last ten years. In particular, the
new legislation will strengthen the power of national regulators, improve the
framework for investment in rail, and ensure fairer access to rail infrastructure
and rail related services. 3.
Developments in EU rail market Despite
the considerable development of the EU acquis and rail markets, the
modal share of passenger rail in intra-EU transport has in average remained
more or less constant since 2000, at around 6%. The latest Euro-barometer
survey suggests that only 6% of Europeans uses the train at least once per
week.[47]
It should be noted that there are marked differences between Member States, but
in overall rail loses out in terms of modal share compared to other modes,
reflecting a (real or perceived) low level of efficiency, service levels and
quality compared to other transport modes. In the Consumer Scoreboard 2011[48], train services score worst of
all transport services and four in ten consumers consider the choices in that
service category to be inadequate. Improvements
will be necessary in all rail segments As
demonstrated by the EVERIS study[49],
to improve the overall modal split in favour of rail, improvement will be
necessary in all rail segments, including conventional long-distance and urban
train services. The
6% modal share for rail in the EU has remained fairly stable in spite of the
impressive development of high-speed train networks. The latter have
managed to gain some markets at the expense of air transport services, but at
the same time air transport has maintained important flows of passenger traffic
on routes competing with rail[50]. Since
the mid-nineties, local and regional passenger train services in most
Member States that did not open up their market have fallen in a downward
spiral of continuous operational losses and subsequent reduced service offer.
This decline has been exacerbated in the EU12 Member States by the decay of old
infrastructure and rolling stock on the one hand, and wealth driven high-growth
of car ownership, on the other hand. Although
commuter transport around urban agglomerations experiences growth in
some Member States, cars still secure an important share of urban transport –
59% of Europeans never use suburban trains. This situation contrasts with the
75% urbanisation rate of the EU27 and therefore indicates a huge market
development potential for suburban and regional passenger rail transport,
especially given the raising congestions on roads. The
rail freight markets within the EU have been opened for a number of
years, and the industry’s stagnation cannot therefore be simply explained by
the existence of legal barriers of the kind that continue to restrict
competition in domestic passenger services. The problem to be addressed
therefore also needs to be defined in terms of technical, physical capacity and
institutional barriers, which have frustrated action to open markets taken at
the EU level. 4.
What are the problems necessitating another rail
package? According
to available studies, the modest development of the rail sector, as explained
above, can be attributed to the presence of several administrative, technical,
institutional and legal obstacles, which still hamper market access and
operational efficiency of service providers. Domestic passenger market opening Whereas
markets for rail freight services have been fully opened to competition since
January 2007[51]
and those for international passenger transport services as of 1 January 2010[52], national domestic passenger
markets remain largely closed[53].
However, by removing the legal barrier by allowing open access to
infrastructure for domestic passenger services, would have rather limited
effects given that major part of the domestic rail market is covered by public service
contracts (PSC). The rules on the provision of transport services under public
service obligations (PSO) are laid down in Regulation 1370/2007[54] which gives the possibility to
competent authorities to exclude rail transport services from the obligation to
award PSCs through an open tendering procedure. This means that most local and
regional services, and certain long-distance services, are operated under PSO
and attributed to operators through direct award. In addition, the actual
impact of market opening depends on the specific requirements imposed for and
within PSCs, making the call either attractive or disguisedly non-attractive
for new entrants in tendering procedures (e.g. with the aim to protect the
incumbent railway undertaking). Infrastructure governance The
First Railway Package established a distinction between infrastructure managers
(IM), who run the network, and railway undertakings (RUs), that use it for
transporting passengers or goods. The legislation requires that infrastructure
charging and capacity allocation, being key factors in opening up the market,
must be performed independently of the incumbent RU so as to ensure fair and
non-discriminatory access of all operators to infrastructure. Independence of
essential functions of infrastructure management has to be ensured in legal,
organisational and decision-making terms as to allow for all railway
undertakings an equal access to infrastructure and related services. Member
States must also have independent regulatory bodies in place to monitor railway
markets and to act as an appeal body for rail companies if they believe they
have been unfairly treated. There
are, however, problems with the transposition and enforcement of these
requirements and the Commission has initiated several infringement procedures,
on which it expects the Court of Justice of the EU to express its view by the
spring 2013. The interactions between railway undertakings and infrastructure
managers, where these independence rules have not been implemented, have created
conflicts of interest still resulting in access barriers and market distortions
at the expense of new entrants, such as access denials to infrastructure and
discriminatory charges. However,
even where the existing legislation has been respected, there remain certain
problems related to the use of infrastructure and related services. Partially
these issues are expected to be solved through the more precise provisions
provided in the Recast of the First Package, especially through the
strengthened role of rail regulators. However, certain issues appear to require
further legislative intervention. For instance, according to the structure and
economics of the railway sector, it could be necessary for the purpose of
efficient infrastructure management to keep certain IM functions together,
rather than allowing them to be performed by separate (though independent)
bodies (e.g. it could be useful to couple traffic management with planning of
maintenance works). Furthermore, today the independence requirements apply only
to the essential functions (infrastructure charging and capacity allocation),
but it might be necessary to extend these requirements also to certain other
activities of the IM crucial for competition, such as infrastructure
investments planning, financing and maintenance. The optimal governance
structure has also led to reflections on the degree of institutional separation
between infrastructure management and service provision. Interoperability and safety Specific
EU legislation exists to promote interoperability in order to overcome national
historic differences in the field of technical specifications for
infrastructure (gauge widths, electrification standards and safety and
signalling systems[55]).
EU legislation also sets the framework for a harmonised approach to rail safety
in the EU[56].
Furthermore, it obliges the Member States to set up the system of national
authorities, consisting of national safety authorities, notified bodies,
national investigation bodies and regulatory bodies. The
European Railway Agency (ERA)[57],
established by the Second Railway Package, plays a central role in promoting
interoperability, harmonising technical standards, and developing common
approach to safety, all requiring close interaction with the Member States and rail sector stakeholders. While
the level of safety on EU railways has gradually increased, and therefore
safety levels as such are not an issue, stakeholders have drawn the
Commission's attention to the fact that certain technical and
administrative hurdles still persist, creating excessive administrative costs
and market access barriers, especially for new entrants. This suggests that the highly
decentralised system of railway authorities in place may not have fully coped
with the European dimension of the rail services. Firstly, existence of
largely non-transparent national technical and safety rules, which overlap
and/or are in conflict with the EU legislation, creates unnecessary
complexities for RUs. Secondly, there are marked discrepancies in how the national
safety authorities (NSAs) conduct vehicle authorisation and safety
certifications processes, some NSAs being less efficient and effective than
others. This has led to reflections on how to further enhance the role of the
ERA in the integration processes. 5.
Rationale of the Fourth Railway Package The
main objective of the Fourth Railway Package is to enhance the quality and
efficiency of rail services by removing remaining legal, institutional and
technical obstacles, fostering the performance of the railway sector and its
competitiveness. As announced by the 2011 White Paper, these issues will be
addressed by the different initiatives in three main domains: -
Domestic
passenger market opening – opening domestic rail passenger market to
competition, including open access lines as well as the routes under PSOs; -
Infrastructure
governance - ensuring that the infrastructure manager performs a
consistent set of functions that optimises the use of infrastructure capacity,
and its organisation guarantees non-discriminatory access to the infrastructure
and rail related services. -
Interoperability
and safety - removing remaining administrative and technical barriers, in
particular by establishing a common approach to safety and interoperability
rules to decrease administrative costs, to accelerate procedures, to increase
economies of scale for RUs and to avoid disguised discrimination. What about infrastructure? Obviously,
to contribute to the growth of the modal share of rail, new rail
infrastructures need to be built across Europe. The 2011 White Paper calls for
completing the European high-speed rail network by 2050, so that it would be
fully connected to airports enabling the majority of medium-distance passenger
transport to be performed by rail. Future EU strategy for infrastructure
development has been already set out in the Commission proposals for Connecting
Europe Facility[58] and the new
TEN-T Guidelines[59] and
therefore remains out of the scope of the Fourth Package. 6.
Content of the Fourth Railway Package The
package consists of following elements in the three domains: Domestic
passenger market opening: amendments to: –
Council
Directive 91/440/EEC on the development of the Community's railways/the Recast
of the first railway package –
Regulation
(EC) No 1370/2007 of the European
Parliament and of the Council of 23 October 2007 on public passenger
transport services by rail and by road The
initiatives will be accompanied by the Access to Domestic Passenger Rail
Markets. Infrastructure
governance: amendments to: –
Council
Directive 91/440/EEC on the development of the Community’s railways as amended
and Directive 2001/14/EC on the allocation of railway infrastructure capacity
and the levying of charges for the use of railway infrastructure/the Recast of
the first railway package The
initiatives will be accompanied by the IA on the
Governance of Railway Infrastructure in the Single European Railway Area. Interoperability
and safety: amendments to: –
Directive
2004/49/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 29 April 2004 on
safety on the Community's railways –
Directive
2008/57/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17 June 2008 on the
interoperability of the rail system within the Community –
Regulation
(EC) No 881/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 29 April 2004
establishing a European Railway Agency The
initiatives will be accompanied by the IA on
improving interoperability of the Single European Railway Area. In
addition the Fourth Package contains: –
a
chapeau Communication, providing overall context and justifications for the
package of proposals; –
an
ancillary initiative repealing Regulation (EEC) 1192/69 on common rules
for the normalisation of the accounts of railway undertakings, which has become
obsolete and is inconsistent with EU law in force today. 7.
objectives of the Fourth Railway package The
analysis conducted by the Commission shows, that the operational inefficiencies
and quality issues of rail services are mainly caused by low degree of
competition, remaining market distortions and suboptimal structure of EU rail
market. Underlying reasons – long and costly procedures, access barriers for
new entrants and different market access rules in Member States – will be
addressed from different angles by all the Fourth Package initiatives. Given
that, the initiatives in the Fourth Package are complementary, they all
contribute to the same general objective of improving the competitiveness
of rail sector vis-à-vis other modes. In addition, some specific objectives are
also similar of the initiatives, e.g. facilitating entrance of new operators
into the market. The
operational objectives are unique for each domain of action. The table below
demonstrates how the different elements fit together. Figure
I-2: Summary table of the objectives of the Fourth Railway
package initiatives. || Domestic passenger market opening || Infrastructure governance || Interoperability and safety General objective || Improve the quality of rail passenger services and enhance its operational efficiency … || Strengthen further the governance of railway infrastructure || Eliminate existing administrative and technical barriers … … thereby enhancing the competitiveness of rail sector vis-à-vis other modes and developing further the Single European Rail Area. Specific objectives || SO1: Intensify competitive pressure on domestic rail markets || SO1: Improve the IM ability to manage efficiently the infrastructure to the benefit of the users || SO1: Facilitate entrance of new operators into market SO2: Create more uniform business conditions || SO2: Eliminate conflict of interest and discrimination in decisions and operations of the IMs || SO2: Reduce administrative costs of railway undertakings SO3: Better value for public money spent on public transport services 8.
Options and main impacts To
achieve these objectives, all IAs will consider a range of different options,
which ultimately should improve the operational efficiency and quality of rail
services. The
IA for the domestic passenger market opening would propose and assess
options on how the interaction of access conditions between open access
services and services under PSC should be arranged. The IA would also discuss
different criteria for the design of PSC and analyse a possibility of
introducing mandatory competitive tendering for PSC. The aim of these options
would be to open the domestic rail market to competition, which should lead
more passenger friendly services and better use of public money. In order to
enhance the positive effects of market opening, the IA would analyse also
additional options for 'framework conditions', such as access to rolling stock,
through-ticketing and inter-availability of train tickets of different RUs. The
IA for the infrastructure governance initiative would study two
dimensions of options: on the one hand, what functions should be included in
the portfolio of an 'ideal IM' in order to optimise its operational and in
investment decisions, and on the other hand, how should the separation between
the IM and RUs to be enhanced in order to ensure equal level playing field for
the access to infrastructure and the related services. As a result, new-entrant
RUs should get a better access to infrastructure and related services, at the
same time the efficiency of infrastructure utilisation at national and EU level
should increase. The
IA under the interoperability and safety pillar would assess several
'institutional' options on the level of interaction between ERA and national
authorities with the aim to (a) enhance the effectiveness and efficiency of
safety certification and rolling stock authorisation processes and (b) reduce
complexity caused by excessive national railway rules. As a separate option, a
set of additional horizontal measures would be considered, which on their own
could achieve the mentioned objectives, but could also be applied on top of the
institutional options to reinforce the overall impact of reduced administrative
costs/less fragmented markets. These
policy options and their impacts will be presented and assessed in detail in
the respective IAs. 9.
Expected synergies of the package The
idea of the proposed package approach is that there are synergies to be
achieved via the combined effects of the individual initiatives. Some examples
of such synergies are provided below. –
Effectiveness
of de jure market opening depends on allowing for certain 'framework
conditions', such as access to infrastructure, rolling stock, stations, train
path allocation, etc. Some of these framework conditions will be addressed
within the domestic passenger market opening initiatives, while the others via
the proposal on infrastructure governance. –
One
way to improve rolling stock availability is to support development of rolling
stock leasing market (as considered under in the domestic passenger market
opening IA). However, a necessary condition for that is more standardised
equipment and the on-going standardisation process[60] is expected
to be enhanced by the European "passport" for vehicles, considered
within the interoperability and safety initiatives. –
All
initiatives would, in their own terms, contribute to a more predictable
business models for RUs operating across the borders of EU Member States: ·
interoperability
initiative by harmonising approach to safety certification and authorisation of
rolling stock, ·
market
access initiative by introducing universal licence for provision of passenger
services throughout the EU and setting common principles for PSO definition,
and ·
infrastructure
governance initiative by proposing a more harmonised institutional setup of
infrastructure managers in different Member States. –
Better
infrastructure governance should improve the operational efficiency of railways
and possibly allow to improve the travel times for passengers and freight. Overall, the
different operational gains expected as a result of each initiative should
allow a better value for public money, on which the functioning of railways is
still heavily reliant. ANNEX
II
PUBLIC CONSULTATION 1.
Introduction – overview of the consultation process The
consultation process was run through several channels to reach out to different
groups that face different problems vis-à-vis railways and that may be impacted
differently by the 4th railway package initiative. In
this context, 4 consultations run in parallel were preferred to an open
consultation: -
a
stakeholder consultation -
a
Eurobarometer survey -
a
consultation of the Sectoral Social Dialogue Committee for Railways -
a
consultation of regional authorities (together with the Committee of the
Regions) The
views of stakeholders were collected through targeted detailed
questionnaires and were completed by face-to-face interviews, one intermediate
hearing and finally a conference. The
views of citizens and passengers were collected through a broad Eurobarometer
survey involving 25.591 interviews in 25 Member States (Cyprus and Malta have no railways) asking some 25 questions. The Eurobarometer did not especially
cover questions related to the management of infrastructure but rather views on
market opening in general. More information on it can be found in the impact
assessment on the opening of passenger domestic rail markets. The
Sectoral Social Dialogue Committee on Railways was consulted twice in
February and June. Finally,
the network of the Committee of the Regions was used to reach local and
regional authorities. 2.
Consultation of stakeholders
2.1 -Overview of the consultation
The
consultation of stakeholders was organised in 5 phases. Figure 1- The Stakeholders
Consultation Action Plan After
a thorough identification of 427 potential respondents (cf. infra), in-depth
questionnaires were sent to each group of main stakeholders (railway undertakings,
infrastructure managers, public transport authorities, safety authorities,
ministries, representative bodies, social stakeholders, etc.). The
contractor in charge of the support study conducted face-to-face interviews
with stakeholders in Germany, UK, Italy, Hungary and Sweden. In parallel,
face-to-face interviews were organised with those stakeholders that wished to
meet DG MOVE, including face-to-face meetings in Sweden, Poland and The Netherlands. On
29 May 2012 a public hearing with 85 participants was organised in Brussels to share preliminary results obtained in the analysis of completed questionnaires
and to obtain feedback on these findings. The workshop also sought to explore
some specific issues: access to rolling stock, unbundling and social impacts
for consumers and workers. On
24 September, a stakeholder conference was organised in Brussels with some 400
participants. The conference gave the opportunity to stakeholders to provide
their views on the opening of domestic rail markets to competition, on their
role to growth, on rail and the value for society. All
feedback made by way of the questionnaire, the public hearing, by phone or by
face-to-face sessions was analysed in detail and contributed to the definition
of the problem and the analysis of impacts. The comprehensive consultation
process described meets the Commission's standards for public consultation.
2.2 - Profile of identified stakeholders and respondents
2.2.1 – Profile of respondents to the stakeholder
questionnaires
Initially,
almost 427 stakeholders from EU-25 (EU-27 excluding Cyprus and Malta which have no railway) were identified as being involved and potentially affected by
the market opening. The detail of these persons and organisations is at the end
of this annex. These
stakeholders can be categorised in four groups: -
authorities
(rail regulatory bodies, competition authorities and ministries of transport) -
infrastructure
manager managers -
railway
undertakings (including incumbent and newcomers), and -
other
stakeholders (railway manufacturers, wagon keeper and rail car leasing
companies, terminal operators, maintenance, workshop operators and other
providers of rail related services, customer and rail passenger organisations,
railway workers' organisations). In
March 2012, these 427 stakeholders were sent several on-line questionnaires
that comprised a set of common questions like the important factors associated
with quality of rail services, the problems that affect the quality of rail
services, the objectives of the Fourth Package policy initiative, policy
options with market opening, but also specific questions related to the issue
that might have greatest relevant to the organisation(s) that they are
representing. Of almost 427 questionnaires sent, 99 completed questionnaires
were returned. Responses
were obtained from the 25 Member States. However, for 12 Member States there
were 5 or fewer responses. Figure 1 - Respondents'
self-reported location of activities The
99 respondents identified themselves as representing a total of 172 different
types of organisations (which represents a response rate of 41%). Figure 2 - Respondents'
self-reported type of activity Because of double identifications[61],
respondents were reclassified to provide a better view of the profile of the
types of stakeholders. Respondents might have more than one role for reasons
such as: -
Railway
undertakings identifying themselves as both passenger and freight, or as
incumbent in one Member State and new entrant in one or more others -
Holding
companies identifying all the roles fulfilled by their subsidiaries -
Regulatory
bodies which are also competition authorities -
Representative
bodies that represent different types of stakeholder As noted above, we received few responses from some Member States and types of organisation. We concluded that it would not be possible to
analyse systematically by both Member State and respondent type. After careful review of the identity of the respondents we
therefore reclassified them with the objective of providing a clearer basis for
analysis: From
the organisation name provided, we identified and distinguished: -
Holdings/groups -
Associations/representatives For
railway undertakings: -
Incumbent
and new entrant passenger railway undertakings were combined as “Passenger RU” -
Incumbent
and new entrant freight railway undertakings were combined as “Freight RU” We
combined into a single category of “National Authorities” three different types
of respondent, all with at least some regulatory role: -
Regulatory
bodies -
Competition
authorities -
National
safety authorities Fig. 3 –
Respondents reclassified by type Finally,
the answers represent an exhaustive sample and a good cross-section of
stakeholders from almost all MS.
2.2.2 – Profile of participants to face-to face interviews
In
April 2012, targeted interviews with stakeholders were organised by the
contractor in charge of the support study in UK, Italy, Sweden, Hungary and Germany to discuss and understand better their responses during the extensive
stakeholder consultation exercise. The majority of these interviews ware held
as face-to-face sessions, with many of the most significant stakeholders within
Member States of those countries for which more detailed case studies were
prepared. In addition, the Commission held bilateral meetings with numerous
associations from the rail sector in order to hear their view. Table 1 Stakeholder interviews (CONTRACTOR) || Rationale || Location || Face-to-face || Telephone || Written || Full country fiche || France || 7 || || || Germany || 6 || || || Great Britain || 5 || || || Hungary || 4 || || || Italy || 4 || || || Intermediate country fiche || Austria || 1 || 1 || || Czech Republic || 1 || || 1 || Netherlands || 1 || || || Pan-European organisations || 4 || || Stakeholders interviewed by contractors France || || || || Ministry responsible for railways || Face-to-face || 23/04/2012 || Representative of region || Face-to-face || 24/04/2012 || ARAF (Regulatory Body) || Face-to-face || 23/04/2012 || RFF (Infrastructure Manager) || Face-to-face || 10/04/2012 || SNCF (Incumbent RU) || Face-to-face || 07/05/2012 || Keolis (Non-incumbent RU) || Face-to-face || 29/03/2012 || FGTE-CFDT (Workers Representatives) || Germany || || || || Ministry responsible for railways || Face-to-face || 20/04/2012 || Bundesnetzagentur (BNA) (Regulatory Body) || Face-to-face || 20/04/2012 || Deutsche Bahn AG (DB) (Infrastructure Manager & Incumbent RU) || Face-to-face || 18/04/2012 || BAG-SPNV (Umbrella body for Competent Authorities) || Face-to-face || 18/04/2012 || Keolis (Non-Incumbent RU) || Face-to-face || 18/04/2012 || HKX (Open-Access RU) || Face-to-face || 30/04/2012 || Hungary || || || || Ministry responsible for railways || Face-to-face || 25/04/2012 || NKH (Regulatory Body and Safety Authority) || Face-to-face || 25/04/2012 || VPE (Capacity Allocator) || Face-to-face || 25/04/2012 || MAV and GySEV (Infrastructure Managers and incumbent RUs) || Face-to-face || 25/04/2012 || Italy FS (Incumbent RU) || Face-to-face || 26/04/2012 || URSF (Regulatory Body) || Face-to-face || 18/04/2012 || Also,
Commission services met in Brussels with representatives from the following
organisations throughout 2012: -
BAFG
– German Association of Passenger Rail Authorities -
CER
– Community of European railways -
EIM
– European Infrastructure Managers Association -
EPTO
– European Passenger Transport Operators -
EPF
– European Passenger Federation -
ERFA
– European Railway Freight Association -
ETF
– European Transport Worker's Federation -
Network
Rail -
NMBS-SNCB
Holding (Belgian Railways) -
ÖBB
– Austrian railways -
UITP
– Union Internationale des Transports Publics -
UK Department
for Transport Additionally,
the Polish, Swedish and Dutch authorities organised meetings between
stakeholders (infrastructure managers, regulators, railway undertakings) and
Commission services in Stockholm, Warsaw and Utrecht:
2.2.3- Profile of participants of stakeholder hearings and
conferences
The
list of participants to the stakeholder hearings and conferences was drawn on
the basis of the list of initially 427 identified stakeholders. The
following organisations took the floor at the stakeholder hearing of 29th May: -
Association
of Train Operating Companies (ATOC) UK -
BAG
SPNV
(German passenger transport authorities) -
Community
of European Railways (CER) -
Deutsche
Bahn -
European
Infrastructure Managers (EIM) -
European
Passenger Federation (EPF) -
European
Passenger Transport Operators (EPTO) -
European
Rail Freight Association (ERFA) -
European
Transport Workers Federation (ETF) -
Ferrovie
dello Stato / Trenitalia -
Freighliners -
Irish
Department of Transport -
JSC
Lithuanian Railways -
Ministry
of Transport, Infrastructure and Environment (Netherlands) -
Ministry
of Transport (France) -
SNCF -
Network
Rail (UK Infrastructure Managers) -
NTV
Nuovo Trasporto Viaggatori -
Transportstyrelsen
(Sweden) -
Union
Internationale des Transports Publics (UITP) -
Veolia The
following organisations made presentations at the stakeholder conference of 24th September: -
Ministry
of Transport (Sweden) -
Community
of European Railways (CER) -
NTV
Nuovo Trasporto ViaggatoriFirst Group (UK) -
Amadeus -
Ministry
of Transport (Belgium) -
CFR
Calatori (Romanian railways) -
GATX
Railcar Leasing -
Office
of Railway Regulation (UK regulator) -
Freighliner
UK -
Freighliner
Poland -
UNIFE
(European railway industry) -
European
Infrastructure Managers (EIM) -
Network
Rail (UK Infrastructure Managers) -
BAG
SPNV (German passenger transport authorities) -
European
Passenger Transport Operators (EPTO) -
Verkehrverbund
Berlin-Brandenburg -
European
Passenger Train and Traction Operating Lessors' Association ( EPTTOLA) -
Province of Gelderland (Netherlands) Members
of the European Parliament were also invited to take the floor.
2.3 - The stakeholder consultation process
This
targeted consultation was organised by the contractor in charge of the support study.
The consultation took place from 1st March till 16 April (responses
obtained till mid-June were accepted and incorporated). As
a first step, the contractor consulted stakeholders through a two-part
questionnaire sent via email. The first questionnaire was common to all
stakeholders and was completed by extra questions for each type of organisation
(infrastructure manager, passenger operations, worker's representative etc…). The
questionnaires were structured in four sections focused on: ·
The
quality of rail services in the EU, which includes punctuality, passenger
comfort, on board services, information, service frequency and intra-modal and
intermodal integration, ·
Obstacles
which hamper market access, limits new entrants and hinder the internal market
for rail passenger services; ·
The
different objectives of this policy initiatives that could improve the quality
of rail services ·
Checking
the willingness of stakeholders to adopt a specific option concerning the
market opening
2.4 - Main results of the on-line consultation
2.4.1 - The problem definition
The
majority of the stakeholders (85% for passenger services and 90% in freight
services) agreed that the quality of rail services affects the competitiveness
of the rail sector. The
majority of the stakeholders of the targeted consultation supported the problem
and agreed that the quality of rail and the competitiveness of the rail sector
in the EU were affected by lack of competitive incentives, inadequate
regulatory oversight, discriminatory framework conditions and access barriers
for railway undertakings.
2.4.2 - The objectives
Overall,
the stakeholders have supported the general problem and the problem drivers as
identified by the Commission, as well as the general direction of EU action.
69% agreed that the objective of improved access to infrastructure addressed
the objectives of the initiative.
2.4.3- The policy options
Concerning
the creation of a coordination body including, in a non-discriminatory manner,
representatives from all infrastructure users to ensure that their interests
are duly taken into consideration by IMs, 64% of those who responded and
offered an opinion supported this idea. Few respondents commented that bodies
allowing a dialogue between IMs and RUs already exist (one referred to RailNetEurope,
EIM and CER as appropriate EU fora for such dialogue). In the same manner, the
unification of IM functions is largely supported by stakeholders. Regarding
the appropriate measure to prevent conflicts of interest and distortion of
competition, the responses of the different stakeholders are highly polarised. Institutional
separation is generally supported by the largest number of stakeholders:
independent IMs (such as Network Rail, RFF, represented at EU level by EIM),
new entrant railway undertakings operating freight (e.g. Mofair in Germany,
Freightliner in Poland, AFRA in France, HektorRail in Sweden, ERFA at EU level)
and/or passenger services (e.g. NTV in Italy, RegioJet in Czech Republic) but
also few IMs and railway undertakings part of holding structures (in particular
Infrabel and SNCB in Belgium). The same position is largely shared among
transport ministries, competition authorities and regulatory bodies (including
in Member States which opted for holding structures), passenger organisations
(such as Passenger Focus in UK, FNAUT in France), freight forwarders and
shippers (represented at EU level by CLECAT and ESC), public transport
authorities (e.g. in Germany BAFG) and industry suppliers (e.g. FIF in France). These interested parties request in particular
the establishment of a genuine level playing field ensuring the absence of conflicts
of interest and full financial transparency. They claim
that institutional separation is most efficient model and the only one capable
to ensure that IMs, as a natural monopoly, work not only in favour of the
incumbent but all whole society and are in a position to develop cross-border
cooperation (rather than to protect the incumbent domestic market). They argue
that with holding models regulatory supervision would be necessarily too
burdensome (and costly). Suspicion of the lack of fairness in infrastructure
management would persist and affect private investments in the rail sector
significantly. The
main supporters to alternatives to institutional separation are quite logically
holding structures, including the incumbent freight and passenger railway
undertakings and infrastructure managers which are part of them, (in particular
the members of DB, OBB, FS and PKP groups) and some workers representatives
(represented at EU level by ETF). Transport ministries, and in few cases, the
regulatory body, in Member States where holding structures are in place tend to
also support status quo or alternatives to institutional separation, such as a
stronger role for regulatory bodies (eg in Germany). Some incumbents currently
separated (such as SNCF in France and NS in the Netherlands) and few new
entrants (specifically those at least partly owned by incumbents such as
Arriva, WestBahn) are also in favour of alternatives to institutional
separation or at least to leave to Member States to choice of such option. In
one Member State, France, the public transport authorities (represented by the
ARF) indicated that they would support the holding model. These
opponents to institutional separation tend to accept that this is the most
effective way to avoid conflicts of interest and ensure financial transparency.
However they argue that there are alternative ways to ensure the absence of
discriminatory practices and, in particular that the reinforcement of
regulatory bodies (which is one measure already introduced by the Recast)
should ensure this in a more efficient manner. They generally claim that
institutional separation could affect the "system efficiency" leading
to loss of economies of scope (misalignments). They favour the existence of a
"system integrator" which would be the incumbent/dominant operator
rather than the infrastructure manager itself. They also suggest that the
chosen model must provide for an efficient and non-discriminatory network
access for all operators but also must remain affordable. Finally, few
stakeholders argued that there is no empirical evidence about the benefits of
complete separation and that part of the available scientific literature highlights
disadvantages of complete separation. A number of incumbent railway
undertakings also suggested that, particularly in small and technically
separated national railway markets, benefits of full separation might not
offset the corresponding transaction costs. Some proposed that respective
Member States should be allowed to choose the most appropriate model. The
following table show the main advantages and risks of each type of governance
of the infrastructure manager according to stakeholders. Institutional separation Potential benefits || Potential risks · No conflicts of interest and absence of discrimination in infrastructure access · Clearer role division and responsibilities of the different market players · Specialisation benefits · Full financial transparency ensured · Harmonisation of national governance facilitating cross-border cooperation between IM · Give confidence to new entrants and stimulate thereby private investments || · Disconnection of IM from the market needs · Abuse of the infrastructure monopoly position · Fragmentations and misalignment of the system: synergy and communication losses · Additional transaction costs and efficiency loss Holding Model Potential benefits || Potential risks · Easier alignment/coordination between IM and RU (the incumbent) for investment and operational decisions · Limited transaction costs (between the IM and the incumbent) · Make the provision of services under public service contracts easier (for the incumbent) · Facilitate investments in rolling stock (for the incumbent) || · No transparency in decisions-making and financial flows · Persistence of discriminations · More intense regulatory supervision required · Minor willingness to cooperate
2.5 - The stakeholder hearing of 29 May
The
stakeholder hearing was devoted to the presentation of the results of the
on-line consultation and subsequent discussions on market opening (not relevant
for this impact assessment) and the IM governance. Several views were expressed regarding
infrastructure governance: -
An association of passenger transport authorities
indicated that integrated structures do not allow for independent investment
decisions. -
An infrastructure manager called for a
broadening of the scope of essential functions beyond capacity allocation and
charging -
Rail freight undertakings advocated separation
as the only way to build the single market and underlined that unbundling would
not hamper performance, quite the contrary. -
Railway undertakings called for a facts-based
pragmatic approach, asking for a thorough estimation of transaction costs and
impact on the quality of infrastructure -
A workers organisation claimed that
institutional separation could destroy jobs and remove the possibilities of
mobility for rail workers (to change functions within single railway
undertakings).
2.6 - The stakeholder conference of the 24th September
The
conference was attended by 420 representatives across the industry who
participated in 3 key workshops as well as hearing an array of speakers. It
was clear that there was a desire to get the structure of the railway right
once and for all. An interactive and competitive railway across all of Europe was in the best interests of everybody. Interoperability is vital to allow
innovation through liberalisation and a level playing field is a pre-requisite
for encouraging new market entrants. On
the governance proposals for IMs, a broad consensus was agreed on the needs of
a better governance relationship containing strategic intermodal and efficiency
drivers. Discussions took place on issues such as equality, impartiality and
the vital need for a level playing field. The relationship between the IM and
all RUs was discussed, as was whether incumbents are better placed to bring
forward operational efficiencies. It was felt that any future proposal should
ensure stability for the medium to longer term bearing in mind the dynamics of
the potential tensions between equality and efficiency. Participants
were broadly in favour of improving the competitiveness of rail and further
development of the Single European Rail Area. For sustainable high quality and
efficient transport a move to mandatory tendering of contracts with some open
access provision was felt to provide improved value through a reduction in
public subsidies and benefits through improvements in service quality and
infrastructure use and patronage. Fears of social dumping and lowering of
safety standards were tempered down drawing on the experience of the Member
States that liberalised their rail markets. Further
details can be found in minutes of the conference. 3.
Consultation of social partners The railway manufacturing
industry responded through one questionnaire and worker organisations were also
consulted through the Social Dialogue Committee and through ETF (European
Transport Workers Association) in the consultation of stakeholders (social
aspects were also covered during the stakeholder hearing of 29 May). The
Sectoral Social Dialogue Committee on Railways was consulted on the 26 March
and the 19 June, in particular on the options and the social impact assessment.
Associations of workers were overall sceptical that the opening of domestic
rail passenger markets would contribute to the growth of the rail traffic, the
improvement of the efficiency and quality of rail services. Worker
organisations present at the meeting highlighted that funding of the rail
sector and its infrastructure would be more effective to reach those same
objectives. In such context, worker organisations did not wish to position
themselves on any of the options related to the IM governance that were
presented to them on those meetings as they considered them as supporting
measures in favour of market opening. The employer's representatives (from
incumbent) did not take part in the discussion on this occasion. ANNEX
III PROBLEM EVIDENCE 1.
Anecdotal evidences related to the problem of
diverging interpretation of existing separation requirements (section 3.2.2.1.1
of the main report) Discriminations
in charging practices: ·
A number of cases have been dealt with by German
competition and regulatory authorities in which the German IM (which is part of
the German incumbent holding group) was accused of having introduced
discriminatory charges. For instance, the competition authority found that the
charging system TPS 1998 allows for charges for DB Regio to be 25% - 40% lower
than that of its competitors. The German regulator also pinpointed the use of
"regional factors" in track access charging (i.e. definition of
charges applicable to specific parts of the rail network) which were discriminatory
vis-à-vis competitors of the incumbent. ·
In Austria, the infrastructure division of ÖBB
is responsible for setting the relevant charges, for both infrastructure and
station access. The new open-access operator, WESTbahn, has reported that,
starting from 2012, station access charges for passenger trains will rise at a
much higher rate than in previous years. According to the competitor, station
prices have risen, but in particular for those stations on the Westbahn line
including St. Pölten (78% more) and Linz (66,33% more). At the same time, track
access charges suddenly increased by 14.4%, while in previous years the
increases were about 2.5% on average[62]. In
addition ÖBB introduced a special surcharge for high-speed trains which did not
exist before. The congestion surcharge will be replaced from 2013 onwards by a
new capacity utilisation surcharge, which is approximately 60% higher. These
increases also affect the incumbent ÖBB's services, however according to the
competitor ÖBB is compensated for such increases by the state in the public
service contract (see below). OECD
(2005b) describes a case in Germany in which the Bundeskartellamt found that IM
DB Netz favoured the integrated railway undertaking DB Regio over rivals by
means of volume discounts in an early version of its track access charging
system. ·
In February 2011 ÖBB Personenverkehr and the
Austrian Competent Authority SCHIG GmbH signed a framework PSC, in which SCHIG
agreed to compensate fully any increases in track access charges throughout the
duration of the contract[63]. This follows the conclusion of a new PSC framework contract
between the Ministry of Transport and ÖBB, which provides for full compensation
for any increase in access charges. WESTbahn have argued that the new charging
structure is discriminatory since ÖBB does not face the same risk. ·
In May 1998, Deutsche Bahn introduced its
charging system ‘TPS 98. This system was essentially based on quantity
rebates.The German Cartel Office Bundeskartellamt came to the conclusion that
new entrants had to pay 25%-40% higher charges than the holding operators of
DB. In another legal procedure regarding the same system the courts recognised
that a new entrant freight operator had to pay 130% higher charges than DB
Cargo. The legal proceedings on this issue lasted until 2005[64]. ·
On 5 March 2010 the regulator BNetzA decided
that the so called regional factors must be deleted from December 2010.
Regional factors lead to an increase of up to the factor 1.91 for lines in the
countryside which are primarily used by DB's competitors. The authority
considered these price factors as an illegal obstacle network access, which was
based on any valid reason. After some legal proceedings the authority concluded
a deal with DB Netz, according to which these regional factors will be scrapped
from December 2011. Since they were introduced already in 2003, htis illegal
discrimination of competitors existed for almost 9 years[65]. ·
In Germany, DB Energie, the DB subsidiary
responsible for providing electricity to the rail network applied volume
discounts that favour DB operating subsidiaries since only they benefit from
the maximum discount available. As a result, competing RUs paid electricity
charges 15-20% higher than those paid by DB. In February 2012 BNetzA, the
German rail regulator, required that DB Energie reduce the fee by 23%, which it
has agreed to do. However, DB Energie did not keep its promise to abolish the
discriminatory discount system as of 1/1/2013[66]. Discriminations in path allocation
practices: ·
On 25 July 2012, the Italian Competition
Authority (ICA) sanctioned Ferrovie dello Stato (FS) for a violation of Article
102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) and imposed a
fine amounting to € 300 000 following a complaint filed by Arenaways S.p.A., a
competitor of FS active on the passenger rail transport market and two
Consumers Associations. In particular, the ICA found that FS, through its
subsidiaries RFI and Trenitalia had put in place a “complex and unified
strategy” to keep Arenaways, which went bankrupted at the time of the decision,
out of the profitable route between Milan and Turin between 2008 and 2011. The
ICA ascertained that RFI put into place a dilatory conduct when Arenaways asked
the assignment of train tracks: when receiving the first track assignment train
path allocation request by Arenaways on 11 April 11, 2008, RFI did not process
the request, arguing that it could not answer before being sure that the PSCs
the economic equilibrium of the PSCs would not be compromised. The access to
the tracks was thereafter delayed for over 18 months, i.e. until 13 May 13,
2010, when RFI finally asked the Regulator to start the procedure aimed at
evaluating the impact of the economic equilibrium of the PSCs of competitor’s. ·
At the end of 2010 and beginning of 2011,
Italian new entrants complained about several unexpected changes in the Network
Statement of RFI which would obstruct their access to the network. First of all
the date for the presentation of a safety certificate was advanced from
November to August in the year before a new timetable. This would have had the
consequence that NTV would not have been able to apply for train paths for the
period from December 2011, since their trains would only be operational from
October 2011. According to NTV there was no technical reason for advancing this
deadline. At the same time, the draft network statement of November 2010 also
inflicted other new and onerous conditions on the operators to apply for train
paths, in particular the obligation to keep reserve locomotives and cranes in
order to continue their operations respectively remove the broken down
locomotives in case of accidents. Such requirement is unusual as in other EU
countries such tasks are done by the IMs. While it is not a problem for a large
company such as Trenitalia, it would be financially so burdensome for smaller
new entrant freight operators that it could seriously affect their ability to
stay in the market. ·
The Italian new entrant NTV complained
publically about the high cost and long duration of the homologation procedure
for its AGV trains (45 months between July 2008 and March 2012) and claimed
that such process has been negatively impacted by FS practices and in
particular by the refusal of its infrastructure management subsidiary RFI to
grant the train paths necessary for testing purposes. ·
In Italy, for example, when incumbent operator
Trenitalia withdrew its Eurocity services to Austria and Germany, it claimed a number of the previously used train paths for other services. This
meant that the joint venture involving DB, ÖBB and an Italian RU received less
favourable paths and was not able to offer equivalent journey times to the
former Eurocity services[67]. It is not clear whether the resulting allocation of capacity was
more or less efficient, but decisions of this kind on the part of a
vertically-integrated railway are likely to give rise to allegations of
discrimination even if they are motivated by other considerations. ·
The company Locomore wanted to offer train services
from Cologne to Hamburg from August 2010. They wanted to apply for a framework
agreement which would give sufficient certainty for the heavy investment which
is needed for long-distance passenger services. In order to have the necessary
time to plan the service and acquire the necessary rolling stock, they wanted
to conclude such a framework agreement in 2010 with a view to offer their
services from 2012 or 2013. However the infrastructure manager DB Netz, which
is part of the integrated DB Holding, refused this and insisted on a start of
the operation in December 2011, with the argument that 5-year periods have to
be respected for framework agreements. Locomore had to postpone its services,
in order not to risk penalty payments in case it is not able to start in
December 2011[68]
. It referred the case to the regulator BNetzA which ruled that DB Netz has to
accept applications for framework agreement even within the five-year periods
(a possibility also foreseen in the law) [69]. However DB did not accept this decision and started a legal
procedure in the Courts which is still ongoing. Similar problems as in the case
of Locomore were also encountered by SNCF which had to withdraw its project to
offer a train from Cologne to Hamburg. They criticised that "the procedure
of DB Netz for the path allocation is done in a way to leave no chance for
competitors to make alternative offers"[70]. ·
In Germany, a recent report by the
Monopolkommission[71] (MK) has accused the incumbent operator DB of discrimination
against competitors when giving access to the network, in particular by
providing: (1) Insufficient information about the infrastructure capacity
available (regarding both train paths and facilities). (2) No information
regarding the physical characteristics of routes (such as curve radii or
gradients). (3) Making non-flexible framework contracts and providing
insufficient time between contract signature and the start of operations. (4)
Lacking a framework of incentives for the IM which would motivate the IM to
improve the quality of its infrastructure. (5) Not granting access to service
facilities for competitors (although the MK believes this problem is the result
of insufficient clarity of current legislation). Competitive
advantages of integrated structures in terms of information asymmetry ·
Westbahn, a new entrant in Austria requested the Austrian IM (ÖBB Infrastruktur) to allow all operators the access to
real time information so that they could inform their passengers about actual
departure times of connecting services – mostly run by the competing incumbent
ÖBB - in the light of delays and cancellations. ÖBB Infrastruktur, which has
real time data available on the whole Austrian rail network, rejected the
request, arguing that it only discloses data belonging to the railway
undertaking making the request. Westbahn filed a complaint to the Austrian
regulator (which has in turn referred prejudicial questions to the ECJ). In his
conclusions of 7 June 2012 the Advocate General of the Court of Justice Niilo
Jääskinen supported this claim of Westbahn[72]. ·
In Germany, in the past, the incumbent was in a
position to propose bids for public service contracts containing discounted
infrastructure charges, which other participants could not enjoy. This practice
was criticised by the German regulator (and was later forbidden) A recent case
published by MOFAIR, the organisation of new entrant passenger operators in Germany, seems to indicate that this practice is still on going. MOFAIR highlights the case
of a public service contract for rail in Saxony-Anhalt where the contract was
directly attributed to DB, on the basis of a commitment of DB's subsidiary DB
Regio to compensate any rise in track access charging affecting the contract
for a duration of 15 years.[73]
MOFAIR claims that such conditions can only be offered by an integrated company
where the losses of the transport subsidiaries are covered by contributions
from the holding which are drawn from infrastructure revenues. ·
In
November 2008 investigators of the French competition authority DGCCRF searched
offices of SNCF on the basis of allegations that several new entrants had made
about the fact that SNCF, in view of its participation in the timetabling
process, obtained knowledge of the train paths requested by these new entrants.
On the basis of this knowledge SNCF was alleged to have found out about the
identity of the prospective clients of these new entrants and to have
approached them proposing more favourable conditions than the new entrants.
[74] ·
According
to the German competitors' association Mofair[75], the yearly
timetable was elaborated in a two-tier system: first DB Netz was coordinating
the basic schedule with its sister companies of the holding, on the basis of
their needs, only afterwards DB Netz tries to fit the requests of competitors
in this schedule. DB Netz refuses to publish schedules which would allow (in an
anonymous way) to see which tracks are reserved and whether the infrastructure
manager has really checked all the possible alternatives in case the path which
was originally rejected cannot be realised. This type of information is given
in other countries such as Denmark, Norway, Sweden, etc. ·
According
to the report of the German Monopoly Commission[76], an
independent consultative body to the German government, there have been in the
past many complaints on insufficient and untimely information about planned
works on the infrastructure. After an action of the regulator, the situation
seems to have improved on the basis of a deal which DB Netz concluded at the
first-level administrative court in Cologne, having first attacked the
regulators injunction to improve the information. However, despite these
improvements, according to the Monopoly Commission the integrated
infrastructure manager still does not take account of the interests of
competitors when planning works, but only considers costs and opportunity of
such measures for the companies of the holding[77]. 2.
Anecdotal evidences related to discriminations in IM
functions not covered by existing separation requirements (section 3.2.1.3 of
the main report) Discrimination
rising from the absence of separation of maintenance and development functions
of IMs ·
A
French MEP has officially expressed to the Commission its dissatisfaction with
the attitude of the Italian IM, RFI, which is integrated in the holding group
of the railway incumbent Trenitalia. RFI would have performed maintenance works
on the Mont Cenis line affecting specifically the provision of cross-border
passenger services by SNCF. ·
The
vertically integrated Lithuanian IM removed 19km of tracks at the border
between Lithuania and Latvia for maintenance reasons. The Latvian authorities
publically claimed that this action has affected competition from railway
undertakings from Latvia. ·
In
Austria, the regulatory body Schienen-Control received several complaints
regarding line closures due to engineering works for the Brenner tunnel in the
summer 2012. In order to save on construction costs, ÖBB-Infrastruktur tends to
close lines for several consecutive weeks. New entrants claimed that this
behaviour leads to increased costs for them since they have to bear extra costs
and higher access fees for deviations or a temporary contracting-out of road
transport services. While the Austrian regulator did not object to the closure
of the tunnel as such, which it considered as necessary, however priority rules
applied during the closure were considered as discriminatory[78]. Discrimination
rising from the absence of separation for traffic management ·
In
2010 the German regulator BNetzA ruled that DB has to change the practice of
its traffic management centres. DB Netz had so far only invited staff of the
railway undertakings of its own holding to attend traffic management activities
in the centres. This gave these persons the possibility not only to know about
traffic relevant issues (delays, works etc.) much faster than the competitors,
but also potentially the possibility to influence the priority given to trains
of different RUs in case of delays. This results in competitive advantages of the
DB Holding companies in terms of costs and punctuality of their own trains[79]. ·
Competitors
criticised the way in which DB Netz organised its performance regime. A
performance regime is a system devised by an infrastructure manager, as part of
its charging scheme, which is supposed to penalise delays in the train
operation caused either by infrastructure managers or railway undertakings. In
the first proposal for such a performance regime 90% of the delays were
attribute to railway undertakings, and only 10% to DB Netz, by exempting delays
caused by works on the infrastructure. This was criticised by competitors, and
the regulator ordered DB Netz to change its system. DB was also criticised by
the competitors for having instructed its dispatchers to attribute the delay
causes in a way to keep DB Netz penalties as low as possible. Another criticism
of this performance regime was that freight trains had to pay the same
penalties for delays as passenger trains which are much more time sensitive. At
that time competitors had a much higher market share in freight traffic in
comparison with passenger traffic where the market share of DB is even much
higher. The performance regime of DB Netz has led to lengthy legal procedures,
leading to a suspension of the system, and a reformulation which was again
under review of the regulator[80]. ·
In
France, the new entrant freight company Euro Cargo Rail (ECR) has since 2011
operated cross-border services between France and Spain in competition with the
incumbent operator SNCF. Due to the different gauge sizes between the two
countries, these operations require a gauge change at the marshalling yards in
Cerbère (Pyrénées-Orientales). Soon after operations began, ECR filed a
complaint to ARAF against RFF and SNCF. The new entrant claimed that its
shunting and train formation activities had been purposefully impeded at
Cerbère, and that the operational management of the service tracks necessary
for the management should not be done by its competitor SNCF Fret, but by DCF,
the traffic management entity of SNCF which is under the supervision of the
independent infrastructure manager RFF. ARAF agreed with the part of the
complaint that the management of shunting should not have been under the
supervision of Fret SNCF. As a result, the Authority ordered RFF to modify the
organisation at Cerbère and to give DCF the responsibility to manage both RUs[81]. ·
In
the Netherlands the regulatory body, the NMa, has reported some complaints over
ineffective allocation of functions in 2010. Transport operators voiced
concerns about ProRail’s neutrality with regard to the Day Plan. This is the
updated version of the Annual Timetable for a specific day in which all
changes, such as ad hoc capacity requests and planned network closures, have
been processed. The reason for these concerns is the presence of NS's presence
at the OCCR (Operational Control Centre Rail), where the Day Plan is
formulated, as this could be a potential threat to the creation of a level
playing field. For this reason the NMa issued a Notice of Opinion concerning
the development of the OCCR to the effect that certain conditions must be met
in order to ensure ProRail’s neutrality. In particular, ProRail must: (1)
Guarantee that it will allocate rail capacity in an independent and non-discriminatory
manner, (2) Ensure that RUs cannot gain access to confidential information, (3)
Charge RUs the costs of the OCCR, by means of an infrastructure charge, (4)
Include all information regarding the OCCR in the Network Statement. The NMa is
closely following the development of the OCCR to ensure that it is consistent
with the development of competition[82]. ANNEX IV OPTION
ANALYSIS 1.
Approach to policy
options The
impact assessment identified two main challenges to be addressed in order to
find an optimal governance structure of infrastructure managers (IMs) – efficiency
challenge and equal access challenge. To
address the efficiency challenge, the IMs should be more market oriented
and focussed on the needs of infrastructure users. Firstly, means should be foreseen
to improve the communication between IMs and RUs. Secondly, coordination among
IMs should be improved. Thirdly, to improve performance, the IM functions
should be managed in a consistent manner. To
address the equal access challenge, there is a need for further
reinforcement of independence of IMs from incumbent operators in order to avoid
discrimination of new entrants and conflicts of interest stemming from
existence of holding structures. The key question is two-fold: which IM
functions should be separated and how strict should the separation requirements
be? This
annex considers five groups of options, each proposing measures to remedy the
different problem elements. The aim is to justify the decision making of policy
creation and make it transparent why certain initial policy measures have been
dropped and how the options in different groups will be assessed and combined. For
each group of options the annex explains the context, discusses possible policy
choices and screens them on the basis of stakeholder views, effectiveness,
efficiency, compliance with subsidiarity principles and overall feasibility.
Where relevant, the different aspects of implementation are also discussed. 2.
Stakeholder views The
majority of stakeholders agreed during the targeted consultation that the
quality of rail services and the competitiveness of the sector in the EU were
affected by different access barriers for RUs. 69% found different
interpretation of legislation to be an issue. Infrastructure capacity
constraints were considered to be the main access barrier for RUs (quoted by
83%). The
results of the consultation show also that views are highly polarised regarding
the appropriateness of solutions to these problems, e.g. how to ensure
independent and efficient governance of railway infrastructure. Some
stakeholders (a large majority of transport ministries, competition
authorities, regulatory bodies, passenger and freight RUs, passengers and
freight forwarders associations) advocated a complete separation which
would ensure full transparency and a level playing field for all operators.
Other stakeholders, in particular holding companies, infrastructure managers
depending on such holdings and workers' representatives, argued that there is
no empirical evidence about the benefits of complete separation and that some
scientific literature, highlights disadvantages such as higher transaction
costs and risks of disconnection inefficiencies. These stakeholders think that
a stronger role of regulatory oversight could be sufficient to solve the
issues. 64%
of respondents support the idea of creation of a specific body of
representatives from all infrastructure users, with the aim of ensuring that
their interests are taken into account in a non-discriminatory way. More
detailed overview of stakeholder views is presented in Annex 2 of the IA. 3.
Description of different
groups of options 3.1.
Coordination (C)
options: Coordination between IMs and rail operators 3.1.1.
Context Railway
infrastructure is a natural monopoly and its construction and maintenance
relies heavily on public support. This means that IMs
tend to manage the infrastructure giving priority to the instructions received
from the public authorities and to neglect the needs expressed by users in the
infrastructure operations and planning.
Therefore, the appropriate incentives for IMs to better
respond to market needs have to be ensured by relevant governance mechanisms. 3.1.2.
Description of options In
this context, the following options have initially been considered: ·
Option C0: Baseline scenario
– do nothing. The Recast reinforces the obligations of IMs to
consult infrastructure users on important decisions, for instance giving
infrastructure users the opportunity to express their views on the content of
their business plan and on the network statement detailing the conditions for
access to the infrastructure. The
Recast also foresees that performance targets defined in multi-annual contract
by Member States and infrastructure managers shall be user-oriented. It
requires Member States to set incentives for infrastructure managers to reduce
both costs and access charges. ·
Option C1: RUs
participate to the administrative board or supervisory board of the IM. While
EU law currently in force implies that RUs do not control the decision making
process of IMs in relation with essential functions, this option would foresee
that all RUs active on a network would be entitled to a seat in the supervisory
board or management of the IM responsible for this network. RUs would therefore
take a direct and active part in the management of the infrastructure. ·
Option C2: Coordination bodies.
This option foresees a creation of coordination bodies representing all RUs and
providing opinions to IMs. RUs would not participate in the administrative
board or supervisory board of the IM, preserving thereby the existing principle
of decision-making independence. However, in order to align strategies and to
address jointly issues which cannot be solved by the implementation of the
charging principles, performance regime foreseen by the Recast (such as
operational costs or capacity under normal conditions), they would be part of a
consultative body allowing a constant exchange of information between IMs and
RUs. ·
Option C3: Financial
incentives alignment. Under this option financial incentives are introduced
for both RUs and IMs to ensure that they contribute to the jointly established
efficiency targets. 3.1.3.
Options discarded at an early stage None. 3.1.4.
Screening of options The
initial set of options has been screened in terms of stakeholder support,
effectiveness in achieving the operational objectives, efficiency and
compliance with the subsidiarity principle. In addition, the overall
feasibility has been verified, i.e. whether the options are legally and
technically possible to pursue. Brief explanation relating to the scores is
presented in the column 'motivation'. Key
of scores applied: --- … - || decreasingly negative 0 || neutral + … +++ || increasingly positive / || not relevant √ || complying ~ || not complying || Stakeholder support || Effectiveness in terms of operational objectives || Efficiency || Subsidiarity || Feasibility || Motivation Better alignment between IMs and RUs || Consistent management of IM functions || Prevent conflict of interests Option C0: Baseline || - || 0 || / || / || 0 || √ || √ || Measures foreseen in the Recast will provide some additional incentives to IMs to improve their performance, but would not allow addressing specific operational problems or ensuring communication of strategic needs of users. Option C1: Participation to IM board || + || ++ || / || - || + || ~/√ || ~ || This option would ensure alignment between IM and RUs and non-discriminatory access to information. However it may still create problems of conflicts of interest and discriminations in IM decisions depending on the weight of each RU in the board. It would be a burdensome solution and difficult to implement as the number and identity of the RUs operating on a network may evolve. Option C2: Coordination bodies || +++ || ++ || / || + || ++ || √ || √ || This option is largely supported by stakeholders. It should ensure IM-RUs alignment while preserving their decision-making independence and thereby preventing conflicts of interest. The creation of a coordination body is the less burdensome option easily adaptable to the characteristics of individual IMs. Option C3: Financial incentives alignment || + || ++ || / || - || 0 || ~ || ~ || This option can be an effective solution for incentive alignment between IM and RU. However, depending on how incentives are designed, they may be sources of discrimination between IMs. The efficiency of this measure largely depends on the way incentives are adapted to the individual IM which may be considered a matter of subsidiarity. Along
with the baseline scenario, Option C2 will be retained for further analysis
of different policy scenarios in the impact assessment. 3.1.5.
Aspects of implementation As
explained above, ad hoc consultations between IMs and RUs are already required
by EU law and IMs have in place different arrangements to dialogue with
infrastructure users. Under Option C2, the formalisation of a coordination body
would be required. Its role and its purpose would be defined by EU law. In
accordance with the principle of subsidiarity, the adoption of more detailed
provisions would be left to Member States, subject to the principle of
transparency and non-discrimination between its members. 3.2.
Function (F) options:
Consistent management of IM functions 3.2.1.
Context The
capacity of an IM to develop and optimise transport infrastructure and ensure
quality, reliability, flexibility and customer orientation, depends on its actual
control over all key infrastructure functions. According
to current legislation the two essential functions of IM are path allocation
and track access charging. However, there are substantial interactions between
these essential functions and other key IM functions, in particular traffic
management, infrastructure maintenance and development. Their distribution
among different market players can lead to inconsistencies in management and
increased coordination costs. 3.2.2.
Description of options The
options below are defined to identify an optimal portfolio of IM functions
ensuring its control over all functions necessary for efficient performance. ·
Option F0: Baseline scenario -
do nothing – EU law foresees the possibility to allocate IM functions to
different entities and stipulates explicitly that existing essential functions
may be allocated to independent charging and allocation bodies, distinct form
the IM. There is no specific incentive to ensure a consistent management of
these different functions when they are allocated to different entities. ·
Option F1: New
coordination mechanism. This option would maintain the current possibility
to allocate IM functions to different entities but foresee the establishment of
a mechanism to oblige these entities to better coordinate the management of IM
functions. ·
Option F2: Unified
IM. Under this option, all IM functions – path
allocation and track access charging, but also traffic management,
infrastructure maintenance and development are
put under the responsibility of a single entity, the unified IM. 3.2.3. Options
discarded at an early stage None 3.2.4. Screening
of options Criteria
applied to screening of options are the same as in previous section. || Stakeholder support || Effectiveness in terms of operational objectives || Efficiency || Subsidiarity || Feasibility || Motivation Better alignment between IMs and RUs || Consistent management of IM functions || Prevent conflict of interests Option F0: Baseline || - || / || -- || - || - || √ || √ || This option does not ensure a consistent management of the different IM functions and may create conflicts of interest as some IM functions may be controlled by a RU. It raises costs as interfaces between the different entities in charge of IM functions have to be established. Option F1: New coordination mechanisms || - || / || + || 0 || + || √ || √ || This option could be neutral in terms of conflicts of interest and improve to some extent consistency in the management of IM functions. However the effectiveness of such a measure is lower than the one of option F2 and its efficiency is limited by the persistence of interfaces between the different entities in charge of IM functions. Option F2: Unified IMs || +++ || / || +++ || + || ++ || √ || √ || This is the preferred option for stakeholders. It ensures full consistency in the management of IM functions and reduces the risk of conflicts of interest as all functions are de facto subject to the same level of independence. It is the most efficient option as interfaces are removed. Option
F2 will be retained for further analysis. 3.2.5. Aspects
of implementation Option
F2 will require that in some Member States (in particular Estonia, France,
Hungary, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Slovenia), the responsibility of specific IM
functions are transferred from the incumbent to the IM (eg. in France the
"Direction des Circulations Ferroviaires" in charge of traffic
management and "SNCF Infra", in charge of maintenance activities,
should become part of the IM, Réseau ferré de France). In some cases, such
change will necessitate an important transfer of staff (nearly 50.000 in France) and resources. It will also lead to some reorganisation of the IM as existing
interfaces would disappear. However it is not expected that such changes would
have an impact on the working conditions of the staff concerned (applicable
social rules are normally the same for IM and RUs staff). 3.3.
Cross-border
coordination (CB) options: Cross-border infrastructure management 3.3.1.
Context An
important condition for completing the Single European Rail Area is well
functioning cross-border cooperation of IMs. National infrastructure management
often neglects interoperability and cross-border infrastructure in favour of
the needs of domestic passenger and freight traffic. Infrastructure managers
neglect the impact of their decisions on the business situation of
international traffic and traffic beyond their network and do not efficiently
cooperate to cope with traffic disruptions and temporary traffic restrictions,
especially when more than two infrastructure managers are concerned. Cooperation
activities under the Rail Freight Regulation and under the Recast will address
these issues only partially.
Therefore there is still a need to
address coordination problems related to development, maintenance and
operations beyond EU rail freight corridors and to ensure
consistency between the existing coordination activities. 3.3.2.
Description of options In
this context, the following options have initially been considered: ·
Option CB0: Baseline scenario – do
nothing. The implementation of the Rail Freight Regulation requires the
establishment of specific European rail freight corridors with a common
"corridor structure". The Recast will oblige IMs to create IMs
associations to coordinate their charging and path allocation practices or to
perform these tasks on their behalf. ·
Option CB1: Establishment
of a EU network of IMs. This
option consists in the institutionalisation of a network of national IMs to
exchange best practices, in particular on operational and infrastructure
development issues. ·
Option CB2: Creation
of an EU structure integrating IMs.
This option foresees the establishment of a structure, such as a European
Economic Interest Grouping (EEIG) integrating the existing national
Infrastructure Managers into a single European
Infrastructure Manager. 3.3.3.
Options discarded at an early stage None. 3.3.4.
Screening of options The initial set of options has been screened in
terms of stakeholder support, effectiveness in achieving the operational
objectives, efficiency and compliance with the subsidiarity principle. In
addition, the overall feasibility has been verified, i.e. whether the options
are legally and technically possible to pursue. Brief explanation relating to
the scores is presented in the column 'motivation'. Key of scores applied: || --- … - || decreasingly negative || || 0 || neutral || || + … +++ || increasingly positive || || / || not relevant || || √ || complying || || ~ || not complying || || Stakeholder support || Effectiveness in terms of operational objectives || Efficiency || Subsidiarity || Feasibility || Motivation Better alignment between IMs and RUs || Consistent management of IM functions || IMs Coordination || Prevent distortion of competition Option CB0: Baseline || + || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || || 0 || Some stakeholders favour the baseline to focus on the implementation of existing law (rail freight corridors and Recast). Option CB1: Establishment of a EU network || ++ || 0 || + || + || 0 || + || √ || ++ || This Option CB1 is the preferred option for stakeholders. While being neutral on parallel objectives (IMs-RUs alignment and distortion of competition), it will improve efficiently IMs ability to optimise the infrastructure management. Option CB1 would develop and extend existing practices and does not raise problems of feasibility Option CB2: Creation of an EU structure integrating IMs || - || - || 0 || ++ || + || -- || ~ || - || Integration of IMs under a single EU structure will be the most effective measure to ensure coordination of investments and operational practices. It would also prevent conflicts of interest that may occur with national incumbent. However this option is not supported by stakeholders in the short term as it may affect negatively the relation with local users. Because IMs are essentially financed and regulated by national authorities who have a more in-depth knowledge of local markets, this Option raises problems of subsidiarity and feasibility. Along
with the baseline scenario, Option CB1 will be retained for further analysis
of different policy scenarios in the impact assessment. 3.3.5.
Aspects of implementation Options CB2 and CB3 are expected to have very
different implications in terms of implementation. The EU
network of IMs under Option CB2 would require the organisation of regular
meetings which could be done with the support of and under the auspices of the
Commission. Such network would develop its activities with any permanent joint
secretariat, at least in short term. Option CB2 would imply the creation of a single
entity, such as an EEIG, responsible for infrastructure management.
Responsibilities for the historical debts of national IMs, allocation of public
funding provided by individual Member States to specific projects and
employment of national IMs staff could raise serious difficulties of
implementation. Another difficulty relates to the fact that
an increasing number of key international rail links are owned and/or managed
by private entity (PPP, concession etc.) which could probably not be integrated
in a single EU entity. 3.4.
Separation (S) options:
Ensuring adequate separation of IMs to prevent conflicts of interest 3.4.1.
Context The
current separation requirements (legal, organisational and decision-making
independence for the essential functions) do not yet prevent completely the
conflicts of interest and discriminatory practices as regards access to rail
infrastructure and related services. In addition, the existing legal framework
has proven to be insufficient to prevent cross-subsidisation from infrastructure
managers to incumbents. The underlying reasons are
two-fold: firstly, current legal provisions leave room for diverging
interpretation and secondly, even if fully implemented and enforced, full
financial transparency would be problematic to achieve. 3.4.2.
Description of options The
options below consider whether and how the separation requirements should be
revised. ·
Option S0: Baseline scenario
- do nothing. Baseline means decision-making independence for the
essential functions, although interpreted differently by Member States. The
Commission detailed its interpretation of the practical implications of
existing requirements in Annex V of the Communication on the implementation of
the First Railway Package[83],
however some Member States remain reluctant to accept this interpretation. ECJ
is expected to express its view on this issue in spring 2013. Regarding
financial transparency, the Recast provides for clear competences and
additional means for regulatory bodies to monitor the existing account separation
obligations. ·
Option S1: New competences for regulatory
bodies. This option foresees that regulatory bodies are
tasked with controlling that existing independence requirements in
organisational and decision-making terms are respected. In this framework any
RU would have the right to appeal to the national rail regulator if it believes
that these independence requirements are not respected. ·
Option S2: Clarify existing EU law.
This would mean revision of the existing provisions in the Directive so that the
interpretations provided by Annex V of the Communication on the implementation
of the First Railway Package would become indisputable. This would clarify in
particular that the existing independence requirements in organisational and
decision-making terms require in particular strict separation between the
holding and IM supervisory/management board, cooling off periods for IM board
members, own staff, IT tools and premises. In this option, the competences for
regulatory bodies are also extended as foreseen under Option S1. ·
Option S3: Institutional separation between IM
and RUs. Under this option, the same persons are not
entitled to control, hold any interest or exercise any right over an IM and a
RU. When both IM and RU are public entities, distinct public authorities must
exercise such control over them. 3.4.3.
Options discarded at an early stage Some
stakeholders proposed an option of appointing compliance
officers in integrated structures. In practice the supervisory board of
integrated IM would appoint a compliance officer responsible for monitoring the
implementation of any specific measures taken within the integrated structure
to ensure non-discriminatory behaviour. The compliance officer would also issue
recommendations and report on these measures to the supervisory board and to
the regulatory body. However, in practice this measure would not guarantee
remedy to conflicts of interests. Compliance officers remain appointed by the
holding compromising their independence or their ability to influence strategic
decisions, as suggested by past experience in Germany. 3.4.4.
Screening of options || Stakeholder support || Effectiveness in terms of operational objectives || Efficiency || Subsidiarity || Feasibility || Motivation Better alignment between IMs and RUs || Consistent management of IM functions || Prevent conflict of interests Option S0: Baseline || 0 || 0 || 0 || -- || 0 || √ || √ || Experience shows that existing separation requirements – as interpreted by some Member States - have not been able to avoid the persistence of conflict of interest. As regards financial transparency, despite the improvements provided by the Recast, monitoring of the use of public finances within integrated structures and identification of cross-subsidisation practices will remain a specifically complex and difficult exercise, even for the most powerful rail regulators. Option S1: New competences for regulatory bodies || + || 0 || + || + || - || √ || √ || Incumbents in integrated structures have called for an increased regulatory oversight as an alternative to further separation. However this option does not differ radically from the baseline since the Recast has already strengthened considerably the powers of regulatory bodies (including for the monitoring of account separation). The effectiveness of such option is limited by the fact that regulatory bodies can only act ex post, which means that violation has already taken place. In addition experience proves that it is specifically difficult for regulatory bodies to provide evidence of the existence of collusion or cross-subsidisation between the IM and the incumbent. Option S2: Clarify existing EU law || ++ || + || + || ++ || + || √ || √ || More straightforward provisions would allow the existing separation requirements to be implemented in a more uniform and effective manner. This would allow prevention of some persistent discrimination practices and facilitate the management of IM functions in a consistent manner, as holdings' interference in IM decisions should be removed. However, as regards financial transparency and potential cross subsidisations in holding structures, their monitoring by regulatory bodies remains a very complex and lengthy process requiring significant resources and exceptional expertise by regulators. This option does not allow to remove completely the distortion of competition between RUs as the ownership of infrastructure may need better financing conditions. Option S3: Institutional separation between IM and RUs. || --/+++ || --/++ || ++ || +++ || ++ || √ || √ || The views of stakeholders vis-à-vis institutional separation are very polarised. Some incumbents, in particular those part of an integrated structure, and workers in such structures oppose it arguing that it would reduce staff mobility and increase risks of misalignment between IM and RUs. Other parties are of the view that a fully independent IM is on the contrary better placed to take into account the needs of all RUs in a neutral way and play the role of system integrator. This option is the most effective option to guarantee the absence of discrimination and cross-subsidisation. Options
S2 and S3 will be retained for further analysis. 3.4.5.
Aspects of implementation Options
S2 and S3 are expected to have very different implications in terms of
implementation. While Option S2 implies additional competences and resources
for the regulatory bodies, Option S3 should reduce the number of appeals, the
need for investigations and therefore it would be less demanding for regulatory
bodies. Option
S2 would allow some Member States to retain existing holding structures but
both Options S2 and S3 would oblige them to review management boards'
appointment and dismissal rules. In both cases, Member States will have to
ensure that IMs have their own staff and premises as well as the resources
necessary to perform their functions independently. In addition Option S3
implies the transfer of control over the IM legal entity from the holding to a
public authority or another entity over which the incumbent does not exercise
control. 3.5.
Separated functions (SF)
options: Functions subject to the separation requirements 3.5.1.
Context As
explained in section 3.3 current separation requirements apply only to essential
functions, being currently capacity allocation and infrastructure charging.
Beyond these essential functions, the insufficient degree of separation for
other activities in integrated structure, such as traffic management,
maintenance and development causes conflicts of interest. 3.5.2. Description
of options In
this context the following policy options have been identified: ·
SF0: Baseline scenario –
do nothing. The separation requirement applies only to the
two functions currently defined as essential, path allocation and track access
charging. Other functions may be managed under the control
of a RU. ·
SF1 Traffic management also covered by
separation requirement. Traffic management, a function
which cannot be dissociated from path allocation and has a very important
potential for discrimination, is added to the list of essential functions
subject to separation requirements. ·
SF2: Traffic management and maintenance also
covered by separation requirement. Essential
functions subject to separation requirements are extended to include both
traffic management and the maintenance of new infrastructure considering the
inter-relation between the two and their high potential for discrimination. ·
SF3: All IM functions
subject to the same separation requirements. This would mean that path
allocation and track access charging as well as traffic management,
infrastructure maintenance and development are subject to the same separation
requirements, independently of the fact that these functions are performed by
the same entity or by different ones. 3.5.3.
Options discarded at an early stage None. 3.5.4. Screening
of options || Stakeholder support || Effectiveness in terms of operational objectives || Efficiency || Subsidiarity || Feasibility || Motivation Better alignment between IMs and RUs || Consistent management of IM functions || Prevent conflict of interests Option SF0: Baseline || -- || 0 || --- || 0 || 0 || √ || √ || The changes in the Recast do not modify the scope of the IM functions subject to separation requirements and therefore do not prevent discrimination in infrastructure maintenance and development decisions. As different functions are subject to different separation requirements, this option has a negative impact on the consistency of IM functions management. Option SF1: Current essential functions+ traffic management separated || + || + || + || + || + || √ || √ || A large majority of stakeholders recognise that traffic management cannot be dissociated from capacity allocation and should therefore be subject to the same separation requirements. This view is only contested by some incumbents who wish to maintain control over on this function arguing that RUs operational constraints have to be taken into account in traffic management. Option SF2: Current essential functions traffic +management maintenance separated || ++ || + || ++ || ++ || + || √ || √ || A large majority of stakeholders argue that maintenance planning is a potential source of discriminations between incumbent and new entrants and applying separation requirements to this function is an effective way to prevent them. As even more functions are subject to the same separation requirements, this option has a positive impact on the consistency of IM function management. Option SF3: all IM functions separated || +++ || +++ || +++ || +++ || ++ || √ || √ || Applying the same separation requirements to all IM functions effectively prevents conflicts of interest and contributes to the consistent management of these functions. It is the most efficient measure as it facilitates the grouping of all functions under the responsibility of one single entity without problems of interface and coordination. Option
SF3 will be retained for further analysis. 3.5.5.
Aspects of implementation Applying
the same separation requirements to all IM functions does not necessarily imply
that they are managed by one single entity. Its implications in terms of
implementation depend largely on the choice of separation requirements retained
under options S (see above). Furthermore, separate functions provide the basis
for an exchange of best practice and monitoring of the progress within the
network of EU infrastructure managers, notably in terms of user orientation as
regards quality, costs and prices of infrastructure services. 4.
Summary of retained
options The
table below provides an overview of all the screened and retained options in
four groups. Problem element || Respective category of options || Policy options considered || Retained? Insufficient market orientation of IMs || C options: Coordination between IM and RUs || Option C0: Baseline – improvements as foreseen by the Recast || √ Option C1: Participation to IM board || Option C2: Coordination bodies || √ Option C3: Financial incentives alignment || IM functions distributed among different actors || F options: Consistent management of key functions || Option F0: Baseline - existing essential functions are clarified by the ECJ || √ Option F1: New coordination mechanisms || Option F2: Unified IMs || √ Cross-border IM cooperation not sufficient || CB options: Cross-border IM management || Option CB0: Baseline - implementation of existing EU law (the Recast, regulation of rail freight corridors, etc.) || √ Option CB1: establishment of an EU network of IMs || √ Option CB2: Baseline: creation of an EU structure integrating national IMs || Conflicts of interests of IMs || S options: Way of separation of IMs from RUs || Option S0: Baseline - decision-making independence for the essential functions, interpretation dependent on ECJ ruling || √ Option S1: New competences for regulatory bodies || Option S2: Clarify existing EU law || √ Option S3: Institutional separation between IM and RUs. || √ Option S4: Compliance officer in integrated structure || Equal access needs to be assured to all key functions || SF options: Functions subject to the separation requirements || SF0: Baseline – separation requirement applies only to path allocation and track access charging || √ Option SF1: Current essential functions+ maintenance separated || Option SF2: Current essential functions +maintenance+ development separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || √ 5.
Construction of policy
scenarios Of
19 options screened in 5 groups, 10 have been retained including 5 baseline
scenarios. The combination of all these options could create theoretically 48
scenarios which would however be impracticable to assess. To reduce complexity,
the following arguments are considered to reduce the number of possible
scenarios: 1.
Any of the baseline options in combination with
non-baseline options in other groups would not be sustainable as the
non-baseline options in each group call for action in the other groups. E.g.
unified IMs (F2) would require that similar separation requirements would apply
to all IM functions (SF3), not only to the existing essential functions as
foreseen in S0. Similarly all IM functions being subject to separation
requirements (SF3) would increase the need for coordination bodies (C2).
Therefore all four baseline options are maintained only in the Baseline
Scenario, necessary for the comparison of other policy scenarios. 2.
While all options discussed under each group
make sense when taken in isolation, the policy choices retained in some groups
may influence or determine the validity of options in another group.
Consequently the interaction of policy choices retained for a) F options - Consistent
management of key functions: "unified IM responsible for all IM
functions" and b) S options – Measure
preventing conflicts of interest: "clarifying existing EU law (re-enforced
decision making independence) or institutional separation" inherently
mean that any separation requirements apply to all IM functions as
foreseen under Option SF3. This leads to the three policy scenarios on
top of the baseline: ·
Scenario 1 - an
IM-users coordination body is created, IM
functions are unified, an EU
network of IMs is created and all IMs functions are subject to the existing
separation requirements;. ·
Scenario 2 - an
IM-users coordination body is created, IM functions are
unified, an EU network of IMs is created and all IM
functions are subject to the existing separation
requirements with their concrete implications according to the Commission
clarified in EU law ;. ·
Scenario 3 – an
IM-users coordination body is created, IM functions are unified, an EU network
of IMs is created and all IM functions are subject
to institutional separation requirements. Their
composition is described in detail in the table below: Category of options || Baseline Scenario || Scenario 1 || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 Coordination between IM and RUs || Option C0: Improvements as foreseen by the Recast || Option C2: Coordination bodies || Option C2: Coordination bodies || Option C2: Coordination bodies Consistent management of key functions || Option F0: Existing essential functions are clarified by the ECJ, but scope remains limited || Option F2: Unified IMs || Option F2: Unified IMs || Option F2: Unified IMs Cross-border IM management || Option SC0: Implementation of existing EU law - the Recast, regulation of rail freight corridors. || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs || Option CB1: Establishment of an EU network of IMs Way of separation || Option S0: Existing separation requirements || Option S0: Existing separation requirements || Option S2: Clarify in EU law the concrete implications of existing separation obligations || Option S3: Institutional separation Functions subject to the separation requirements || SF0: Only path allocation and track access charging separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated || Option SF3: All IM functions separated All
three scenarios foresee establishment of coordinating bodies which should
enhance the interaction between infrastructure users and IMs and the creation
of an EU network of IMs to facilitate cross-border cooperation. They also
provide that all key functions should be unified under the IM. However, when
Scenario 1 would continue to apply existing separation requirements (to a
larger number of functions), Scenario 2 proposes to clarify the existing rules
and thus achieve a reinforcement of organisation and decision making
independence and Scenario 3 foresees a more fundamental institutional
separation of all key functions. These
three scenarios, along the baseline scenario, are assessed in more detail in
Section 6 of the IA report. ANNEX V THE ANALYSIS OF THE COSTS
AND BENEFITS OF FURTHER SEPARATION 1.
INTRODUCTION This annex explores the costs and benefits of separation, as they
occur depending on the way the separation requirements are applied. It should
be noted, that the principle of vertical separation is already established in
the EU law and need for separation as such is not discussed. Instead the
discussion focuses on the way of separation – i.e. how
IM functions shall be separated in a most efficient and effective way. The analysis distinguishes between the three
main categories of costs directly rising from separation requirements: –
Implementation costs, which are related to one-off
arrangement to establish required structures, e.g. creation of "Chinese
walls" (safeguards necessary for ensuring the decision-making and
organisation independence) between entities being the parts of
the same vertically integrated company; or changes in the ownership structure. –
Transaction costs - the cost associated with exchange of goods or services and incurred in
overcoming market imperfections. Transaction
costs cover a wide range of costs: communication charges, legal fees, informational
cost of finding the price, etc. In railways
some of these transaction costs are related to core operations, such as
including long-term capacity allocation, security management, timetable
coordination and investment planning. In addition to the operation related
costs mentioned, transaction costs could also derive from the need of
establishing business relationship, including contractualisation, establishment
of partnerships, negotiation, performance monitoring, and alignment of
incentives. To justify separation, the competition driven efficiency gains
resulting from separation should be higher than additional transaction costs
between the IM and the incumbent operator. –
Regulatory costs related to regulatory oversight and
enforcement by competent authorities. In addition the costs and benefits linked to discrimination,
financial transparency and scope efficiencies of integrated and
separated systems are discussed. Below is recalled the content of the
the policy scenarios combining the efficiency (coordination) measures with
different level of separation, for which separation related costs and benefits
will be assessed. –
Baseline – No additional coordination
measures, existing separation requirements (legal, organisational and
decision-making independence) applicable for the essential functions (path
allocation and infrastructure charging). It should be noted, that some costs
associated to legal separation but also some costs resulting from
decision-making and organisational separation are supposed to be part of the
Baseline Scenario. –
Scenario 1 – focussing only on the
efficiency measures - IM functions are unified (i.e. in addition to current
essential functions also maintenance, investments and traffic management) and
coordination bodies created to mitigate loss in scope efficiencies; all IMs
functions are subject to the existing separation requirements; –
Scenario 2 – efficiency measures and better
enforcement of existing separation principles
- like Scenario 1, but the practical consequences of the
existing separation principles will be
clarified to allow better enforcement; –
Scenario 3 – efficiency measures and new
institutional separation requirements
– like Scenario 1, but all IM functions are subject to
institutional separation requirements No change of separation requirements is foreseen under Scenario 1
which focuses exclusively on IM efficiency measures. Therefore the analysis of
separation related costs concentrates essentially to the comparison of Scenario
2 (enforcement of existing separation principles)
and Scenario 3 (institutional separation). Measures
taken under Scenario 1 are still
considered to the extent they include unification
of all IM functions and creation of coordination bodies. 2.
CONSTRAINTS The IA support study concluded that, evidence on which to quantify
the impacts of different governance arrangements is limited and, as the
stakeholder consultation and literature review illustrates, has been
interpreted in different ways by different parties. Fundamental difficulties
include: –
Limited empirical evidence - no Member State has unbundled exactly
as envisaged in Scenario 2 or 3 without simultaneously making other changes. –
Access to data - the costs of separation is not monitored in
sufficient detail to determine the difference between distinct approaches, for
example institutional separation as compared with legal,
decision-making and organisational separation. –
The benefits, which include a reduction in or elimination of
discriminatory behaviour as well as greater financial transparency, cannot be
measured easily due to the mixed impacts with other contextual factors and the
lagged effects on observed outcomes. In these circumstances, no full cost benefit analysis can be
provided. Instead an attempt is made to compare the scale of potential costs
and benefits of separation in case of different governance models. 3.
RESULTS OF THE
ASSESSMENT
3.1.
Implementation costs
There is evidence that restructuring costs are likely to be
limited when compared with total industry costs. Even in Great Britain, where restructuring and privatisation went much further than requirements
set by EU law, total set up costs only amounted to no more than 3.5%[84]
of total annual industry costs. The table below summarises the requirements and their implications
in terms of potential cost impacts. Table 1 One-off cost implications of separation Requirement || Cost implication Scenario 2 || Compliance to be monitored by independent authority or third party || No additional costs – regulatory bodies already created under existing legislation Statutory/contractual independence of entity entrusted with essential functions, maintenance planning and investment from other entities in the same group || Establishing the necessary statutory or contractual provisions is an administrative change, the costs of which are likely to be negligible Members of the board of the entity entrusted with essential functions, maintenance planning and investment should not be on the board of any entity within the same group || Could require the recruitment of additional board members depending on how existing boards are currently comprised – one-off costs of recruitment likely to be negligible Members of the board of the entity entrusted with essential functions, maintenance planning and investment barred from serving on the board of any entity within the same group for a number of years || No additional costs beyond those already identified above The management board of the entity entrusted with essential functions, maintenance planning and investment must be appointed under clear conditions and legal commitments to ensure the necessary degree of independence || This is an administrative change which would not result in material additional costs, although it could lead to further recruitment in circumstances where a new board had to be appointed in order to comply The entity entrusted with essential functions, maintenance planning and investment must have its own staff and be located in separate premises (or be subject to protected access) and access to its information systems must be protected || Could require changes in staff allocation and administration as well as modification of IT systems depending on the degree of functional separation already implemented Scenario 2 || All of the requirements of U1 as well as change in ownership needed to secure institutional separation of infrastructure management and train operations || Primarily the costs of legal activity required to establish separate ownership although there may also be costs arising from the reallocation of staff and functions from the holding entity, depending on the extent of its previous functions Implementation costs of Scenario 3 In the case of Scenario 3, set-up costs would arise from changes
in the ownership of existing
legal entities and associated contractual relationships. The
additional costs are likely to be limited given that the degree of
organisational and decision-making separation adopted in the majority of Member
States in response to existing legislation is already substantial. Furhter evidence on which to quantify the impacts of different
governance arrangements is limited. The cost of separating functions will
depend on whether and how they were integrated under the former structure.
Moreover, in larger railway organisations, the incremental costs will depend on
the existing management configuration: integrated railways may be organised by
engineering function, or by regional or route, or by business market, with
different degrees of subcontracting of functions and activities to external
suppliers. The costs of separation may be borne by a number of bodies, over a
period of several years, and are not collated or reported in sufficient detail
to allow extrapolation. From the available evidence, the IA support study looked into
following cases: Rail reform in Great Britain Some of the costs of restructuring the rail industry were
identified and reported in Great Britain, where however restructuring of rail
sector was very radical and therefore the observed costs should substantially
exceed those of the simpler forms of separation envisaged under Scenario 2 or
Scenario 3. The restructuring costs incurred by both British Rail and
Railtrack (the initial IM, subsequently replaced by Network Rail) in 1993-94
and 1994-95 are shown in Table
2. Table 2 Restructuring and privatisation costs of British
Rail £ million (current prices) || 1993-94 || 1994-95 British Rail || 92 || 85 Railtrack || || 46 Total || 92 || 131 As percentage of total industry costs || 2.6% || 3.5% Source: Hansard, 26 November 1996, volume 286, British Rail Annual Report
1993-94 The period covered by
the table excluded initial feasibility studies but included all of the
restructuring activity, incurred within those organisations (but not others,
such as the Department of Transport which specified and oversaw the process).
These include the creation of Railtrack as a separate legal entity, and part of
the subsequent work in support of privatisation. However, it is unclear how
much of the reported cost relates to institutional separation which would be
required by Scenario 3, not least because: –
A
proportion reflects activity associated with bringing Railtrack to market, and
would therefore not have been incurred had the objective been institutional
separation alone. –
Much
of the restructuring cost incurred in 1993-94 was the result of a radical
restructuring of British Rail, which included the creation of 25 train
operating subsidiaries (subsequently franchised), a number of rolling stock
leasing, renewals, maintenance and other companies as well as a separate
infrastructure manager. –
The
activity undertaken involved reform of an industry structure in place prior to,
and therefore not complying with, the requirements of the First Package. This cost information is nevertheless useful in illustrating that
restructuring costs are likely to be limited when compared with total industry
costs in any given year. Even in Great Britain, where restructuring and
privatisation went further than in any other Member State, total set up costs
amounted to no more than 3.5% of total annual industry costs. The costs of
implementing Scenario 3 in isolation would have been considerably lower
although highly dependent on the exact internal management organisation in each
case. If the creation of a separate infrastructure manager in 1993-94[85]
resulted in British Rail incurring one third of the restructuring costs
actually reported for that year, the total would have amounted to only 0.9% of
overall annual industry costs. Setting up the independent Infrastructure Manager in
Spain The overall cost of the setting up of ADIF, the independent
Infrastructure Manager for the Spanish rail industry, identified total
restructuring cost of € 6.8 million over the three year period 2004-2006.
It is not clear what activities these costs covered, but the figure was
equivalent to 0.2% of the reported operating costs of RENFE, the incumbent
national rail service provider, in 2004 (the last year in which RENFE operated
as a vertically integrated entity). This indicates that one-off costs of
functional separation, which will exceed those of the more limited forms of
separation under Scenarios 2 or 3, are relatively small in relation to overall
industry costs. Transformation
of Czech Railways Further
data is available for Czech Republic, which in 2000 specified a project
entitled “Preparation of conditions for the application of the EU Directives in
the transformation of Czech Railways (CD)”[86].
The project anticipated much of the work needed to implement the changes
eventually put in place in 2003 and was expected to cost €2 million, around
0.1% of CD’s annual operating costs at the time. This tends to support the view
that the costs of implementing more focused unbundling on a simpler rail
network than in Great Britain are likely to be substantially less than those
reported in Table 2. However, the evidence from the Czech Republic must also be
substantially qualified since: –
There is no information confirming that the outturn costs of
the project were comparable to the estimate of costs in the project
specification –
The
project included a number of elements, such as harmonising infrastructure
charges and financial
revitalisation, required for implementation of the First Package but which
would not be required in order to implement either Scenario 2 or 3. Finally,
corroborating evidence was sought also form the experience of other network
industries. Table 3 below gives insight on one-off cost of separation in
electricity distribution, which is broadly comparable to the rail sector in
that it is network based and has been subject to restructuring, including the
creation of institutionally separate entities responsible for activities such
as generation, transmission and distribution, in a number of countries within
and outside Europe. Table 3 One-off costs of separating electricity
distribution Example || Estimated cost || Scale factor || Comment || Source Creation of Distribution Network Operators in New Zealand || NZ$30 million || 3.5% of annual revenues || Represents the cost of creating separate operating entities from a fully integrated structure || PWC (2006) Creation of distribution Network Operators in the Netherlands || €70-100 million || 0.7% - 1% of annual operating costs || Costs attributed to modification of IT systems, transfer, re-contracting and re-administration of staff and legal activity underpinning ownership separation || Deloitte (2005) Further separation of Distribution Network Operators in the Netherlands || €20 million || 0.2% of annual operating costs || Estimate of moving to separation of ownership after functional separation has been completed || De Nooij and Baarsma (2008) Further separation of Transmission System Operators in Germany || €100 million || 0.2% of annual operating costs || Explicitly based on estimates made by De Nooij and Baarsma (2008) || Brunekreeft (2008) Source: Brunekreeft (2008) These figures should be treated with care, given the uncertainties
surrounding the estimations and differences between the sectors. However, the
evidence consistently supports the conclusion that the costs of radical
restructuring of a fully integrated industry of the kind undertaken in Great Britain will substantially exceed those of the simpler forms of unbundling envisaged
under U1 and U2. More specifically, it suggests that changes in staff
allocation and administration together with supporting IT systems changes can
be expected to be significantly below 1% of annual operating costs, and that
the costs of establishing separate ownership, assuming functional separation
has already been achieved, might be only 0.2% of annual costs. In conclusion, the Member States currently without institutional
separation (categories 2-6 in Table 1 of the main report) could be expected to
incur potential
one-off costs as equivalent to 0.7% of annual operating costs (the 0.5%
mid-point estimate for implementing Scenario 2 plus the 0.2% arising from full
institutional separation). This would imply expenditure of €0.24 billion. These
estimates are considered conservative in the light of the estimates of one-off
costs for Spain and the Czech Republic reported above. Implementation costs of Scenario 2 Under Scenario 2 the set-up costs would be related
to the costs of internal reorganisation deriving
from the establishment of the "Chinese walls" necessary to enforce
the existing decision-making
and organisational separation requirements within a vertically
integrated undertaking, as indicated in Table 1. This means that some
vertically integrated Member States would incur one-off costs of up to 0.8% of
annual operating costs (the 1% indicated by Deloitte (2005), less the 0.2%
required for ownership separation estimated by De Nooij and Baarsma (2008)). In
practice some Member States, for example Belgium, which have already
implemented measures to meet the requirements of Annex V of the Communication
on the implementation of the First railway Package[87] , would incur no
significant additional costs. On the assumption that, as a whole, these Member
States would incur enforcement equivalent to the mid-point average of these two
extremes (0.5% of annual operating costs), the resulting expenditure would be
€0.17 billion. Implementation costs of Scenario 1 Under Scenario 1 there are limited implementation costs
related to the establishment of national coordination bodies between IMs and
RUs. Some Member States already have mechanisms in place to deal with some or
all of the proposed functions of the proposed coordination body, in other cases
involving bodies already established, functioning and with effective powers. It
has not been attempted to estimate the additional cost of establishing a
coordination bodies in all Member States, as the related costs would depend on
the number of actors and on the detail of whether any of the functions were
transferred from existing bodies or arrangements. In any case, the scale of
expected efficiency benefits (very difficult to quantify - see the discussion
on misalignment cost below) would be of a much higher scale than establishment
and administration costs of the coordination bodies. In addition Scenario 1
foresees the establishment of an EU network of IMs, which would require
organising regular meetings. This could be done with the support of and under
the auspices of the Commission. Such network would develop its activities
without any permanent joint secretariat, at least in short term and thus will
have only limited cost implications. In a limited number of Member States (Hungary, Estonia, Luxembourg, Slovenia and Lithuania but also in France) the unification of IM functions will require merging the IM with
allocation and charging bodies or specific departments of the incumbent. This
reorganisation will necessitate transfer of staff and reorganisation of the IM
management chain.
3.2.
Transaction costs
The IA support study suggests that the recent study by Merkert et
al. (2012) provides relatively robust estimates of recurring transaction costs
as it is based on bottom-up investigation of costs through interviews with
individual rail organisations in Germany, Great Britain and Sweden. This
approach allows for identification of relevant cost categories. Although it has
to be noted that the resulting estimates are not fully compatible with the
additional transactions costs likely to arise under either policy Scenarios
compared to the Baseline since some of the costs covered are driven primarily
by factors other than the degree of institutional separation in place, while
others arise, at least to some degree, from EU rail legislation that is already
in place. The key results, expressed in the form of transaction costs per
train-kilometre and as a proportion of total operating costs, are shown in
Table 4. They indicate that, on either measure, the German rail network has the
lowest transactions costs and Great Britain has the highest. This is consistent
with the view that a more disaggregated industry structure leads to higher
transactions costs, although the authors qualify the comparison by noting that
the German network may benefit from scale economies and that there is in any
case considerable variation in the level of transactions costs between
individual rail organisations in Germany. Table 4 Estimates
of rail industry restructuring costs || Transaction costs per train-kilometre (€, Purchasing Power Parity PPP) || Transaction costs as proportion of operating costs (%) Germany || €0.08 || 0.49% Great Britain || €0.34 || 1.42% Sweden || €0.22 || 1.27% Source: Merkert et al. (2012) More specifically, the Merkert et al study sought to identify,
through discussion with industry representatives in both IMs and Rail
Undertakings, seven main categories of transaction cost. These are summarised
in the Table below. In each case, the impact of further unbundling has been
summarised, drawing on a more comprehensive qualitative assessment of the
likely effects of policy changes on transactions costs. Table 5 Impact
of further unbundling on transactions costs Transaction cost category || Summary of likely impact Franchise and transport contract bidding and making open access applications || Overall process should not differ materially from that already in place. These costs are driven primarily by the level of competition rather than the level of separation. Procuring and modifying assets || Possibly some additional transactions costs incurred under Scenario 3 where new or modified assets affect the wheel-rail interface. Setting up and amending access and performance regimes || No significant additional costs under either Scenario 2 or Scenario 3 – performance regime already required under existing legislation. Allocating train paths, timetabling and train planning || Should not differ materially from existing processes under either Scenario 2 or Scenario 3, although any associated disputes may be more costly to resolve under Scenario 3. Day-to-day operations (including train operation/formation, maintenance and the provision of customer information) || Operational procedures already in place should continue to operate, although disputes over scheduling of engineering works may be more difficult to resolve under Scenario 3. Reporting, billing and application of performance regimes || Existing procedures should continue to apply, although disputes over responsibility for service disruption could be more difficult to resolve. Safety, planning and enforcement processes || No material change under either Scenario 2 or Scenario 3. Planning in respect of issues relating to the wheel-rail interface might be affected. On
the basis of this assessment it can be concluded that the majority of
transactions costs covered by the study would not increase as a result of the
implementation of either Scenario 2 or Scenario 3. Hence, the estimates derived
by Merkert et al need to be adjusted for the purpose of this IA. Recognising
that the findings of the study by Merkert et al. are based on an investigation
of transactions costs in only three Member States, and in the absence of
similar detailed investigation of rail industry transactions costs in other EU
countries, it has been sought to identify evidence of similar costs in other
sectors. A number of the studies of the electricity sector cited above provide
some estimates of transactions costs in addition to the estimates of one-off
separation costs already reported. This evidence is considered to be
informative since some studies take account of the implications of different
levels of separation. Key results are summarised in the Table 6 below. Note
that these studies do not distinguish between enforcement and transactions
costs or between the explicit costs of supporting a given organisational
structure and loss of synergy. However, costs are attributed to specific
categories of activity including general management, human resources, IT,
finance and general support. Table 6 Estimated transaction costs
of separation, electricity sector Example || Estimated cost || Scale factor || Comment || Source Creation of distribution Network Operators in the Netherlands || €350 – 450 million per annum || 3.5% - 4.5% of annual operating costs || Full costs of organisational separation || Deloitte (2005) Further separation of Distribution Network Operators in the Netherlands || €20 million || 0.2% of annual operating costs || Estimate of moving to separaion of ownership after functional separation has been completed || De Nooij and Baarsma (2008) Further separation of Transmission System Operators in Germany || €50 million || 0.1% of annual operating costs || Base case estimate - explicitly based on estimates made by De Nooij and Baarsma (2008) || Brunekreeft (2008) Further separation of Transmission System Operators in Germany || €250 million || 0.5% of annual operating costs || High case estimate based on top-down analysis || Brunekreeft (2008) Source:
Brunekreeft (2008) This evidence suggests a range of possible outcomes but supports
the view that the costs of further separation after functional separation has
already been implemented amount to no more than 0.5% of annual operating costs. Transaction
costs of Scenario 3 To derive a range for the assumed level of transaction costs, the
key evidence can be summarised as follows: –
The
costs of functional unbundling could be significant, and in the electricity
sector have been estimated at up to 4.5% of annual operating costs. However
the IA support study concluded that there is no evidence that the costs of separation
in the rail sector to date are of this magnitude. –
Evidence
from Belgium suggests that they are no more than 1.4% of operating costs. The
authors of the report prepared for the National Bank of Belgium[88] do report some evidence of the
impact of restructuring in the form of a recent claim by the Chairman of
SNCB-Holding to the effect that the restructuring had resulted in additional
costs of €50 – 100 million per annum. These were attributed to the increased
cost of IT services, communications and legal services, although the basis on
which the estimate was derived is not clear. However, while costs of this
magnitude could be considered significant, equivalent to up to 1.4% of annual
operating costs, they apparently relate to the effects of the restructuring of
SNCB in 2005 rather than the costs of ensuring compliance with the requirements
of Annex V in isolation. –
Evidence
from the rail sector indicates that additional transactions costs in Sweden, which has implemented institutional separation, account for a higher proportion of annual
operating costs than in Germany under a holding company model. However, the
difference, equivalent to 0.78% of operating costs, undoubtedly overstates the impact of
institutional separation in isolation since it includes costs that are driven
primarily by the level of competition. The difference in transactions costs
between Germany and Great Britain, equivalents to 0.93% of operating costs,
further overstates the impact since it reflects the complex nature of the
contractual structure put in place following the restructuring and
privatisation of British Rail. –
Further
evidence from the electricity sector indicates that the cost of
institutional separation implemented following functional separation of
transmission and distribution has resulted in ongoing transaction costs of
between 0.1% and 0.5% of annual operating costs. Given the lack of
precision in the available cost estimates, a relatively wide cost range of
transaction costs has been calculated. The basis of the estimate is the
difference in normalised transactions costs between Germany and Sweden derived from the study by Merkert et al., equivalent to 0.78% of operating costs. To
obtain a range it has been 20% of this figure to derive a lower bound (giving
0.16%) and 60% of the figure to derive an upper bound (giving 0.47%). This choice of range has been
informed by the following considerations: –
The
study by Merkert et al., while it is the most detailed available and the most
relevant for the purposes of, covers only three Member States, and it is
therefore necessary to estimate a relatively wide range of outcomes to ensure
that potential cost impacts in other Member States are represented. –
The
assessment of the likely impact of Scenario 3 on the various cost elements
included in the study nevertheless suggests that any increase in transactions
costs will be limited. The review of the evidence on enforcement costs also
suggests no discernible impact on annual operating costs. The proposed range is
therefore based on a significant adjustment of the transaction cost differences
reported by Merkert et al. –
The
proposed range is consistent with a similar range estimated for ownership
separation in the electricity sector (of between 0.1% and 0.5%), as reported by
Brunekreeft (2008). Applying the range to the annual
rail sector operating costs of Member States in categories 2-6 in Table 1 of
the main report, gives a transaction ongoing cost impact of Scenario 3 of
between €0.05 billion and €0.16 billion per annum. Transaction
costs of Scenario 2 The study results reported above do not provide a basis for
estimating the transaction costs of Scenario 2. Many organisations
implement so-called Chinese walls in order to preserve confidentiality or
decision-making independence, but do not seek to estimate or report the
associated costs. However, the costs of implementing Scenario 2 will be
restricted to those of introducing decision-making independence in maintenance
planning and investments. Scenario 2 could thus be expected to have broadly
similar cost impacts to Scenario 3, since it would require the incumbent Rail
Undertaking and IM to operate as if they were institutionally independent even
though they remained in the same holding group. Hence, the range of cost
impacts estimated for Scenario 2 is considered being broadly equivalent to
those for Scenario 3. It should be noted though that Scenario 2 transactions
costs could be somewhat lower to the extent that the lack of institutional
separation enabled disputes over train planning, the cause of service
disruption or the scheduling of engineering works to be resolved more easily.
However, these effects are considered being not material. Transaction
costs of Scenario 1 Scenario 1 reduces transaction costs in two
ways: (1) with the unification of IM functions, those costs resulting from
interfaces between the different entities in charge of IM functions will be
removed; (2) better coordination between IMs and infrastructure users will
ensure alignment of strategies and objectives. These benefits apply to all
Member States, which do not yet have these coordination mechanisms in place. Under all scenarios some induced increase of transaction costs
would appear together with the increase in the number of infrastructure users
and the related growth of traffic volumes. The latter reflects the increase in
the offer of rail transport services in line with the general policy objectives
and will be recovered by track access revenues.
3.3.
Regulatory costs
Any separation arrangement would imply regulatory oversight costs
linked to the need of the authorities to prevent, control and detect discriminatory
behaviour and cross-subsidisation within the integrated and holding structures.
Transparency resulting from institutional separation under Scenario 3
should, compared to the Scenario 2, lead to the reduction of regulatory
enforcement costs of market opening, both by eliminating the incentive for
discriminatory behaviour and by improving the financial information available
to regulators. The potential reduction in regulatory enforcement costs can be
estimated from the results of the study by Merkert et al. (2012) cited above.
The study takes regulatory costs into account in the calculation of overall
transactions costs and these are reported separately, as shown in Table 7.
While the authors note that they cannot be certain of whether all of the associated
staff within the various regulatory organisations are involved in transactions
relevant to the study, they consider that the costs shown provide a reasonable
basis for comparing between Member States. Table 7 Estimates
of rail industry regulatory enforcement costs || Regulatory enforcement costs per train-kilometre (€, Purchasing Power Parity PPP) Germany || €0.08 Great Britain || €0.08 Sweden || €0.02 Source: Merkert et al. (2012) Again, the results must be interpreted with particular caution,
since the Member States do not align with either the existing requirements or
the separation options under consideration. In addition, given the
qualification offered by the authors of the study and for other reasons, the
findings may understate or overstate true enforcement costs within each Member State. For example: –
The
costs reported for Germany relate only to rail specific organisations, the
Federal Network Agency (BNetzA) and the Federal Railway Authority (EBA), and do
not include the cost of court action in response to discriminatory behaviour
(an important channel of enforcement in the absence of institutional separation
according to the study by Merkert el al. (2008). –
The
costs reported for Great
Britain include the staff employed by the Rail Safety and Standards Board (who
account for 37.5% of the cost per train-kilometre shown in the Table 7) who
would arguably undertake similar functions whether institutional separation had
been implemented or not. –
The
level of enforcement costs would
be related to the volume of application, access and congestion on the network,
which may change considerably under future conditions of domestic market
opening. Regulatory
costs of Scenario 3 The difference in cost estimates for Germany and Sweden reported in Table 7 suggest that enforcement costs per train-kilometre could decline
by up to 75% as a result of institutional separation as suggested by Scenario
3. This is consistent with a lower incidence of discriminatory or other
anti-competitive behaviour on the part of an IM under Scenario 3. Regulatory costs of Scenario 2 As in the case of transactions costs, the cost estimates provided
in Table 7 do not provide a basis for estimating the impact of Scenario 2
on regulatory enforcement. Under Scenario 2, monitoring
of the enforcement of the new
"Chinese walls" should, in comparison to the
Baseline, increase moderately the cost of regulatory
oversight. These costs concern only MS where these safeguards have not yet
been fully applied (categories 2 to
6 in Table 1 of the IA). On the other hand,
extending requirements in respect of independent decision-making to maintenance
planning and investments (as introduced by SF options - Functions Subject to
Separation) could reduce allegations of discrimination relating
to these functions. Furthermore, experience of the competitive entry in Member
States with holding structures, such as Austria, Germany and Italy, has gone hand-in-hand with increasing complaints by new entrants concerning access
to infrastructure and an increasing need for regulatory decisions. For example,
since it introduced new intercity services in Austria, the new entrant WESTbahn
has raised complaints about pathing priorities, the use of infrastructure to
provide real time information on onward connections, promotion of services
through on-station advertising and alleged cross-subsidisation of ÖBB services
from a PSO contract awarded without competitive tender.[89] It could be concluded
that need for regulatory intervention would have been less had these Member
States adopted the institutional separation of infrastructure management and
rail operations required under Scenario 3. Given
these considerations, it is not expected the costs of regulatory enforcement
under Scenario 2 to be substantially lower from
those arising in the Baseline Scenario. Creation of IM-users coordination bodies under Scenario 1
will imply limited reporting obligation (which can be considered being
administrative burdens) for IMs and infrastructure users which are already
involved in ad hoc consultations. The establishment of a European IMs' network
is not expected to create important enforcement costs.
3.4.
Other costs and the benefits of separation
The core benefit of vertical separation is related to elimination
of discrimination in gaining access to infrastructure leading to
the development of competition and being
the means for more efficient railway. Separation is also expected to
help reducing the asymmetries information and improve financial transparency in
the railway business. Discrimination By reducing or even eliminating the scope for discriminatory
behaviour, vertical separation would evade opportunity costs of potential
operations of new entrants omitted due to discrimination in gaining access to
infrastructure. Equal access to infrastructure would also provide for the
development of competition for, and in, the market, in particular if coupled
with market opening initiative. Already in the Baseline Scenario any discriminatory practices are
prohibited by existing EU law and regulatory bodies are competent to act
following an appeal or on their own initiative. However, as presented in the
problem definition of the IA, the discrimination in infrastructure access,
preventing the smooth functioning of Single European Railway area, still
occurs. In case of Scenario 2 the scope of oversight of regulatory
bodies is extended to verify that the detailed independence requirements in
organisational and decision-making terms are respected. However, without full
institutional separation and without guarantees for financial transparency, an
opportunity and motivation for discrimination remains. Moreover, actions of
regulators would be mostly reactive, rather than preventive. Even if the case
for discrimination is later established, the damage created to new entrant
operators could be irretrievable (see Section 3.2 of the IA for evidence and
further discussion). Such damage could be illustrated in terms of 'opportunity
costs' expressed as loss from non-running of services as well as lost return on
investments. Whilst such costs can be significant, quantification is
challenging being each time dependent on the circumstances and the nature of
services involved. For instance, one of the discrimination cases quoted in the
IA report refers to hurdles the Italian new entrant NTV experienced during the
homologation procedure for its AGV trains. The process took 45 months between
July 2008 and March 2012 main reason for delays being the infrastructure
manager's RFI (subsidiary of the Ferrovie dello Stato) refusal to grant the
train paths necessary for testing purposes. The excessive duration of the
procedure led to a lost return on its €1 billion investment for the development
of its new rail transport services. Scenario 3 would imply a structural change by
introducing full institutional separation and thus prevent (rather than
correct/react on) the occurrence of discriminatory behaviour. Therefore this
Scenario is much more efficient in terms of evading discrimination related
opportunity costs. Cross-subsidisation Separation would also reduce the risk of cross-subsidisation
embedded in integrated and holding structures. Complex bundle of services
offered over the same network and potentially by the same or closely linked
companies has inherently implications for cost-accountancy and transparency
even if account separation requirements are in place. In these terms only full
institutional separation, as foreseen under Scenario 3, would reduce and
ultimately eliminate the risk of cross-subsidisation between different rail
services. Improved transparency would provide the decision-makers within the
relevant competent authorities with more transparent financial information
about asset values and cost structure, allowing improving the allocation of
public funds to, and within, the rail sector. However, likewise the opportunity
costs, transparency linked benefits would not be easy to quantify. In any terms
Scenario 3 is considered much more effective, given that institutional
separation would structurally prevent the case for cross-subsidisation, while Scenario
2 would still allow the persistence of cross-subsidisation through the use
of complex accountancy tools which are difficult for regulators to monitor and
control. Scope efficiencies The negative impacts related to separation concern above all the
so called 'misalignment' costs resulting from breaking the scale economies
between the IM and incumbent operator, which in rail
industry can be significant due to loss in system integration. There is no
quantitative evidence available to assess such costs consequences, but their
scale and nature much depends on the circumstances of the national context and
the way in which the system is managed. As a matter of principle, such economies
of scope would anyway be applicable only to incumbent operator, creating
further frustration in terms of uneven playing field. However, to mitigate any
negative consequences, while ensuring equal access to infrastructure,
separation and liberalisation measures will need to be supplemented by
complementary initiatives designed to ensure that
the IM is in a position to play the role of system
integrator in rail network. Therefore, all three policy scenarios
proposed by the Commission foresee creation of coordination bodies between IMs
and operators which include, in a non-discriminatory manner, representatives
from all infrastructure users and should ensure that their interests are duly
taken into consideration. 4.
SUMMARY OF SEPARATION
COSTS AND BENEFITS The Table 8 below summarises the findings of the analysis. '+'
indicates positive impacts, and '- ' negative impacts. As explained above, a
full cost benefit analysis has not been feasible and the scores therefore
compare the impacts within a row but are less telling in expressing the
relative importance of impacts between different rows. Table 8 Comparison
of the costs and benefits of further separation Impacts compared to the Baseline || Scenario 1 (only efficiency measures) || Scenario 2 (efficiency and enforcement of separation) || Scenario 3 (efficiency and institutional separation) Implementation costs (one off) || 0/– || – – Potential scale of costs €0.17 billion || – Potential scale of cost €0.24 billion – Limited costs related to establishment of coordination bodies in many MSs and unifying IM functions in some MS. || Related to the costs of internal reorganisation necessary to put in place "Chinese walls". Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. || ~0.9% of yearly operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Transaction costs || + || – Potential cost range €0.05 bn and €0.16 bn per annum || – – Potential cost range €0.05 bn and €0.16 bn per annum Some improvement due to better coordination. Impacts to all MSs. || At least 0.15% of operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. || ~0.3% of operating costs. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Regulatory costs || 0 || 0 || + It is not expected the costs of regulatory enforcement under Scenario 1 to be materially lower than those arising in the Baseline. || It is not expected the costs of regulatory enforcement under Scenario 2 to be materially lower than those arising in the Baseline. || Regulatory costs per train-kilometre could decline by up to 75% as a result of institutional separation. Impacts the MSs having integrated or holding structures. Other costs and benefits, linked to: || || || || || Discrimination || 0 || 0/+ || ++ No impact || The scope of oversight of regulatory bodies is extended, but remains mostly reactive thus only partly evading discrimination related opportunity costs. || Full institutional separation would eliminate opportunity and motivation for discrimination. Cross-subsidisation || 0 || 0/+ || ++ No impact || Transparency issues and cross-subsidisation risks remain inherent in integrated and holding structures even if account separation requirements are in place. || Full institutional separation would provide necessary transparency and eliminate opportunity for cross-subsidisation. Scope efficiencies || + || 0/- || – All policy scenarios foresee creation of coordination bodies between IMs and operators to mitigate the misalignment issues resulted from the loss of scope efficiencies, which are considered of being higher for full institutional separation. Therefore, Scenario 1 improves the situation slightly compared to the Baseline, while the other 2 scenarios, implying additional separation, would worsen it (though Scenario 2 only marginally). Scenario 1 impacts most MS, while Scenarios 2 and 3 only those having integrated or holding structures. In terms of scale, the implementation, transaction and regulatory
costs are relatively less significant than (induced or direct) costs linked to
discrimination and lack of financial transparency. Misalignment costs could
also be significant. However, given that market
opening and vertical separation are already the
chosen policy path in EU rail reform, the conclusions should be drawn on the
basis of which separation method has the potential to provide a level playing
field in access to the infrastructure costing most effective and efficient
manner, while mitigating to the extent possible any misalignment consequences. In
these terms full institutional separation, as by Scenario 3 seems to be the
preferred way forward. 5.
SYNERGIES OF SEPARATION
WITH MARKET OPENING Finally, the ultimate goal of separation is to create more
competitive and efficient rail sector and thus encourage service offer, while
improving the use of public funds fed via subsidises into railways. The
institutional separation envisaged under Scenario 3 is an important precursor
to the delivery of the full benefits of market opening, as already implemented
for rail freight market and international passenger rail market and further
proposed by the 4th Railway package for domestic passenger market. This can be
demonstrated by comparing the estimated outcomes of a specific form of market
opening with and without separation, which has been developed by the IA support
study. The
projections were carried out by the consultant in cooperation with the
Commission. There are high uncertainties linked to calculations of aggregated
impacts, because of: ─
limited empirical evidence; ─
any effects are dependent on baseline situations in Member States; ─
other principal uncertainties in the baseline developments and
exogenous factors. Therefore
the quantification results were not used for comparison of options. However, scenario
analysis accompanied with sensitivity tests, as presented below, should give a
relatively sound idea of potential outcomes of the proposed policy in different
situations, based on the most credible information available as of the date.
The core features of analysis and assumptions for the assessment are summarised
in the Table 7 below. For the detailed information on the assessment
methodology (which covers both – Market Access and Infrastructure governance
initiative) see Annex 8 of the IA on Access to Domestic Passenger Rail Markets
and Appendix I of the IA support study.
1.
Table 7 Assumptions
Assumption || IM Scenario 3 || Domestic opening || Combined impacts Open access effects Sectors || High speed, long distance, medium/regional, international Effects || New entrant’s open access train-kilometres as a proportion of current “commercial” train-kilometres || 1% || 2% || 3% Share of incumbents’ “commercial” services in this sector converted to PSC as a result of open access competition || 10% || 20% || 30% New entrant’s fares as a proportion of the incumbent’s || 95% Share of new entrant’s passengers taken from incumbents || 70% New entrants operating costs per train-kilometre as a proportion of incumbent’s || 80% Potential reduction in incumbent’s operating costs (A) || 20% Proportion of incumbent’s services stimulated to higher efficiency by new entry (B) || 10% || 15% || 20% (AxB) Resulting average reduction in incumbent’s costs in this sector stimulated by competition from open access || 2% || 3% || 4% Compulsory competitive tendering effects Sectors || All PSCs, including commercial services becoming PSCs because of open access Effects || Reduction in incumbent’s share of PSC train-kilometres || 2% || 10% || 15% Potential reduction in PSC service operating costs (C) || 15% Proportion of PSCs subject to effective competition (D) || 25% || 75% || 90% (CxD) Resulting average reduction in PSC costs || 3.75% || 11.25% || 13.5% Share of PSC cost savings invested rather than retained Scenario 1 - Focus on cost savings Scenario 2 - Reinvestment || 0% 50% Quality-related rise: train-kilometres and capital expenditure || 0.1% || 0.5% || 0.75% Quality-related rise: passenger-kilometres and revenue || 0.1% || 0.5% || 0.75% Timescales and discounting Start || Implementation of Package, creation of open access rights and award of first competitive tenders for PSCs || 2019 End || Last existing PSC contracts replaced in competitive tendering || 2025 || Base year for discounting purposes || 2019 Table 8 below summarises the financial benefits for: ·
the separation initiative only (column 1) ·
the domestic passenger market opening only for two scenarios: ─
Market opening Scenario 1
- Focus on savings (column 2) - In this scenario it is assumed that competent
authorities would focus on cost savings, taking all the reductions in PSC
tender costs as cash savings and not reinvesting any of these in higher rail
quality or capacity. ─
Market opening Scenario 2 - Reinvestment (column 3)- In
this scenario it is assumed that competent authorities would not focus on cost
savings but would instead implicitly “reinvest” half the potential reductions
in PSC tender costs by specifying higher quality or capacity in PSCs. In terms
of monetary impacts this implies reduction in NPV, while the benefits appear in
terms of increase in passenger km-s. ·
combined impacts of both initiatives separating two different
outcome scenarios: ─
Combined impacts Scenario 1 – Focus on
savings (column 4) ─
Combined impacts Scenario 2 – Reinvestment
(column 5) Table
8 Combined impacts of market opening and infrastructure governance
policies – Summary of core financial estimates All changes are illustrative estimates NPVs (bil €) to 2035, discounted at 4% to 2019 || Separation Scenario 3 || Market opening: Scenario 1 - Savings || Market opening: Scenario 2 - Reinvestment || Combined impacts: Scenario 1 - Savings || Combined impacts: Scenario 2 - Reinvestment || 1 || 2 || 3 || 4 || 5 Transaction costs (mean estimate) || -1.37 || -0.42 || -0.42 || -1.77 || -1.77 Domestic service benefits* || 5.86 || 29.85 || 21.46 || 43.07 || 33.71 International service benefits || 1.07 || || || 1.05 || 0.89 Freight benefits || 1.00 || 1.00 || 1.00 Total NPV || 6.56 || 29.44 || 21.04 || 43.35 || 33.83 || * The benefits encompass mainly savings for competent authorities, but also profits of operators. For
freight, a lump estimation of €1 bn is added. It is based on consideration that
EU-wide rail freight market has a turnover of around €18 billion but has long
been subject to extensive competition from other modes, is not subsidised, and
under Directive 2004/51/EC has been completely liberalised
since 1 January 2007. Nonetheless, effects of institutional separation, where
it does not already exist, and hence greater scope for new entry, might result
in some further increases in entry and hence a combination of price reductions,
quality improvements and transfer to rail from other modes. If the combined
effect of extending institutional separation to all networks resulted in
benefits equivalent to 1% of rail freight industry turnover, this could result
in additional benefits until 2035 with an NPV of €1 billion (uncertainty ±50%).
These freight benefits are additional to the benefits in domestic and
international passenger markets calculated on the basis of assumptions in Table
7. Table 9 below presents a wider range
of indicators for individual and combined policies. Table
9 Impacts of market opening and infrastructure governance policies -
range of expected outcomes All changes are illustrative estimates || Financial benefits (NPV*, € bn) || Increase in annual revenue (€ bn) || Increase in annual CAPEX (€ bn) || Additional passenger-km (bn by 2035) || Increase in new entry market share (% points) Scenario 1 –Focus on saving Vertical separation[90] || 6.56 || 0.1 || 0.01 || 0.8 || 0.5% Domestic passenger market opening || 29.44 || 0.3 || 0.03 || 2 || 3.8% Combination of market opening and vertical separation || 43.35 || 0.5 || 0.1 || 3.8 || 6.4% Scenario 2 – Reinvestment Vertical separation alone || 4.42 || 0.1 || 0.01 || 1.1 || 0.5% Domestic passenger market opening || 21.04 || 0.9 || 0.13 || 8.4 || 3.7% Combination of market opening and vertical separation || 33.83 || 1.7 || 0.2 || 16.4 || 6.2% * NPVs to 2035, discounted at 4% to 2019, the benefits encompass mainly savings for competent authorities, but also profits of operators. The results for both scenarios demonstrate existence of
significant synergies between the separation and market access measures as
proposed in the 4th package. 16 billion passenger-km potentially
made available by implementing market opening and separation polices, while
re-investing half of efficiency savings back to railways, would result in 6%
increase of passenger-km on top of the baseline developments. In addition, more
level playing field in access to infrastructure, as provided by vertical
separation measures, would enable to increase the market share of new entrants
from 19% in the baseline to 25%. Further burst will be given by quicker time and cost to market for
rail undertakings, as provided by the revised scope of the European Railway
Agency, also being the part of the 4th Package. Annex Vi ASSESSMENT OF SOCIAL IMPACTS In
a guided system like railways with quite a generalised excess capacity on the
tracks the management of the network is crucial to exploit assets as much as
possible, thus reaping economies of scale and improving the price/quality
relationship. Neutrality in infrastructure management will improve quality,
increase the attractiveness of rail traffic and therefore traffic numbers which
in turn will lead to more employment and/or higher productivity allowing wage
increases and improvements in working conditions. Separation
has an induced impact on employment in the EU, as the lower costs of transport
will free resources to carry out other activities thus increasing the
competitiveness of the EU and its production and employment. As
to the direct employment deriving from organisational changes, separation will
reduce the economies of scope of carrying out the infrastructure and operation
tasks within a single organisation. Therefore it will imply that more people
will be required to do complementary tasks in the infrastructure manager and in
the different operating companies which may increase costs. However, the
transparency brought by market contractual relationships with independent
companies will also reduce the costs of monitoring by the regulator. It will
also help the government to better tailor PSO and investment subsidies to the
real needs of society, breaking its "agency" dependency[91] in respect of an integrated
incumbent. The
current system where certain incumbents are partly integrated and all new
entrants are fully separated from the infrastructure manager creates legal and
functional insecurity giving rise to conflicts and litigation, which represent
a waste of resources including human ones. It also deters investments in
rolling stock. With
unified infrastructure management, it is possible that a more specialised IM
will have a greater interest in the better use and correct maintenance of the
current infrastructure and the right dimensioning of the future one. But it is
difficult to draw conclusions due to the role of governments themselves. Concerning
the different measures, the most favourable ones from a social viewpoint are
those that provide the infrastructure manager with a wider portfolio of
competencies whether on the day-to-day management of the infrastructure (paths
and charges) or concerning its maintenance and development over time. Annex Vii Governance and Access to Service Facilities 1.
Introduction Access
to service facilities such as shunting and maintenance yards or passenger train
stations is essential for the effective functioning of competition in railway
markets. If new entrants do not get access to facilities at acceptable
conditions, they will in many cases not enter the market, even if access to the
main infrastructure is secured. In most cases it would be too costly for new
entrants to build their own facilities in the Member States where they intend
to operate. Moreover, even in case they would be prepared to invest, new
facilities would not necessarily have the same good connections to other modes
of transport as those offered by existing facilities (ports, airports, bus
stations etc.). New entrants may be private rail operators; however access
problems also affect State owned companies wanting to enter markets other than
their home market. With no new market entry, competition will fail and
customers will continue to rely only on the services of the former monopolists,
which will not improve through the lack of incentives to do so. The
degree of provision of rail related services varies significantly across the
EU. In many countries the state-owned rail undertaking not only controls the
infrastructure itself, but also service facilities and therefore their access.
This creates a natural conflict of interest. While the EU Directives oblige the
operator of the facility to provide access to all railway operators (under
certain conditions), integrated incumbent operators may be reluctant to provide
such services to new entrants, as the latter are direct competitors of their
own transport subsidiaries. This does not only jeopardise fair competition
amongst rail operators, but it is also unacceptable when, as in most cases, the
facilities were built with public funds, and their use should therefore not be
reserved to specific companies who for historical reasons maintain a monopoly
position. The
recently adopted Recast of the First Railway package, in its Article 13 and
Annex II, addresses problems in the application of the existing legislation,
and problems which the existing legislation is not able to solve. 2.
Experiences with the
application of competition law Currently, complaints on access problems to service
facilities may only be brought to competition authorities. The existing
Directives 91/440/EEC (as amended by Directive 2001/12/EC) and 2001/14/EC do
not give railway regulators any powers to control issues of access to
rail-related services. According to the rules of
competition law, access to a specific facility must only be given if this
facility is considered to be "essential" for the operation of a
market entrant and thus for establishing competition in the market
("essential facilities doctrine"). The
criteria that must be fulfilled for a facility to be considered as essential,
and which have been in a number of cases brought before European and national
courts, may be summarised in the following five points: ·
the facility must be controlled by a dominant
firm ·
access to the facility is indispensable in order
to compete in a market which is related to the one in which the operator is
dominant ·
the competitor must be unable to duplicate the
essential facility under reasonable economic conditions ·
access to the facility is refused or granted
under unjustifiably restrictive conditions ·
it must be feasible to provide access to the
facility. These
criteria offer many possibilities for the operator of the facility to escape
the obligation to grant access. The burden of proof to show that all these
criteria are fulfilled falls on the market entrant. This is difficult because a
new entrant, in particular when coming from another Member State, does not
necessarily have sufficient information on available alternative facilities and
their services, while in most cases the operator, especially if it belongs to
an integrated company, owns most of the facilities in the country and therefore
has all the necessary information. Apart
from this lack of information on the side of the market entrant, fulfilment of
all the five criteria is objectively very difficult to prove. The market
entrant must demonstrate that access to a particular facility is indispensable
in order to compete within the relevant market. Therefore he must practically
prove that without access to that facility he has no access whatsoever to the
market. This is difficult if the new entrant is already active in other parts
of a national market, but needs access to a specific terminal to open a new
service. Then it could be said that he does not need access to the specific
facility, because he would not have to exit the market completely, given his
remaining activities. If the new entrant is not yet active in the market, and
has to give up its intention to enter the market because of the denial of
access to a facility, the terminal operator may argue that the plans were not
realistic anyway, no sufficient business plan existed etc. If the applicant had
used the facility previously, and access is now denied, the proof that this
criterion is fulfilled may only be made once the railway undertaking exits the
market definitively However in this case even a positive decision of a competition
authority would be of limited use for the complainant. Access
to the facility may also be deemed not to be indispensable if the terminal
operator offers access to an alternative facility. Even if this alternative
terminal is far away from the railway line which the new entrant wants to use,
and it does not make economic sense to use this facility, it may be difficult
to demonstrate that the rail operator would not also be able to compete using
the alternative facility. Fulfilment
of the third condition ("the competitor must be unable to duplicate the
essential facility within reasonable economic conditions") is also very
difficult to prove, because the notion of "reasonable economic
conditions" is subject to interpretation. Finally,
the criterion "granted under unjustifiably restrictive conditions"
leaves a large margin of discretion for the facility operator to escape access
obligations. It is sufficient to combine access with unrealistic conditions
(e.g. limit the usable space in a shunting yard so that shunting operations are
impossible). The applicant will have to prove to the competition authority or
the court why access needs to be granted in a specific technical way. This
opens the door to costly procedures involving expert opinions etc., something
which a small rail operator with limited resources would not be able to do. These
difficulties in the application of the "essential facilities"
doctrine explain why there is hardly any precedent for successful court cases
or complaint procedures before competition authorities on this point.
Competition authorities are aware of these difficulties and try to achieve a
settlement between the parties in such cases. However, since the incumbents are
aware of these legal difficulties in terms of burden of proof, their readiness
to settle is normally limited. Since
Directive 2001/14/EC takes up the "essential facilities" doctrine
with the formulation that access may not be denied if there is "no viable
alternative", the Recast addresses these problems with the introduction of
more concrete rules on access to services. 3.
Examples of access
problems to service facilities In
order to illustrate the problems, the following overview offers some examples
of discriminatory practices in the access to services that have been reported
by new entrants (sometimes themselves incumbents in their home state) in
several Member States. This list is however by no means exhaustive. –
Discriminations in passenger railway stations: Incumbents
oblige new entrants to accept ticket distribution agreements which give the
incumbent the exclusive right to sell tickets at rail stations. Therefore
competitors have no right to use the travel centres or ticket vendors in those
stations. In some cases, the commission on ticket sales is larger for the
incumbent than for external competitors. Furthermore, competitors encounter problems with access to information displays,
visual and oral passenger information. In some cases there are even explicit
instructions to the train station staff not to inform passengers about the
competing offers. This results in difficulties for the new entrants to inform
their potential customers about their offers, which deprives customers of the
benefit of choice between rail operators. –
Long-term leases of service facilities through
the incumbent: Most
of the service infrastructure is leased to the incumbent on a long-term basis,
e.g. all tracks of a strategically important marshalling yard. In many cases
incumbents also tend to block side tracks by renting them, although they are
not needed, for the sole purpose of preventing access for their competitors. If
the facility is built to meet the needs of the new entrant, the costs charged
to the new entrant by the infrastructure manager for the connection to the main
line and to signalling equipment are often prohibitive. –
High costs of shunting locomotives as a barrier
to market entry: Since
shunting yards are predominantly not electrified, shunting with mainline
locomotives is technically not possible. Buying additional shunting locomotives
means an increase in fixed costs for new entrants, which most of them cannot
bear. –
Car transport – general access to the
marshalling yards: Competitors
do not have a general right of access to the marshalling yards to load their
cars onto the trains of the incumbent. Offers of the incumbent to organize this
on behalf of the new entrant are often subject to prohibitive prices. –
Massive capacity reduction and reactivation only
on discriminatory conditions: Many
railway operators are prevented from using idle facilities by terms set by the
infrastructure manager. The infrastructure manager may well demand to cover all
costs of reactivation and/or to rent the facility for an excessively long
period. –
Lack of transparency as regards the billing for the
use of the service facilities: Operators
of service facilities must set up a price list but are not obliged to link
services to specific prices. Courts in some Member States have reached this
conclusion on the basis of the wording of the Directive. –
Massive capacity reduction without viable
alternatives under normal market conditions: In
some Member States infrastructure managers close service facilities and offer
competitors / market entrants access to alternative stations which are however
very distant from the lines they want to operate. In some cases availability is
denied for the complete facility due to the alleged deactivation, although
parts of the facility would still be available for the new entrant. –
Supply of traction current, usage of fuelling
facilities Competitors have to deal with unfair pricing and usage
conditions in the supply of traction current and when using fuelling
facilities. In some cases transport companies belonging to the incumbent
operator receive considerable rebates which are not offered to the new
entrants, which creates serious competition problems. 4.
The new rules of the
Recast on access to service facilities The
Recast of the First Railway Package addresses these problems above in its
Article 13. Key elements of these provisions are: –
organisational and decision-making independence
of the infrastructure manager required in case it belongs to an integrated
company –
denial of access admissible only if there is a
viable alternative for the proposed route –
reservation of adequate capacity to competitors
in case not all requests can be followed –
extension of the powers of the rail regulator to
control all aspects of access to services. The
new Recast Directive empowers rail regulators to decide about disputes on
access to rail-related services, as they know the rail market best and
competition authorities do not have the necessary powers to enforce access to
service facilities, as explained above. In
view of the conflict of interest in companies which are operators of service
facilities and have at the same time transport activities in competition with
other railway undertakings, the Directive strengthens the independence of the
facility operator in such situations. This is the case if it belongs to a body
or firm which is dominant in a national railway transport services markets for
which the facility is used. However, this does not concern maintenance
terminals and maritime and inland port facilities
which are linked to rail activities. As
to the type of independence which the facility operator must have, it must be
strengthened when it forms part of an integrated company. The Commission had
originally proposed "legal, organisational and decision-making
independence". However, in the final text of the Recast only "organisational
and decision-making independence" were adopted. This does not mean that
separate bodies must be created for each facility. They could all be regrouped
under one body, or be included within the infrastructure manager for whom the
Directive already provides the same description of its necessary independence
(and in addition "legal independence"). As
to the new provision according to which access can only be denied if there is a
viable alternative which allows the railway undertaking to operate the freight
or passenger service concerned on the same or alternative routes under
economically acceptable conditions. This provision is meant to clarify what is a
"viable" alternative and to avoid the situation where the rail
operator would be sent to a remote terminal, which would make the alternative
useless. The
provision that an adequate capacity must be reserved for competitors is
intended to avoid the claim by the facility operator that the whole
infrastructure is in permanent and complete use by the subsidiaries of the incumbent,
a claim for which the new entrant will have great difficulty to provide
counter-evidence, due to his lack of relevant information. The proposed
provision should in principle have no impact on the revenues of the facility
operator and leaves a considerable margin of discretion to the rail regulator
since it is impossible to say in a piece of general legislation what
"adequate capacity" corresponds to in every specific situation. To
address the difficulties encountered by competitors in passenger stations, the
Recast includes the obligation for the operator of the station to offer a
location for ticketing and to display travel information of all railway
undertakings. The Recast also obliges station operators to offer ticketing
facilities to all operators, in case they offer these services to any railway
undertakings. This is important in particular for smaller train operators
running only a few trains and who cannot afford to provide permanent staff in
railway stations to sell tickets for their own trains. The
recast also deals with the issue of idle facilities proposing that the service
facility that has not been in use for at least two consecutive years by its
owner must be offered for lease or rent. Another option could be to tender the
sale of the facility, so that prospective rail users may make offers for
purchasing it. The
numerous problems of overpricing or non-transparent pricing encountered by new
entrants are dealt with in the Recast by clear transparency provisions
concerning the network statement and the rule that services are offered at full
cost. This ensures on the one hand that facility operators are not obliged to
make losses by granting access to their competitors. They will even be enabled
to claim a reasonable profit for the relevant services. On the other hand the
reference to full costs allows a control of pricing by the regulator and thus
avoids prohibitive over-pricing which is detrimental to the development of
railway markets. 5.
Potential of the new
rules of the Recast to solve the problems for access to service facilities The
new rules of the Recast will go a long way in solving access issues for service
facilities. They do not only provide for increased regulatory oversight, but
also clarify access criteria. They do not only offer ex-post remedies through
the action of a regulator, but also contain some structural ex-ante solution by
obliging undertakings having a dominant position in a service market to foresee
separation of their facilities in organisational and decision-making terms. It
is possible that this type of structural solution could be affected by similar
problems as the existing "legal, organisational and decision-making
independence" for the essential functions of an infrastructure manager in
relation to railway undertakings. In particular the efficiency of the
"decision making independence" may depend on whether and how the
Court of Justice will clarify this concept in the context of the infringement
procedures on the First Railway Package. Therefore
the question arises whether it would not be useful to have a complete
institutional separation also for the relation between facility operators and
railway undertakings, respectively to integrate these facilities in the
independent infrastructure managers. This could create the same type of legal
certainty as a complete institutional separation of the infrastructure manager.
However, while the rules of the directive on decision-making independence for
the essential functions of an infrastructure manager have been in force since
2001, the reinforced rules on access to the service facilities have just been
adopted after intense discussions in Council and Parliament, and will enter
into force only in November 2012. It does therefore not seem to be suitable to
propose such measures already in the framework of the Fourth Package proposal.
The impact of the new rules can only be fully assessed after a certain time
period in which they were applied. ANNEX
VIII Summary
document of the conference
“The Last Mile towards the 4th Railway Package” Held on 24
September 2012 in Brussels, Belgium Keynote addresses Mr Siim Kallas, Vice-President of the European
Commission Vice-President
Kallas welcomed all the delegates to the conference and explained that many
challenges lay ahead to enable the trans-European rail sector to achieve its
full potential through the creation of a single European railway area. Plenty
of progress has been made with recent agreement on the rail recast which will
considerably change the way the rail market works, stimulating investment,
improving market access conditions and reinforcing the role of national rail
regulators. More
reform was needed if rail was to achieve its full potential and compete
effectively with other modes, by breaking down barriers, attracting more
operators to the market, removing nationalistic protections, making the
industry more efficient and raising service quality, punctuality and
reliability. EU-wide
standards are required, the use of which would facilitate a move to a single
European approval system allowing trains to be built and certified to run
everywhere in the EU and saving money in the process. The European Railway
Agency should become the primary vehicle to issue single certificates for
safety and authorisation provided there is technical compatibility. Access
needs to be granted to rolling stock, particularly for market newcomers,
otherwise it is very difficult for them to compete. Only a few countries are
fully open to competition, a mixture of open access and public service contracts
should be encouraged to provide competition in and competition for the market. Infrastructure
management functions such as charging and the allocation of rail capacity,
financial transparency, maintenance, renewal, upgrade and development of the
infrastructure, day-to-day traffic management and the provision of real-time
information must be kept apart from the operation of transport services and be
exercised independently through a separated structure. This
conference is not about having competition for competition's sake but about
providing a better service and ensuring rail is able to fulfil its underused
potential. We hope to hear the views of a wide audience of stakeholders to
develop our options for reform. Mr Dominique Riquet, Member of the European
Parliament (PPE-FR) Mr
Riquet echoed a warm welcome to all the attendees and explained that the
creation of an integrated transport system had proven difficult with a
continued need to overcome bottlenecks of physical and organisational problems.
Updated guidelines on connectivity and the compatibility of regulations have
started to clarify some of the complex issues but rail needs to compete with
other modes such as road and solving some of the interoperability issues will
start to assist this. There
is an enormous amount to do and in some cases there has been considerable
national resistance, however the freight industry has demonstrated the benefits
of opening up the markets. It is time to start to adapt to single European
market ways of thinking and embrace interoperability, transparency, create the
right fare conditions and vitally open up the infrastructure. I
support the concept of the European Railway Agency (ERA) taking on an enhanced
managerial role and one day it is hoped that a single European regulator may
exist. In the meantime, rail can no longer be the outlier and must not escape
the rules of the single market. Plenary
I: Opening a new page in European Railways (Moderator:
Mr Matthias Ruete, Director General - European Commission, DG MOVE) Ms
Catherina Elmstäter-Svard, Swedish Minister for Infrastructure Ms
Elmstäter-Svard presented how deregulation had taken place in the Swedish
market since 1988 following a financial crisis. Despite attempts at a financial
overhaul, the quality of rail transport and infrastructure could not be
maintained. Railway transport was not customer driven. There was a lack of
funding for investment in rolling stock, and in new service concepts. The
incumbent had become a powerful but impenetrable “state within a state” that
asserted its own interests at the expense of common interests. Radical measures
had to be taken. Real
reform came based on separating the responsibility for infrastructure
management and the operation of rail transport, both in terms of organisation
and decision-making through increased transparency (helping various previously
excluded bodies influence the railway system), increased competitiveness
(making the split between taxpayers and passengers to develop railway
infrastructure more financial stable) and providing rail transport on a
commercial basis (based on customer requirements). These
and other reforms such as diversifying the supply of rail transport services
within a competitive procurement system were aimed to create and open up more
markets to effective competition, to provide better conditions while still
maintaining high levels of railway safety. In return, demand for rail transport
began to increase, investment in railway infrastructure and rolling stock also
increased. More rail companies were established, and so competition increased
too. Both railway freight transport and railway passenger transport increased
capacity and efficiency. Had new market entrants not been convinced that they
could use the railway infrastructure on non-discriminatory terms, the positive
stimulus would simply never have happened. Entrusting the management of the
infrastructure to an independent entity with competitive neutrality and
non-discrimination removed any suspicion that the state could place effective
barriers to entry. A vertically separated railway system considerably reduces
the need for any detailed regulation which is neither efficient nor sufficient.
European railway legislation must require vertical separation clearly within
the framework. Some
difficulties will remain which will need to be resolved in a way that does not
damage competition, for example how to deal with the introduction of ERTMS in a
neutral way without specifying the equipment to be purchased but ensuring
interoperability? Having ensured that the Infrastructure Manager (IM) behaves
in a non-discriminatory way, how do we ensure it operates efficiently, and on
the basis of the demand of rail companies for capacity so that they can offer
transport services that correspond to customers’ requirements? Sufficient
incentives need to be provided to ensure it effectively fulfils its remit. An
effective and consolidated rolling stock market is urgently required. Rolling
stock is expensive and has its risks. New and smaller rail companies have
difficulties entering the market due to a lack of access to rolling stock on
reasonable terms. The
challenges we face in realising railway policy both in Brussels and at home
must ultimately be about the benefits for rail customers. Mr
Mauro Moretti, Chairman - CER Mr
Moretti considered that despite the implementation of three railway packages at
EU level, there was still need for change in the mindset of managing rail. As
each change passed, productivity increased, ever more independence from public
budgets was possible and competition against other transport modes and within
rail increased. The
rail sector needs a fair and stable regulatory framework, not one that changes
every two or three years. Rules must be homogenous and valid for everybody to
create a sound business environment, to attract private and public investments
and to create a Single European Rail Area. We
must streamline the certification and authorisation processes that constitute
huge barriers for market entry and consider the efficiency gains that an
enhanced ERA may benefit the sector with, such as centralising some functions
currently performed by national safety authorities (NSA), speeding up the
processes for rolling stock authorisation and placing on the market, safety
certification of railway undertakings (RUs) and the development and application
of the legal framework (regarding safety, interoperability and technological
development). Control may then take place through one body and replace today’s
non-transparent procedures applied by different NSA's. Since there is a common
and widespread agreement on this point, the Commission's proposal should be
“fast tracked” through the legislative procedure in the case of ERA. Consideration
must be given to the best way to open domestic markets. Free interplay of
supply and demand and competitive pressure should push companies towards new
efficiencies while understanding that the rail network benefits all customers
only if good rules are applied. Open access services must therefore not develop
to the detriment of services provided under a regime of public service
contracts. A
European legal framework should be drawn up to recognize that national and
regional competent authorities must have enough room to find a good match
between EU legal obligations and the specificities of their territories and of
their customers’ needs in terms of tendering. The
best structural way to organise our systems and our companies should be
considered, ensuring we guarantee a fair competitive environment for operators
while and at the same time minimising the costs for the industry as a whole.
Stronger national regulatory bodies would certainly help and constitute an
essential tool for a fair functioning of the market. Evidence
on the impact on the market of different organisational models (where the
incumbent operator is or is not fully separated from the IM), show mixed
results and suggest that other variables (such as system cost, modal share, and
State funding) partially count towards explaining performance outcomes. CER
conducted a study at the beginning of this year which suggested that different
structures work best in different circumstances and therefore a flexibility of
structural models may be beneficial. Mr
Philippe De Backer, Member of the European Parliament (ALDE-BE) As
Member of the TRAN Committee, Mr De Backer stated that during his first full
year as MEP, rail policy was one of the most discussed items in the Committee.
The 4th package has not yet emerged but has already been broadly discussed in
the European Parliament as elsewhere. Experience with the recast of the 1st
package has shown that emotions can run high and that lobbying will become more
intense, approaching adoption of the EC proposals and afterwards, when
discussing them in Parliament. The
first Directive (approved in 1991) established that Member States would
separate infrastructure and services so trains could be used for cross border
journeys. The aim was to increase the attractiveness of transporting goods by
rail. The results were disappointing because most of the Member States did not
want to give up their national monopolies. 3 rail packages have followed, 21
years later we are still discussing the issue. The single European rail market
is still not in place or working as it should be which is unfortunate as rail
has the potential to relieve the over congested European roads. Eurostat data
shows rail share of passenger and freight transport in still low for the EU27
at 6.3% and 10.2%. A
single European rail market will have enormous added value for Europe,
encouraging companies to transport their goods and helping to reach the 60% GHG
emission reduction by 2050 as laid down in the White Paper on the Future of
transport. Member
States must put interoperability into practice, allowing cross acceptance and a
single process of placing vehicles into service. Unreasonable discriminatory
demands on foreign railway companies wanting to enter national markets are
unacceptable. Transparent rules (thus monitoring and control) are needed and
most importantly Member States must implement them and the EC take infringement
action as required. It's unacceptable to let years pass by before taking any
action. Safety
is and should stay the main concern for every railway company and is often
linked (not in a good way) to liberalisation. Trade unions claim that
liberalisation leads to less safety on rail which is completely untrue and
unproven (rather the contrary) and the EC should provide information in order
to inform Citizens properly. Thanks
to the recast, national regulators will receive more competences and have more
responsibilities. The European Railway Agency works well and it is accepted by
all stakeholders in the rail sector so should be made the one stop shop that is
needed. In the future national technical and safety rules should no longer
exist. There should be one authority that gives out licences, gives vehicles
authorisation and monitors and controls the market. It
is very difficult to convince Member States of the added value an open market brings,
as in most cases national passenger transport is in the hands of the
State-owned historic companies. They are often not ready to cope with efficient
competition as they are funded with State money and are in most cases
accumulating debts. However the advantages if done in a consistent manner are
that it will give the passenger greater choice and lead to better quality of
service. Market liberalisation should be accompanied by a legal separation
between the IM and the RU. Unbundling should be the standard. The debts many
companies are bearing now are the result of the existing inefficient integrated
structure. Efficiency gains are desperately needed, also for the public purse. Further
discussion on this subject will no doubt become very intense but the EC should
put Citizens in the driver seat and come forward with an ambitious proposal for
a 4th railway package. Mr
Mark Hopwood, Managing Director - First Great Western, First Group Mr
Hopwood described his train passenger operating business, the largest in the UK
with over 25% of the market and the experience gained through the franchise
bidding process, winning tenders to operate intercity long distance, regional
and commuter services across a geographic range. He also described how an open
access operation within the same country had been established since 2000 and
how the company had some European exposure from open access in freight. The
UK already operates with a certain level of decentralisation with some
contracts being contracted by local rather than national authorities either
solely or as co-signatories. Privatisation in the UK had been born from British
Rail not delivering, with poor performance and low passenger satisfaction and
with government focus at the time on other areas of expenditure. Innovation
came from the introduction of market competition which has been so successful
that significant growth has now led to a change of political context (all UK
political parties support rail investment), limited support for returning to
public sector operation and a continued move to funding from the fare payer
rather than the tax payer. In
London and South East demand is already 10% above forecasts with TfL projecting
demand by 2020 as high as 33% above 2007 expectations. Similarly passenger
journeys in the West Midlands show significant year on year increases. Targeted
marketing campaigns help to increase patronage for leisure customers and along
with the creation of new partnerships with tourist associations and promotion
on websites led to increases in revenue and return on investment of 3.9:1 with
10% increases in customer numbers. A
number of local service case studies were described demonstrating how private
operators had worked with local councils, IMs and development funders to create
and implement schemes for infrastructure enhancements leading to the provision
of additional services or improved station services and accessibility and thus
also benefiting the social railway. The
customer experience is vitally important, railway decision making cannot be a
theoretical exercise. Twice yearly National Passenger Surveys conducted by an
independent organisation (Passenger Focus) provide a focus of passenger
perception with a number of aspects of the service provided. This is in
addition to four weekly customer services monitoring to ensure the service
provided is appropriate to the needs of the passenger. Transparency
of cost and performance data is important because it helps the industry, its
customers and its funders to understand the real story around what the rail
sector costs and how it performs, and whether they are getting value for money.
The next step is to make customers and taxpayers much better informed. A
firm framework with flexibility for innovation and partnership working needs to
be created to allow private companies such as FirstGroup to grow in Europe post
liberalisation. The obstacles to new entrants must be tackled, such as directly
awarding in some so-called “open” markets. Competitive tendering levels the
playing field as long as all entrants have access to full transparency of
information. Without leasing companies state/regional authorities will need to
absorb financial risks or new entrants will not be able to lease or acquire
stock. Through ticketing arrangements should be managed alongside a
"clearing house" mechanism run by an independent body to ensure
fairness and reimburse operators quickly. Mr
Vicenzo Cannatelli, Vice President – NTV Mr
Cannatelli explained how NTV entered the Italian rail market following the
advent of liberalisation and explained some of the difficulties that saw it
take 6 years from incorporation to starting to run services. Railway
companies can be capital intensive businesses with very high fixed costs. The
financial turbulence since 2008 has also made funding within European markets
more difficult. When
entering the Italian market this year, as it is not fully liberalised many
constraints exist such as a no complete and independent separation between IM
and incumbent national operator, as both the IM and train operators are 100%
owned by the same companies. The cost of high speed access was one of the
highest in Europe at more than € 13 per train-km and the homologation process
not well defined and continuously thwarted by the incumbent operator. The
approvals process is way too long. It took 45 months from request of
homologation to commercial service operation. No
national body has overall ability to grant permission, which is very
inefficient. The NSA is technically independent from the railway operator and
is supervised by Ministry of Transport while the regulatory body has different
tasks including supervision and monitoring of competition and the degree of
market contestability. Furthermore
the Italian Government announced in January the creation of an independent
Transportation Authority which will have to introduce fair competition in all
railway sectors, have power to constrain uncompetitive situations and possibly
analyse the benefits of unbundling in the upcoming months. NTV's
introduction in the market has had a major impact on economic and social
structure in Italy. NTV have invested over € 1 billion in 25 trains, depots,
IT, training and staff. The benefits have spread to the customer as the advent
of NTV has improved the incumbents' proposition and customer service to
compete. Prices have decreased while higher frequency and additional services
are now running leading to growth taking place far in excess of the wider
economy. Marketplace innovation has also led to a new more efficient mix of sales
channels with 70% coming from the internet. This all demonstrates the vital
benefits of the liberalisation agenda. Plenary
II: Railways - an agenda for growth, innovation and employment in Europe (Moderator:
Mr Karel Vinck, ERTMS coordinator) Mr
Melchior Wathelet, Minister of Mobility – Belgium Mr
Wathelet spoke about independence of the RU and IM and that it was clear that
this was a sensitive subject and that work is not yet complete. Some barriers
exist, some of which were wished for. Rail has an enviable record on safety and
respect of the environment. Rail demand is continually growing. Technological
renewals are more sustainable, ecologically beneficial and economically better
for all. Mobility leads to growth (estimated to be 2% GDP) and therefore we
need to remove the bottlenecks, harmonise interoperability rules and introduce
ERTMS. Non-discriminatory
access is needed for all operators. Competition raises not just economic but
also political issues. The changes are giant steps when you consider the
historical level of protectionism we have come from. Rights of access,
financial stability and independence have been created along with the
establishment of tariffs, separation of accounting functions, safety and
interoperability requirements, certification of train drivers and
liberalisation of the freight market. We
are making the sector more dynamic, however when we view the sector objectively
we must admit that the work is not done. Rail is not the preferred mode of
transport for most Europeans or for key businesses such as logistics and
haulage companies. To achieve such changes requires the opening up of a single
European rail market providing non-discriminatory access to all operators and
encouraging an increase in the predictability of major investment. Tariffs are
still too high for consumers and the density on some networks could lead to
different solutions being sought. Greater clarity is required on the unbundling
package. Member States must take the responsibility to develop a corporate long
term infrastructure development plan. The
ERA could be seen to signal a detriment to NSA's, however we must not find new
barriers to undermine liberalisation. Sometimes we have been guilty of deciding
on the direction of travel without giving ourselves the means to make the full
journey and therefore get stuck in the mire. We must not allow that to happen
again. The sector needs a specific dynamic approach which should be looked at
objectively together by the EC, Member States and the industry. Mr
Svend Leirvaag, Vice - President Industry Affairs - Amadeus Mr
Leirvaag presented how his company Amadeus grew out of the supply chain from
the deregulation and liberalisation of the aviation sector and how they are now
a global European player, employing 59 different nationalities and represented
in 195 countries. Amadeus
started the migration to open systems 15 years ago and has invested over € 2
billion in research and development since 2004 proving that you never stop
learning and this is why we should say that this is the "next km" in
rail deregulation rather than the "last mile". Its main focus is as a
cost efficient outsourcing provider connecting travel providers with consumers
through choice and transparency. Connecting
Railways and other modes of transport will become the number 1 priority for
European consumers. The future of the integrated European transport system
needs to be sustained by a robust Inter-modal system that enables any traveller
to plan, book, pay for and collect their ticket seamlessly. The sector needs to
start preparing for deregulation and increased competition. Following
discussion with railways and industry stakeholders, the three main challenges
in today’s rail industry are the importance of the traveller and satisfying
their evolving needs, the role of the opening of the rail market in Europe with
its opportunities for increased competition and the need to generate
efficiencies and to look for new revenue streams. Technology will be the key to
remaining competitive and driving innovation. An
efficient and competitive European railways sector will strengthen the
competitiveness of Europe and their enterprises but this requires changes.
Currently the dynamics of the marketplace mean that high price variation exists
and sharing of technology to drive expansion and keep costs down is not yet
widely undertaken. One example of such inefficiency is distribution channel
ticketing bonds. These are required with each and every Rail Undertaking rather
than a single European bond to cover them all. Mr Johannes Mansbart, Chief Executive
Officer - GATX Mr
Mansbart explained that rolling stock was the key sector asset and determines
the performance of the rail industry. It is vital that entrants have
availability of rolling stock on reasonable terms. Challenges
currently exist around slow industry integration. ECM responsibility requires
solid vehicle operating data and there is still much to be done on the
availability and consistency of such data. An automated data exchange should be
developed in a standardised format between workshops, keepers, RUs and
customers. New
regulations such as vehicle noise emission standards have a material impact on
the life cycle costs of rolling stock and as they deliver economic (public),
rather than any commercial payback benefits, providers are not commercially
driven to seek the best solutions, instead choosing where applicable to pass
the costs onto the RU. Maintenance
concepts need to be fine-tuned with unified rules and standards, optimised
spare part logistics, shared services, component swaps and more preventive and
less reactive maintenance. The
ERA should be given a stronger European role including the rights to enforce
common rules on the market and bring clarity to a single information database. Mr
Stefan Roseanu, Chief Executive Officer - CFR Călători (RO) Mr
Roseanu presented how CFR Călători the national railway passenger
operator in Romania had been created in 1998 by splitting the former national
railway in line with EC directives and how the key challenges were a very old
train fleet, poor infrastructure and a lack of investment funds. Rail
travel has been decreasing with 20% reduction in train kilometres travelled and
60% less passengers, with a corresponding increase in car and road usage. This
is partly down to the quality of rolling stock offer, the new found
accessibility of private car ownership, the increasing competition from the
recently deregulated bus market and a change from bulk manufacturing plant
commuters (very efficient for rail) to a service industry economy to which rail
services have not yet adapted . Strategic
focus in Romania will be on short-distance, long-distance and cross border
services, the introduction of regular-interval timetables, integrating rail in
metropolitan transport offers to develop suburban services and the acquisition
of new rolling stock and modernisation of the existing fleet. Access
to the rolling stock market is important with lead times being so long and
lessons should be learned regarding the requirements of long term
infrastructure from the aviation and ports sectors. Generally supportive of the
idea of open access operation supporting public service contracts which are
awarded through competitive tendering to improve value. Workshop 1 – Rolling stock:
reduced time-to-market (Moderator:
Mr Marcel Verslype, Director - European Railway Agency) Mr
Verslype introduced the panel of speakers and then invited Patrizio Grillo from
the European Commission to present some initial thoughts on the implications of
the 4th railway package and how it could lead to a simplified
authorisation process. Some
of the key problems identified in the sector relate to differing
interpretations and implementation of EU law by Member States. In some cases
national rules are unclear, inappropriate, non-transparent (including incumbent
staffing seconded to NSA's) or overlap with existing TSIs. The authorisation
process is long (up to 2 years), uncertain and is expensive due to multiplicity
and unnecessary repetition of tests and verifications. It has been observed
that the cost of a safety certificate and for additional vehicle authorisation
can be hugely variable. As
part of the impact assessment different options have been assessed in terms of
costs and benefits. These include looking at an enhanced role for the ERA in
the safety certification of RUs and in monitoring and control of NSA's along
with migration towards a single vehicle authorisation (a European
"passport"). The
most cost-effective option was that the final decision on RU certification and
vehicle authorisation should be taken by ERA in cooperation with NSA's and
national authorities. In this way a single vehicle passport reflecting
compliance with rules, confirmation of technical characteristics necessary and
checked compatibility with the network would be issued by ERA valid in all
Member States with the RU responsible for verifying route-specific
compatibility. Mr
Alan Bell, Head of Railway Safety Policy - ORR UK Mr
Bell spoke about the issues related to market opening and how removing barriers
to entry would increase efficiency for the railway sector while ensuring that
the level of safety was maintained or improved. It was however important to
identify practical measures to achieve improvements in realistic but short
timescales including the proper implementation of interoperability and safety
directives. There
is a problem with the length of time to get new vehicles into service in some
Member States leading to increased capital costs and hampering innovation by
slowing developments in the market. Inconsistent implementation of processes
and rules and bureaucracy where nationalistic interests take priority over a
collective commitment to a single market also delay the process further. To
speed up the authorisation process clear guidelines need to be provided
including early and consistent engagement by NSA and clarity on what needs
authorising or not. Availability of information (through a document management
system), differences in national laws and the constituents of interoperability
need to be addressed along with the competence and consistency of national
bodies. ERA
role should be enhanced to a ‘partner’ role promoting harmonisation and
ensuring the current structure works as it should by monitoring the
implementation of directives and resolving disputes as well as enhancing
processes such as responsibility for a single safety certificate. The
advantages of the NSA should not be lost including the knowledge base and
feedback loop at a local level. Mr
Philippe Citroen, Director General - UNIFE Mr
Citroen explained that there was a need for a drastically simplified European
authorisation process as the current situation where European and national
rules & processes both have to be applied was the worst possible situation
with the results of this complexity being that it takes on average 600 days to
gain authorisation and the process is tying up € 1.4 billion capital that could
be utilised for other benefits. There
has only been a partial transposition of the safety & interoperability
directive, allowing a number of national processes to survive. UNIFE, CER, UIP
and ERFA therefore all strongly support the enhancement of the role of ERA to
become the European Railway Safety Agency. They should also become an appeal
body and have decision-making powers in the event of disputes about vehicle
authorisation processes and/or safety certificates The
EC should strongly encourage Member States to implement the present directives,
which offer the best possible basis for quick convergence, so as to eliminate
unnecessary rules. In this respect ERA should identify the unnecessary and
superfluous national rules and be able to request their removal as is done by
the Aviation (EASA) and Maritime (EMSA) agencies. RUs
also need to play their part and review their procurement processes to support
standardisation amongst the manufacturers as such initiatives have the
potential to reduce costs and time to market. Mr
Vicenzo Cannatelli, Vice President - NTV Mr
Cannatelli having already presented in Plenary I, discussed how liberalisation
should lead to better efficiency for all players in the industry and cheaper
prices for the consumer, however changes were required in order to get private
investors to invest capital in the railway. The most fundamental of such
changes was the need to set clear rules that are non-discriminatory, clear
timings and ultimately a transparency of process. It is currently too easy for
incumbents to create problems for new entrants. Mr
Konstantin Skorik, European Business Development Director – Freightliner Mr
Skorik stated that lots of regulation and control creates high complexity and
low efficiency. In the freight market there is generally reluctance by
manufacturers and operators to “experiment” and bring new innovative products
to the market. There are fundamental differences in complexity, timing and cost
of certification between locomotives and wagons with the later generally
certified to run on the entire continental network and the former problematic
due to different Member State requirements on safety and signalling systems, no
cross-acceptance, requirements for repetitive tests, unclear procedures and
obstructive NSAs and IMs. In part this is because processes are not transparent
with clear deadlines. ERTMS
costs may be prohibitively high and burden rail freight operators making them
less competitive against road. No clear strategy exists on who picks up these
bills. But success stories are possible as has been demonstrated by the
certification of new GE Powerhaul locomotive in the UK which was delivered in
less than two years through close cooperation between the parties involved
during the design and build phases. There
should be a single certification for rolling stock to the extent possible and a
clear role for ERA as a facilitator of cross-acceptance or as a one-stop shop
provided NSAs fully accept ERA rulings. NSAs should concentrate on national
(safety systems) issues. Clarity of the time limits for various stages of the
certification process must be made transparent. Both ERA and NSAs should be
incentivised to work fast and adhere to the interoperability rules. Mr
Michael Cramer - Member of the European Parliament (Greens-DE) Mr
Cramer stated that we need fair rather than unfair competition between modes of
transport and that a cross modal plan is required to start this process. Cross
acceptance of rolling stock must be beneficial and more efficient however a
more precise framework is required. The wider European agenda should be to lead
to the removal of EU regulations. We need a register of infrastructure so that
all bidders have transparent access to the necessary information. The
new Airbus plane cost € 1 million for acceptance worldwide before introduction,
whereas rolling stock costs in some cases twice that amount for acceptance in
just one country. Workshop
2 – The optimal Infrastructure Manager for the future (Moderator:
Mr Jean-Eric Paquet, Director, DG MOVE.B) Mr
Paquet introduced the panel of speakers and then invited Sian Prout from the
European Commission to present some initial thoughts on the implications of the
4th railway package and how it could lead to changes in the governance
relationship for IMs and RUs. The
two biggest problems identified in the governance of IMs related to efficiency
and equal access. Railway infrastructure is a natural monopoly and the current
governance arrangements do not provide sufficient incentives to respond
effectively to the needs of users. There are no incentives for European
cooperation with issues existing relating to path allocation, maintenance and
development and charging regimes. Efficiency can be improved by encouraging
appropriate cooperation between IM and RUs on an equal basis and ensuring the
IM has all the functions needed to run the infrastructure in an optimised,
efficient and non–discriminatory manner. The
existing separation requirements do not prevent conflicts of interests or
discriminatory behaviour possible from non-essential functions. Persistent risk
exits of cross-subsidisation without complete financial transparency. Therefore
the minimum appropriate degree of separation of the IM from RU's should be
defined to ensure that all IM activities which are potential sources of
conflicts of interest are subject to separation requirements, this may be
separation which guarantees at least legal, economic and financial independence
from RUs and sets as objective institutional independence. The
proposed approach for the creation of common rules for the governance structure
of IMs involves ensuring all RUs are on an equal footing including the setting
of economic incentives and performance indicators, promoting cooperation
between IMs, establishing a coordination body with IMs, RUs, customers, users
and public authorities to ensure the proper involvement of public authorities
and all users. Ms
Debora Serracchiani, Member of the European Parliament (S&D-IT) Ms
Debora Serracchiani explained that the trend in rail passenger transport usage
had risen slightly since 2000 with rail market share at around 6% and 10% in
freight. These low levels are proof of the need for improvement. Adequate
financing and charging for rail infrastructure, better conditions for
competition on the railway and new organisational reforms to ensure appropriate
supervision are required as was put forward in the Commission proposal of
September 2010. Despite
important elements of the recast ensuring greater competition between rail
operators and better supervision by an independent regulator to ensure fair
competition along with obligations on complaints handling, the primary goals
have not yet been achieved. The new rules should provide a solid basis for
financing of infrastructure contracts but it's up to Member States to guarantee
the appropriate levels. If
we want to create a single market in railways, non-discriminatory access to
rail infrastructure is essential. Member States must not use a one size fits
all excuse to preserve their current model. More encouragement should be
provided for freight transport across Europe to ensure competitiveness and
reliability when compared to road traffic. The goal is a system where a train
can access each station in Europe and circulate throughout the infrastructure
and hence investment in the interoperability of the network, and also in
rolling stock is required along with a real separation of the IM from the
operator to remove cases of discrimination which exist in many countries. The
conclusion of the Advocate General appears to be that the holding system is
compatible with the existing law. But imagine if in the aviation sector, each
domestic airline had to ask the permission of their counterparts in other
countries before being able to make any flights, the market would not be as
competitive as it is now. Therefore the Commission and the Parliament must now
act fast to achieve this goal. Mr
Hubert du Mesnil, President - EIM Mr
du Mesnil stated that a key role of separated IMs is to cooperate with their
neighbours to form the backbone of European transport, over and above strict
modal or national interests and is one of the main differences from those IMs
that remain structurally linked to their national carriers. Much
focus has been given to equal access to rail networks but this does not
guarantee good quality treatment. The efficiency and performance of our rail
systems needs to be addressed and transparency is a pre-requisite for
efficiency. The
optimal IM needs to adapt to the customer needs, it needs to be entirely above
suspicion and must stand above any conflict of interest as well as being safe
and efficient. This will create value for the whole system, including their
clients, users and for tax-payers through control over efficiencies on costs,
prices and capacity and be responsible for timetabling through to traffic
management. Mr
Garry White, Head of European and Strategic Affairs - Network Rail Mr
White spoke about how the 4th package should contain important proposals
intended to bring about full domestic liberalisation and that it should
consider the optimal role for the IM including the activities of bodies around
it such as regulators and ERA. Experience
from the UK showed that liberalisation opened up valuable opportunities for new
and existing operators, promoted new services and investment for passengers
creating a competitive market served by over 20 passenger operators, most
having won public tenders with no one controlling RU. A number of reports
demonstrating a positive correlation between liberalisation and competitiveness
and tendering of franchises have been produced. Liberalisation since the
mid-1990s has led to major growth in passenger demand (over a billion more
passengers each year now), good levels of safety, new levels of punctuality and
one of the highest levels of passenger satisfaction. A 5-year multi-annual
agreement of €43 billion of funding to the UK infrastructure exists with over
€10 billion for increased capacity and capability. The
challenge is to deliver the live railway network needed efficiently,
sustainably and transparently as noted in the McNulty study published last year
which recommended a wide range of change and reform (e.g. franchises were seen
as too short and prescriptive) to achieve potential efficiencies of around 30%
through evolution, but ruled out radical legislative change as disruptive and distracting.
Flexibility for industry to determine, under transparent and regulated
conditions, how independently to work together will benefit passengers, freight
users, and taxpayers who fund the industry. IMs
and RUs can deliver efficiencies through better alignment of incentives, higher
train utilisation, new technology, and stronger partnership working. Progress
is being made towards building these strong partnerships through ‘alliances’
which are co-operative partnerships at a local level, based on transparently
sharing information to create joint objectives with shared risk and reward
benefits. Alliances are two separate organisations not the creation of new
joint entities with both sides retaining legal, regulatory responsibility and
final decision making power if there is a disagreement. The
4th package should place the responsibility for levers of network and system
performance in the hands of the IM, freeing RUs to focus on short term
operational train performance driven largely by the life of their PSCs. As the
amount of tendering increases, the IMs become critical in taking a system-wide
long-term view, bringing together better use of infrastructure and ways of
maintaining it, investing in it, and balancing demand. Asset management, on a
whole-life system basis, requires the ability to determine how the railway is
maintained and renewed and how costs need to be controlled on behalf of
customers and funders. An
independent IM becomes a natural system integrator transparently providing
information to customers, coordinating research and development with suppliers,
leading to innovation for the benefit of the industry rather than any one
specific interest in a transparent, non-discriminatory and whole network
manner. Planning meetings already take place in the UK to coordinate its
priorities, innovations and making its planning of the network reflect
cross-industry requirements. Encouraging
the right behaviours and providing IMs with the tools and flexibility,
backed-up by effective and appropriate regulation should be the key to
achieving the Commission’s goals. Regulators with the right balance of powers
should be allies in opening fair and efficient markets that are properly funded
by Member States. Rather than re-inventing the wheel, the 4th package could
seek to support on-going work to improve access to the rail network and adopt
common approaches for example with a European Passport (although it may not be
necessary if not crossing borders). Overall
the challenge is clear. Europe needs a robust and clear legal framework for the
role of independent IM and to create a transparent system that unlocks
innovation and growth, drives investment, and grows the railway. Mr
Rafal Milczarski, Managing Director - Freightliner Poland Mr
Milczarski discussed the EC`s White Paper 2050 objectives of getting 30% of
road freight over 300 km to shift to other modes such as rail or waterborne
transport by 2030, and more than 50% by 2050. Given that current rail freight
modal share in WE countries is 13% and in CEE countries is 22%, we are a long
way from achieving these objectives. We
therefore need changes to the IMs current functions which are railway traffic
management and path allocation along with maintenance and development (this
could for instance be excluded and be financed by the state) of infrastructure. IMs
should be non-discriminatory, transparent, efficient and adequately financed.
There should be total separation of IM and transportation functions across
public infrastructure. Maintenance of rail and road infrastructure should be
financed by member states by equal proportions to eliminate modal
discrimination (current proportions in Poland are 70% in road and 30% in rail).
Rail share in EU cohesion fund spending should be at least 40% in the EU-15
member states and at least 50% in new member states in the period from
2014-2020. Railway investments are mostly for passenger transport and don't
focus enough on bottlenecks. Approval boards (operator`s representation) which
will make strategic decisions (maintenance and investments priorities, costs
level, access charges, etc.) should be established and empowered. Basic
loading and discharge infrastructure and sidings must be made available by
default by infrastructure owners. Access must no longer be restricted. Mr
Ludger Sippel - BAG-SPNV Mr
Sippel stated that rail authorities in various countries across Europe have
good experience of competitive tendering of regional services and have been
able to reduce the level of subsidies on rural, suburban and interregional lines
by up to 15%, 23% and 47% while also improving the level of quality
significantly. However infrastructure fees and costs for staff and energy are
increasing, while public budgets for financing non profitable services are
becoming tighter. Railway
infrastructure should be operated efficiently to provide the highest possible
capacity at the lowest possible cost with fees reflecting the costs necessary
for operating the infrastructure only. The infrastructure framework should
encourage competition between RUs. Infrastructure development should take
account of regional passenger requirements regarding capacity and availability
to improve the offer, attract additional passengers and maximise the use of
public budgets. Problems
exist linked to the operation of the infrastructure by integrated railway
companies. Station and infrastructure fees (which are not transparent and
include high overhead costs) paid by regional rail transport are too expensive
compared to the costs they incur to the IM. Some package deals have led to
overcompensated direct awards of PSCs and regional IMs may be more efficient
than the incumbent company in some circumstances. Infrastructure
development projects to improve regional rail transport are difficult to
initiate by passenger rail authorities, even if economically viable as often
the incumbent IM focusses on the needs of RUs within the incumbent holding. It
is necessary to fully unbundle RUs and IMs in order to solve the structural
problems of the integrated railway companies including transparency concerning
business target planning, cash-flow management, terms on internal funding,
financial flows across the group, cross subsidisation, domination and profit
transfer agreements and discrimination in the development of the infrastructure
based on incumbent RUs needs. Workshop
3 – Rail and the value for society (Moderator:
Mr Alain Flausch, Secretary General – UITP) Mr
Flausch introduced the panel of speakers and then invited Eddy Liégeois from
the European Commission to present some initial thoughts on the implications of
the 4th railway package and how it could lead to domestic rail market opening. Problems
of poor service quality and operational performance exist in the domestic rail
passenger transport market driven by low intra-rail competition, lack of
competitive pressure, inefficient use of public funds and a variety of national
approaches to the provision of access. The objective is to now improve the
competitiveness of rail by further developing the single European rail area to
open domestic rail passenger markets, getting better value for money spent on
public rail transport services and creating more uniform business conditions. Initial
thoughts suggest generalised open access with possibility to limit access when
"economic equilibrium" of public service contract is compromised
would be a sensible way to proceed along with mandatory tendering of public
service contracts. Member
States, competent authorities and RUs should also be encouraged to set up
integrated ticketing schemes at national level subject to non-discrimination
requirements and use existing provisions on transfer of staff if deemed
necessary. Mr
Philippe De Backer, Member of the European Parliament (ALDE-BE) Mr
De Backer explained that the perspectives of the 4th package (as was the recast
in the process of reforming the railway market) have already been heavily
discussed in the Transport committee. Improving
the level of service offered by RUs increases the attractiveness of
transporting goods and passengers by rail. Passengers often prefer the car
because rail transport has poor service, is not punctual and has limited inter
modal connection. For freight, cross border transport is made difficult by
Member States by different entry barriers, causing unreliability and delay so
customers choose road instead, despite congestion. A move away from the one
mode approach to focus on the multimodality for goods and passenger transport
is now required. Passengers
and clients should be the first priority of the IMs and RUs again by opening
all markets, separating RUs from IMs and being stricter on Member States so
they implement the existing European interoperability and safety rules. The
necessary European legislation on interoperability is already in place but
there is a gap between theory and practise. It is unacceptable that Member
States often create barriers to entry by making unreasonable demands for new
market entrants. National regulators need to take action. The ERA should be the
one stop shop that is needed to create a single market where national technical
and safety rules no longer exist, and where only European law applies. Opening
the market will give passengers more choice leading to better service quality
but needs to be accompanied by sufficient infrastructure financing and
establishment of a cross-modal level playing field. A European framework should
be established allowing robust RUs easier access to the open market. Such RUs
should have their own corporate governance and be able to pursue their own
Human Resource policy including regarding the transfer of workers from one
company to another. Member
States play a vital role in the financing of infrastructure, and should make
sure PSOs are in place and are efficient and effective, but should not
interfere with RUs. Legal separation between the IM and the RU is the best way
to create a level playing field with transparency, clarity and no more cross
subsidies, leading to more efficient railway companies requiring less state
funding. Freight
transport activity is projected to increase, with respect to 2005, by around
40% in 2030 and by over 80% by 2050. Passenger traffic would grow slightly less
at 34% by 2030 and 51% by 2050. To cope with this increase, actions are
necessary now such as high speed rail which is a sustainable alternative for
shorter flights. The
TEN-T network aim is to create a unified transport network, removing
bottlenecks, upgrading infrastructure and streamlining cross border transport
operations for passengers and businesses on an intermodal basis. Railways are
the backbone for these corridors. Mr
Christopher Irwin, Vice President - EPF Mr
Irwin stated that by 2050 the majority of medium distance passenger transport
should go by rail and over 50% of road freight should shift to other modes such
as rail and waterborne transport and demonstrated what this would mean in terms
of changes to modal shift in passenger kilometres and rail tonnage. Relative
consumer satisfaction with rail services in the EU is relatively poor with many
passengers considering rail travel a distress purchase rather than the mode of
choice. Consumer needs must be addressed using market opening and the advent of
competition as a driver, measuring satisfaction and monitoring outcomes and
considering end-to-end journey requirements. Public
transport and spatial planning must be considered to address congestion.
Investment in capacity needs to be enabled by providing dependable services
offering integrated seamless interfaces between modes. Users must be empowered
through effective information provision and beneficial market opening (TAP-TSI)
opportunities to facilitate collective transport inter-availability,
co-modality and through ticketing. The ERA should be reinforced to deliver
interoperability with appropriate authority and resources to tackle some of the
national duplication and reduce the cost base. Cost benefit analysis appraisals
should be used as the lodestar for interventions to ensure the correct
priorities are delivered. Mr
Michel Quidort, Director Institutional Relations - Veolia Transdev - EPTO Mr
Quidort explained that the development of a competitive market structure was
vital for the supply of public transport services and that his members (9
largest private public transport companies in Europe) support the opening of
the passenger transport markets for competition. Since
market liberalisation a number of countries have seen considerable benefits,
the UK (additional 450 million passenger journeys, 20 billion passenger
kilometres between 1987 and 2009), the Netherlands (20–50% gains through
competitive tendering efficiencies), Germany (28% increase in train kilometres,
26% reduction in subsidy paid, 43% increase in passengers, 500 kilometres of
re-opened lines and 300 re-opened and new stations), France (RhônExpress 55%
increase in passengers in 19 months), Sweden (20–30% subsidy reductions through
tendering and much higher customer satisfaction). Competition does not impact
safety and employment conditions are not an issue. In the UK, train drivers
appear to earn some 50,000 EUR per year, while in Germany the drivers of
private operators appear to earn 86-94% of the wages of DB, the German
incumbent. Sustainable working conditions are required with lean management,
empowerment, local responsibility and an ability to match the working time
needs of local employees. Competitive
awarding procedures must become standard to provide value for society. This
should be through a general obligation to tender for PSCs with a clear scope
and no impairment of open access to ensure no restriction of market
opportunities for new entrants. Direct award should remain an exception
restricted to specific situations for limited duration. Tenders should be
defined at local level and be coherent territorially and economically. Strong,
independent and properly resourced national regulatory authorities should be
maintained and co-ordinated through an EU network. Mr
Hans-Werner Franz, Managing Director - VBB Mr
Franz spoke about the social benefit of railways with a need to consider
improving the regional economy, environmental aspects and synergies through
networks. Competition for the regional and local rail market in Germany is
still dominated by DB Regio with 76% of the market even though 91% of awards
were made by competition. Where
competition exists benefits have included increases in patronage of up to 30%,
improvements in quality and customer satisfaction, lower prices (market entry
prices) and similar or reduced financing through cost reductions of 10-50%.
Contracts should be at least 8 years (maximum of 15) with gross incentive
contracts by taking risk preferred. Employment rises by competition by ensuring
social standards and improvements in quality through more staff. However there
is a potentially negative dynamic in the cost of open competition when compared
to functional tendering. Infrastructure
monopoly is a barrier to market entry. The dominating role of DB in nearly all
tending procedures creates a large distortion in the market. Interest in
vehicle financing is slowly on the increase again but most banks possess little
understanding of the SPNV market and therefore take a conservative approach
which plays to DB's advantages of being a federal enterprise and therefore
having strong credit-worthiness with more favourable credit conditions, plenty
of transport contracts, low residual-value risks and direct access to financial
markets. The
EU should improve interoperability, strengthen regulation and regional
responsibility for infrastructure and improve open access competition to markets. Mr
Tim Gilbert, President – EPTOLA Mr
Gilbert expressed the views of the European Passenger Train & Traction
Operating Lessors’ Association, representing the interests of (private) train
leasing companies that invest in and lease locomotives, passenger trains and
wagons across Europe. With
an asset life of typically 30 – 35 years, lessors are long-term investors in
the market who provide flexible access to rolling stock throughout the
competitive process. What the market really needs is clarity, consistency and
stability to allow continued growth. Mr
Ton Spaargaren – Gelderland province (NL) Mr
Spaargaren described how his province of Gelderland is able to grant
concessions for train services and the experiences of competitive tendering of
rail PSCs that have been gained. There
is a difference between liberalisation and market forces relating to Government
control of market forces through tendering concessions. This
debate took place in the Netherlands when it was decided that the Dutch Rail
Company should operate profitably. 32 train services (6 in the province of
Gelderland) didn’t fit the business case so decentralising to the region under
the precondition that these train services would be awarded by tendering took
place. The province vision relates to sustainable mobility that supports the
economy, prosperity and stimulates social integration. Decentralisation
contributed to this vision by placing more focus on passengers by developing
successful products for existing and new customers such as commuters, business
travellers, peak accessibility, schoolchildren, tourists and leisure shoppers. The
province invested about € 100 million during the last 10 years leading to an
increase in train kilometres of 26% and yet still there is a lot of complaining
about public transport which doesn’t help, instead innovative and surprising
solutions should be sought. The
tenders are not awarded exclusively on lowest price but are awarded to the most
economically- advantageous tender. They are net cost contracts, i.e.
responsibility for the industrial risk as well as the commercial risk is for
the operator. The higher the income, the higher the reward, the lower the
income, the more effort is needed by the operator. Criteria relating to the
concession include quality, sustainability, price, travel information and
marketing strategy. A
transport plan rather than a production plan is required with a creative
marketing implementation plan (backed by the RUs money) to deliver innovative
programmes for growth. The
management of the PSC is based on output criteria such as punctuality,
reliability or complaints. Both the Province of Gelderland and the Arnhem
Nijmegen city region have awarded intermodal concessions for train services
that serve the same route. Agreements have been reached between the contracting
bodies about cooperation in relation to passengers on product development, safety,
marketing and fare offers, facilities including social safety and priority for
solving bottlenecks. The As
the market becomes more dynamic, customers become more demanding and
performance levels as well as quality increase. Cultural change relating to attitude
and skills is required such as being decisive, using initiative, passion,
perseverance, optimism rather than pessimism, market focus and willing to
invest. An
intermodal public transport network is desirable with the train as the back
bone and bus transport feeding in (easier if trains and busses are in the in
the hand of one single operator) at transfer points such as Park and Ride
facilities. Plenary
III: Presentation of Workshop findings (Moderator:
Mr Keir Fitch, Deputy Head of the Cabinet of Vice-President Kallas - European
Commission) Mr
Fitch stated that having been in a number of the workshops it seemed clear that
there was a desire to get the structure of the railway right once and for all.
An interactive and competitive railway across all of Europe was in the best
interests of everybody. Interoperability is vital to allow innovation through
liberalisation and a level playing field is a pre-requisite for encouraging new
market entrants. Mr
Fitch thanked all the delegates for their involvement in the workshop sessions
and introduced the moderators who would summarise the key points debated in
each session. Mr
Verslype summarised the discussion that took place in Workshop 1 on the
proposals for a European passport for rolling stock approvals. Lots of
questions had been raised and in particular 5 key points had come out of the
lively debate that ensued. Firstly
there was an essential need for immediate action to prepare for the target
vision of a single certificate, but also specific attention must be given in
the short term to the better implementation of the current regime. Secondly
there was general agreement from all participants on the reinforced role of ERA
but different possible solutions such as a one-stop-shop, partnership with NSAs
or ERA as single authorising body. Thirdly the current legislation is generally
considered sufficient by all participants (only one dissenting voice) and
therefore should be "tweaked" rather than completely
"re-written". Fourthly
an appeal body and procedure to settle conflicts regarding vehicle
authorisation is required with appropriate responsibility ensured and fifthly
the transparency of rules and processes should be improved and monitored. Finally
it was noted that there is a genuine enthusiasm in defending a Commission
proposal which does not exist yet and indeed some participants lobbied for even
more ambition and faster delivery. Mr
Paquet summarised the discussion that took place in Workshop 2 on the
governance proposals for IMs. The debate had been lively with a healthy number
of participants and the structural debate on bundling / unbundling was the most
contentious of the issues discussed. A
broad consensus was agreed on the needs of a better governance relationship for
optimal IM containing efficiency drivers. How
the IM relates to market signals and all RUs was discussed, as was whether
incumbents are better placed to bring forward operational efficiencies.
Arguments were raised about equality, impartiality and the vital need for a
level playing field. In this respect it is difficult to foresee how one RU in
the shape of the incumbent, can make fair decisions on others. The
EC now needs to make a proposal ensuring stability for the medium to longer
term bearing in mind the dynamics of the potential tensions between equality
and efficiency. Mr
Flausch summarised the discussion that took place in Workshop 3 on improving
the competitiveness of rail and further development of the Single European Rail
Area which involved mainly representatives from the UK, Netherlands and
Germany, all of whom were broadly in favour. SNCF highlighted that backtracking
took place when attempting to deregulate the US rail market and that it should
not be forgotten that rail is a capital intensive industry. Where RUs have
invested important sums on money in railway infrastructure they should be
rewarded. Domestic
regional and local rail accounts for 90% of the market and as such changes to
elements such as through ticketing to allow a doubling of ridership by 2025.
High quality efficient transport is required from a sustainability viewpoint
and a move to mandatory tendering of contracts with some open access provision
would provide improved value through a reduction in public subsidies and
benefits through improvements in service quality, infrastructure use and
patronage. Tendering
should not only be dependent on price, otherwise if operators fail to make
significant money by overbidding, loss-leading , or failing to deliver their
initiatives, the market disappears with all other players and contracting
authorities losing value. Barriers to proposed cross-border tenders should be
removed. There
is a need to kill off some of the iconic myths such as social dumping or safety
issues in liberalised markets as these are simply untrue. Access
to rolling stock is vital for market entry as is the need for consistency and
clarity of regulations and stability in the marketplace. In addition the rules
that already exist must be implemented. Integrated ticketing and workforce
integration could lead to increased productivity. Plenary
IV: Presentation of the Eurobarometer survey and Conclusions of the Conference Mr
Matthias Ruete, Director-General - European Commission, DG MOVE Mr
Ruete thanked all the speakers and participants who shared their important
thoughts and contributions on the Fourth Railway Package throughout the day. He
introduced Olivier Coppens who presented some high level findings from the
Eurobarometer survey which had been conducted across 25 Member States (EU27
except Cyprus and Malta) through approximately 26000 (around 1000 per
country) face-to-face interviews in the respondent’s homes. The
survey was designed to assess satisfaction with rail, attitudes towards
competition in railways and the effects of competition. 46% of respondents were
satisfied with the national and regional rail systems in their countries, with
36% unsatisfied. However significant variation exists between individual
countries ranging between 67% and 18%. 71% of Europeans supports more
competition, with only 21% opposing. Again variations exist between individual
countries ranging from 90% to 46%. However the overarching support is
consistent across regular and occasional users. The
most important factors that could encourage Europeans to use the train are lower
prices (43% of all respondents), better network with more routes and stations,
more frequent and faster journeys, more reliable services and better rolling
stock. Respondents believe for all these areas and for the safety of the
railway network (which showed the highest variation of 76% to 21% between
countries) that more competition in the rail market in their country will have
a positive effect. There is also a very strong belief that more competition
would lead to more innovative ways of buying tickets. 49%
of respondents felt that public funding of the rail sector will increase or
remain the same if there is more competition in the rail market whereas 34%
believe it will decrease. The full survey is now available at
http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/ebs/ebs_388_en.pdf Mr
Ruete then summarised the three key workshop issues discussed; reducing the
time of placing new rolling stock in the market; optimal IM for the future; and
the value of public services by rail for society, will be properly addressed
following a robust impact assessment and in-depth stakeholders’ consultation. The
consultation has now concluded with questionnaires sent to more than 400
interested parties, several workshops organised involving the main market
players and the European associations. A high level outline of the
Eurobarometer passengers’ survey across the EU with more than 25,000
respondents was presented earlier. All of these along with the conclusions of
this conference will be considered when finalising the legislative proposals. Despite
its comparative advantages versus road, rail is not considered reliable enough,
flexible enough, innovative enough and affordable enough. There is evidently a
problem of efficiency which needs to be addressed. All stakeholders appear to
realise that current regulatory arrangements are not optimal. Long and costly
procedures and discriminatory access barriers have caused a lack of new market
entrants across many Member States. Stakeholders
also seem to agree that a new concept of a single vehicle "passport"
valid in all Member States issued by the European Railway Agency (in
conjunction with national safety authorities) would improve efficiency. The ERA
may also be tasked with the facilitation of the deployment of ERTMS,
strengthened communication, improved economic evaluation and cost-benefit
analysis, and an enhanced role in international relations and research. Further
improvement of non-discriminatory access to rail infrastructure through
clarifying the relations between IMs and RUs (unbundling) are required to
create the Single European Rail Area. We are finalising proposals for a
regulatory framework for the market opening of domestic rail passenger services
covering open access services and rail transport under public service contracts
as well as their mutual co-ordination. The
costs savings from public tendering for competent transport authorities have
been in the order of between 20% and 30% in the countries that have opened
their doors to competition. Taxpayers expect that rail infrastructure usage
will be optimised rather than restricted to the benefit of specific commercial
interests for historical reasons. The
discussions at the workshop made it also clear that domestic market opening
requires integrating ticketing schemes and access to rolling stock to enable
new RUs to participate in tender procedures. At
this stage, the Commission is listening to all ideas from all parties and has
not yet adopted its own position. Once the various options are examined, we
will publish our impact analysis.
ANNEX IX
GLOSSARY &
ACRONYMS
The
following definitions are based on existing EU law but do not have any legal
value and only aim to provide a simplified explanation of the concepts used in
the impact assessment and its annexes. These definitions only serve for the
impact assessment. 'railway
undertaking' means any public or private undertaking licensed according
to EU law, the principal business of which is to provide services for the
transport of goods and/or passengers by rail with a requirement that the
undertaking ensure traction; this also includes undertakings which provide
traction only; 'infrastructure
manager' means
any body or firm responsible in particular for establishing, managing and
maintaining railway infrastructure, including traffic management and control‑command
and signalling; the functions of the infrastructure manager on a network or
part of a network may be allocated to different bodies or firms; 'infrastructure
users'
means a railway undertaking or an international grouping of railway
undertakings or other persons or legal entities, such as competent authorities
under Regulation (EC) No 1370/2007 and shippers, freight forwarders and
combined transport operators, with a public-service or commercial interest in
procuring infrastructure capacity; 'railway
infrastructure' means an area comprising railway ground area, tracks and
track bed (including inter alia embankments, goods platforms, passenger platforms,
crossings), engineering structures (covering inter alia bridges, tunnels,
underpasses), level crossings, superstructure (covering inter alia rails
sleepers, traversers), access ways for passengers and goods), safety
installations, signalling installations, telecommunication installations,
lighting installations, catenaries, contact wires and buildings used by the
infrastructure department. 'infrastructure
capacity'
means the potential to schedule train paths requested for an element of
infrastructure for a certain period; 'network'
means
the entire railway infrastructure managed by an infrastructure manager; 'train
path allocation ' means the allocation by an infrastructure
manager of the infrastructure capacity needed to run a train between two places
over a given period; 'operator
of service facility' means any public or private entity responsible
for managing one or more service facilities or supplying one or more services
to railway undertakings; List
of acronyms ARAF Autorité
de Régulation des Activités Ferroviaires ARF Association
des Régions de France (French Regions' Association) CEF Connecting
Europe Facility CER Community
of European Railway and Infrastructure Companies CLECAT European
association for forwarding, transport, logistics and customs services DB Deutsche
Bahn AG (German railways) DG
CLIMA Directorate-General for Climate Action DG
COMP Directorate-General for Competition DG
ECFIN Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs DG
ELARG Directorate General for Enlargement DG
EMPL Directorate-General for Employment, Social Affairs & Inclusion DG
ENER Directorate-General for Energy DG
ENTR Directorate-General for Enterprise and Industry DG
ENV Directorate-General for Environment DG
MARKT Directorate-General for Internal Market DG
MOVE Directorate-General for Mobility and Transport DG
REGIO Directorate-General for Regional Policy DG
SANCO Directorate General for Health & Consumers DG
TRADE Directorate General for Trade DGCCRF Direction
Générale de la Concurrence, de la Consommation et de la Répression des Fraudes ECJ European
Court of Justice EEAS European
External Action Service EEIG European
Economic Interest Grouping EIM European
Rail Infrastructure Managers EPF European
Passenger's Federation EPTO European
Passenger Transport Operators EPTOLA European
Passenger Train & Traction Operating Lessors’ Association ERA European
Railway Agency ERFA European
Rail Freight Association ERTMS European
Rail Traffic Management System ETCS European
Train Control System ETF European
Transport Workers' Federation EU European
Union FIF Fédération
des Industries Ferroviaires FNAUT Fédération
Nationale des Associations d'Usagers des Transports FS Ferrovie
dello Stato GHG Greenhouse
gas IA Impact
Assessment IASG Impact
Assessment Steering Group ICA Italian
Competition Authority IM Infrastructure
manager LS Legal
Service NS Nederlandse
Spoorwegen (Netherland Railways) NSA National
Safety Authority NTV Nuovo
Trasporto Viaggiatori OBB Austran
railways OECD Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development PPP Public-Private
Partnership PSC Public
service contract PSO public
service obligations PZB Punktförmige
Zugbeeinflussung RFF Réseau
Ferré de France (French Railway Network) RFI Rete
Ferroviaria Italiana RMMS Rail
Market Monitoring Scheme RNE RailNetEurope RU Railway
undertaking SG General
Secretariat SMEs Small
and medium enterprises SNCB Belgian
railways SNCF Société
Nationale des Chemins de fer Français (National Community of French Railways) TAP-TSI Telematics
Applications for Passenger Services Technical Specifications for
Interoperability TEN-T Trans-European
Transport Network TFEU Treaty
on the Functioning of the European Union UIC International
Union of Railways UITP International
Association of Public Transport UK the
United Kingdom [1] White Paper Roadmap
to a Single European Transport Area – Towards a competitive and resource
efficient transport system (COM/2011/0144 final) [2] http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/127599.pdf [3] COM (2012) 299
final [4] COM(2012) 259 final [5] Communication from
the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic
and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions “A Budget for Europe
2020”, 29.6.2011, COM(2011)500 Final. [6] Frequently asked
questions on the recast of the first railway package. European Commission, http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/12/520&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en [7] List of
abbreviations with explanations is provided in Annex IX. [8] Cyprus and Malta
have no rail system. [9] [reference to be
added (unknown, text adopted by Council on 29 October and published in OJ in
December)] [10] Steer Davies Gleave
(2012): "Study on further action at European level regarding market
opening for domestic passenger transport and ensuring non-discriminatory access
to rail infrastructure and services" (further referenced as IA support
study) [11] A natural
monopoly is a type of monopoly that may arise when there are extremely
high fixed costs such as exist when large-scale infrastructure is required to
ensure supply. These costs are also sunk costs, and they deter entry and exit. [12] integrated structure'
means an entity being in charge of both transport operations and infrastructure
management. [13] OJ L 237, 24. 8.1991, p. 25. [14] OJ L 075 , 15.3.2001, p. 1. [15] OJ L 75, 15.3.2001,
p. 29. [16] COM
(2010) 474 final. [17] EVERIS (2010)
"Study on Regulatory Options on Further Market Opening in Rail Passenger
Transport", p.55).
http://ec.europa.eu/transport/modes/rail/studies/doc/2010_09_09_study_on_regulatory_options_on_further_market_opening_in_rail_passenger_transport.pdf; [18] Cf. EIM Working
Paper on the 4th railway package adopted on 26 October 2012. [19] Realising the
Potential of GB Rail, Report of the Rail Value for Money Study, May 2011,
http://assets.dft.gov.uk/publications/report-of-the-rail-vfm-study/realising-the-potential-of-gb-rail-summary.pdf [20] http://www.developpement-durable.gouv.fr/-Assises-du-ferroviaire-.html [21] There are still more than twenty different
signalling systems coexisting in Europe. These systems, generally developed on
the scale of a national network, which are very heterogeneous as regards
performance and the level of safety. The European Rail Traffic Management
System (ERTMS) constitutes a major European industrial standard that enables
trains to cross national borders and enhances safety. [22] SWD (2012) 246
final. [23] Absolute decline between 2008 and
2009 can be at least partly attributed to the impact of the economic crisis on
the transport sector in general. However such a negative trend is faster than
the one observed during the same period in other transport modes. [24] Regulation 913/2010
concerning European railway network for competitive freight [25] Report from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and
Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions on the implementation of the
first railway package, COM(2006)189 [26] This risk was also
highlighted during the stakeholder hearing [27] Account separation
is the first level of separation introduced by Directive 91/440/EC requiring
the publication of separate regulatory accounts for the infrastructure activity
and the rail transport activities. [28] See e.g. Decision of
the French Regulator ARAF No 2012-016 of 11 July 2012, para. II.33 where it is
said that the regulatory body did not have access to and was not able to find
out about the precise data on investment volumes and priorities of the part of
SNCF which is operating railway stations. [29] See case related in
judgment of highest German administrative court Bundesverwaltungsgericht,
BVerwG 6 C 39.10 – judgment of 7 December 2011 [30] See report of Monopolkommission, http://www.monopolkommission.de/sg_60/s60_volltext.pdf,, page 55, Fn. 69. On the profit transfer agreements see [31] On the profit transfer agreements and their consequences
see e;g. article in http://www.wiwo.de/unternehmen/dienstleister/deutsche-bahn-gewinne-aus-infrastruktur-verdoppeln/6146542.html, and in the printed version of Wirtschaftswoche 6.2.2012, page 54,
page 12. [32] Examples taken from a press
release of Mofair, a competitors organisation, of 3.9.2012, http://www.mofair.de/db/news/meldung_13033.html [33] Communication from
the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic
and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions COM(2011) 206/4. [34] Booz Allen Hamilton (2006),
Privatisierungsvarianten der Deutschen Bahn AG "mit und ohne Netz"
(PRIMON), Berlin. [35] Sanchez P., Monsalvez
J., Martinez L. (2008), Vertical and Horizontal Separation in the European
Railway Sector, Bilbao. [36] Public support includes grants provided by local authorities
competent for the award of public service contracts, called public transport
executives (PTE). [37] Impact Assessment
accompanying the White Paper (SEC(2011)358) [38] World Bank
Report—Connecting to Compete 2010 Trade Logistics in the Global Economy -The
Logistical Performance Index and its Indicators [39] Noise Pollution
Emitted by Transportation Systems, Dr. Jean-Paul Rodrigue 2009 [40] SDG support study. [41] C.f. also Appendix I
'Impact assessment' of the IA support study by SDG [42] As foreseen by
Scenario 3 of IA Governance IA. [43] http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/127599.pdf [44] COM (2012) 299
final. [45] COM(2012) 259 final [46] The intention is to
add this (identical) background Annex to each of the 3 rail package IAs. [47] http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/flash/fl_326_en.pdf [48] http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/consumer_research/cms_en.htm [49] http://ec.europa.eu/transport/rail/studies/doc/2010_09_09_study_on_regulatory_options_on_furt
her_market_opening_in_rail_passenger_transport.pdf [50] 27 out of the 40
largest intra-EU air routes in the EU were within the reach of competing long-distance
(high-speed) railway services and yet attracted some 50 million passengers a
year - i.e. as much as the 4th largest EU airport, Madrid-Barajas. [51] Directive
2004/51/EC, amending Council Directive 91/440/EEC. [52] Council Directive
91/440/EEC, as amended inter alia by Directive 2007/58/EC. [53] Some Member States,
such as United Kingdom, Germany, Sweden or Italy, have unilaterally opened
their domestic markets. [54] Regulation (EC) No
1370/2007 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 October 2007
on public passenger transport services by rail and by road and repealing
Council Regulations (EEC) Nos 1191/69 and 1107/70 [55] Directive 2008/57/EC
of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17 June 2008 on the
interoperability of the rail system within the Community (Recast) [56] Directive 2004/49/EC of the European Parliament and
of the Council of 29 April 2004on safety on the Community's railways (Railway
Safety Directive). [57] Regulation (EC) No
1335/2008 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 16 December 2008
amending Regulation (EC) No 881/2004 establishing a European Railway Agency
(Agency Regulation) [58] Proposal for a
Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the Connecting Europe Facility, COM(2011)
665 final – 2011/0302 (COD) [59] Proposal
for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on union
guidelines for the development of the Trans-European
Transport network, COM/2011/0650 final/2 - 2011/0294 (COD). [60] As the result of the
changes induced by the Technical Specifications for Interoperability (TSIs)
decision. [61] The 99 respondents reported 172
different industry roles: - 38 described
themselves as having a single role - 35 described
themselves as having more than one role -
26
described their role as “other” [62] See article in "Die
Presse", 4.6.2011, http://diepresse.com/home/wirtschaft/economist/kordiconomy/667572/ [63] This results from Article 7(5) of
the PSO contract concluded between SchIG and ÖBB Personenverkehr of February
2011, as mentioned in a parliamentary question of MP Deimek, Vilimski and
others, http://www.parlament.gv.at/PAKT/VHG/XXIV/J/J_09274/fnameorig_230429.html [64] http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Trassenpreissystem#cite_note-eri-2003-278-9 [65] http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Trassenpreissystem#cite_note-eri-2010-210-28;
Annual report of BNetzA for 2010, page 63, http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/BNetzA/Presse/Berichte/2011/TaetigkeitsberichtBahn2010pdf.pdf?__blob=publicationFile [66] See press release of Mofair, a competitors organisation,
of 9.11.2012 http://www.mofair.de/db/bahnpol/meldung_13345.html [67] See Bahnbrief of DB of February 2010, page 6; http://www.deutschebahn.com/file/2194792/data/bahnbrief_februar_2010.pdf [68] See for this case
Wirtschaftswoche, 9.4.2010, http://www.wiwo.de/unternehmen/bahn-konkurrenz-ein-schwarzer-tag-fuer-bahnreisende-seite-all/5635928-all.html [69] See annual report of the German Regulator, BNetzA,
Jahresbericht 2010, page 209/210; http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/BNetzA/Presse/Berichte/2011/Jahresbericht2010pdf.pdf?__blob=publicationFile [70] Süddeutsche Zeitung 10.4.2010, http://www.sueddeutsche.de/wirtschaft/deutsche-bahn-konkurrenten-geben-auf-1.14209 [71] See special report of the German Monopoly Commission
"Sondergutachten 60 der Monopolkommission, Bahn 2011: Wettbewerbspolitik
unter Zugzwang", pp. 105 – 106, pp. 106 – 109, pp. 112 – 113, pp. 114 –
122
http://www.monopolkommission.de/sg_60/s60_volltext.pdf [72] Case C-136/11
Westbahn-Management GmbH v ÖBB-Infrastruktur AG [73] See MOFAIR's press release of
21 September 2012 "Eisenbahnregulierungsgesetz
hilft der Deutschen Bahn und nicht dem Wettbewerb" [74] See article in
"La Vie du Rail International", 3/12/2008, pages 52-55. [75] See competitors' report of 2009,
page 132, http://mofair.de/content/20090707_wettbewerber-report-eisenbahn.pdf [76] See Sondergutachten 60 der Monopolkommission, Bahn 2011:
Wettbewerbspolitik unter Zugzwang, page 179; http://www.monopolkommission.de/sg_60/s60_volltext.pdf,
point 179. [77] See Report point 182. [78] See annual report of the Austrian regulator for 2011,
http://www.schienencontrol.gv.at/files/schienen-control_taetigkeitsbericht-2011.pdf [79] See annual report of the German Regulator
Bundesnetzagentur Jahresbericht 2011, page 208, http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/BNetzA/Presse/Berichte/2011/Jahresbericht2010pdf.pdf?__blob=publicationFile [80] See competition report of competitor association Mofair, http://mofair.de/content/20090707_wettbewerber-report-eisenbahn.pdf, page 142,
and Activity Report of BNetzA for 2010, page 65, http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/BNetzA/Presse/Berichte/2011/TaetigkeitsberichtBahn2010pdf.pdf?__blob=publicationFile.
According to the Mofair Report, several instances of jurisdiction were dealing
with the system (Landgericht and Oberlandesgericht Frankfurt) [81] See decision of regulator ARAF of 3.5.2011, http://www.regulation-ferroviaire.fr/index.asp?a=10758&n=2&b=3 [82] See opinion of Dutch regulator NMa from 17.6.2010, http://www.nma.nl/images/Zienswijze_NMa_OCCR_OV22-157933.pdf [83] Report from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and
Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions on the implementation of the
first railway package, COM(2006)189 [84] IA support study. [85] It is likely that only costs incurred in
1994-95 are relevant to the calculation, since those in 1995-96 were heavily
driven by the legal and financial activity underpinning flotation of Railtrack
and procurement of the various train operating franchises. [86] Project fiche
CZ01-03-01, December 2000. [87] Report from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and
Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions on the implementation of the
first railway package, COM(2006)189 [88] National
Bank of Belgium Working Paper Document No 221 (2012). [89] Cf. Appendix K
‘Country fiches’ of the IA support study. [90] As foreseen by
Scenario 3 of IA Governance IA. [91] A public agency
always knows better the cost structure of its services than the public
authority that controls it.