This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52013SC0125
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT In-depth review for the UNITED KINGDOM in accordance with Article 5 of Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances Accompanying the document COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL AND TO THE EUROGROUP Results of in-depth reviews under Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT In-depth review for the UNITED KINGDOM in accordance with Article 5 of Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances Accompanying the document COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL AND TO THE EUROGROUP Results of in-depth reviews under Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT In-depth review for the UNITED KINGDOM in accordance with Article 5 of Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances Accompanying the document COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL AND TO THE EUROGROUP Results of in-depth reviews under Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances
/* SWD/2013/0125 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT In-depth review for the UNITED KINGDOM in accordance with Article 5 of Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances Accompanying the document COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL AND TO THE EUROGROUP Results of in-depth reviews under Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances /* SWD/2013/0125 final */
Contents Executive summary and conclusions................................................................... 3 1........... Introduction........................................................................................................ 6 2........... Macroeconomic situation and potential imbalances.................. 7 2.1........ Macroeconomic
scene setter........................................................................................... 7 2.2........ Competitiveness
and export performance........................................................................ 8 2.3........ Sustainability
of external positions.................................................................................. 12 2.4........ Government
indebtedness............................................................................................. 12 2.5........ Private
sector indebtedness........................................................................................... 14 3........... In-depth analysis of selected topics..................................................... 19 3.1........ External
competitiveness............................................................................................... 19 3.1.1..... Developments
in external competitiveness...................................................................... 20 3.1.2..... Characteristics
of the UK trading sector........................................................................ 26 3.1.3..... Structural
challenges..................................................................................................... 32 3.1.4..... Conclusions.................................................................................................................. 37 3.2........ Private
debt, deleveraging and growth........................................................................... 39 3.2.1..... Corporate
debt and access to finance............................................................................ 39 3.2.2..... Housing
policy and household debt............................................................................... 45 3.2.3..... What
risks do private debt dynamics and servicing costs pose to stability and
growth? .. 54 3.2.4..... Conclusions
................................................................................................................. 59 4........... Policy challenges............................................................................................ 60 references.......................................................................................................................... 63 Executive
summary and conclusions In May 2012, the
Commission concluded that the UK was experiencing macroeconomic imbalances, in
particular as regards developments related to household debt, the housing
market and, to some extent, external competitiveness. In the Alert Mechanism
Report (AMR) published on 28 November 2012, the Commission found it useful,
also taking into account the identification of an imbalance in May, to examine
further the persistence of imbalances or their unwinding. To this end this
In-Depth Review (IDR) takes a broad view of the UK economy in line with the
scope of the surveillance under the Macroeconomic Imbalances Procedure (MIP).
The main observations and findings from this analysis are: ·
The
challenges identified in the 2012 IDR, namely the high levels of household debt
and the deterioration in external competitiveness, remain valid. As such, the
2013 edition of the IDR revisits these themes, while expanding and going deeper
into selected aspects, including the dynamics of private debt, both household
and corporate. In the short term the macroeconomic imbalances that the UK is
experiencing pose a more immediate threat to growth than to stability, but if
not addressed they could store up future risks to macroeconomic stability and
to the financial sector. ·
As
regards external competitiveness, the UK experienced a large drop in export
market shares from 2007 to 2010. The trade balance has been negative since
1997, mainly as the result of a chronic deficit in goods trade. Nevertheless, export
volumes have been a modest net driver of growth in the UK economy in the crisis
period. Exports were 3.3% higher in 2011 than 2007, while total GDP remained
below its pre-crisis peak. External performance in 2012 was worse than anticipated,
although the current account is expected to continue to move towards a more
balanced position in the medium term. The deterioration in the
UK's current account balance in 2012 was mainly due to weaknesses in external
demand and foreign income, in particular from European countries, unfavourable
developments in oil trade, and buoyant imports despite the economic recession. The
effects of the depreciation of sterling in 2008 seem to have passed through
whilst providing only a modest boost to the trade balance, and to make
sustained improvements the UK needs to confront structural challenges in the
areas of transport infrastructure, skills and access to finance. The UK faces
the twin challenges of sustaining the pre-crisis dynamism in service exports
and boosting the underlying drivers of productivity in the industrial sectors
in order to regain the external competitiveness that was partly eroded in the
pre-crisis years. As regards trade in services, the UK has maintained a
significant surplus for several decades, which continues to sustain the current
account despite the negative effects of the global financial and economic
crisis on the financial and professional services cluster. As regards trade in
goods, the balance has been in a persistent deficit since the early 1980s and
productivity levels in the manufacturing sector have fallen behind those of
other highly-advanced economies. ·
Household
debt is currently falling, largely due to low levels of new mortgage lending,
but is likely to remain at a high level. Low interest rates and forbearance
mask risks associated with a minority of over-indebted households. The level of
household debt, which is mainly in the form of mortgages, decreased slightly in
2011 to 96% of GDP. Both residential construction and new mortgage lending
remain low, and continue to be affected by a weak domestic economy,
deleveraging pressures and policy constraints. Despite falling by 17% in real
terms since 2008, UK house prices remain high relative to incomes, supported by
a shortage of housing supply. The government has put in place a number of
regulatory and fiscal measures aimed at increasing residential construction,
but it is not yet clear how effective these will be in boosting the supply of
housing. Total mortgage servicing costs have been reduced by low interest rates
and a high share of variable-rate debt. However, this hides a significant
minority of very highly indebted households. As a consequence of a combination
of high house prices and the widespread and growing use of variable-rate
mortgages, households are particularly exposed to interest rate changes, as
well as to rises in unemployment. A sharp fall in house prices remains a
possibility, but household debt is likely to pick up again in the medium term,
as housing transactions return to more normal levels, unless real progress is
made in addressing housing supply shortages. The private rental market has
grown in recent years as more households have been priced out of home
ownership, but renting is still not seen by most tenants as a desirable long
term option. ·
The
stock of UK corporate debt is moderately high and there are signs of
less-than-viable companies being kept in business through low interest rates
and bank forbearance, while other firms are having difficulty accessing adequate
funding for investment. Many corporations have accumulated significant
surpluses in recent years and have built strong balance sheets, but there is a
divergent picture across sectors and firms. Evidence suggests that a number of
companies continue operating despite having little prospect of paying off their
stock of debt. This can store up risks to financial stability and prevent
credit from being reallocated to more dynamic and productive sectors of the
economy. A fine balance has to be struck in order to reconcile the longer term
benefits of "creative destruction", and the shorter term advantages
of low insolvency rates supporting employment in a weak domestic economy. Firms
in sectors such as construction and real estate, and many SMEs, suffer from
debt overhang or are experiencing difficulty in obtaining credit to finance
investment. Overall public investment remains low and it is not clear when and
to what extent private investment will pick-up. On current policies, the flow
of credit may only be normalised once broader macroeconomic conditions improve. ·
The
government deficit, although decreasing, remains elevated while government debt
is high and increasing. The UK is currently subject to the Excessive
Deficit Procedure of the Stability and Growth Pact and to the Council
recommendations which frame the adjustment to be undertaken. The government is
implementing a fiscal consolidation programme and plan to continue it until the
financial year 2017-18, after having extended it by one year in the Autumn
Statement. These developments will be discussed in detail in the European
Commission's assessment of the UK Convergence Programme, as part of the
European Semester in May 2013. The IDR also discusses
the policy challenges stemming from these developments and possible policy
responses. A number of elements can be considered: ·
As
regards the challenge of increasing external competitiveness, many of the
drivers of the UK's persistent trade deficit relate to structural weaknesses
that disproportionately impact upon capital-intensive sectors and goods'
producers. Firstly, the competitiveness of the UK economy could be boosted by
addressing shortages in airport and seaport capacity, by tackling road
congestion and by upgrading the rail network. This would entail meeting the
substantial transport infrastructure investment needs indicated in the National
Infrastructure Plan 2011, much of which is currently unfunded, by identifying
additional sources of funding, addressing high unit costs in transport, and
removing regulatory barriers to investment. Secondly, industrial producers
require a labour force with the correct advanced and intermediate technical
skills, an area where evidence suggests that gaps and recruitment difficulties
persist. Ensuring that the National Apprenticeship Programme effectively equips
participants with the professional and technical skills demanded by the
tradable sectors of the economy can contribute to closing the skills gap and
fostering export performance. Finally, access to finance is crucial for UK
firms seeking to enter, or expand in, exporting sectors. Difficulties in
accessing finance are a cross-cutting problem at the current juncture,
particularly for smaller and younger companies. It is important that they be
addressed at an economy-wide level as well as through specific financing instruments
for exporting companies. ·
Concerning
the challenge linked to deleveraging, maintaining financial stability and
avoiding unduly compromising investment and growth, policy needs to carefully
balance a pressing need for new lending to support investment with a long term
need for macroeconomic and financial stability. In the short term, loose
monetary policy is appropriate in a context of weak domestic and external
demand, but this should not be at the cost of allowing existing imbalances to
remain unresolved indefinitely. The government's focus on broader actions to
improve access to finance are also appropriate given that credit constraints
are contributing to low investment and weak growth. To maximise the impact of
the Funding for Lending Scheme and other access to finance policies they need
to focus as far as possible on supporting an increase in productive investment
rather than bidding up the price of existing assets. Action to address the
problems of companies with limited prospects of paying back their outstanding
debts and hidden risks in bank balance sheets – namely through higher levels of
provisioning by banks and, possibly, further company debt restructurings – could
both deal with risks to the stability of the financial system and support the
reallocation of resources through investment in more productive firms and
sectors. Alleviating the housing shortage over the medium term would reduce the
risk of imbalances related to persistently high house prices and household debt.
This could be aided by further liberalising spatial planning laws, ensuring the
planning system operates efficiently, and partially relaxing green belt
restrictions. Moving toward flat rate property or land taxes could be a
relatively efficient way of raising additional revenue and improving the
functioning of the land market. Making long-term private renting more
attractive by giving more security to tenants and fostering a professionalisation
of the sector could enhance the welfare of households who rent and help reduce
the pressure on households to take on high levels of mortgage debt. 1. Introduction On 28
November 2012, the European Commission presented its second Alert Mechanism
Report (AMR), prepared in accordance with Article 3 of Regulation (EU) No. 1176/2011
on the prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances. The AMR serves as
an initial screening device helping to identify Member States that warrant
further in-depth analysis to determine whether imbalances exist or risk
emerging. According to Article 5 of Regulation No. 1176/2011, these
country-specific in-depth reviews (IDR) should examine the nature, origin and
severity of macroeconomic developments in the Member State concerned, which
constitute, or could lead to, imbalances. On the basis of this analysis, the
Commission will establish whether it considers that an imbalance exists and
what type of follow-up it will recommend to the Council. This is the second IDR
for the UK. The previous IDR was published on 30 May 2012 on the basis of which
the Commission concluded that the UK was experiencing macroeconomic imbalances,
in particular as regards developments related to external competitiveness, household
indebtedness and the housing market. Overall, in the AMR-2013 the Commission
found it useful, also taking into account the identification of an imbalance in
May, to examine further the persistence of imbalances or their unwinding. To
this end this IDR takes a broad view of the UK economy in line with the scope
of the surveillance under the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure (MIP). Against this background,
Section 2 of this in-depth review looks more in detail into developments
covering both the external and internal dimensions of the UK economy. This is followed
by a specific focus on external competitiveness and the level and dynamics of
private sector debt in Section 3. Section 4 discusses policy considerations. 2. Macroeconomic
situation and potential imbalances
2.1.
Macroeconomic scene setter
The economic and
financial crisis had a severe effect on the UK economy. Real GDP growth was
-1.0% in 2008 and -4.0% in 2009, mainly as a result of large declines in
household consumption and private investment. Household consumptions fell by 1.6%
in 2008 and 3.1% in 2009, and private investment fell by 13.7% in 2009 alone.
Unemployment[1]
jumped from 5.3% in 2007 to 8.0% in 2011, with youth unemployment[2] reaching a
historical high of 21.1% in 2011. Despite weak GDP growth, inflation remained
stubbornly high and even increased from 2.2% in 2009 to 4.5% in 2011. This was
mainly as a result of imported inflation following a fall in the value of
sterling of more than 20% over 2008-2009. The current account deficit remains
in deficit, with goods exports lagging but the exports of services remaining
more vibrant. The fiscal position of
the UK deteriorated rapidly after the onset of the crisis. The deficit
increased from 5.1% to 11.5% of GDP between 2008 and 2009 as a result of falling
tax revenue and increasing expenditure, owing to the operation of automatic
stabilisers and government injections in the financial sector. Government debt
also rose substantially from 52.3% in 2008 to 85.3% in 2011. The UK has experienced a
slow, subdued and stuttering recovery from the financial crisis. In the
final quarter of 2012, the level of real UK GDP was 3% below the pre-crisis
peak in the first quarter of 2008 (per capita GDP is approximately 6% lower).
GDP growth was just 0.2% in 2012 and is forecast to only gradually pick up in
2013 and 2014, 0.9% and 1.9% respectively.[3] The unemployment rate peaked
at 8.3% in the second half of 2011 but fell back to 7.8% in the third quarter
of 2012. The recent fall in unemployment is surprising given the weakness of
GDP growth. Public sector employment has been falling every quarter since the third
quarter of 2009 where it was 6.37 million, to 5.75 million in September 2012.[4] This labour
has been reallocated to the private sector, where employment has continued to
increase, with recent strong growth in the business services and consumer
sectors. In the third quarter of 2012, the employment rate[5] reached 70.5%,
the highest rate since the final quarter of 2008 whilst the inactivity rate[6] has remained
relatively stable around 24.3% since 2005. The strength of the
labour market has been surprising given the recent weakness in GDP, even after
taking into account the possibility of data revisions. Labour hoarding, weak
real wages and an increase in part-time work and self-employment account for
part of this phenomenon. The consequence of weak GDP growth combined with a
resilient labour market has been a marked drop in labour productivity. It is
unlikely that the unemployment rate can continue falling given the weak growth
outlook. Unemployment may have reached its trough and it is forecast to
increase to 8.0% in 2013 before falling back to 7.8% in 2014. Inflation has mostly been
on a general downward trajectory since September 2011 where it peaked at 5.2%. Inflation
was 2.7% in the final three months of 2012 and the first month of 2013, up from
2.2% in September. This increase is largely due to temporary factors such as
the increase in tuition fees in England in October and rises in utility
prices. However, inflation is still expected to fall given weak demand, but at
a slower rate than previously forecast. Inflation is estimated at 2.6% in 2013
and 2.3% in 2014. The UK economy's
adjustment capacity is affected by the degree of flexibility of its product and
labour markets. According to international benchmarks, UK product markets are
among the least regulated in the EU and worldwide, and its business environment
is generally favourable. With no large collective bargaining arrangements
outside the public sector, which has seen widespread pay freezes, and very
little automatic wage indexation, real wages have been falling for three years.
While this has had a negative impact on household consumption, it has also
helped to limit increases in unemployment. The UK's flexible labour and product
markets remain a strength but low public and private investment, impaired
credit flows, and a resulting low level of churn in the economy could all
impair the effective reallocation of resources in response to the shocks that
the UK economy has experienced.
2.2.
Competitiveness and export performance
The UK experienced large
losses in global market shares, in both value and volume[7]
terms, in 2007, 2008 and 2010, before returning to stability in 2011, as shown in
Graph 1. A secular trend of dwindling export market shares has been the
experience of many developed economies due to the emergence of highly competitive
and faster growing economies, in particular in Asia. The UK, however, appears
to have been more affected than most, displaying the highest losses in the EU-27
according to the export share scoreboard indicator of the AMR-2013. Graph 1: UK export market share growth Source: Commission services Since 1997, the UK
current account has been in a persistent, albeit moderate, deficit, which
amounted to ‑1.3% in 2011. The current account data for 2012 surprised on
the downside due to weak net trade and investment income, combined with resilient
import dynamics. The current account deficit is forecast to have increased
to 3.7% of GDP in 2012. This outcome was essentially due to unfavourable cyclical
conditions rather than a fundamental deterioration in external competitiveness.
In particular, the demand faced by UK exporters was constrained by unfavourable
developments in foreign markets, namely in Europe, which have also contributed
to reduce the income inflows from foreign investment. Additionally,
perturbations in the production of North Sea oil and gas and lower remittances
from abroad have also had a negative effect on the current account. The UK trade balance is
characterised by dynamic service exports which, however, do not fully
compensate for the chronic deficit in goods, as depicted in Graph
2. The crisis period which started in 2007 saw a halting in the widening
of the trade in goods deficit as a percentage of GDP, which has hovered between
6% and 7% in recent years. On the other hand, the surplus in trade in services
has continued to grow to reach 4.7% in 2011, even though its evolution has been
partially affected by a drop in foreign demand for financial and related
services in the wake of the global financial crisis. The UK has historically
benefited from positive foreign income inflows, although these have weakened in
2012.
The high-yielding foreign assets held by UK domestic agents, namely in the form
of foreign direct investment (FDI), have permitted the UK to derive net inflows
from a negative net international investment position (NIIP). These, however,
have been decreasing since 2008, turning negative in the first half of 2012.
This was due, in particular, to the lower profitability of investments in
Europe[8].
The independent Office for Budget Responsibility expects investment income to
return to positive ground in 2013 and to remain stable over its forecast
horizon.[9]
Current transfers have historically been negative, reflecting government
transfer outflows and the effects of remittances (the UK is a recipient of net
immigration inflows). Graph 2: Decomposition of the UK current account Source: Commission services *Estimated After a sharp
depreciation in 2007-2009, the real effective exchange rate (REER) remained relatively
stable in 2011 and appreciated somewhat in 2012. As shown in Graph 3, these
movements have been mostly driven by swings in the nominal exchange rate. The
sharp nominal depreciation in the wake of the crisis contributed to stabilise
the trade in goods deficit, which had been increasing since 1997, when sterling
entered a decade-long period of relative strength. The confidence crisis in
parts of Europe contributed to the appreciation of sterling in 2012 which,
coupled with an inflation rate that has remained persistently above target, has
led to a higher REER in 2012. However, sterling started weakening towards the
end of 2012 and beginning of 2013. Graph 3: Decomposition of developments in the UK REER Source: Commission services Unit labour costs (ULCs)
have increased moderately in recent years due to high inflation and weak labour
productivity, which is the result of a surprisingly strong labour market in a
context of weak or negative growth. Even though real ULCs
decreased in 2011 as nominal wages continued to grow below inflation, nominal
ULC growth in the UK has outpaced that of the euro area, thereby contributing
to erode the competitiveness of the UK vis-à-vis its main trading partners
(Graph 4). However, even taking into account the recent appreciation of
sterling, the strong 2007-2008 nominal depreciation has so far been sufficient
in offsetting the cumulated increases in ULCs from a strict price
competitiveness point of view. Graph 4: Decomposition of developments in the UK Unit Labour Costs Source: Commission services UK current account
deficits have generally been funded by portfolio investment into UK securities,
such as shares and bonds, and by other investments such as loans (see Graph
5). By contrast, the UK built up a positive international position in
FDI by being a foreign direct investor in most years. This funding profile has
been relatively stable over time, although the crisis year of 2008 was
remarkable for its inflows of portfolio investment and its outflows in other investments,
namely in the form of deposit flights. Overall, the persistence
of competitiveness shortfalls merits attention as a possible source of
macroeconomic imbalances. As such, Section 3.1 further analyses external
competitiveness developments in the UK. Graph 5: Financing of the UK current account Source: Commission services *Estimated
2.3.
Sustainability of external positions
The NIIP displayed a
noticeable improvement, from -24% in 2010 to -17% in 2011 due to valuation
changes, rather than a shift in the fundamentals. In fact, a negative
current account in 2011 and 2012 has contributed negatively to the IIP, which
deteriorated in 2012. Valuation changes in 2011 do not appear to have been
caused by movements in the exchange rate but may have been partly driven by a
drop in the UK stock market[10]
and an increase in the nominal value of foreign direct investment abroad. Overall, the UK has maintained
a modestly negative NIIP since the late 1990s, which has not prevented it from
deriving a net positive income inflow. In fact, as shown in
Graph 6, UK foreign external assets are dominated by high-yielding assets such
as direct investments, which have historically offset larger but lower-yielding
liabilities in the form of loans, bonds and deposits in UK banks. Evidence
suggests that the UK has also managed to extract higher returns from its
foreign asset base, even after controlling for its composition. The
denomination of the NIIP is also a generally favourable one whereby most
liabilities have been taken up in the domestic currency. Although the evolution
of the UK NIIP is rather volatile due to erratic valuation changes (Graph 7),
it remains well within the scoreboard indicator threshold of -35% and appears
to be sustainable in the medium term. According to Commission and consensus
estimates, the UK current account is expected to move closer to the
NIIP-stabilising value, which, excluding valuation effects, should preclude a
rapid and sustained deterioration of the NIIP in the medium term. Graph 6: Decomposition of the UK net international investment position || Graph 7: Decomposition of changes in net international investment position || Source: Commission services * Estimated || Source: Commission services
2.4.
Government indebtedness
The general government
deficit fell to 7.8% of GDP in 2011, after spiking at 11.5% in 2009. The
Commission services' Winter forecast estimates a deficit of 6.3% in 2012, which
includes a one-off Royal Mail pension fund transfer of GBP 28 billion (approx.
1.8% of GDP), 7.4% in 2013, which includes the sale of 4G mobile phone licences
and 6.0% in 2014. The debt ratio was 85.2%
in 2011 and is forecast at 89.8% in 2012. It is expected to continue increasing
in 2013 and 2014 and reach 95.4% and 97.9%, respectively (Graph 8).
This is far above the 60% threshold specified in the scoreboard indicators and
the Maastricht threshold. In the Autumn Statement[11], the UK
government has continued its fiscal consolidation plans without any major
changes to the general thrust of the strategy. Some adjustments were made by
substituting current for capital spending but within the same expenditure
envelope and the period of consolidation was extended by one further year to the
financial year (FY) 2017-18. Due to the impact of weak GDP growth on public finances,
the deficit is unlikely to fall exceptionally quickly despite a considerable
decrease in government expenditure as part of the government's multi-year
consolidation programme. However, due to some one-off transfers into the
general government accounts, the deficit figure looks better than the
underlying position.[12] Graph 8: UK government debt Source: Commission services *Forecast The UK has been under
the Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP) since July 2008. In 2009,
acknowledging the worsening macroeconomic situation and the need to support
growth in the short term, the Council adopted a decision and recommendation that
led to the extension of the EDP deadline to 2014-15. The UK fiscal position
will be discussed in detail in the assessment of the UK Convergence Programme
to be carried out in a forthcoming Commission Staff Working Document. It is not clear how much
of the recent drop in UK sovereign yields has been driven by increasing
confidence in the UK's fiscal position. Yields are likely to have been
depressed by quantitative easing, international financial flows in the midst of
a confidence crisis affecting the euro area, and (perversely) by weakening
growth prospects which have reduced expectations of future interest rate rises. This has led
to very favourable interest rates on public debt. While it is difficult to
predict the timing, speed or direction of any change to this situation, a
return to interest rates more consistent with historical trends may have a
significant impact on the capacity of both the public and the private sectors
to honour interest payments without further squeezing investment and
consumption. As shown in Graph 9, the
general government sector remains a significant net borrower in the economy. By
contrast, households are net lenders since 2009 but this has been falling in
recent years. Both financial and non-financial corporations are net lenders to
the economy since 2002. The details of private sector indebtedness will be
discussed in Section 2.5 and further in 3.2.2. Graph 9: Net lending or borrowing by sector Source: Commission services
2.5.
Private sector indebtedness
Private
sector debt as a share of UK GDP increased steadily and significantly, from
123% of GDP in 1995 to a peak of 221% in 2008, and has since fallen back to
206% in 2011. This is well above the scoreboard indicator threshold of
160%. The ratio of private sector debt to GDP can be disaggregated into
non-financial corporation (NFC) debt of 110% and household debt of 96%, as
depicted in Graph 10. The debt of financial corporations, which is considered
separately to other private debt, swelled sharply in the crisis and remains
high. There has been some progress in deleveraging in both the corporate and
household sectors, due at least as much to flows of new lending remaining
unusually low as to existing debt stocks being paid off or written off. Graph 10: Decomposition of financial liabilities in the UK economy Source: Commission services Credit flows
to the private sector as a whole remain muted The net flow
of credit to the private sector in 2011 as a whole was muted, with 1% growth,
and net credit trends remained weak throughout 2012. The rate of
growth in the stock of lending to UK businesses was -4.1% in the year to
November 2012, while secured lending to households rose by 0.6% over the same
period.[13]
This is in sharp contrast to the abundant credit flows to UK firms and
households in the pre-crisis years. Net credit to households averaged 8.7% of
GDP per annum in the decade to 2007 compared to just 3.8% for the euro
area, as shown in Graph 11. This, combined with the average net credit
flows to NFCs of 8.9% in the same period, led the UK to exceed the 15% scoreboard
indicator threshold for private sector credit flows every year from 1999 to
2007. The UK private sector
has tightened its lending more sharply than the euro area average. After a
sharp correction during the crisis in 2009, when investment collapsed, credit
flows to NFCs are weak but show signs of bottoming out and financing conditions
vary significantly across sectors and firm, as discussed in Section 3. Larger
firms with strong balance sheets are able to borrow at a historically low cost
but many other firms, particularly SMEs, are credit constrained. Financial
corporations have moved to being significant net savers as they consolidate
their balance sheets. A low level of housing transactions and tighter mortgage
lending criteria has reduced credit flows to households. Graph 11: Decomposition of net credit flows in the economy Source: Commission services Note: Non-consolidated data. Figures for each sector are the sum of the flow of loans and securities other than shares. Recent
gradual deleveraging of NFCs has been driven by low investment While the debt of NFCs
has fallen slightly since 2008, business investment has remained at a very low
level and the stock of lending to UK businesses has been falling consistently
since 2009.[14] An
unprecedented drop in business investment after 2007 saw the UK level of gross
fixed capital formation as a share of GDP fall to 14.2 % in 2011, the third
lowest level in the EU-27. Business investment has started to pick up slightly,
with an annual increase of 5.1% to the third quarter of 2012, but remains low.
Public investment has been cut sharply as part of the government's fiscal
consolidation programme. The low investment rate is due not only to the low
share of capital-intensive manufacturing in GDP but also to the combined
effects of an uncertain and unfavourable economic environment and difficulties in
accessing finance, especially on the part of small and medium companies. Structural
features partly explain the higher leverage levels of UK companies compared to
the euro area average. The UK has a relatively large share of output
generated by large companies and by multinationals, both of which are
associated with higher levels of leverage, and investment. Multinational
companies, in particular, are able to service debt taken up in the UK with
revenue streams from overseas. The corporate sector in the UK is also likely to
be more integrated, for example making use of inter-company loans, which
also tends to raise the headline unconsolidated debt figures. Household
debt falling from historic highs, mainly due to a low volume of new lending The run-up to the crisis
saw the housing market overheat, with house price-to-income ratios reaching
historic highs in the context of a growing housing supply shortage, leading to
the accumulation of high levels of mortgage debt. The level of household
debt rose from 69% of GDP in 2000 to a peak of 104% in 2009 and the 2012
in-depth review of the UK concluded that high household debt, around 85% of
which is mortgage debt, constitutes an internal imbalance in the UK economy.
Graph 12 shows that net deleveraging of households started in 2009 measured
against gross disposable income, or 2010 measured against GDP (GDP fell more
sharply than disposable income in the recession). In 2011, household debt fell
from 99.6% of GDP to 96%, against a euro area average of 64%. As discussed in
Section 3, to date household deleveraging has been driven mainly by an
abnormally low level of housing transactions although the household saving rate
has also picked up to 7.7% in the third quarter of 2012. Graph 12: Household leverage indicators Source: Commission services Households
have significant net assets but this masks growing inequality in net worth UK households have
substantial net assets in aggregate, but these have become more concentrated. The
financial assets of UK households, which exclude (significant) housing wealth
but include illiquid pension funds, were 183% of GDP in 2011, well above the
euro area average of 128%. UK households have relatively high levels of both
gross assets and gross liabilities, which in large part reflects the effects of
high house prices. The impact of rising asset prices in driving gross household
leverage is shown in Graph 14, which depicts an alternative way of viewing household
leverage ratios. The upper line shows that if one removes valuation effects,
households' previously apparent stable debt-to-assets ratio is actually
increasing over the boom years. This is also the case for Sweden, although in
Sweden it is largely the same households that hold assets and liabilities.[15] While the
average net asset position of UK households has been quite stable over the last
decade, net wealth has become more polarised by income, tenure and across the
life cycle. Net wealth has become increasingly concentrated in older households,
with the ratio of median net worth among households aged 45+ to those aged
18-34 rising from 1.9 to 3.7 between 2005 and 2012.[16] The net
wealth of younger households has fallen, whether they are renting or mortgage
holders, and a growing minority have negative net wealth. These trends are
likely to increase the macroeconomic risks associated with a given household
debt stock. Graph 13: Households debt-to-assets ratio Source: Commission services Residential
construction also remains weak but house prices are still high High house prices are
linked to a shortage of housing supply, which is linked in turn to a scarcity
of land available for development.[17] As discussed
in Section 3.2, the government has put in place a number of measures to reform
the restrictive spatial planning system and provide financial support to
residential developers and first-time buyers, but it is not yet clear how
effective these will be in boosting the supply of housing. UK housing
completions rose slightly from a low of 137,000 in 2010-2011 to 146,000 in
2011-2012, but as shown in Graph 14 the level of housing completions remains
historically low. The most recent forward looking data, show annual housing
starts in England (UK data are not yet available) totalling 98.280 in 2012, a
decrease of 11% compared to 2011.[18] Graph 14: UK dwelling completions by type Source: Department for Communities and Local Government As Graph 15 shows, UK
real house prices have fallen from their peak in 2007 but still remain well
above the levels before the house price boom of the 2000s. The run-up
to the crisis saw the housing market overheat, with house price-to-income
ratios reaching historic highs and the accumulation of high levels of mortgage
debt. Since 2007, the average real house price has fallen by 17% but the
average nominal house price is only 4% below the peak. After falling sharply in
2009, UK house prices rebounded by 10% by mid-2010, after which time nominal
house prices have been relatively flat. Graph 15: Developments in UK house prices and mortgage lending[19] Source: Commission services, ECB Overall, high
household debt, stemming mainly from mortgage lending on expensive houses, a continuing
housing supply shortage and uncertain prospects for household deleveraging,
warrants further investigation as a source of potential macroeconomic
imbalances. This topic, along with a closer look at corporate debt, are
further developed in Section 3.2. 3. In-depth
analysis of selected topics 2.
3.
3.1.
External competitiveness
This section assesses
developments in external competitiveness in the UK and reviews the structural
characteristics of the UK trading sector, identifying its main strengths and
possible bottlenecks. It follows-up on the 2012
in-depth review (IDR) of the UK economy[20]
and on the AMR-2013[21]
which were published under the Macroeconomic Imbalances Procedure. As captured in the
AMR-2013 scoreboard indicator, losses in UK export market shares in the five
years to 2011 were the highest of all EU member states (-24.2%). Although UK market shares remained broadly stable in 2011, large
losses occurred in 2007, 2008 and 2010. This result was partially driven by the
sharp depreciation of sterling that took place in 2008‑2009 which reduced
the value of UK exports when measured in a common currency. However, UK
exporters counteracted the effects of the depreciation to a large extent by
increasing their sterling-denominated prices. Therefore, when considering
simultaneously exchange rate and export price developments, it is clear that
they offset each other to a large extent, the result being that a large drop in
export market shares is still evident when controlling for these price effects
(see Table 1[22]). Unlike in AMR-2012,
the 3-year change in the REER no longer breached the scoreboard indicator threshold
in AMR-2013. This is due to the fact that the large
depreciation in 2008 has since dropped out of the scoreboard indicator
calculations. The REER remained broadly stable in 2011 and appreciated somewhat
in 2012 driven by sterling's strength during most of the year. As will be seen in
this Review, there is no single dominant factor explaining the external
underperformance of the UK economy, although a number of structural constraints
are apparent. Overall, the external dimension of the UK economy is less a
source of macroeconomic instability, and more a field of often underexploited
growth possibilities. Section 3.1.1 starts by presenting
recent competitiveness developments which, in 2012, took place in an
unfavourable external economic context and resulted in a worse-than-expected
trade performance. Section 3.1.2 then reviews the structural characteristics of
UK trade and its exporting sector, identifying strengths and weaknesses.
Section 3.1.3 delves deeper into specific bottlenecks in infrastructure, skills
and access to finance. Section 3.1.4 concludes. As discussed in the present
section, the external competitiveness challenges identified in the 2012 IDR
remain valid.
3.1.1.
Developments in external competitiveness
A worse-than-expected outturn in 2012, largely driven by unfavourable
external circumstances The UK posted a
small but significant current account deficit of -1.3% of GDP in 2011, which is
forecast to have deteriorated to -3.7% in 2012. This
was due to low export growth, weaknesses in investment income inflows, in particular
from EU countries, a buoyant import demand given the domestic recession and lower
remittances from abroad. The external economic
context in 2012 was not the most favourable one for European exporting
companies, the UK's included. Weak and negative growth the in EU, the largest
single market for UK exports (representing 47% in 2011) has constrained the
expansion of the UK's external demand. In 2012, the percentage of manufacturing
firms citing "political or economic factors abroad" as a factor
limiting exports reached 40%, the highest value in a decade (Graph 16). Graph 16: UK firms citing factors abroad as inhibiting exports Source: CBI Industrial Trends Survey Not only foreign-income
effects, but also price effects are presently affecting the export performance
of the UK. The appreciation of sterling in trade-weighted terms during most of
2012 may deliver negative contribution to export volumes, while higher oil
prices have contributed to the deterioration of the oil trade balance. The
recent depreciation of sterling vis-à-vis the euro can, however, provide some
support going forward. The current account is
expected to improve in the medium term. Commission forecasts
currently estimate the current account balance at -3.1% in 2013 and -2.0% in
2014. The Office for Budge Responsibility expects net trade to contribute 0.2
pp. on average per year to GDP growth between 2013 and 2017. It also expects
the current account deficit to progressively narrow until 2017, when it is
projected at approximately ‑1.5% of GDP. The dynamism
of UK service exports has not managed to compensate for the large deficit in
trade in goods The UK is the
largest services exporter in the EU and its services trade balance posted a
surplus worth 4.7% of GDP in 2011, as shown in
Graph 17. In the pre-crisis period running from 2000-2007 the UK
continued to increase its global market share in services exports, even as its
goods share declined more than any other EU country. After 2007 and until 2011
UK market shares were subject to a double setback. Not only did the share of
goods' exports continue falling, but services exports also experienced negative
developments (see Graph 19). Although the nominal value of total service
exports continued to grow in this period, its pace was significantly slowed
down by a decline in exports of financial and insurance services (see Graph 18). Graph 17: International market shares of the six largest service exporters in the EU || Graph 18: Developments in UK aggregate and financial services exports || Source: Commission services || Source: Commission services * Estimated Graph 19: UK export market share growth decomposition Source: Commission services The UK has
experienced a negative trade balance in goods since 1983, which started
deteriorating markedly after 1997. Its value stabilised
a little below 7% of GDP in recent years. Although UK external
trade has underperformed for several years, it should be acknowledged that some
degree of rebalancing towards net exports has taken place. From 2007 to 2011
export volumes increased by 3.3%, a time when GDP contracted by 2.3%. In fact, net trade delivered a positive contribution to GDP
growth in every year during this period, with the exception of 2010. The post-crisis depreciation of sterling provided only a modest
boost Sterling depreciated
sharply in 2008-2009, after a decade of strength which saw the UK trade balance
deteriorate markedly (see Graph 20). Notwithstanding
this exchange rate correction, Commission services' analysis of the equilibrium
exchange rate suggests that sterling may have remained slightly overvalued
during most of 2012. The drop in sterling vis-à-vis the euro towards the end of
2012 and beginning of 2013 may thus mean a movement towards equilibrium values.
The recent depreciation of sterling can also be understood as the consequence
of the resolution of uncertainties regarding the euro area crisis, concerns
over UK public finances, expectations of further quantitative easing and rising
uncertainties regarding the UK’s future relationship with the EU. Graph 20: UK exchange rate and trade balance performance Source: Commission services The depreciation of
sterling was not, however, sufficient to put the trade balance on a sustained
upward trend. This could be due to a number
of factors. Firstly, exporters compensated for the depreciation by raising
their sterling-denominated prices. The fact that exporters opted to increase
their margins rather than expand market shares and invest in capacity may be
due to uncertainties regarding the likelihood of sterling remaining at its new
low level and a cautious approach in the face of a volatile external
environment. However, as sterling remains at a relatively low level, exporters
strengthen their balance sheets and uncertainty resolves, expansion should
become an increasingly attractive option. Secondly, the depreciation
contributed to raise input prices for some exporters. Thirdly, the depreciation
took place at the same time as the external demand for UK goods collapsed due to
the global financial and economic crisis, which would mask the positive effects
accruing from the new exchange rate.[23]
These factors have been highlighted in a recent survey of manufacturers where
the global economic downturn, rising input costs and significant movements in
the exchange rate were cited as the three foremost risks to growth.[24] Finally, as discussed
in subsection 3.1.3, a number of bottlenecks are constraining the external
performance of the UK. Competitiveness losses and unfavourable geographical specialisation
drove the post-crisis fall in market shares In the pre-crisis
period of 2000-2007, UK export markets grew in line with the world average. In this period, the geographical markets in which the UK was
specialised, especially European markets, were growing in line with global trends.
Likewise, the product markets in which the UK was specialised were growing, on
aggregate, in line with overall product markets. In this period decreases in
market shares were thus due to competitiveness losses, namely with respect to
fast-growing emerging economies. In the post-crisis
period of 2007-2010 UK exports were affected by their focus on slow-growing
markets, competitiveness losses in geographical destinations and by
competitiveness losses in product markets (Graph 21).
In fact, the traditional geographical markets to which the UK exported,
namely advanced economies in Europe, slowed down. Furthermore, the UK appears
to have suffered from strong competition in the products and destinations in
which it specialises. However, as shown in Graph 22, the UK is likely to have
faced only moderate competition from China, as the overlapping index[25] between both
countries is in the mid-range when compared with other EU economies. Considering
a breakdown of the overlapping products, the categories where direct
competition from China appears to be more relevant are in minerals, chemicals
and, particularly, machines (see Graph 23). || Graph 21: Contribution to UK market share growth from geographical and sectoral composition || || || || Source: Commission services || Graph 22: Overlapping indices with China || Graph 23: UK export products - similarity with China vs. share in total UK exports || Source: Commission services, Comtrade || Source: Commission services Rebalancing towards new geographical markets is unfolding In 2011, the EU
still represented approximately half of the UK export market, but exports to
new emerging markets have been rising fast since 2009. As shown in Graph 24, export values to the BRIC countries have more
than doubled, albeit from a low base, since a trough in 2009. By year-end 2012,
BRIC countries represented approximately 8% of total goods exports. The dynamism of
exports to BRIC countries contrasts with the slow growth of exports to the rest
of the world over the same period. In particular, export
volumes to EU countries in 2012 were only slightly above those witnessed in
2009. This was due not only to weaknesses in the euro area, but also to the slow
appreciation of sterling vis-à-vis the euro since mid-2011 and through the
first half of 2012. Graph 24: UK goods exports to BRIC and other countries Source: ONS Fast-growing
countries present an important opportunity for selected British goods. Exports to Asian countries have shown a remarkable dynamism since
the 2007 crisis. For instance, exports to China and Korea more than trebled
during this period, although this was from a low starting point. Fast-growing
Asian markets have shown an appetite for UK cars[26], fashion
products and other luxury goods, as well as, to some extent, capital goods and
professional services, which could be further exploited.
3.1.2.
Characteristics of the UK trading sector
Trade in goods and services is relatively diverse, but with
important specialisation areas The UK trades a diverse
mix of goods and services (Table 2). As to
the former, industries with a strong export propensity in the UK include machinery
and electrical products, vehicles, aeronautics and aerospace, chemicals,
pharmaceuticals, and metals, stones and related products. Car exports have been
particularly dynamic in recent years. The UK posted its first quarterly car
trade surplus since 1976 last year and approximately eight in ten cars produced
in the UK are now exported. The trade in oil
balance turned negative in 2005 and is expected to continue to drag down the trade
balance in the future (Graphs 25 and 26). By
year-end 2012, trade in oil contributed nearly 1 pp. to the current account
deficit. Besides an on-going trend of declining oil production, the recent
deterioration was also due to a rise in oil prices, which has further
contributed to increase price pressures for (non-oil) UK exporters. Graph 25: Trade in oil balance || Graph 26: Oil production || Source: Office for National Statistics || Source: DECC, OBR The financial and
professional services cluster is of obvious importance to UK services' trade. As depicted in Graph 27, financial, insurance and business services
constitute the majority of UK service exports. Tourism and transport make up
most of the remainder. Graph 27: Decomposition of UK service exports ource: Commission services The dividing lines
between goods and services are increasingly blurred, which can play to the UK's
commercial strengths. Services can complement, add
value to and be bundled with goods and other services. The UK's strengths in
professional services, media, publishing, entertainment and in range of
immaterial goods can be further exploited, not only for the growth potential
that these increasingly global markets represent, but also in association with
other productive activities. UK productivity lags behind that of other leading economies Labour productivity
increased rapidly in the 1990s in the UK, but remains somewhat below that of
France or Germany (see Graph 28). In particular,
productivity growth in the goods‑producing
sector lagged behind that of the services sector. Whereas
the UK displayed the seventh highest labour productivity growth in the EU-27
from 2000 to 2010 in the services sector, it ranks sixteenth when the same
measure is applied to the industrial sector.[27]
Additionally, the evolution of total factor productivity in manufacturing from
2001 to 2009 compares unfavourably to that of other EU countries.[28] While rates
of return on employed capital where similar in 1997 in the services and
manufacturing sectors[29],
they have since diverged and are now significantly higher in the services
sector. In fact, the UK's structural problems set out in this review (including
a restrictive planning system, high land and house prices, weak infrastructure
and gaps in technical skills) tend to disproportionately hamper capital-intensive
and manufacturing industries. Graph 28: Current price GDP per hour worked relative to the UK Source: ONS The UK shows distinct strengths in R&D, but investment remains
low R&D intensity is
lower in the UK than on average across the EU. In
2010, the UK invested 1.8% of GDP in R&D, a figure which is lower than the
EU average (2.0%) and which decreased during the previous decade. While the UK
has one of the highest R&D investment intensities in the services industry[30], as well as one
of the highest shares of knowledge-intensive services in total services,
R&D investment intensity in manufacturing is only the tenth highest in the
EU. Nevertheless, the UK
possesses important R&D assets, which can be further exploited. The UK is home to several world-class universities and its
scientific production is among the most quoted in the world. It also benefits
from highly-skilled talent, some of which it has been able to attract from
overseas, and is a leading researcher and developer in a number of sectors such
as aerospace, nanotechnology and pharmaceuticals. However, the commercialisation
of research in the UK could be better exploited by reinforcing the links
between industrial and research sectors.[31] A favourable business environment, but the planning system can raise
costs for businesses The UK compares well
to EU peers on several business environment indicators. The UK ranked second among EU countries, and seventh worldwide, in
the 2013 edition of the World Bank's Doing Business report with respect to the
overall "ease of doing business" indicator. Likewise, the UK ranked
eight out of 144 countries in the 2012-13 edition of the Global Competitiveness
Report, moving up two positions compared to the previous year. Corruption
perceptions are comparatively low according to Transparency International's
corruption perception index and the UK is the least regulated of all OECD
countries according to the economy-wide product market regulation index.[32] Nevertheless,
model-based analysis suggests that there is still scope for a decrease in the
mark-up of intermediate goods producers to reflect positively on the current
account.[33] Planning and land
use restrictions are not usually captured in standard indicators, but can be a
significant source of costs for businesses in the UK. As discussed in the next section on debt and the housing market, the
planning system and restrictions on the use of land impact negatively on
economic performance in the UK. This is the case for capital-intensive and
goods-producing industries, which rely more heavily on land as a primary
production factor, but also for office space, which is among the most expensive
in the world, imposing a "regulatory tax" on businesses.[34] SMEs dominate
the corporate landscape in the UK, as they do in the EU generally SMEs constitute the vast
majority of companies in the UK and in the EU, and tend to display a lower
export propensity. As shown in graphs 29 and 30, firm size is
strongly correlated with productivity for industrial companies and with export
propensity more generally. In fact, the ability to compete internationally is
usually reserved for the most productive companies. It is therefore important that
legislation and business frameworks do not incentivise SMEs to stay small.
Overall, the UK does not stand out negatively when compared to EU peers in
terms of market structure and number of firms by size class, and it is home to
a significant number of large and multinational companies. Graph 29: Number of UK firms distribution by firm size class || Graph 30: UK exports by destination || Source: Commission services || Source: Commission services Graph 31: UK labour productivity distribution by firm size class Source: Commission services Exporting companies in
the UK tend to be larger when compared with EU peers and there is scope for
increasing the number of exporting SMEs. Small and medium enterprises
in the UK are more focused on the internal market and make up less of the total
number of exporting companies than they do in Germany or France. By contrast,
the UK possesses a comparatively high share of firms in the two extremes of the
size distribution of exporting companies (approximately 60% and 15% of
exporting companies in the large and micro category, respectively). Whereas 25%
of EU SMEs exported in 2006-2008, this figure drops to 21% in the case of the
UK.[35]
Therefore, helping SMEs gain a foothold in external markets could contribute towards
boosting the UK export performance. The import content of exports is relatively low in the UK mainly due
to the large size of its economy and the importance of service exports The import content
of UK exports was the lowest in the EU-27 in 2009, standing at approximately
18%, as shown in Graph 32. This means that
the UK imports relatively few intermediate imports to further process into
exports. In general, the extent of imported intermediate inputs typically reflects
access to greater input variety in terms of quality and price, which should
benefit a country's exports. It also gives an indication of how well a country
is integrated in global value chains. Graph 32: Import content of exports (2009) Source: WIOD, Commission services In the case of the
UK, the low import content can be understood as a consequence of the large size
of its economy, the importance of services in its export profile and its high degree
of energy sufficiency. Large economies tend to be
less open to imports as they can more easily find the necessary production
inputs within their economic territory. The fact that the UK is self-sufficient
in terms of energy needs to a comparatively high degree also contributes to a
lower import content of exports. Finally, service exports typically display a
lower import content and the UK possesses a comparatively large share of
services as a percentage of total exports. In fact, 60% of the value of UK
gross exports originate from service industries according to the OECD-WTO trade
in value added database, one of the highest figures among the 41 countries in
the dataset. Domestic value added is particularly high in financial and
business services, and the UK displays a significant services content in manufacturing
exports. As such, preserving a dynamic services exporting sector remains
crucial, even as the UK seeks to increase its manufactured exports. When considering only the
import content of manufactured exports, estimations for the UK stood at 30% for
2005, a figure similar to that of other large EU countries such as Germany,
France and Italy[36].
3.1.3.
Structural challenges
UK infrastructure
struggling to meet the demands of the global economy Investment in the UK
has remained consistently among the lowest in the EU throughout the years, as shown in Table 3. This is partly explained by the importance of
the services and other less capital-intensive sectors in the UK economy, but
also by the fact that government investment is particularly low. In the post-crisis
period, UK companies have also favoured the accumulation of surpluses to
investment, as demand remains muted and uncertain, and external funding is not
always available for small and medium companies. Investment in the UK is tilted
towards brand equity, firm specific human capital and organisational capital,
with machinery and equipment representing a comparatively small share of total
investment.[37] The UK displays
important investment needs in infrastructure. According to the World
Economic Forum, the UK currently ranks 24th on quality of its
overall infrastructure. As a comparison, France ranks fifth and Germany ninth. Transport
infrastructure is of particular importance for the goods-producing sector, an
area where the UK trade balance is in a persistent and significant deficit. UK
producers need to be able to move goods and factors around in their economic
territory and to export them overseas. Around GBP 310 billion of investment is
needed over the duration of the current parliament and beyond in energy, roads
and network rail, according to Infrastructure UK, a unit of HM Treasury. The
need to upgrade the UK's infrastructure is also widely recognised in business
surveys (see Graph 33 for an example). Graph 33: UK infrastructure compared with other countries Source: CBI/KPMG infrastructure survey Transport is a
significant contributor to producer's costs. The increase in the UK's
HICP of transport services was the highest of all Member States in the 2009-2011
period. The UK's motorway and
rail network is one of the least dense in the EU-27 with respect to the number
of inhabitants and airline passenger transport services display one of the
worst market performance indicators[38].
The
UK's ratio of average speed to free-flow traffic speed is also one of the
lowest in the EU[39]
and research by the Federation of Small Businesses suggests that the state of
roads costs approximately half of small businesses up to GBP 5000 per year due
to congestion and poor maintenance. Seaport capacity is of
particular importance to the UK given that its ports handle the second highest gross
weight of goods in the EU and seaports could benefit from better transport
connections. Additionally, there is a growing shortage of airport capacity in
the south east of England, where demand is concentrated. Shortfalls in energy
capacity are looming and some companies are reporting electricity shortages. A large part
of the UK's electricity generation capacity will require renewal or upgrading
in the next decade. According to a recent survey by the British Chambers of
Commerce, more than half of the surveyed companies had experienced an energy
interruption in the last three years, with a large share of companies
considering that the security of energy supply will be a greater issue in the
future. The government has
stated it wants to access pension funds and other private capital to fund
infrastructure improvements including new road developments and replacing
ageing electricity generating capacity. However, while the
impact of sharp cuts to publicly-funded construction and maintenance is already
being felt, the government's aspirations on private funding have not yet
generated results. In the Autumn Statement 2012[40], a successor
initiative was also announced to the private finance initiative (PFI) – this
will be called PFI 2. The government announced a GBP 40 billion infrastructure
guarantee fund to assist large infrastructure projects that are currently
struggling due to adverse credit conditions. The projects can come from a range
of sectors including transport, energy, utilities and communications, and must
satisfy a number of criteria. The scheme has received 75 enquiries from project
sponsors to date, of which projects with a capital value of around GBP 10
billion have been prequalified as eligible for consideration of a guarantee. On
29 November 2012 the UK Government proposed a new energy bill, putting in place
measures to attract the GBP 110 billion investment which is needed to replace the
current generating capacity and upgrade the grid by 2020, and to cope with a
rising demand for electricity. Most of the government's
plans for increasing private investment remain aspirational and the UK needs to
be careful not to repeat the mistakes of past PFI projects. Audit
evidence suggests the previous PFI model was a costly way of procuring public
infrastructure, largely because long term projects were funded at a (higher)
private rate of return than the cost of public borrowing. There has been a lot
of uncertainty over the prospects for energy investment due, in significant
part, to regulatory risks. Skill gaps
affect labour productivity, in particular in manufacturing sectors Evidence
suggests that UK producers are confronted with a significant skills gap, namely
in manufacturing, where the required intermediate technical skills are not
always available. A recent survey of manufacturers cited lack of
technical skills as the single most important reason for recruitment problems.[41] In fact, recruitment
difficulties in the manufacturing sector have continued to rise in 2012 as
shown in Graph 34, even as the overall economy has struggled. This, in turn,
has contributed to hinder the rebalancing of the economy towards the
goods-producing tradable sector. Graph 34: Recruitment difficulties Source: The British Chambers of Commerce Skills
mismatches in the UK are mostly of a vertical nature, whereby a significant
share of the population does not possess the appropriate level of education.
According to a recent study, more than 40% of employees are either over- or
under-qualified (see Graph 35). The large share of under-qualified
personnel is a reflection of the insufficient number of workers with
intermediate 'vocational' training. Conversely, a non-negligible share of the
workforce is deemed to be over-qualified. This is linked to the government and
social focus on university education, which may lead to its overvaluation
vis-à-vis the technical skills demanded by some sectors of the labour market.
By contrast, the UK displays a comparatively low level of horizontal mismatches
meaning that, given the educational level, the fields of study are broadly
appropriate (Graph 36). Nevertheless, insufficient knowledge of foreign
languages may constrain the ability of companies to conduct business in foreign
markets. According to a recent survey[42],
the overwhelming majority of business owners do not possess the necessary
language skills to conduct business in the buyers' language, with 52% of
respondents claiming that language barriers are either highly or somewhat
influential when deciding if, when and where to export. Graph 35: Average incidence of vertical mismatch (2001-2011) in EU-27 countries, % of employees (aged 25-64) Source: Commission services Graph 36: Incidence of horizontal mismatch in Europe, % of employed, 2009, EU-27 Source: Commission services, Randstat More
restrictive immigration policies may affect the UK's ability to compete for
global talent. According to the Office for National Statistics, net
migration to the UK decreased by one quarter in 2012. This was partly due to
more people leaving the country, but also due to 20,000 fewer overseas students
entering the country. The UK authorities have made it more difficult for
graduates to work in the UK, affecting the UK higher education industry, which
has a significant export propensity. Additionally, the fact that visa
applications may take a long time to be processed and that allocations are not
fully used may hamper the UK's ability to attract globally-mobile talent. A number of
initiatives are underway to improve skills and reform the educational offer in
the UK, among them the national apprenticeships programme. The number of
apprenticeship starts in 2011-2012 was 520,600, up from 457,200 in the previous
academic year. It is crucial that apprenticeships deliver high quality training
to participants and that the technical and professional skills so developed be
properly assessed.[43]
A review of the national curriculum in England is also currently underway and
new programmes of study are planned to be introduced in 2014. In Scotland, the
new curriculum for schools from age 3-18 is gradually being implemented and in Wales
the National Literacy and Numeracy Framework sets out annual expected outcomes
in literacy and numeracy since 2012. Overall, it is important that reforms to
the educational system be demand- rather than supply-led, in the sense that
they be able to address skill shortages in the UK's workforce going forward. Difficulties accessing finance constrain entry into and expansion
of the exporting sector An important
share of SMEs, including younger and innovative companies, remains credit
constrained. Although the UK compares favourably with the EU peers on
indicators measuring availability and ease of access to venture capital, access
to credit by UK SMEs was severely affected by the financial crisis. A composite
indicator derived from the ECB/European Commission surveys on SME access to
finance[44]
shows that access to bank loans by SMEs in the UK deteriorated markedly in the
post-crisis period (see Graph 37). In fact, during this period, most surveys of
SME access to finance in the UK put loan rejection rates between one fifth and one
third of total applications.[45] Graph 37: Index of SME access to bank loans Source: ECB, Commission services Note: the index was constructed based on responses to six questions on SME perceptions and experience from the ECB/Commission surveys on access to finance; the index ranges from zero (worst possible situation) to one (best possible situation). Following the
2008-2009 depreciation, the UK exporting sector became more attractive, with
many of the current exporters opting to increase their margins. Promoting
access to finance for current and potential exporters can help tilt the
positive effects of depreciation from an increase in export prices to an
increase in export quantities. This is especially true for younger companies,
which often struggle to obtain credit according to survey evidence. Access to
trade finance and trade credit is particularly important at the current
juncture. Following
the financial crisis and as a consequence of deleveraging efforts by the
banking sector, some banks exited the market for exporter-specific financing
instruments. The UK authorities have devised specific measures that cater for
the financing needs of the exporting sector. These include a lending facility
to provide up to GBP 1.5 billion in loans to foreign importers acquiring
capital goods and services from UK exporters, a supply chain finance scheme whereby
banks extend supply chain credit at favourable rates to SMEs in deals involving
large companies, and an export marketing research scheme offering support and
funding to companies searching export markets.
3.1.4.
Conclusions
UK trade and
external competitiveness demonstrates a noticeable underperformance. The current
account has been in a persistent, albeit moderate, deficit since 1997 and
important losses in international market shares have accumulated during the
2000s. The trade in goods balance has been locked in negative territory for
decades, although this has been partly compensated for by trade surpluses stemming
from the more dynamic services sector, and by foreign income flows. The factors
explaining the external dynamics of the UK economy are multifaceted, with no
single dominant reason accounting for the suboptimal performance of the UK
external sector. These factors are both circumstantial and structural. Among the
circumstantial and cyclical factors impacting the UK's competitiveness in
recent years are a decade-long of strong currency which lasted until 2007 and
which has since reversed, a temporary collapse in foreign demand in the wake of
the crisis that affected sectors in which the UK is specialised such as
financial and professional services, and strong unit labour cost dynamics,
which were driven by high inflation (part of which is imported) and a drop in
labour productivity (part of which is likely to be cyclical).[46] In 2012, in
particular, the UK current account suffered from weak demand from traditional
European markets, depressed foreign income inflows and a deterioration in the
oil trade balance. The UK trade performance has also been affected
by more lasting and structural burdens. Traditional UK export markets have
remained focused on slower-growing developed economies, although the exporters
continued to rebalance towards new geographic destinations in 2012.
Additionally, overall labour productivity in the UK lags behind that of other
leading economies. This is noticeably the case in manufacturing, where
productivity growth has been sluggish. Also, the UK is becoming increasingly
confronted by the dwindling production levels of the North Sea oil fields. A number of structural
constraints lend themselves to appropriate policy intervention. Foremost among
these are infrastructure inadequacies, a technical and intermediate skills gap
and problems in accessing finance. Higher investment in
infrastructure would crucially support businesses in circulating goods, inputs
and production factors in the UK, and exporting products overseas. Narrowing
the existing gap in intermediate and technical skills would foster higher
productivity and expansion of the manufacturing sector. Finally, easing access
to finance could help new companies enter the exporting sector and facilitate the
expansion of current exporters. The UK
authorities have sought to address these constraints through a diverse set of
policy measures. Investment in infrastructure is being increased, but only
after capital spending slashes in 2010 and 2011. The apprenticeships programme can
help close skill gaps, but the quality of training provided should be carefully
monitored. Access to finance initiatives have been supportive of the flow of
credit and funding to the real economy but have not been able to normalise it,
which, on current policies, may not happen until growth and more favourable
macroeconomic conditions have been fully re-established. Despite some
non-negligible weaknesses, the competitiveness of the UK economy benefits from notable
strengths. The UK offers a business-friendly environment and its
economy is comparatively flexible with respect to both product and labour
markets. The quality of the UK science base is recognised worldwide, although
commercial appropriation of research can be improved. The UK industrial fabric
includes global leaders in the services sectors as well as in medium- and
high-tech goods-producing sectors, the car industry being a good case in point
in 2012. Although the
persistence of an external competitiveness underperformance constitutes an
imbalance in the UK economy, a degree of rebalancing towards net exports has
taken place since the outset of the crisis. Export volumes have
grown 3.3% between 2007 and 2011, a time when overall GDP contracted. With no important
medium-term threats from an external sustainability point of view, the external
dimension of the UK economy has not been an important source of macroeconomic
instability, but neither has it delivered so far on its full potential as an
engine of growth.
3.2.
Private debt, deleveraging and growth
This section analyses
the distribution and dynamics of corporate and household debt in turn, and how
current government policy and macroeconomic conditions are affecting them. It
then assesses the potential paths of private debt stocks, flows and servicing
costs, and the extent to which they are a potential source of macroeconomic
instability or persistently weak growth.
3.2.1.
Corporate debt and access to finance
Though total non-financial
corporation (NFC) debt is on the high side, firms are saving in aggregate and
some are cash-rich As discussed
in Section 2.5 and shown in Graph 38, the leverage of UK NFCs increased in the
pre-crisis period and corporate debt remains above the EU average, despite some
deleveraging since 2008. In common with firms across the EU, UK
businesses steadily increased their total borrowing in the decade before the
crisis, encouraged by benign macroeconomic conditions and easy availability of
credit.
The corporate debt-to-equity ratio increased rapidly in the early 2000s, due to
a fall in the UK stock market following the bursting of the international
dot-com bubble, then stabilised until the crisis. However, the increase in
debt-to-equity did not lead to a period of deleveraging as wider economic conditions
remained favourable. In the run up to the financial crisis banks continued to
be willing to lend and companies to take on additional debt. Debt-to-equity
spiked in 2008 due to temporary valuation effects from a drop in the stock market.
In contrast, the NFC debt-to-financial-assets ratio has remained broadly stable
since 1995, as financial assets have grown at a similar rate to debt. Note that,
as discussed below, the assets and liabilities are not necessarily in the same
firms and sectors. Graph 38: Indicators of leverage in non-financial corporations Source: Commission services As Graph 39 shows, in
aggregate UK NFCs remained profitable before and during the crisis, with a
higher share of retained earnings than the euro area average every year since
2003. A combination of continued profitability and low investment has led to
NFCs being net lenders since 2002, as seen in Graph 40. Since the
onset of the crisis, when business investment fell sharply but profits held up
relatively well in a context of falling real wages, net lending of NFCs has
increased further. UK NFCs as a whole have consequently accumulated significant
surpluses, as many businesses are wary of investing in face of a subdued and
volatile demand. Additionally, a large fraction of smaller businesses have had
to build up internal funding buffers due to difficulties accessing credit and
some companies have been faced with the need to save to recapitalise pension
funds. For example, while the fall in interest rates is favourable for firms
wanting to borrow, it has created a hole in the finances of companies with
defined benefit pension schemes. A recent call for evidence from the UK
Department for Work and Pensions[47]
concerns the tension between the need to ensure that pension fund deficits are
addressed in a timely manner, and the potential negative impact on investment
and macroeconomic stability if firms are required to make good any shortfalls
resulting from asset price movements too quickly. Graph 39: Profitability of non-financial corporations[48] || Graph 40: Savings and investment by non-financial corporations || Source: Commission services || Source: Commission services The aggregate picture
masks significant variation across sectors and firms, which has significant implications
for stability and growth. The NFC profit and savings figures have in part
been flattered by a high oil price driving large profits in the oil and gas
extraction sector, much of which is in the hands of companies who do not
necessarily invest specifically in the UK. Additionally, the balance sheets of
companies in sectors that have been hardest hit by the crisis, including real
estate and construction, are not as robust. In addition to the boom in loans
for residential property, discussed in Section 3.2.2., there was also a
pre-crisis boom in loans to commercial property companies, much of which went
to push up prices rather than supply.[49] Banks and
firms have been focused more on securing stability than expanding lending The unconsolidated debt
of UK financial corporations is exceptionally high, reflecting the large size
and high degree of integration of the UK financial sector, including in its
role as a global financial hub. The unconsolidated debt of the
financial sector amounted to 410% by end-year 2011.[50] After a
period of turmoil in the wake of the 2008 crisis, which required large
government interventions to guarantee the liquidity and solvency of
several UK banks, the banking sector has stabilised. The balance sheets of UK
banks have been expanding slowly in the last couple of years, after the rapid growth
witnessed in the pre-crisis period. Overall, the banking
sector appears to have returned to relative stability, as reflected in a number
of indicators. Capital ratios have strengthened significantly since 2008 and UK
banks are now among the best capitalised in the EU. CDS and senior unsecured
bond spreads remain contained and have been narrowing since 2011. Finally, the
UK banking sector shows a low exposure to public debt of countries under market
stress, although the exposure to private debtors, especially in Ireland and
Spain, is more significant. However, banks may not be appropriately
provisioning for the expected losses that may arise from their loan books in
the future. The interim Financial Policy Committee (FPC)[51] judges
that banks are overstating their true capital adequacy and have recommended
that the Financial Services Authority (FSA) takes action to ensure that the
capital of UK banks and building societies reflects a proper valuation of their
assets, a realistic assessment of future conduct costs and prudent calculation
of risk weights. Banks' loan-to-deposit
ratio has fallen sharply since 2007, from 65% in 2007 to 57% in 2011, as shown in
Graph 41. This will help secure financial sector stability but significant
further shrinkage of banks' loan books through tight restrictions on new credit
could hold back the recovery of the wider economy. Graph 41: Financial corporations' liabilities and loan to deposit ratio Source: Commission services The credit crunch
observed in the UK since the onset of the crisis has resulted from negative
shocks in both credit demand and credit supply. Credit demand has
decreased due to fewer investment opportunities, higher perceived risk, poorer
collateral and less appetite to leverage up in an uncertain environment. Several
reasons may explain the contraction in credit supply including a higher
perceived risk of lending in a weak economy, higher risk aversion by banks, a
more demanding regulatory environment, a need to rebuild balance sheets and
insufficient competition among credit providers. Monetary
policy remains very loose but lending is still low The Bank of England has
continued its loose monetary policy, with the base rate remaining at a low 0.5%,
the quantitative easing programme being expanded by GBP 50 billion to GDP 375
billion in July 2012, the Extended Collateral Term Repo Facility being
activated in June 2012 and the Funding for Lending Scheme (FLS) being opened in
August 2012. The monetary policy measures undertaken by the Bank of
England[52]
are positive for the economy overall but may not in themselves be sufficient to
re-establish lending in an economy where the monetary transmission mechanism
and money-to-loan transformation ratios have been weakened. Net bank lending is
still falling for both large firms and SMEs, and total net funding to UK NFCs
also remains negative. As Graph 42 shows, a return to positive net
issuance of corporate bonds and commercial paper in 2011 and 2012 does not
fully offset negative net loan and equity issuance. On one hand some larger
firms are using their access to cheap bond finance to undertake significant
share buy backs. In fact, debt financing may have become more attractive than
equity issuance for some managers as the stock market remains comparatively
depressed. On the other hand many smaller firms remain credit constrained and
often do not have access to sources of funding for investment other than
retained earnings. Graph 42: Net funds raised by UK businesses Source: Bank of England. Note: Data for 2012 are up to and including November. Credit availability show
signs of improving for some firms and households, but this is only starting to
translate into lower costs and a higher volume of lending. The Bank of
England's Credit Survey found that the overall availability of credit to the
corporate sector increased significantly in the last quarter of 2012. Both an
improvement in external economic conditions and credit easing policies appear
to have contributed to this trend. However, demand for credit remained muted
and major UK lenders report that a lack of confidence among firms is still
weighing down on the demand for credit. The cost of credit has fallen slightly
for SMEs in recent months (see Graph 43) but remains above 2009 levels. Similarly
while the reported availability of credit has improved across the board, as
shown in Graph 44]there has been least improvement for small businesses. Graph 43: Indicative median interest rates on new SME variable rate loan facilities || Graph 44: Availability and demand for credit by firm size || Source: BIS, Bank of England and BoE calculations || Source: Commission services Access
to finance policies aim to boost credit to firms In June 2012, the
government and the Bank of England announced the FLS to provide cheap funding
for banks in order to boost lending to the real economy. Banks and
building societies that increase lending to UK households and businesses will
be able to borrow at lower cost than banks that scale back on lending.
Participating banks and building societies will be able to borrow up to 5% of
their stock of existing lending to the real economy, plus any net expansion of
lending during a reference period (from end-June 2012 to end-December 2013). There
is no upper limit on the size of either individual or aggregate borrowing under
the scheme.
Banks
will be able to borrow under the FLS until 31 January 2014 by pledging their
household and NFC loan books as collateral. According to the second data release[53] and to the
list of participating institutions published as of March 2013, 39 banks and
building societies representing more than 80% of the lending stock to
households and NFCs have signed up for the FLS. Of these, 13 banks and building
societies had used the scheme by the end of 2012, representing a total of GBP
13.83 billion in outstanding drawings. While the 39 participating institutions
registered a small decrease in net lending during the first two quarters of
operation of the scheme, it is still early to measure the effects of the FLS as
they continue to pass through to the real economy. The funding costs of UK
banks have fallen more sharply than those of EU peers since the FLS was
launched in July 2012, likely reflecting the effects of the scheme but also improved
sentiment in global financial markets.[54]
Lower funding costs should facilitate a gradual easing in domestic credit
conditions which may explain why respondents to a recent Bank of England survey[55] expected that
the availability of credit to all sectors would increase further in the first
quarter of 2013. While the scheme has likely contributed to increased mortgage
lending, it has been less successful so far in boosting corporate lending, in
particular to SMEs. It is possible that even if the FLS has some positive
impact, it may only succeed in arresting the decline in lending to SMEs, rather
than reversing it. The FLS builds on a
range of other access to finance policies. The government will
invest GBP 1 billion in a new "British Business Bank" to support the
provision of long-term loans to SMEs via existing financial institutions. Plans
for the Business Bank are under development but one element will be providing
co-financing for the private sector to invest in sources of finance that help
diversify the business finance market. If properly designed and implemented, the
Business Bank could make some contribution to increased competition in the
banking industry. The National Loan Guarantee Scheme has been underway since
March 2012 to reduce the costs of bank loans and to promote lending to
businesses. According to HM Treasury, GBP 2.5 billion in cheaper loans have
been offered to over 16,000 businesses so far. Both banking
competition and access to non-bank finance are narrow Access to non-bank
lending remains largely restricted to bigger firms. UK bond
markets are comparatively well-developed for large companies, which rely more
strongly on wholesale debt markets than their counterparts in many other EU
countries. In the UK, in common with most of Europe, other firms primarily
finance investment through a combination of retained earnings and bank loans.
When the availability of bank loans dropped sharply in the crisis this consequently
had a greater impact on smaller firms, while larger firms were able to mitigate
the effects of the credit crunch by temporarily becoming more reliant on other
forms of finance. In the US, a wider range of firms use equity or the capital
markets directly, allowing them to bypass an impaired banking system. The Breedon
Task Force, commissioned by the government to inquire into alternatives to bank
funding for businesses, estimated a substantial ongoing financing gap over the
next five years, especially for SMEs. The government welcomed the report's
conclusions and a number of related initiatives are being considered or
implemented.[56] Competition in the
banking sector is also limited, which is more of a problem for SMEs. Evidence suggests that competition in UK
retail banking markets is low, with concentration levels rising markedly in the
wake of the financial crisis as the assets of distressed banks were taken over
by the government or rival banks. The government is attempting to help increase
competition in the banking sector through the divestiture of part of the branch
networks and loan books of large incumbent retail banks to challenger banks.
The government is also working with the banking industry to reduce switching
costs for bank accounts. The tension between
corporate deleveraging and access to credit is as much of a growth concern as a
stability one in the short term, but risks from a high debt stock remain The stock of UK
corporate debt is relatively high, but in the short term tight credit
conditions are as much of a problem as excessive debt. If banks
are seeking to reduce their balance sheets but hesitating to recognise losses
from a potentially stale stock of debt, it could both store up risks to
financial stability and prevent credit from being reallocated to more dynamic
and productive sectors of the economy. A fine balance has to be struck in order
to reconcile the longer term benefits of "creative destruction", and
the shorter term advantages of low insolvency rates supporting employment in a
weak domestic economy. There is also a tension between the need for a sound
banking system and the need to increase credit flows to fund investment.
3.2.2.
Housing policy and household debt
The 2012 in-depth review
of the UK concluded that high household debt constitutes an internal imbalance
in the UK economy. As discussed in Section 2.5, household debt grew
unsustainably in the boom years preceding the crisis. Commission services'
analysis suggests that between 2002 and 2007 the cumulative increase in UK
household debt above the sustainable path was 26pps. of GDP. Since 2008 real household
debt, which is mainly in the form of mortgages, has been falling gradually as
mortgage issuance has remained at unusually low levels (nominal household debt
has been broadly flat). Debt secured on a mortgage was almost 86% of total household
debt at the end of June 2012.[57]
Given that household debt levels remain high, there is a continuing need for
deleveraging. There is also a challenge to successfully reform the planning
system and housing market so that they deliver the housing supply the
population needs and are not a source of macroeconomic instability. However, as
discussed below, it is not clear that UK household debt is set to continue
falling as a share of GDP into the medium term. House prices
remain high relative to incomes and historical averages, supported by supply
fundamentals Real UK house prices
have fallen by 17% since 2007, but average nominal house prices have stayed
relatively flat through 2011 and 2012.[58] The high
level of UK household debt has been driven by house prices, which are still
elevated relative to incomes. Despite the fall in real house prices since 2007,
prices remain high and affordability is stretched. Graph 45 shows that, given
that the UK experienced among the largest house price increases in the EU in
the last upswing, the fall in real house prices since then has been relatively
modest. In many other member states prices have fallen further towards the
previous trough which is represented by the red line. A combination of high
inflation, low wage growth, high unemployment and tax-benefit changes has also
squeezed the disposable incomes of UK households. Consequently, as Graph 46
shows, the price of housing relative to income remains well above its long-term
average. As discussed elsewhere in this paper, severe supply constraints are
underpinning UK house prices. Due to planning restrictions the price of land
with permission for residential development is very high.[59] The UK was
unusual but not unique in seeing a house price boom without a supply response.[60] Graph 45: UK house price cycle compared to other EU Member States[61] || Graph 46: UK price to income ratio, 2006=100 || Source: Commission services, ECB, OECD, BIS. || Source: OECD However, the aggregate
picture on UK house price trends masks important regional variations. House
prices have tended to recover most in cities and regions with stronger
economies, growing populations and the most severe housing shortages.[62] For example,
nominal house prices in London are approximately 20% above their pre-crisis
peak. The prices of prime residential property have been especially strong,
driven in part by the weak pound and safe haven capital flows. In contrast,
house prices and levels of housing transactions in many poorer regions remain depressed.
This has exacerbated existing house price differentials and could both block
labour migration to areas of relatively high labour demand and mean that
problems associated with negative equity become concentrated primarily in
poorer parts of the country. Planning
reform has been enacted but construction remains weak and the longer term
impact is uncertain A new spatial planning
system that aims to create a presumption in favour of sustainable development
and simplify the planning system is now largely in place, but it has not fully bedded
down yet.
In addition to the new National Planning Policy Framework (NPPF), there will be
a major infrastructure fast track procedure to facilitate planning applications
for big projects. The measures announced in the 2011 Housing Strategy for
England[63]
are also being implemented, which include freeing up public sector land and
various financial incentives such as the New Homes Bonus, Community
Infrastructure Levy, Growing Places fund and a 'Get Britain Building' investment
fund. The government also recently announced the liberalisation of planning
rules to allow offices, which have high vacancy rates in much of the country,
to be converted into residential use. Housing completions
remain at historic lows and the level of new mortgage loans continues to be
held back by a weak domestic economy, impaired credit markets and policy
uncertainty and constraints. As Graph 47 shows, residential investment
remains low at 3.2% of GDP and building permits are still only running at approximately
half the level of 2005 and Graph 48 shows that the UK suffers from a
structurally low level of residential investment compared to its European
neighbours. Overall construction output (not just residential) fell by 11.2% in
the year to 2012 Q3 and is over 18% lower than the pre-recession peak.[64] The low level
of residential investment compared to the EU average is particularly notable
given the UK's relatively high rate of population growth and new household
formation. According to the UK's Office for National Statistics (ONS), in 2012 there
were 62.2 million people living in Britain, this is expected to reach 71.4
million by 2030. Official long term forecasts are for the number of households
in England alone to rise by 232,000 per year.[65]
This is well above the 146,000 dwellings completed in the UK in 2011-12. Linked
to the high cost of land, new dwellings in the UK are also small, even in
comparison to other densely populated countries. A new-build house is 38%
smaller in the UK than in Germany and 40% smaller than in the Netherlands.[66] This exacerbates
the shortage of living space. Graph 47: Residential investment and building permits[67] || Graph 48: Residential investment, % GDP || Source: Commission services || Source: EMF, ECB, Commission services It is also not yet clear
how far the reforms that the government has so far delivered or promised will
have the desired positive effect on housing supply. Some of the
government's reforms first caused further reductions in housing supply. For example,
when top-down housing supply targets in Regional Spatial Strategies were
abolished, the number of new dwellings targeted for construction across the
country fell by 272,720.[68]
Strong local political opposition to new housing remains in areas of high house
prices, and the financial incentives available to local authorities may not be
strong enough to overcome this. It also appears that the UK can only make
limited progress in addressing the housing supply shortage in the areas of
highest demand without developing parts of the current "green belt"
that restricts development around most of the UK's major cities. Many of the
major housing developers have made it clear to investors that they are
currently focused more on expanding margins than volumes,[69] which could
limit the positive impact of policies designed to boost housing supply in the
short to medium term. Capacity in the planning
system could also be a genuine constraint on development in coming years. Whether or
not decisions on planning applications are timely and efficient can make a
large difference to developers' risks and returns on potential residential
construction projects, and hence the quantity and cost of new housing. Planning
approvals have recently been running at very low levels.[70] Local
authorities are sharply cutting spending on administering the planning system
in response to cuts in their overall budgets, and the government has decided
against allowing local authorities to increase user charges for planning- and
housing-related services to reflect the full cost of the system. However, the
government has threatened to take decision-making powers away from local
authorities which are too slow to make planning decisions or take an
excessively anti-development approach. As well as leading to an
insufficient and ageing housing stock, UK planning rules also often heavily
restrict modernisation and refurbishment of the housing stock in many places. Insulation
of the housing stock in the UK also remains an issue which adds to energy costs
and locks in resource inefficiency for the future. Government has also
introduced a range of financial incentives to stimulate lending and development On 6 September 2012, the
government announced a list of new measures designed to increase the supply of
housing by making more financial incentives available. This was
accompanied by a temporary reduction in planning regulations for modifications
to houses. HM Treasury will put up GBP 10 billion in guarantees for newly-built
houses in order to reduce the borrowing costs of housing associations and
private developers. "Section 106 agreements" drawn up before the
crisis, which require developers to provide a set proportion of
"affordable" housing on a given site, will be removed in cases where the
cross-subsidy would now make the project unviable. The Local Government
Association estimate that there are plots for 400,000 homes on sites with
planning permission in England and Wales where development is yet to start.[71] The measures taken are
welcome additions to the government's plan for stimulating house building.
However, it is unclear if the government's agenda as a whole will be successful
in leading to many more homes being built. House builders contend
that there is a lack of affordable mortgages which is blocking the system. In
addition to the capacity constraints referred to above, significant scope for
local political opposition to block residential development remains. Mortgage
finance still restricted but debt write offs remain low In addition to a low
level of construction, the activity in the wider housing market also remains
subdued.
The housing market remains stuck in a low transaction equilibrium, as
affordability remains stretched for potential house purchasers, the
availability (if not cost) of mortgage finance has been a constraint, but there
have been relatively few forced sales. As Graph 49 shows, the number of loans
for house purchase has been quite stable for the last three years, at less than
half the rate before the crisis. The rate of re-mortgaging remains flat, at a
fraction of the levels seen before the crisis. There has also been a decrease
in households trading down, possibly reflecting the low transaction equilibrium
in which the housing market has been. There is some evidence that the cost of new
mortgages is starting to fall and the availability of mortgages with
loan-to-value (LTV) ratios of over 75% to increase,[72] possibly in
part due to the impact of the FLS. However, the vast majority of mortgages are
still at an LTV of less than 90%, and 65% are at an LTV of less than 75%.[73] At the end of
2011, the Financial Services Authority (FSA) announced its Mortgage Market
Review which aims to deter risky mortgage lending and ensure the sustainability
of the mortgage market. A policy statement[74]
was announced in October 2012 with most of the changes coming into effect in
April 2014. The main changes are that lenders are fully responsible for
determining the customers’ affordability even if an intermediary is used,
affordability assessments should allow for interest rate increases and
interest-only loans should only be available where there is a credible strategy
for repaying the mortgage. While the rate of
mortgage arrears and house repossessions did rise after the onset of the
crisis, they remain quite low. As shown in Graph 50, a little more of
than 1% of mortgages are in arrears and the annual repossession rate is below
0.5%. Both arrears and repossessions have remained much lower than the levels
they reached in the early to mid-1990s, when interest rates were much higher.
The Council of Mortgage Lenders[75]
forecasts arrears and repossessions to rise only very slightly over the next
two years, during which time interest rates are expected to remain low (see
Graph 58). As discussed in Section 3.2.3, there are risks that rising interest
rates, higher unemployment or possibly a house price crash could lead to a less
benign outcome. Graph 49: Approvals of loans secured on dwellings || Graph 50: Mortgage arrears and repossession rates || Source: Bank of England || Source: Department for Communities and Local Government Average interest costs fell
in the crisis, and most mortgages are now variable rate, but rates for high LTV
loans are much higher Average mortgage costs fell
following the base rate fall, then stabilised, but a minority of borrowers are
trapped on high rates. When the Bank of England cut the base
rate sharply at the onset of the crisis, from 5.75 in July 2007 to 0.5 in March
2009 where it has since remained, the gap between the average interest rate paid
on mortgages and the base rate increased sharply, even as average mortgage rates
fell. Before 2008, almost no mortgage holders paid more than 2 pp. above the base
rate, but since 2009 nearly half have been paying more than 3 pp. above base
rate.[76]
Initially, this was largely due to a substantial apportion of mortgage holders
being on fixed rates with interest rates dating from pre-crisis conditions. As
these fixed rate deals gradually expire, mortgage holders may either move onto
a variable rate or sign up for another fixed rate deal at lower post-crisis
interest rates. The proportion of mortgage holders who are currently on a
variable rate has increased from approximately half at the onset of the crisis
to more than 70%.[77] However, there has also
been the growth of a "dual" mortgage market where those taking out
new mortgages with a large deposit pay a much lower interest rate than people
with a high LTV, whether for new or older mortgages. As shown in
Graph 51, banks have been increasing their standard variable rates (SVRs),
which a growing proportion of mortgage holders are on, although the FLS may
help to halt or partially reverse this trend. Many people with a high LTV loan
are unable to re-mortgage because they are seen as too risky to be accepted by other
lenders and are therefore effectively "trapped" on the existing SVR.
Most of these mortgage holders would not be eligible for the various government
policies to aid first time buyers, purchases of new houses or loans for other
new mortgages. A higher cost and restricted availability for high LTV mortgages
is justified by the greater risk and the need for banks to hold more capital
against them, but the continued rise on SVRs could also be a reflection of an
appreciation by the banks that they have a captive market. Graph 51: Quoted interest rates on fixed rate and floating rate mortgages Source: Bank of England A rise in
household saving has not translated into more "active" deleveraging
by mortgage holders The household savings
rate picked up sharply from historically low levels in the pre-crisis years
(below 2% of GDP in 2007) as households increased their precautionary saving
and began deleveraging from high levels of cumulated debt. Although the
savings rate rose rapidly during the recent crisis, it had until recently
remained lower than in the aftermath of the recessions of the 1980s and 1990s,
as shown in Graph 52. The household savings rate picked up to 7.7% in the third
quarter of 2012, aided by stronger growth in total household incomes and
continued precautionary saving in an uncertain macroeconomic environment. Many
households that are not currently home owners are also likely to have increased
their saving on the expectation that they will now need to accumulate a larger
deposit before they can obtain a mortgage. Graph 52: Savings rate and growth in real household disposable income Source: Office for National Statistics Despite a higher saving
rate, the rate of "active" deleveraging by households making repayments
over and above regular mortgage servicing requirements does not appear to have
risen.[78] Although
debt servicing costs having fallen significantly for many borrowers, falling
real wages and an increased risk of unemployment have placed pressure on the
finances of many households. Unlike many other countries, mortgage interest is
not tax-deductible in the UK so there is no explicit tax incentive to avoid
paying off mortgages early. Unsecured
lending has stretched the finances of a minority of households The stock of non-secured
lending is limited in aggregate, but it contributes to financial pressure on
poorer households. Lower income households spend a larger
proportion of their incomes on debt repayments, although they are less likely
than higher-income households to be home owners.[79] Households
with debt in the bottom decile have four times their annual income in debt and
pay 47% of their gross monthly income in servicing this debt. Low income
households instead tend to have more unsecured debt, which is usually subject
to higher interest rates in part because it does not have property as
collateral. A 2011 NMG Consulting Survey found that of unsecured borrowers
benefiting from some form of forbearance, 47% said that they would be behind on
their debt repayments without the forbearance and that another 31% would only
be able to keep up payments with difficulty.[80] Only 28% of secured
borrowers receiving forbearance said they would be behind with their payments
without the forbearance, even though their debts tend to be larger. High housing
costs also put pressure on tenants, and renting is not seen as a desirable long
term option The UK home ownership
rate has been falling for the last decade as an increasing number of households
have been priced out of home ownership. The home ownership rate
has fallen from 70% in 2002 to 65% in 2011, while the proportion of households
renting privately has increased from 10% to 17% over the same period.[81] While there
have been some recent signs of a pick-up in mortgage market activity, much of
this appears to be for prime and buy-to-let lending.[82] The private
rented sector in the UK is dominated by short term, unsecure tenancies.[83] Tenancy
agreements tend to set for a relatively short fixed period, following which
they revert to a rolling basis (running on a week-to-week or month-to-month
basis). Notice is usually given on a one to six month basis. One reason for the
flexibility and dominance of short term tenancies in the private rental market
renting is that it has generally seen as a temporary solution with most people
having the aim of buying their own house at some point in the future. On average it is tenants
not home owners who have the highest housing costs relative to incomes. Graph 53
shows that the rate of home ownership in the UK is similar to the euro area
average, although home ownership has been falling in the UK. The average housing
cost overburden rate[84]
for UK owner-occupiers in 2008-2010 was only 10.6%, also similar to the euro
zone average, although this is currently being held down by low interest rates.
In contrast the housing cost overburden rate for tenants was 46.1% in 2010,
much higher than the EU average and reflecting the generally high cost of land
and housing in the UK. When the cost of renting rises it quickly impacts on
almost all tenants in a flexible private rental market like the UK, whereas a
rise in the cost of buying a house only directly affects the subsequent flow of
purchasers, not the existing stock of home owners. Graph 53: Housing tenure and housing cost overburden rates (2008-2010 average)[85] Source: Commission services Despite the financial
pressure on tenants, rents are still historically low relative to prices. As shown in
Graph 46 the house price-income ratio remains elevated. House prices are still
also high relative to rents, in common with some other EU Member States that
experienced large house price booms in the years to 2007. While UK house prices
have been relatively flat since 2010, rents have been increasing significantly.
An increasing number of households priced out of the option of home ownership
have been forced to rent privately, which in a context of a restricted housing
supply is pushing up rental prices despite the weakness in real income growth. Subsidies
for private rented housing provided through Housing Benefit have also acted to
increase effective demand and helped to bid up both private rental and sale
prices of housing in high demand locations, although this is starting to be
addressed by the government. Subsidies for tenants in scarce social housing are
also a barrier to labour mobility. If a combination of high house prices and
tighter lending standards persists, the role of long term private renting will
continue to expand, particularly for middle income households. Housing taxation still
characterised by major distortions The UK system combines a
regressive recurring tax (Council Tax) with a progressive transaction tax (Stamp
Duty Land Tax or SDLT). The government rejected the introduction of a
'mansion tax' which would levy taxes on higher value properties and partially
address the currently regressive structure of Council Tax. Two problems exist
with the current council tax system: the system is based on valuations linked
to the price of housing of 1991; and it is regressive as properties in the
lower valuation bands pay proportionally more tax relative to properties in
higher valuation bands. Tax bills are therefore not updated in line with house
price changes, which removes one potential means by which the volatility of
house prices might be reduced, as changes in tax liability should be
capitalised into house prices. SDLT is distortionary, discourages labour
mobility and is highly cyclical. SDLT revenues halved from 1% of GDP in 2007 to
0.5% in 2009, contributing disproportionately to the growth of the UK budget
deficit. Despite the pro-cyclicality of SDLT revenues, the sharp house prices
in the decade before the crisis suggest the tax was not effective in dampening
the house price cycle or preventing speculation when the market was rising. A
top 7% rate was introduced in March 2012 for the purchase of residential
properties worth over GBP 2 million (increased to 15% if purchased by certain
non-natural persons), but no wider reform has been carried out in this tax. Undeveloped
land is taxed on sale or transfer but not recurrently on its annual economic
value. There are some biases in
the UK tax system towards home ownership, but mortgage interest is not
deductible in the UK. Rental income is taxable in the UK while
imputed rents from owner-occupation are not. A combination of the exemption of
primary residences from capital gains tax, and the exemption of the first GBP 325,000
of bequests from inheritance tax (now effectively GBP 650,000 for couples),
means that capital gains from increases in house prices can be retained and
transmitted inter-generationally with relatively little taxation. Risks associated with a
minority of over-indebted households and structurally high house prices are
currently masked by low interest rates and forbearance Household debt is
currently falling due to low levels of new lending, and some further
deleveraging is likely in the short term, but in the medium to long term
household debt is likely to remain high. Despite falling by 17%
in real terms since 2008, UK house prices remain high relative to incomes,
supported by a shortage of housing supply and loose monetary policy. The
government has put in place a number of regulatory and fiscal measures aimed at
increasing residential construction, but it is not yet clear how effective
these will be in addressing housing supply shortages. A sharp fall in house
prices remains a possibility, but household debt is likely to pick up again in
the medium term, as housing transactions return to more normal levels, even if
many middle income households continue to be priced out of home ownership and
the distribution of net wealth remains polarised.
3.2.3.
What risks do private debt dynamics and
servicing costs pose to stability and growth?
Although the current
level of defaults is modest and debt servicing costs are manageable at an
aggregate level, a relatively high stock of private debt poses a number of
potential risks to both UK growth and to financial stability. A mix of
risk aversion and credit constraints should support some further overall
private sector deleveraging in the short term. However, there is a tension
between a need for higher gross credit flows to finance economic growth through
corporate investment and residential construction, and a need for deleveraging
and effective financial regulation to prevent the build-up of further
imbalances and financial sector risks in the future. Sustainable growth is also
an important part of ensuring that the ratios of UK debt to GDP, especially public
debt, remain sustainable and do not generate excessive risks to macroeconomic
stability. Reforms to
financial sector regulation should reduce future risks of irresponsible lending As Graph 54 shows, UK
banks are now better-capitalised than before the crisis hit and compare well
with international peers. The more stable financial position of UK banks
is reflected in three banks being among the five largest positive contributors
in the rise on the FTSE 100 index in 2012, although market value of the major
UK banks' share equity is still only two-thirds of the book value. The Bank of
England has acknowledged investor concerns that banks may have been
aggressively interpreting risk weights, implying that banks' capital buffers
may not be as large as the headline figures imply.[86] Graph 54: Banks' tier 1 capital ratios (%) Source: SNL financial, published accounts and Bank of England calculations The Financial Services
Bill, which would rearrange the UK's system of financial supervision, is in the
process of being agreed in the UK Parliament. Once implemented
day-to-day supervisory activity will move to the newly created Financial
Conduct Authority; the Prudential Regulatory Authority, responsible for
macro-prudential affairs, will sit inside the Bank of England; and the
Financial Policy Committee of macro-prudential experts will exist alongside the
Monetary Policy Committee at the top of the central bank to complement its
monetary role. While the authorities need to be alert and ready to respond to
any signals of excessive risky lending that could threaten future financial
stability, the economy would also benefit from a period of regulatory
stability. In the medium
term a normalisation of lending conditions could see household debt start to
rise again The insufficient and
rigid supply of housing in the UK continues to expose the country to higher and
volatile house prices, and consequently high household debt. As Graph 55
shows, the independent Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) forecast that
household debt will soon start to rise again relative to disposable incomes,
although at a much less rapid rate than seen before the crisis. As discussed in
Section 3.2.2, the fundamentals point to UK house prices remaining high
relative to incomes, and in the short term low interest rates are supporting
asset prices despite a weak domestic economy. A sustained and significant fall
in household debt is only likely if both house prices fall relative to
disposable income, and levels of home ownership continue to decline. Graph 55: UK household debt: 2009-2017 Source: Office for Budget Responsibility The optimal scenario for
the short and long term growth and stability of the UK economy would be a
gradual elimination of the housing shortage accompanied by house prices falling
gradually in real terms, without sharp nominal price falls. However, as
discussed above, it is unclear how far housing supply will expand, and UK house
prices have historically been unstable. Rapid house price falls would risk
pushing many households into negative equity and create negative wealth
effects. In contrast, significant house price rises would increase risks to
macroeconomic stability while also pushing up household debt levels. If credit is
too tight it could harm the prospects for addressing the UK's investment
deficit The UK also has a need
for increased investment, which would not be helped by rapid deleveraging or
tight credit conditions. The challenge must be balanced with the need to
reduce the risk of future debt-related instability in the UK macroeconomy. An
unprecedented drop in business investment after 2007 saw the UK level of gross
fixed capital formation as a share of GDP fall to 14.3% in 2011, the third
lowest level in the EU-27. All types of private investment (business,
residential and infrastructure) continue to be very weak in the UK. This is holding back
short-term growth, preventing the "rebalancing" of the UK economy
from consumption and debt towards investment and net exports, and exacerbating
existing weaknesses (of low capital stock, housing shortage and inadequate and
congested infrastructure). The UK also risks losing the capacity to
cost-effectively ramp up investment later if a combination of weak demand and
tight credit conditions continues to drive low investment and a loss of
construction capacity. UK investment needs in transport and energy
infrastructure, and related government initiatives, are discussed in Section
3.1.2. There are specific
issues with the structure of the residential construction market and the
incentives for developers that may be reducing the response of housing supply
to market signals and to housing policy. As land is expensive
and developers typically purchase the land on which they subsequently build, a large
part of developers' profitability rests on how successfully they play the land
market and negotiate the planning system. This creates significant barriers to
entry but also often creates incentives for developers to hang on to
undeveloped land with planning permission, rather than building on it as soon
as possible, either in the hope of future price rises or in order to avoid
having to write down the value of land bought in the run up to the crisis when
land prices were higher than they are now.[87] It is currently the
stated policy of most major residential developers to build margins rather than
market share, which risks diverting government subsidies into the profits of
developers or into higher house prices, rather than into a net increase in
housing supply. Developers' share prices have recently increased significantly
without an increase in construction volumes.[88]
Developers have also expressed concerns that increased capital requirements for
bank financing commercial real estate could reduce new development in that
sector.[89] Excessive and
prolonged forbearance could harm stability and growth One of the aims of loose
monetary policy is to aid short-term growth by preventing excessively rapid
deleveraging in the short term, but this risks harming the functioning of the
economy if it persists for too long. In particular, in a
climate of low interests rates and incentives for banks to delay calling in or
writing down loans that are unlikely to be paid back, there is a risk that
large parts of banks' loan books become "ossified", crowding out new
lending, and that bank balance sheets continue to carry hidden risks. As
discussed above, the data suggest that turnover in the loans stock is low and
falling, driven by a weakness in new lending.[90] There is some evidence
of "zombie" firms which continue operating despite having little
prospect of paying off their stock of debt, aided by a low interest environment. R3, the
insolvency industry trade body, found that 160,000 companies are only able to
pay the interest on their debt but do not see a prospect of being able to pay
back the principal, and the number is rising.[91] Corporate
insolvencies have remained low in the UK, despite more firms reporting that
they are loss-making, as shown in Graph 56. If banks are seeking to reduce
their balance sheets but hesitating to recognise losses from a potentially
stale stock of debt, it could both store up risks to financial stability and
prevent credit from being reallocated to more dynamic and productive sectors of
the economy. It could also contribute to low productivity as weaker firms fail
to exit the market. Evidence from the ONS[92]
shows a widening of the dispersion of productivity performance across firms in
2008 and 2009, with a possible weakening of competitive pressure contributing
to this. More recent data on firm level productivity is not available but in a
climate of weak growth, weak investment and low insolvencies, it is likely that
high firm-level dispersion of productivity has persisted. Graph 56: Company liquidations in England and Wales and an estimate of loss-making companies Source: Bureau van Dijk, The Insolvency Service and Bank of England calculations Note: 2012 figure estimated based on data for Q1 and Q2 There is also
a risk that access to finance policies could subsidise increased bank profits
or private sector gearing more than growth Access to finance
policies need to be carefully designed and monitored to ensure they benefit
investment and growth without increasing potential macroeconomic instability or
subsidising banks or healthy firms. The FLS is incentivised
by scale but not by sector or firm size. There is a risk that individual banks
and building societies take advantage of the scheme without actually increasing
their lending to credit constrained firms. If housing supply
remains constrained there is also a risk that the FLS ends up channelling money
into bank margins, wealthier households or inflating the price of existing
housing. Mortgage
lending on existing houses is included in the FLS, not just lending to finance construction
or business investment. It is therefore at least as much of a demand side as a
supply side policy operating in a market with constrained supply. On the one
hand, there are currently relatively few attractive investment options for
households, and property retains a number of tax advantages, as set out in
Section 3.1.2 Bank of England evidence[93]
suggests banks are looking to expand their volume of secured lending but are
reluctant to loosen the scoring criteria that have limited loan availability to
households without large deposits. On the other hand, the FLS and other
drivers of lower bank funding costs do appear to be leading to reductions in
the cost of credit for less risky borrowers, which may lead to either an increase
in remortgaging or bidding up the prices that the existing pool of eligible
borrowers are able to pay for housing. A rise in interest rates
could cause a shake out of non-performing loans and hit the macroeconomy, but
does not look imminent Write-offs of all forms
of debt rose after the onset of the crisis as shown in Graph 57, though much
less for mortgages than other forms of debt. While the fall in
interest rates in 2008-2009 reduced debt servicing costs for most borrowers
significantly, a moderate increase in insolvencies and unemployment led to
unavoidable defaults. Write-offs rose most for consumer credit, where as
discussed in Section 3.2.2, a minority of households have very high debt
servicing costs although consumer credit is a small share of overall lending
and poses limited risks to financial and macroeconomic stability. Despite
forbearance, the defaults rate on NFC loans has also risen. Given forecasts
that the UK economic recovery will continue to be muted, the Bank of England is
not expected to significantly increase the base rate for some time. As shown in
Graph 58 market expectations are that the bank base rate will still be below 1%
until 2015. There are however two potential risks from the high private debt
stock when interest rates do rise. If interest rates rose sharply, it would
risk making the interest burdens of large numbers of households and businesses
unsustainable, as happened when official interest rates peaked in the early
1990s. This could generate business insolvencies, repossessions and significant
losses for the banking system. A large stock of variable rate private debt also
means that the sensitivity of aggregate debt servicing costs as a share of GDP
to interest rate changes has increased. Graph 57: Write off rates on lending to UK businesses and individuals || Graph 58: Bank of England base rate and forward market expectations || Source: Bank of England || Source: Bank of England and Bloomberg Mortgage defaults have
been modest to date but could increase in the future if unemployment or
interest rates rise. As discussed in Section 3.2.2, mortgage arrears
and defaults have remained relatively low since the crisis, in contrast with
some other European countries that saw housing market busts. Real wages have
been weak but most people who remain in work have been able to meet mortgage
repayments, which have often fallen significantly as a result of lower interest
rates. Except for the depths of the recession, redundancies have not been especially
high. On the whole, it is the youth and those who are currently excluded from
the option of home ownership who have been hit hardest by the recession and
muted recovery. Fewer existing homeowners have suffered from long term
unemployment. However, if unemployment does rise overall it could lead to
increased mortgage defaults. While interest rates may not rise until the
economy and labour market are strengthening, households whose income has fallen
permanently as a result of the crisis may get into difficulty when interest
rates rise back towards historical norms. This may for example include people
who lost their previous job and have had to move into a lower paying sector or
post, or households that have moved from having two earners to one earner. Households
with high LTVs who are stuck on standard variable rates with limited scope to
remortgage could be especially vulnerable.
3.2.4.
Conclusions
The level of household
debt remains high and constitutes an imbalance. There has been some progress in
deleveraging in both the corporate and household sectors but there is a tension
between needs for further deleveraging and for improved access to credit to
fuel an investment-led recovery. Aggregate debt service costs are
sustainable at current low interest rates thus short term pressures are low,
but the high stock of household debt poses potential risks to both UK growth
and to financial stability when interest rates rise. To date household deleveraging
has been driven more by a low level of new lending than by an increase in the
rate at which existing debt stocks are paid or written off. The financial
sector has returned to relative stability following the crisis and, although
large, the balance sheets of UK banks are not expanding rapidly. There is a
tension between a need for higher gross credit flows to finance economic growth
through corporate investment and residential construction, and a need for
deleveraging and effective financial regulation to prevent the maintenance and
future build-up of imbalances and financial sector risks. Low interest rates
have partially masked the issue of a significant minority of very highly
indebted households, and there is a risk of a sharp increase in mortgage
arrears if official or effective interest rise significantly, or unemployment rises.
Overall, it is currently unlikely that households will in aggregate see
sustained strong deleveraging. 4. Policy
challenges The analysis in Sections
2 and 3 indicates that developments in external competitiveness and the need
for both deleveraging and safeguarding financial stability, without unduly
hampering growth, are the main challenges relating to macroeconomic imbalances
in the UK. It should be recalled
that these challenges were identified under the MIP in the first IDR and
relevant policy responses were reflected and integrated in the country-specific
recommendations issued for the UK in July 2012. The assessment of progress in
the implementation of those recommendations will take place in the context of
the assessment of the UK National Reform Programme and Convergence Programme
under the 2013 European Semester. Against this background, this section
discusses different avenues that could be envisaged to address the challenges
identified in this IDR. Concerning the challenge
of improving external competitiveness, a number of different avenues can be
considered as regards: Investment in
infrastructure: as set out in this review and in line with Council
recommendations issued in 2012[94],
there is significant scope for the UK to improve its transport infrastructure
by addressing shortages in airport and seaport capacity, tackling road
congestion and upgrading its rail network. In the first instance, this would
entail meeting the substantial transport infrastructure investment needs indicated
in the National Infrastructure Plan 2011, much of which are currently unfunded,
by identifying additional sources of funding, addressing high unit costs in
transport in the UK, and removing regulatory barriers to investment. In order
to reconcile the need for increased investment in infrastructure with the
budgetary constraints arising from consolidation needs, the UK authorities
could endeavour to harness private funding by introducing user pricing schemes where
appropriate, and by relying on the strength of the government's balance sheet
to provide guarantees. Careful design and implementation of such schemes is
crucial to safeguard their value for money. This would call for a clear
division of risks between public and private sectors, and an avoidance of other
deficiencies identified in previous private finance initiatives. Skill gaps: exporters
require a labour force with the right skills. Intermediate and advanced technical
skills are an area where evidence suggests that gaps and recruitment
difficulties persist. As set out in this review, labour productivity growth in
manufacturing has been slow in the UK and lags behind that of other advanced economies.
Effective implementation of the national apprenticeship programme could help
close the skills gap. This would require apprenticeships to be high quality and
to equip participants with the skills needed by the tradable sectors of the
economy. There is scope for further cooperation between the Government and
employers to increase the number of apprenticeships and foster work-based
experience. Appropriately addressing the related 2012 Council recommendation on
young people's skills and early school leaving (which is comparatively high in
the UK) would also contribute positively in this regard. Finally, reinforcing
the role of science, engineering and foreign languages in educational curricula
could also help the educational system meet the needs of employers, in
particular in export-oriented sectors. Access to
finance: difficulties
in accessing finance are a cross-cutting problem at the current juncture,
particularly for smaller and younger companies. They could be addressed at an
economy-wide level, as well as with regard to the specific financing instruments
for exporting companies. The UK authorities have implemented a number of
initiatives which respond to the 2012 Council recommendations on access to
finance. Some of these initiatives are still embryonic, such as the British
Business Bank and, as discussed below, the Funding for Lending Scheme (FLS).
Overall, cross-cutting measures promoting access to finance can foster entry
into, and expansion of, the exporting sector, which has become more attractive
following the post-crisis depreciation of sterling. Measures promoting
financing instruments that are specific to the exporting sector could also be
strengthened, subject to state aid rules. Other
elements: the
external performance of the UK economy is affected by a multitude of other
factors, some of which can be shaped by policy action. The geographical
composition of UK exports continues to reorient itself towards faster-growing
markets, and the initiatives of government bodies such as UK Trade and
Investment can continue to have positive effects in this regard. There is also
scope to further reinforce the links between the strong UK research base and industrial
sectors. Finally, the UK witnessed strong unit labour cost (ULC) dynamics in
the pre-crisis years. In order to maintain the price competitiveness of the UK
economy, it is desirable that ULC growth does not outpace productivity gains. Concerning the challenge
linked to the needs for deleveraging, maintaining
financial stability and avoiding unduly compromising investment and growth, there are a
number of issues that can be considered: Increasing
residential construction: alleviating the housing shortage over the
medium term would reduce the risk of imbalances related to high house prices
and consequently household debt persisting into the long term. This could be
achieved by a combination of ensuring that interpretation of the new planning
system is clear and that it is effectively resourced, further simplifying the
planning system, relaxing green belt restrictions that prevent development of
new land in many of the areas of highest demand, increasing the fiscal
incentives given to local communities that allow development, and potentially a
land value tax. Undeveloped land with planning permission, which is not
currently subject to recurrent taxes as the system focuses on taxing existing
property, could also be taxed on its imputed economic rent on an annual basis.
This could help incentivise developers to build housing rather than hold onto
undeveloped land with planning permission in the hope of a rise in land values.
The government could also look for ways to promote greater competition in the
residential development sector by lowering barriers to entry and changing the
incentives for firms. The UK sector is dominated by firms which both purchase
land and build property. The UK authorities could look at further options for
encouraging higher volumes of self-build construction projects, as are seen in
many other European countries, although reducing the barriers imposed by the
planning system will be key. Property
taxation:
the UK system combines a regressive recurring tax (Council Tax) with a
progressive transaction tax (the Stamp Duty Land Tax or SDLT). The recurrent taxation
of land and property ownership is in general relatively economically efficient but
there is some scope to reform UK property taxes to make the system as a whole
less distortionary and regressive. Transaction-based property taxation could
discourage speculation, but it also involves significant distortions and can
generate highly cyclical revenues. Reform of Council Tax could be considered so
that it both reflects current property values (the system is now linked to the
price of housing in 1991) and is paid as a fixed percentage of the property
value rather than the existing regressive system of bands. This could be done
in combination with a broader land value tax as noted above. Such reforms could
improve the functioning of the housing market and the efficiency of the tax
system, promote better labour mobility and efficient capital allocation. It
could also potentially contribute to fiscal consolidation if net revenues
increased. There would be some risks involved in raising property taxes for
households with existing problems servicing their mortgages in an environment
of low liquidity, but this is unlikely to include many of the higher income,
high net wealth households that would predominantly be affected by a flatter
rate Council Tax replacement. Rental
market:
a combination of high house prices, stretched household finances and more
responsible lending criteria are likely to continue to exclude many middle
income households from the option of home ownership. Subsidies for private
rented housing provided through Housing Benefit have acted to increase
effective demand and helped to bid up both private rental and sale prices of
housing in high demand locations, although this is starting to be addressed by
the government. Subsidies for tenants in scarce social housing are also a barrier
to labour mobility. The private rental market is currently dominated by short
term, unsecure tenancies. Long-term private renting could be made more
attractive as a long term option by improving the current rental framework so
as to promote greater use of longer term contracts that give more security to
tenants, and by a further professionalisation of the sector. This could improve
the welfare of households who rent and help tackle high levels of household
debt by reducing the pressure that UK households often feel to borrow heavily
to get on the property ladder as soon as possible. Financial
stability: economic policy as a whole needs to carefully balance a
pressing need for new lending to support investment and growth, with a long
term need for deleveraging and macroeconomic and financial stability. In the
short term, loose monetary policy remains appropriate in a context of weak
domestic and external demand, but this should not be at the cost of allowing
existing imbalances to remain unresolved indefinitely. The government's focus
on broader actions to improve access to finance is also appropriate given that
credit constraints are contributing to low investment and weak growth. For the
FLS and other access to finance policies to maximise their impact they need to
focus as far as possible on supporting an increase in productive investment
rather than bidding up the price of existing assets. Action to address the
problems of companies with limited prospects of paying back their outstanding
debts and hidden risks in bank balance sheets – namely through higher levels of
provisioning by banks and, possibly, further company debt restructurings –
could both deal with risks to the stability of the financial system and support
the reallocation of resources through investment in more productive firms and
sectors. Effectively addressing the recommendation of the interim Financial
Policy Committee[95]
that banks need to assess more realistically their true capital adequacy ratios
could help dissipate concerns about hidden risks in banks' balance sheets. This
would imply taking action to ensure that bank capital and provisions reflect
proper asset valuations and that a realistic assessment of expected losses and
a prudent calculation of risk weights are applied. References: Altomonte,
C., Aquilante, T. and Ottaviano, G. I. P., ‘The triggers of competitiveness -
The EFIGE cross-country report’, 2012 Bank of
England, ‘Credit Conditions Survey – 2012 Q4’, January 2013a Bank of
England, ‘Trends in Lending’, January 2013b Bank of
England, ‘Inflation Report February 2013’, 2013c Bank of
England, ‘NMG Consulting Survey’, 2012a Bank of England,
‘Credit Conditions Survey – 2012 Q3’, September 2012b Bank of
England, ‘Financial Stability Report’, November 2012c Bank of
England, ‘Mortgage Approvals’, December 2012d Bank of England,
‘Understanding recent developments in UK external trade’, Quarterly Bulletin,
Q4 2011 Ben Broadbent, ‘Deconstruction,
speech to Lancaster University Management School’, 29th October 2012 British Chambers of
Commerce, ‘Exporting is good for Britain and exporters need skills’, 2012a British Chambers of
Commerce, ‘The energy market: business requires security’, 2012b Centre for Cities, ‘Cities
Outlook 2013’, January 2013 Cheshire, P. C. and
Hilber C. A. L., ‘Office space supply restrictions in Britain: the political
economy of market revenge’, The Economic Journal 118, June 2008 Confederation of British
Industry and KPMG, ‘Infrastructure Survey 2012’, September 2012 Consensus Forecasts,
Survey Report, 14 January 2013 Council of Mortgage
Lenders, ‘Housing and mortgage forecasts’, December 2012 Council of the European
Union, ‘Council Recommendation of 10 July 2012 on the National Reform Programme
2012 of the United Kingdom and delivering a Council opinion on the Convergence
Programme of the United Kingdom, 2012-2017’, Official Journal of the
European Union (2012/C 219/27) Department for Business,
Innovation and Skills, ‘Industrial strategy: UK sector analysis’, BIS
Economics Paper no. 18, September 2012a Department for Business,
Innovation and Skills, ‘Implementing the recommendations from the Breedon
Review – a progress report’, November 2012b Department for
Communities and Local Government, ‘House Building: December Quarter 2012,
England’, February 2013 Department for
Communities and Local Government, ‘Table 101 Dwelling stock: by tenure, United
Kingdom’, December 2012 Department for Work and
Pensions, ‘Pensions and Growth: Whether to smooth assets and liabilities in
scheme funding valuations; Whether to introduce a new statutory objective for
the Pensions Regulator; A call for evidence’, January 2013 Deutsche Bank, ‘UK Building
Sector - What to expect from the Q4 12 results’, February 2013 EEF, ‘Executive Survey
2013’, January 2013 EEF and JAM, ‘Skills for
Growth: A More Productive and Flexible Labour Force’, 2012 European Central Bank
and European Commission, ‘Access to Finance – Analytical Report’, September
2009 European Central Bank
and European Commission, ‘SMEs' Access to Finance - Survey 2011’, December 2011 European Commission, ‘Employment
and Social Developments in Europe 2012’, 2012a European Commission,
‘Key areas: comparing Member States' performances, SME access to finance, http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/making-it-happen/key-areas/index_en.htm,
2012b European Commission,
‘Key areas: comparing Member States' performances, Network industries –
Transport’, http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/making-it-happen/key-areas/index_en.htm,
2012c European Commission, ‘Macroeconomic
imbalances – Sweden, Occasional Papers 108, July 2012d European Commission, ‘Macroeconomic
imbalances – United Kingdom’, Occasional Papers 110, July 2012e European Commission, ‘Report
from the Commission, Alert Mechanism Report – 2013’, 2012f European Commission, ‘Research
and Innovation performance in EU Member States and Associated countries –
Innovation Union progress at country level’, 2012g European Commission,
‘Internationalisation of European SMEs’, 2010 Federation of Small
Businesses, ‘Voice of Small Business Index’, Q4 2012 Field, S. and Franklin,
M., 'Micro-data perspectives on the UK productivity conundrum', Office for
National Statistics, January 2013. Financial Policy
Committee, ‘Record of the Interim Financial Policy Committee Meeting – 21
November 2012’, December 2012 Financial Services
Authority, ‘Mortgage Market Review – feedback on CP11/31 and final rules’, October
2012a Financial Services
Authority, ‘FSA statistics on mortgage lending’, December 2012b Financial Times, ‘Zombie
companies stalk UK economy’, November 18, 2012 Financial Times, ‘FSA
clampdown sparks friction’, January 16, 2013a Financial Times, ‘House
builders enjoy state backed boom’, January 22, 2013b Hilber, C. and
Vermeulen, W., ‘The Impact of Supply Constraints on House Prices in England’,
September 2012 HM Government, ‘Laying
the Foundations: A housing strategy for England’, November 2011 HM Treasury, ‘Autumn
Statement 2012’, December 2012 Home Builders
Federation, ‘Housing Pipeline Report – Q3 2012 report’, December 2012 IMF, ‘Changing Patterns
of Global Trade’, June 2011 Local Government
Association, ‘An analysis of unimplemented planning permissions for residential
dwellings’, September 2012 Morton, A., ‘Why aren’t
we building enough attractive new homes?’, Policy Exchange, September 2012a Morton, A., ‘Planning
for Less: The impact of abolishing regional planning’, Policy Exchange, December
2012b Office for Budget
Responsibility, ‘Economic and Fiscal Outlook’, December 2012 Office for National
Statistics, ‘International Comparisons of Productivity - Final Estimates for 2011’,
February 2013a Office for National
Statistics, ‘Profitability of UK Companies, Q3 2012’, January 2013b Office for National
Statistics, ‘ONS House Price Index’, November 2012a Office for National
Statistics, ‘Quarterly National Accounts Q3 2012’, December 2012b Office for National
Statistics, ‘Household Projections, 2008 to 2033, England’, 2010 OECD, ‘Measuring
Innovation: A New Perspective’, 2010 OECD, ‘OECD Economic
Surveys: United Kingdom’, 2013 R3, ‘Today's official
insolvency figures - decreasing insolvency’, February 2013 Reinold, K., ‘Housing
equity withdrawal since the financial crisis’, Bank of England Quarterly
Review, 2011 Q2 Richard, D., ‘The
Richard Review of Apprenticeships’, November 2012 Rubini, L., Desmet, K.,
Piguillem, F. and Crespo, A., ‘Breaking down the barriers to firm growth in
Europe - The fourth EFIGE policy report’, 2012 Shelter, ‘A better deal:
Towards more stable private renting’, September 2012 Statistics Sweden,
‘Housing Statistics in the European Union 2004’, 2005 Weale, M., ‘The Balance
of Payments’ (speech given at the Warwick Economics Summit 2013), February 2013 The World Bank and the
International Finance Corporation, ‘Doing Business 2013’, 2013 Whittaker, M., ‘On
borrowed time?’, Resolution Foundation, December 2012 World Economic Forum,
‘The Global Competitiveness Report 2012-2013’, 2012 [1] Eurostat definition for total unemployment:
less than 25 years and 25-74 years. [2] Less than 25 years. [3] Forecasts stem from the Commission
services' 2013 Winter Forecast. [4] It should be noted that Further Education
Corporations and Sixth Form College Corporations in England were classified as
public sector until March 2012 and as private sector from June 2012. These
educational bodies employed 196,000 people in March 2012 and the
reclassification therefore results in a large fall in public sector employment
and a corresponding large increase in private sector employment between March
and June 2012. [5] Eurostat definition: 15-64 years. [6] Eurostat definition: 15-64 years. [7] Although the scoreboard indicator on market
shares is measured in value terms and is thus affected by movements in the
sterling exchange rate, section 3.1 shows that export shares in volume terms also
decreased markedly when controlling for the offsetting and largely coincident
effects of a depreciation in sterling in 2008-2009 and an increase in prices by
UK exporters. [8] It should be noted that initial estimates
of foreign income flows are uncertain and subject to revision. [9] Office for Budget Responsibility (2012). [10] The stock market is counted in part as
foreign liabilities, reflecting foreign equity investment in UK companies. [11] HM Treasury (2012). [12] Apart from taking over the Royal Mail
pension fund in April 2012, which reduced the deficit by 1.8 pp. that year and
the sale of 4G mobile phone licences in March 2013, which reduced the deficit
by 0.1pp. approx., both one-off effects, the government also decided to
transfer the excess cash held at the Bank of England's Asset Purchase Facility
to the general government accounts. The treatment of this transfer, including
the expected future flow of the coupon payments on the gilts had not been
confirmed by Eurostat at the time of the forecast and therefore does not
feature in the Commission services’ Winter forecast. [13] Bank of England (2013b). [14] Bank of England (2013b). [15] European Commission (2012d). [16] Whittaker (2012). [17] Hilber and Verleulen (2012). [18] Department for Communities and Local
Government (2013). [19] Nominal and
real house price index (2005=100). Year-on-year change in the loans for house
purchase granted by MFIs (as a % of GDP). Source: Eurostat, ECB. [20] European Commission (2012e). [21] European Commission (2012f). [22] Behavioural effects on export quantities
are ignored. Controlling additionally for these effects would mean a larger
drop in estimated market shares in recent years. [23] The average estimate for the price
elasticity of UK exports has been estimated at -0.4, the same as the price
elasticity of imports. By contrast, the income elasticities of exports and
imports tend to be higher and are often found to be unitary. See Bank of
England (2011). [24] EEF (2013). [25] The overlap was calculated using the
Finger-Kreinin index. It is based on the number of HS 6-digit products that are
exported to the rest of the world, and that both China and the UK export. [26] More than half of cars exported by the UK
go to non-EU markets, whereas the equivalent figures for France, Italy and
Spain range between 10% and 30%. [27] Data from DG ECFIN's Sectoral Performance
Indicators database, which is based on public sources. [28] See Altomonte et al (2012). [29] See ONS (2013b). [30] As measured by business enterprise R&D
expenditure in market services as a share of the value added in market
services. [31] European Commission (2012g) [32] OECD (2013). [33] See the 2012 in-depth review for the UK
(European Commission, 2012e) [34] See Cheshire et al. (2008). [35] European Commission (2010). [36] IMF (2011). [37] OECD (2010). [38] European Commission
(2012c). [39] European Commission (2012c). [40] HM Treasury (2012). [41] EEF and JAM (2012) [42] British Chambers of Commerce (2012a) [43] See Richard (2012). [44] See European Central Bank and European
Commission (2009, 2011). [45] For a recent survey see Federation of Small
Businesses (2012). [46] For a complementary assessment of
competitiveness developments in the pre-crisis and the initial post-crisis
years including issues not dealt at length in this review see the 2012 in-depth
review of the UK economy (European Commission, 2012e). [47] Department for Work and Pensions (2013). [48] Gross
operating surplus captures the excess of production over intermediate costs and
compensation of employees (it includes also remuneration of capital for SMEs).
Gross entrepreneurial income adds net interests and dividend received. Retained
earnings correspond to the savings of non-financial corporations. [49] See Broadbent (2012). [50] Financial sector debt is considered
separately from the concept of private sector debt in this Review and in the
scoreboard indicator. [51] Financial Policy Committee (2012). [52] In partnership with HM Treasury in the case
of the FLS. [53] 4 March 2013. [54] Bank of England (2013c). [55] Bank of England, (2013a). [56] Department for Business, Innovation and
Skills (2012b). [57] Bank of England. [58] Office for National Statistics (2012a). [59] Hilber and Vermeulen (2012). [60] See Broadbent (2012). [61] The cumulated
real house price growth from the latest trough to the latest peak is plotted
against the adjustment from the latest peak to the latest data available
(Q2-2012 in this case). Some countries for which the house price time series
are too short and thus do not allow to identify the trough are excluded. [62] Centre for Cities (2013). [63] HM Government (2011). [64] Office for National Statistics (2012b). [65] Office for National Statistics (2010). [66] Statistics Sweden (2005). [67] Residential
investment is a flow measure which could be used as a proxy for the change in
residential supply. Building permits are a leading indicator, showing how new
construction is going to evolve in the near future. [68] Morton (2012). [69] Deutsche Bank (2013). [70] Home Builders Federation (2012). [71] Local Government Association (2012). [72] Bank of England (2012d). [73] Financial Services Authority (2012b). [74] Financial Services Authority (2012a). [75] Council of Mortgage Lenders (2012). [76] Financial Services Authority (2012). [77] Financial Services Authority (2012). [78] Reinold (2011). [79] Whittaker (2012). [80] Bank of England (2012a). [81] Department for Communities and Local
Government (2012). [82] Bank of England (2013a). [83] Shelter (2012). [84] The housing cost overburden rate is the %
of the population living in households where the total housing costs ('net' of
housing allowances) represent more than 40 % of disposable income ('net' of
housing allowances). [85] The left hand side illustrates housing cost
overburden rate, The right side shows the percentage of low and high income
population owning a house. Low income is defined to be below the 6th decile and
high income above the 6th decile of the distribution. [86] Bank of England (2012c). [87] Morton (2012a). [88] Financial Time (2013b). [89] Financial Times (2013a). [90] Bank of England (2013b). [91] R3 (2013). [92] Field and Franklin (2013). [93] Bank of England (2012a). [94] The Council recommendations mentioned in
this section refer to Recommendation 2012/C 219/27 as published in the Official
Journal of the European Union. [95] Financial Policy Committee (2012).