This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52012SC0031
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Accompanying document to theProposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the freezing and confiscation of proceeds of crime in the European UnionIMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Accompanying document to theProposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the freezing and confiscation of proceeds of crime in the European UnionIMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Accompanying document to theProposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the freezing and confiscation of proceeds of crime in the European UnionIMPACT ASSESSMENT
/* SWD/2012/0031 - COD/2012/0036 */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Accompanying document to theProposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the freezing and confiscation of proceeds of crime in the European UnionIMPACT ASSESSMENT /* SWD/2012/0031 - COD/2012/0036 */
TABLE OF CONTENTS 1........... Introduction.................................................................................................................... 2 2........... Procedural issues and
consultation of interested parties.................................................... 2 2.1........ Chronology of the Impact
Assessment and results of consultations................................... 2 2.1.1..... Policy context................................................................................................................. 2 2.1.2..... Organisation and timing................................................................................................... 2 2.1.3..... Consultation of interested parties..................................................................................... 2 2.2........ Consultation of the Impact
Assessment Board................................................................. 2 3........... The recovery of criminal assets
explained........................................................................ 2 3.1........ The asset recovery process............................................................................................. 2 3.2........ Fundamental questions of the
asset confiscation and recovery process.............................. 2 3.3........ Asset recovery in the Member
States and existing EU legal framework............................ 2 4........... Problem definition........................................................................................................... 2 4.1........ Insufficient recovery of criminal
assets in the EU.............................................................. 2 4.2........ Components of the problem............................................................................................ 2 4.2.1..... Inadequate powers for confiscating
criminal assets........................................................... 2 4.2.2..... Inadequate powers for preserving
criminal assets pending confiscation............................. 2 4.2.3..... Inadequate powers for enforcing
confiscation orders between Member States (mutual recognition) 2 4.2.4..... Powers for confiscation,
preservation and enforcement are underutilised........................... 2 4.2.5..... Member States lack tools to
maximise social utility from recovered assets (Redistribution) 2 4.3........ How would the problem evolve, all
things being equal?.................................................... 2 4.4........ The EU's right to act and
subsidiarity............................................................................... 2 4.4.1..... Conferral of power......................................................................................................... 2 4.4.2..... Legal basis .................................................................................................................... 2 4.5........ Fundamental rights.......................................................................................................... 2 5........... Policy objectives............................................................................................................. 2 6........... Policy options................................................................................................................. 2 6.1........ Identification and screening of
"policy actions"................................................................. 2 6.2........ Discarded policy actions................................................................................................. 2 6.3........ Policy actions grouped into
policy options....................................................................... 2 6.3.1..... Policy option 1 – Status quo........................................................................................... 2 6.3.2..... Policy option 2 – Non-legislative
option.......................................................................... 2 6.3.3..... Policy option 3 – Minimal
legislative option...................................................................... 2 6.3.4..... Policy option 4.1 – Maximal
legislative option without mutual recognition......................... 2 6.3.5..... Policy option 4.2 – Maximal
legislative option including mutual recognition....................... 2 7........... Analysis of the impacts of the
policy options.................................................................... 2 7.1........ Analysis of Option 1 - Status Quo................................................................................... 2 7.2........ Analysis of Option 2 –
Non-legislative option.................................................................. 2 7.3........ Analysis of Option 3 – Minimal
legislative option............................................................. 2 7.4........ Analysis
of Option 4.1 - Maximal legislative option without
mutual recognition.................. 2 7.5........ Analysis of Option 4.2 - Maximal
legislative option including mutual recognition................ 2 8........... Comparing the policy options.......................................................................................... 2 8.1........ Comparison of options and
justification for choosing the preferred option......................... 2 8.2........ Proportionality and subsidiarity
of the preferred option..................................................... 2 9........... Implementation, monitoring and
Evaluation...................................................................... 2 Annex 1. Summary of fieldwork of the
external IA study............................................................. 47 Annex 2. Confiscation statistics................................................................................................... 49 Annex 3. List of EU-level actions.................................................................................................. 2 Annex 4. Asset recovery in the UK............................................................................................. 58 Annex 5. EU27 profitability model.............................................................................................. 72 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Accompanying document to the
Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL
on the freezing and confiscation of proceeds of crime in the European Union
IMPACT ASSESSMENT Disclaimer: This report commits only the European
Commission’s services involved in its preparation and does not prejudge the
final form of any decision to be taken by the Commission
1.
Introduction
In order to disrupt organised crime activities it is essential to
deprive criminals of the proceeds of crime. Organised crime groups are building
large-scale international networks and amass substantial profits from various
criminal activities. The proceeds of crime are laundered and re-injected into
the legal economy. The confiscation and recovery of criminal assets is considered as a
very effective way to fight organised crime, which is essentially
profit-driven. Seizing back as much of these profits as
possible aims at hampering activities of criminal organisations, deterring
criminality and providing additional funds to invest back into law enforcement activities
or other crime prevention initiatives.
2.
Procedural issues and consultation of interested
parties
2.1.
Chronology of the Impact Assessment and results
of consultations
2.1.1.
Policy context
As an effective tool, especially in the fight against organised
crime, confiscation has been given strategic priority at EU level. The 2009 Stockholm Programme[1]
highlights the importance of identifying and seizing
criminal assets more effectively and re-using them where appropriate. The Justice and Home Affairs Council Conclusions on confiscation and
asset recovery adopted in June 2010[2]
aim at promoting a more coordinated approach between Member States and achieve
a more effective and widespread confiscation and recovery of criminal assets.
They call on the Commission to consider strengthening the legal framework in
order to achieve more effective regimes for third party confiscation and
extended confiscation. They also highlight that attention should be focused on
all phases of the confiscation and asset recovery process and recommend
measures to ensure the preservation of assets during the confiscation process
and the reuse of confiscated assets. The Commission Communication "An Internal Security Strategy in Action"[3]
indicates that the Commission will propose legislation in 2011 to strengthen
the EU legal framework on confiscation, in particular to allow more third party
confiscation and extended confiscation and to facilitate mutual recognition of
non-conviction based confiscation orders between Member States. The Commission Work Programme 2011 includes the proposal for a
Directive on the confiscation and recovery of criminal assets as a strategic
initiative which forms part of a broader package on the "protection of the
licit economy", an agenda to protect Europe's economy which is closely
linked to the EU 2020 Strategy. This package includes anti-corruption initiatives
adopted in June 2011[4]
and a Communication on an EU anti-fraud strategy[5].
The envisaged legislative proposal on the confiscation [correct
terminology? Does not "recovery" include confiscation? Needs to be
checked in the Directive as well. Indeed it does. When reference is made to
the Directive, it is better to use "confiscation", as the Directive mostly
covers the legal proceedings. The asset recovery process also includes the
asset tracing phase (eg national financial investigations, the work of the
AROs) and the disposal phase (eg sale of an asset in a public auction or reuse
of the asset for public purposes).]of criminal assets is also in line with
the ten strategic priorities emphasised by the Commission in its Communication
on the proceeds of crime adopted in 2008[6].
This Communication highlights shortcomings in the EU legal framework (lack of
implementation, lack of clarity of some provisions, lack of coherence between
existing provisions) and proposes to amend it. It further states that a
revision would also allow to introduce new provisions in order to achieve a
more coherent and comprehensive framework. This impact
assessment serves as a basis for the above legal proposal.
2.1.2.
Organisation and timing
Work on the
impact assessment started in May 2010 with the launch of an external study
to support the preparation of the Impact Assessment[7].
The identification and finalisation of problems, objectives, policy options and
assessment of impacts presented in this report were informed by the study which
was completed in March 2011. The study is
based on a broad consultation of practitioners and experts, including interviews
with some national contact points of the Camden Asset Recovery Inter-agency Network (CARIN)[8],
and a limited consultation of other stakeholders. The results of these
consultations are discussed below. As shown by their position in negotiating
the JHA Council Conclusions, Member States generally agree that more needs to
be done on confiscation and asset recovery[9]. This impact
assessment is also based on the conclusions and recommendations of another
external study[10]
[the study seems to have been removed from the link indicated in the footnote!
Thanks ! We will ensure that both this study and the IA are posted online before
the proposal is published.] entitled "Assessing the effectiveness of EU Member States' practices
in the identification, tracing, freezing and confiscation of criminal assets", contracted by the Commission to Matrix Consultancy and finalised in 2009. This study analyses Member
States' practices in confiscation, focusing in particular on what has proven
effective at national level with a view to promoting and exchanging best
practices. The study identified several obstacles to effective confiscation,
such as conflicting legal traditions, resulting in the lack of a common
approach to confiscation measures, difficulties in securing and maintaining
assets, lack of resources and training, limited cross-agency contacts and a
lack of a coherent and comparable statistical system. Finally, the
impact assessment is based on the implementation reports issued by the
Commission on the existing EU legal acts (see infra, Section 3.3). The
reports on Framework Decisions 2005/212/JHA[11],
2003/577/JHA[12]
and 2006/783/JHA[13]
show that Member States have been slow in transposing them and that the
relevant provision have been often implemented in an incomplete or incorrect
way. Only Council Decision 2007/845/JHA seems to have been implemented in a
moderately satisfactory way[14]. Statistics on confiscation
and asset recovery activities are scarce (Annex 2 contains most of the
available data on assets recovered). Reliable data sources on the number of
ongoing freezing and confiscation procedures (especially those to be executed
in other Member States), the turnover of criminal organisations, the costs of
judicial procedures or the administrative costs related to asset management or
data collection activities are even scarcer. Therefore, the economic impacts of
the foreseen actions are often difficult to quantify.
2.1.3.
Consultation of interested parties
Wide
consultations and discussions with experts were carried
out in the CARIN Plenary meeting (September 2010) and in seven meetings of the
EU informal Asset Recovery Offices' Platform between 2009 and 2011. An expert meeting with Member States was held in October 2011. Confiscation and asset recovery issues are also widely discussed
between experts. International practitioners' meetings[15]
and strategic seminars on confiscation and asset recovery[16]
are increasingly taking place. Practitioners consider that most of the policy
actions foreseen are best practices and as such have been included in the
recommendations issued by CARIN between 2005 and 2010. While the governments of the Member States were not formally consulted,
they expressed their position on these issues last year in the negotiations of
the JHA Council Conclusions mentioned earlier. Although there was broad
agreement on most issues, a few Member States held a more reserved position on
non-conviction based confiscation (e.g. Romania due to constitutional issues).
Conversely, on other issues (eg third party confiscation, asset management)
Member States agreed that more should be done, but suggested different
solutions due to differences in their legislation, structures and practices. Defence lawyers expressed concerns about the increased use of
extended confiscation, non-conviction based confiscation and third party
confiscation due to fundamental rights concerns (possible limitation of the
right to property and of the right to a fair trial). No open Internet consultation was carried out, as confiscation is a
rather specialised topic where limited expertise is available but contacts were
established with civil society, notably with the organisations promoting
legality, the fight against organised crime and the protection of the victims
of crime.[17]
These organisations fully supported the envisaged measures. During recent hearings on organised crime in the European
Parliament's LIBE Committee, several Members of Parliament expressed a keen
interest in strengthening the EU legislation on confiscation, mainly by using
the existing Italian legislation (probably the most far-reaching) as a model. The internal consultations in the
Commission were mainly carried out through the inter-service group (ISG) on
confiscation and asset recovery. The DGs and services represented in this ISG were
DG HOME, DG JUSTICE, OLAF, DG EEAS, the Secretariat General, the Legal Service,
DG MARKT, DG TAXUD and DG ECFIN. Three meetings of the ISG took place in 2011
(i.e. on 16 February, 14 April and 4 May 2011) before the submission of this
impact assessment to the Impact Assessment Board. Another meeting of the ISG
was held on 30 June 2011 to discuss the Impact Assessment Board's opinion. The
ISG members were in principle supportive of the main issues addressed in the impact
assessment and their comments and suggestions were considered during the drafting
of this report. In view of the above, minimum standards for
consultation of interested parties have been met in the preparation of this impact
assessment.
2.2.
Consultation of the Impact Assessment Board
The Impact
Assessment Board (IAB) reviewed a preliminary version of this impact assessment
and delivered its opinion on 10 June 2011. The recommendations for improvement were
accommodated in this revised version of the report. In particular, the
following changes were made: ·
The problem requiring EU intervention has been explained
more precisely. ·
The justification for the preferred option has
been strengthened, in order to clarify why it can be considered proportionate
despite fundamental rights concerns. ·
Stakeholder views have been presented earlier
and in more detail in the report and the limited consultation has been acknowledged.
·
Some cost element likely to arise from
implementation has been indicated. ·
The objectives of the initiative have been
clarified to enable a meaningful evaluation in the future.
3.
The recovery of criminal assets explained
3.1.
The asset recovery process
Confiscation
applies in principle to all crimes (or at least to most criminal activities in
some Member States). However, in practice it is more frequently applied to
serious cases involving organised crime. Typical examples are crimes generating
huge income and liquidity, such as drug trafficking. The proceeds of crime are
then converted into assets ranging from cash held in bank accounts to real
estate, vehicles, livestock, artworks, company shares, businesses, collector's
items etc. State authorities should be able to expediently identify and trace
such assets, freeze them and manage them properly once they have been frozen. Confiscation
and recovery of criminal assets are two stages of a legal process whereby
criminal assets (proceeds or instrumentalities of crime) are recovered in
favour of victims, deprived communities or the state. At the heart of this
process lies the determination by a court that particular assets are criminal
and, thereby, liable to confiscation. This typically takes the form of a confiscation
order. The full process is illustrated in the table below. Figure
1: Steps in the asset confiscation and recovery process The first
stage in the asset recovery process is the tracing and identification of
assets. This phase involves law enforcement investigations (usually under the
coordination of a prosecutor) and requires substantial financial investigation
skills. National Asset Recovery Offices (AROs) play a key role in expediently
providing information to other AROs on the assets located in their territory. After criminal
assets are located in one or more countries, judicial procedures are needed to
first freeze them and later to confiscate them. Following their freezing [what
does seizure imply? LS suggested deleting this wording in Directive. In some
national legislations and international conventions freezing refers only to the
money on bank account and real estate, while seizure refers to all other
assets, including cash. The EU legislator referred only to freezing orders for
any property in FD 2003/577/JHA, therefore we can delete "seizure" in
the IA], assets should be properly managed between the time when they are frozen
and the time when a confiscation order is issued, so that their value is
maintained. After a confiscation order is issued by a court, its execution is
carried out. In principle assets become the property of the executing Member
State, which may sell them or re-use them as appropriate. Each stage in
the asset recovery process poses different challenges. For example, AROs should
have the necessary resources to operate effectively, including access to all
relevant information. Prosecutors and judges should trust the legal system of
other Member States in order to recognise and execute foreign freezing and
confiscations orders. Authorities should have the necessary skills and
expertise to manage different assets as well as handle procedures in
cross-border cases. Attention should be focused on ensuring effectiveness in
all phases of the confiscation and asset recovery process. The challenges
of the asset recovery process can therefore be summarised as follows: how to
identify criminal assets; how to
preserve these pending a confiscation order; how to obtain
a confiscation order so that they can be recovered; and how to
enforce these orders. These
questions represent stages of an attrition process as explained in figure 2. Figure 2: Stages of attrition
3.2.
Fundamental questions of the asset recovery
process
The
confiscation process is complicated in practice because sophisticated criminals
attempt to conceal their illicit gains from investigators, taking whatever
measures they can to put assets beyond the scope of confiscation laws or
enforcement measures. In response to this, newer confiscation tools have been
introduced, such as: value
confiscation, so that assets of equivalent value can be confiscated
where specific criminal assets are outside the reach of investigators; third party
confiscation, so that assets can be confiscated from the third parties
to whom they have been transferred; and mutual recognition of
confiscation orders, so that assets can be more
efficiently confiscated from other jurisdictions. These tools are designed to make it easier
for authorities to recover criminal assets. However, the key question is what
assets should be deemed ‘criminal’ and, thus, liable to confiscation. The
traditional approach of ordinary confiscation is to confiscate assets
linked to a specific crime, following a criminal conviction for that crime. The availability of
ordinary confiscation can never ensure the recovery of all criminal assets because
authorities will not always be able to prove that assets are the proceeds of
specific crimes. In some cases, a conviction will have been obtained for the
relevant crime, but authorities will lack evidence that particular assets are
in fact proceeds of this crime. In other cases, criminal
assets will go unrecovered because there is no criminal conviction to serve as
a basis for ordinary confiscation. Such cases consist of two types: i) those
where authorities have sufficient evidence but a case cannot be brought because
it is time-barred or because the defendant is too ill, has died or absconded,
lacks legal capacity (e.g. is a minor or of unsound mind), or has immunity from prosecution or amnesty; and ii) those
situations in which authorities have insufficient evidence to obtain a criminal
conviction. This typology of criminal assets is illustrated in Figure 3. Type
1 assets are those amenable to ordinary confiscation proceedings; type 2 assets
are those not so amenable due to barriers to prosecution; type 3 assets are
those not so amenable due to insufficient evidence; type 4 assets are those not
so amenable for both of these reasons. Figure
3: Typology of criminal assets Yet here too
there have been legal developments in favour of the state powers. Examples
include: extended
confiscation, in which a criminal conviction is followed by the
confiscation not only of assets associated with the specific crime, but of
additional assets which the court determines are the proceeds of other, unspecified
crimes; non-conviction
based confiscation, in which civil, administrative or criminal procedure
applies to recover illicit assets; and extended criminalisation, which
involves defining non-traditional crimes, with the result that more assets are
liable to confiscation. The above
demonstrates that the following three questions need to be addressed when
designing the asset recovery process: ·
what assets should be liable to confiscation
(i.e. how to delineate between assets which are, and are not, ‘criminal’); ·
how to confiscate and recover these assets; and ·
what to do with the recovered assets. The asset
recovery process must also be designed in such a way that it meets fundamental
rights concerns.
3.3.
Asset recovery in the Member States and existing
EU legal framework
Within the EU,
each Member State’s asset confiscation laws have evolved organically in
response to domestic imperatives and, more recently, an EU legal framework. By
the time the EU began to act in 2001 some Member States had potent asset
confiscation regimes, whilst others did not[18]. The current EU
legal framework consists of four Council Framework Decisions (FD) and one
Council Decision: ·
Framework
Decision 2001/500/JHA, which obliges Member States to enable confiscation, to
allow value confiscation where the direct proceeds of crime cannot be seized
and to ensure that requests from other Member States are treated with the same
priority as domestic proceedings ·
Framework
Decision 2005/212/JHA, which harmonises confiscation laws. Ordinary
confiscation, including value confiscation, must be available for all crimes
punishable by 1 year imprisonment. Extended confiscation must be available for
certain serious offences, when "committed within the framework of a
criminal organisation"; ·
Framework
Decision 2003/577/JHA, which requires mutual recognition of freezing orders for
a long list of crimes punishable by 3 years imprisonment, or if the ‘dual
criminality’ principle is satisfied (i.e. for any offence punishable in both countries);
and ·
Framework
Decision 2006/783/JHA, which mirrors these provisions for the mutual
recognition of confiscation orders. ·
Council
Decision 2007/845/JHA on the exchange of information and cooperation between
Asset Recovery Offices. Each of these
instruments was passed unanimously by the Council, exercising broad powers
under Title VI of the Treaty on European Union. The context was in each case
the fight against organised crime but, with the exception of the provisions on
extended confiscation, the EU legal framework is not limited to organised
criminal activity.
4.
Problem definition
4.1.
Insufficient recovery of criminal assets in the
EU
The problem
addressed by this impact assessment is the insufficient recovery of criminal
assets in the EU. To date, estimates of money lost to organised crime in the
Member States, as well as data on success in asset recovery, remain patchy.
Some recent reports and unofficial sources estimate the annual proceeds from
organised crime in some Member States as very high[19]. Even considering a
fraction of the estimated amounts as more credible, the figures provide a
striking contrast with the amounts recovered annually in the Union[20]. Although only some
Member States maintain statistics on the amounts recovered annually from crime,
at present the number of freezing and confiscation procedures in the EU and the
amounts recovered from organised crime seem modest if compared to the estimated
revenues of organised criminal groups. In the UK an
official estimate in 2006 put organised criminal revenue at £15bn per annum.[21]
Meanwhile, the UK’s Joint Asset Recovery Database (JARD) recorded approximately
£125m worth of recoveries that year (see Annex 6)[22].
In Italy, organised criminal revenues were estimated at €150bn per year and the costs of corruption at
50-60 bn per year[23], eclipsing the amounts
recovered and returned annually to the state (including to communities via
social reuse programmes) (see Annex 2). Data from the UK and Italy therefore
indicates that a low proportion of criminal assets are recovered.
Moreover, comparing data on an annual basis (the value of assets recovered versus
criminal turnover) is in fact a conservative approach, as it ignores
unrecovered amounts from previous years which remain recoverable. Although reliable
data sources are indeed scarce[24],
the value of assets recovered in the EU can be considered insufficient,
especially if compared to the estimated revenues of organised criminal groups
or to the number of criminal convictions decided by courts for serious crimes. Organised crime
activities are often transnational in nature and the assets of criminal groups
are increasingly invested in other Member States[25].
A good example is the recent operation "Shovel", described in Box 1,
which shows the ramification of criminal activities and that important means
need to be deployed to fight them successfully. Box 1 – Operation "Shovel": The operation "Shovel" (2010) was conducted by the Spanish authorities in collaboration with the UK, Ireland and Belgium and with the assistance of Europol. The targeted criminal group led by Irish and UK criminals was involved in drug and weapons trafficking, money laundering, forgery of documents and murders. Over 700 police officers were deployed in many Member States on the day of the operation (more than 145 persons and 100 companies were under control). "Shovel" resulted in 38 arrests (24 in Spain including two lawyers who facilitated money laundering operations, 12 in the UK, 1 in Ireland and 1 in Bulgaria) and in the freezing of 60 luxury properties on the ”Costa del Sol” and 25 Luxury cars. 180 bank accounts were also frozen. Pursuing assets
located abroad is invariably more problematic, due to the increased
difficulties in tracing them and to legal obstacles in obtaining evidence and
executing freezing or confiscation orders. Table 1 lists examples of assets
confiscated in cross-border cases with the assistance of Eurojust in 2010. Table
1: Examples of asset confiscation in cross-border cases Member State || Assets subject to confiscation with Eurojust's assistance Belgium || Two boats to be confiscated in Spain. Bulgaria || €37,000 cash and real estate property confiscated in the UK Germany || €100,000,000 confiscated in a large tax fraud case involving coordinated searches in 15 countries Ireland || Substantial amounts of property confiscated in Spain and Ireland Spain || Five cases involving confiscation of €112,000,000, €17,000,000, €1,000,000, €23,000, and €9,000,000 Italy || Provisional confiscation in the Netherlands of €400,000. Freezing of 800 kg of counterfeit products in 10 countries. Freezing of a luxury watch in Germany. Freezing of 300 kg of cocaine in Belgium, Spain, Italy and Czech Republic. Freezing of documents related to the registration of 100 vehicles in Germany. Freezing of 700 kg of hashish, one pc, mobile telephones and documents in France, Spain and the UK. Freezing of one server in Austria. France || Property and vehicles in Italy, one ship and the freezing of 1,400 kg of cocaine. Sweden || €1,685,800 confiscated in Sweden and a ship in another country UK || All property and money of a main suspect (including a house, a speedboat and money with a total value in excess of €1,200,000). Several luxury vehicles in Spain. Moreover, the
penetration of organised crime into the licit economy, even if it takes place
in a single Member State, affects the functioning of the whole EU Internal
Market, not only of that country. Even when managing licit businesses,
organised crime groups often support these activities with the recourse to
intimidation and corruption, thus altering competition and the smooth functioning of the Internal Market. The resulting loss of revenues affects both national and EU
financial interests, even when it takes place in only one Member State. The aims of
asset recovery are realised not only when criminals are deprived of their
ill-gotten gains, but when these are redistributed effectively. In particular,
the impact of asset confiscation upon public confidence in the criminal justice
system may be enhanced through redistribution and restorative justice. [reuse
wording. Yes, but not advocating reuse for social nor public purposes. ] Although asset recovery is a popular
concept with a basis in international law[26],
EU law and Member State laws, these laws remain underdeveloped and
underutilised. It is unlikely that any Member State confiscates a significant
proportion of criminal assets and, accordingly, it is unlikely that the laws
themselves are achieving their stated aim.
4.2.
Components of the problem
There are essentially three problems in
relation to the EU legislative framework: its incomplete or late transposition,
the existence of diverging national provisions and the low utilisation of
confiscation in practice. The most plausible underlying reason for the late or
incomplete transposition of the existing legislation is the workload of the
responsible national authorities. This seems demonstrated by the somewhat
surprising fact that transposition of the EU acquis has been slow or
partial also in countries (eg Italy and the UK) where fighting organised crime
through confiscation is a well-established priority at national level and where
national legislation is well developed. For example the Commission
implementation report on the EU rules on extended confiscation (FD
2005/212/JHA) showed that most Member States are slow in putting in place
measures to allow more widespread confiscation, with only 16 of them
transposing in full or partially by end 2007. The situation has slightly improved
since the report, but transposition is not yet complete today However, this is not only a case of
incomplete transposition. The lack of clarity of some EU provisions has
resulted in a different (and often diverging) transposition into national law,
further widening the differences in the national legislations. One example is
the notion of extended confiscation, which requires Member States to choose
between three alternative criteria for extended confiscation, or to adopt two
or all three of them cumulatively. As a result, the mutual recognition of
orders based on extended confiscation is problematic. Due to the lack of
coherence between provisions in the 2005 and 2006 Framework Decisions, a Member
State can refuse to execute an order issued in another Member State if the two
countries have not chosen the same criteria. Moreover, as highlighted in the
Commission implementation reports, Member States have often added conditions
(for example additional grounds for refusing the mutual recognition of confiscation
orders) which further limit the effectiveness of the EU provisions. These problems are compounded by a low
implementation in practice (under-utilisation) of confiscation, as evidenced by
the gap between the estimated size of criminal profits in a country and the
amounts confiscated, or by the gap between criminal convictions and number of
cases when they have been followed up with effective confiscation. The
inadequate implementation in practice of the EU legislation may be due to
different reasons depending on the stakeholders involved. For example,
practitioners requesting the execution of orders in other Member States find
the ad hoc request forms unclear and difficult to use. Law enforcement
officers and prosecutors may perceive asset tracing and confiscation as a drain
of scarce and expensive resources (financial investigators) that does not
always entail tangible results (hence the importance to inform widely on the
profitability of confiscation). Among the judges there may be some
"cultural" resistance to apply confiscation widely, as it is
perceived as an additional punishment on an already convicted person. Bearing
in mind the challenges encountered during the different stages of the asset
recovery process, the problem of the insufficient recovery of criminal assets
in the EU can be broken down into components. These are discussed in more
detail below.
4.2.1.
Inadequate powers for confiscating criminal
assets
The national confiscation systems in the Member States differ
substantially. As organised criminal groups operate without borders and
increasingly acquire assets in other Member States, there is greater need for
both harmonised substantive law provisions and effective mutual recognition
procedures in order to enforce freezing and confiscation orders in other Member
States. The EU legislation described above harmonises only some provisions
on the national confiscation systems. For example, while it is common practice
for suspected or investigated persons to transfer their assets to a knowing
third party with a view to avoid confiscation, there are no provisions at EU
level on third party confiscation. Also, the current EU legal framework only
applies to criminal proceedings and the issuance of confiscation orders
generally requires a criminal conviction. On the other hand, some Member States
apply also non-conviction based systems to deprive criminals of illicit
profits, which are not provided for at EU level. The limited EU legal framework in place
presents shortcomings. As it consists of a series of measures proposed by
Member States over time, it is not sufficiently coherent and consistent. It
ultimately provides relatively little harmonisation and offers wide discretionality
to the Member States in its implementation. Moreover, some provisions have been
implemented poorly or in a diverging way. There are also indications (eg from expert
reports within the framework of technical assistance projects financed by the
Union or by Member States) that legal inadequacies and political/structural
problems in a few Member States may be so significant that they largely prevent
the use of confiscation and asset recovery against high-ranking organised
criminals. While these shortcomings mainly relate to extended confiscation
(which exists in EU legislation since 2005), even obtaining ordinary
confiscation seems somewhat problematic in these countries, as demonstrated by
the low number of confiscation cases and the modest amounts recovered every
year. For the reasons above, a complete and
correct implementation of the existing legal framework would not be sufficient
to address the problem of the insufficient recovery of criminal assets in the Union.
Many national provisions are not harmonised at EU level and the Member States
exercise their powers in a very different way. A summary description of the
provisions and the shortcomings existing in each Member State, as well as the
potential impact of the proposed measures is provided in Table 5 (infra). Box 2 – Examples of differences in the Member States' national provisions On the scope of the targeted assets, Member States currently employ varying definitions of criminal "proceeds" (as this term is currently undefined within the EU legal framework). As a result, the indirect proceeds of crime cannot always be confiscated. On the question whether particular assets are proceeds, most Member States employ a criminal standard of proof (high in some countries, such as Germany) while others, such as the United Kingdom, use a civil standard of proof which facilitates confiscation. On the timing for the confiscation procedure, in many Member States, the opportunity to confiscate criminal assets ends when criminal proceedings are finalised. This encourages criminals to try to conceal assets for the duration of the criminal proceedings, so that the assets which "resurface" after its conclusions cannot be confiscated. This can also cause authorities to rush financial investigations (with the risk of missing some assets) in order to conform to timetables imposed by criminal procedure. On the existing barriers to prosecution, the EU legal framework contains no mandatory provision for the confiscation of assets which cannot be confiscated because criminal proceedings are not allowed to be brought despite sufficient evidence. The assets believed to be criminal even though there is insufficient evidence to obtain the criminal conviction are covered by Framework Decision 2005/212/JHA in a limited and complicated way. Another relevant barrier is that in some Member States it is impossible to confiscate criminal assets where a conviction cannot be obtained (eg because the suspect has died, fled the jurisdiction, is unable to stand trial due to mental illness, has immunity from prosecution, etc). Finally, confiscation from third-parties is an entirely optional aspect of the existing EU legal framework. Some national confiscation regimes do not apply to assets which have been passed on to third parties. Others do, but require proof of mala fides even where the third party is a relative or close associate who has received for less than market value. These differences in legislation often become
barriers to the mutual recognition of freezing and confiscation orders between
Member States. It is widely recognised that a minimum level of harmonisation should
exist in order to facilitate mutual recognition. An increased level of
harmonisation is therefore needed in this area, in order to ensure in each Member State a minimum level of protection from
criminal infiltration in the legal economy (through the acquisition of assets)
and facilitating the mutual recognition of freezing and confiscation orders in
other Member States.
4.2.2.
Inadequate powers for preserving criminal assets
pending confiscation
The EU
legislation does not contain harmonised provisions on preservation of assets
and does not cover the management of seized assets pending the confiscation
procedure, which is addressed exclusively by national provisions. On asset preservation, while all
confiscation regimes are supported by freezing powers, in a minority of cases
these do not apply to all assets liable to confiscation (eg not to assets in
the possession of third parties or assets representing equivalent value). Moreover,
Member States do not always have in place appropriate mechanisms to ensure that
assets in danger of being hidden or transferred out of the jurisdiction are
able to be immediately frozen/seized while the request for judicial freezing is
pending. On asset management, in many Member States,
assets are managed by agents (court officials, prosecutors, and police)
involved in the criminal proceeding. In some cases, they lack even basic powers
to realise seized assets which are liable to decline in value (even where
requested to do so by the affected person). More generally, while a few Member
States have established dedicated centralised structures, in most Member States
expertise in managing complex assets is lacking and the management of assets is
not centralised. This shortcoming directly affects the stages of attrition
described in Figure 2. In some cases the spread between the value of the assets
frozen or seized in view of confiscation and the value of the assets recovered
at the end of the confiscation procedure is quite significant. Box 3 – Examples on the risks in managing different assets While cash and financial products do not create particular management issues, the management of perishable goods or of vehicles has provoked in some instances substantial loss of value. Even managing real estate can be problematic. Assets frozen when the real estate market is booming may lose substantial value if they are auctioned at the moment when the market has declined. Other items which could risk losing value between the freezing and the confiscation are artwork and livestock (eg race horses).
4.2.3.
Inadequate powers for enforcing confiscation
orders between Member States (mutual recognition)
The enforcement of freezing and
confiscation orders is generally not problematic in a national context.
Problems arise more often when enforcing in a Member State an order issued by a
judge in another Member State. The existing EU legal framework seeks to address
the cross-border aspects of confiscation through provisions on minimum
harmonisation and mutual recognition. However, at present the EU legal
framework is insufficient, not completely transposed, not correctly transposed and
in a few cases lacks coherence[27]. Box 4 Examples of problems with the mutual recognition of freezing and confiscation orders between Member States Framework Decisions (FD) 2003/577/JHA (freezing orders) and 2006/783/JHA (confiscation orders) establish a mechanism whereby the judicial authority issuing an order to be enforced in another Member State can send it directly to the judicial authority in that country which is competent to execute it, by filling in a specific certificate. This mechanism derogates from mutual legal assistance procedures, under which such orders should be sent to Central Authorities in each Member State. However, the full benefits of the swifter procedure provided in the FDs may not be fully reaped. The lack of transposition or the partial transposition by some Member States of the existing mutual recognition obligations significantly hampers the enforcement of freezing and confiscation orders in other Member States. The report issued by the Commission on FD 2003/577/JHA shows significant delays in the transposition, with only 19 Member States transposing this FD fully or partially by December 2008. Even today transposition is still not satisfactory, with four Member States not having transposed. The implementation report issued by the Commission on FD 2006/783/JHA shows that only 13 Member States transposed this FD fully or partially. Again, today the situation has marginally improved but is not yet satisfactory. Regrettably, the legal framework is not only incompletely transposed. Its provisions are sometimes transposed into national law in a diverging way. FD 2003/577/JHA emphasises that the national legislations show numerous omissions or misinterpretations. The report on FD 2006/783/JHA highlights that almost all Member States included additional grounds to refuse the mutual recognition of confiscation orders issued in other Member States. Again, a complete and correct implementation of the existing legal framework would not be sufficient, as some EU legal provisions are not well coordinated. Footnote 27 describes the negative impact on mutual recognition of the three alternative criteria for extended confiscation in Framework Decision 2005/212/JHA and the provisions on the grounds for refusal of mutual recognition of confiscation orders laid down in Framework Decision 2006/783/JHA. The existing FDs on mutual recognition are also limited in scope. Extended confiscation is not supported by FD 2003/577/JHA, whilst FD 2006/783/JHA supports extended confiscation only in a limited way. Neither requires mutual recognition of non-conviction based confiscation orders. These limitations handicap the ability of Member States to combat organised crime. This is especially true for non-conviction based confiscation, as the alternative mutual legal assistance route is relatively weak. The issues with the certificates which lead to under-utilisation of these procedures are described in paragraph 4.2.4. Finally, the existing legal framework includes two similar instruments, ie FD 2006/783/JHA on the mutual recognition of confiscation orders and FD 2005/214/JHA on the mutual recognition of financial penalties, including compensation orders. This dichotomy between confiscation and compensation seems unnecessary given that the recovery mechanisms employed are very similar.
4.2.4.
Powers for confiscation, preservation and
enforcement are underutilised
Based on available statistics (Annex 2), there is a significant
underutilisation of asset confiscation laws throughout the EU. This is in some
cases a matter of law, but mostly due to other factors. The study on confiscation conducted by Matrix in 2009 shows how cultural
differences in the Member States affect the general approach to confiscation. As
a result some judges consider confiscation almost as an additional punishment
of an already convicted person and are reluctant to apply it systematically. In general the profitability of asset
confiscation work is also poorly understood by government decision-makers in
some Member States. This lack of understanding causes asset confiscation work
to be viewed as a drain upon scarce resources. Also because of this factor, underutilisation
of asset confiscation tools persists, notwithstanding ample rhetoric on the
utility of confiscating and recovering criminal assets. At law enforcement
level, in some Member States the tracing and identification of criminal assets are
neglected in favour of the criminal investigation. This evidently hampers the
possibility to confiscate criminal assets. Within the judicial system
prosecutors have a discretionary power to request freezing and confiscation
orders and the courts have a discretionary power to issue them. As a result
they are underutilised. On a cross-border level, the requests for freezing are
very often made alongside other requests (eg. a house search), so practitioners
using the specific certificates in FDs 2003/577/JHA and 2006/783/JHA must
complete additional paperwork (for mutual legal assistance mechanisms) and need
to be familiar with many different instruments. Fieldwork revealed these to be
significant barriers for practitioners.
4.2.5.
Member States tools for maximising social
utility from recovered assets (Redistribution)
The existing EU legislation does not contain provisions on the
disposal of assets. National provisions exist in some countries, including on
the reuse of confiscated assets (eg for social purposes). In practice not all
Member States have redistribution schemes in place. The assets recovered from
organised crime are often sold in public auctions and the proceeds are returned
to the State budget. In some cases organised criminal groups have been able to
re-acquire the confiscated assets by discouraging potential bidders through intimidation.
In countries where a system of decreasing value auction is in place (ie the
price of the auctioned asset is progressively reduced if no one bids for it)
they have also been able to pay a very low price. So this factor may also reduce
State revenues resulting from recovered assets and affect the stages of
attrition described in Figure 2. Moreover, the social reuse schemes established
in some Member States take various forms. In some cases confiscated assets are
directly put to social purposes, in others income streams are used to fund
social benefits.
4.3.
How would the problem evolve, all things being
equal?
The baseline scenario or status
quo indicates how the identified problem is likely to evolve without
additional public intervention, taking account of existing and forthcoming
interventions and following the introduction of the Lisbon Treaty. Based on historical
progress, at EU level the status quo policy option would likely
result in an increase in the assets owned or controlled by criminal
organisations, as well as an increase in their acquisitions of assets in other
Member States. Evidence of a progressive increase in cross border criminality and
in the cross-border acquisition of assets can be derived from investigative
sources. The threat assessments issued by Europol[28]
show an increasing trend in cross-border criminal activities and in the links
between criminal groups located in different regions. The number of
investigations coordinated by Europol, facilitated by Eurojust or supported by
Joint Investigation Teams is steadily increasing. To some extent, the
increasing cross-border acquisition of assets by organised crime is
demonstrated by the steadily increasing number of requests for information on
assets which are exchanged on a daily basis between Asset Recovery Offices in
the Member States. The expected increase
in the cross-border acquisition of criminal assets would be mitigated to some
extent by a corresponding slight increase of the amounts frozen or seized, of
the amounts confiscated, of the amounts recovered and of the cases where mutual
recognition of orders issued in other Member States is successful. Such
increases would partly result from a slightly better transposition of the EU instruments.
Better transposition could entail a wider recourse to extended confiscation and
an increased number of cases of successful mutual recognition of freezing and
confiscation orders issued in other Member States. The TFEU provides for the
possibility of using infringements procedures to ensure transposition of the EU
acquis in the area of Freedom, Security and Justice. However, even if
these procedures may serve as an incentive for the Member States to act, their benefits
will not be visible in the short-term. Moreover, as the EU
legislation currently harmonises only some provisions on the national
confiscation systems, significant gaps would persist and would continue hampering
a more successful recovery of criminal assets across the Union. For example, while
it is common practice for criminals to transfer their assets to a knowing third
party with a view to avoiding confiscation, there are no binding provisions at
EU level on third party confiscation. The current EU legal framework only
applies to criminal proceedings and the issuance of confiscation orders
generally requires a criminal conviction. Non-conviction based rules to deprive
criminals of illicit profits, which are successfully used in some Member States,
are not provided for at EU level. While assets tend to decrease in value in the
period between their freezing and the confiscation, the EU legislation does not
contain harmonised provisions on preservation of assets and the management of
seized assets pending the confiscation procedure. At national
level the progressive exchange of best practices and cross-border judicial
cooperation between Member States will result in a slight increase of the
utilisation of existing instruments, which should result in more successful
asset investigations and confiscations. However, this progress in cross-border
law enforcement and judicial cooperation may be partially offset by the
expected increase in cross-border criminal activities, in the links between
organised criminal groups and in the revenues of criminal organisations. On the
other hand, the collection of statistics to measure the actual extent of
confiscation and asset recovery activities (notably judicial statistics) and
the corresponding costs will remain patchy, rendering any comparison between
Member States difficult. At international
level the EU Member States will progressively sign and ratify the 2005
Council of Europe Convention (CETS 198). This new set of international
obligations may induce some Member States to amend their national legislation
to align it with the provisions of the Convention.While this Convention is
based on a relatively good consensus, seven EU Member States have not even
signed it yet. Without EU action, the implementation of the provisions of this
Convention only by some Member States may therefore further widen the
differences in the legislation between the Member States, at least in the
short/medium term. In any case action
at EU level would still be necessary in order to address the shortcomings
identified above. The shortcomings on asset preservation and reuse and on
utilisation of confiscation powers are not addressed in the Convention. The
existing EU legislation on the powers to confiscate (e.g. on extended
confiscation) is more detailed than the provisions of the Convention. Finally, the
enforcement of orders in other Member States is based on the principle of
mutual recognition instead of mutual legal assistance. As a result, the spread between criminally
owned assets and assets recovered by governments is likely to increase and the
cross-border dimension of confiscation is likely to gain relevance. We will be
even more in a situation where "crime does pay". It is likely that the
current costs of confiscation procedures would remain unchanged.
4.4.
The EU's right to
act and subsidiarity
4.4.1.
Conferral of power
The EU has already passed measures relating
to the confiscation and recovery of criminal assets. However, the EU’s
conferral of power has changed following the entry into force of the Treaty of
Lisbon. Whereas action under the old Third Pillar was essentially unconstrained
provided all Member States agreed, the Treaty of Lisbon places specific conditions
upon the EU’s right to act.
4.4.2.
Legal basis
The legal
basis to support action in the field of confiscation and recovery of assets can
be found in Article 82(1) TFEU for the provisions on mutual recognition and in
Article 82(2) and Article 83 (1) TFEU for harmonisation. Under Article 5(3)
TEU, the Union shall only act if the proposed action cannot be sufficiently
achieved by the Member States. Article 67 TFEU foresees that the Union shall
provide citizens with a high level of security by preventing and combating
crime. Pursuing criminal assets is increasingly recognised as an essential tool
to combat organised crime, which is very often transnational in nature and thus
needs to be tackled on a common basis. This is all the more true in the EU,
where the abolition of internal frontiers makes it far easier to commit
cross-border crimes. As acknowledged by the Stockholm Programme, the Union must reduce
the number of opportunities available to organised crime as a result of a
globalised economy, not least during a crisis that is exacerbating the
vulnerability of the financial system. The EU is
therefore better placed than individual Member States in sharpening more
efficiently one of the most effective tools to fight organised crime groups. The assets of
organised criminal groups are increasingly invested outside their home country
(often in several countries). This double cross-border dimension (of organised
crime activities and their investments) further justifies pan-European action
to target the assets of organised criminal groups. While
cross-border criminal and asset investigations may occur in several countries,
prosecution and the judicial activities leading to confiscation normally take
place in only one Member State. The resulting freezing and confiscation orders
then need to be enforced in other Member States. Therefore, while criminal
activities and investments are increasingly cross-border, confiscation
procedures remain essentially national. However, their cross-border dimension
is immediately evident in the enforcement of orders in other Member States. Moreover, the
penetration of organised crime into the licit economy even of a single Member
State has an inherent cross-border dimension, as this affects the functioning
of the whole EU Internal Market. Apart from the
issue of cross-border organised crime, the free movement of persons (11.3
million EU citizens live in a foreign Member State) and capitals within the
Union entails a need for action at supra-national level in enforcing judicial
decisions, including those on asset freezing and confiscation.
4.5.
Fundamental rights
Inasmuch as it
deprives the offender of his or her possession, confiscation interferes with
the right to property enshrined in Article 17 of the EU Charter of
Fundamental Rights. This right is not however absolute: it can legitimately be
subject to restrictions when the legislator pursues a valid objective of
general interest or the need to protect the rights and freedoms of
others, such as the prevention of organised crime. There must nevertheless be
reasonable proportionality between the policy behind the law and its effect
upon the individual. In the
decisions of the European Court on Human Rights (ECtHR), the proportionality
test mainly depends on the application of the confiscation order in the
particular case under examination. The Court gives great weight to the
procedural guarantees in place: a measure will be usually proportional if the
individual had effective means to contest it. Article 17
guarantees a right to own, use, dispose and bequeath lawfully acquired
possessions. This wording seems to corroborate the possibility to confiscate
the direct and indirect proceeds of crime, which by definition have been proven
to have illicit origin. In fact under this Article it seems unclear whether a
right to property exists where said property has illicit origin. Article 47 of the Charter guarantees the right to an effective remedy and the right to a fair trial. Inasmuch
as confiscation orders interfere with the right to property, affected parties must
be able to challenge such orders under the conditions set by this Article. 1) Ordinary
conviction-based confiscation is generally perceived to be a legitimate
restriction to the right to property guaranteed by Article 17 of the Charter,
if coupled with procedural guarantees to secure the right of affected
individuals to an effective remedy and to a fair trial provided in Article 47.
In certain circumstances, this right must be exercised together with the right
to presumption of innocence of Article 48, the principles of legality and
proportionality of criminal offences and penalties of Article 49 and with the
right not to be tried or punished twice in criminal proceedings for the same
criminal offence of Article 50 of the Charter. 2) Non-conviction
based and extended confiscation regimes enable interferences with the right
to property, in the meaning of Article 17 of the Charter, without the said
property being linked to a specific criminal conviction. These measures are in
principle harder to justify as necessary and proportionate restrictions to the
right to property. Since these regimes do not relate to assets for which a
criminal conviction has been obtained, they may raise issues with regard to the
presumption of innocence guaranteed by Article 48(1) of the Charter and Article
6(2) ECHR. As with non-conviction based confiscation,
extended confiscation may raise questions with regard to the presumption of
innocence, as it is by definition a process which enables confiscation without
an established link between the asset and a particular criminal conviction.
Extended confiscation regimes may also raise concerns with regard to Articles
49 of the Charter and 7 ECHR which spell out the principle of legality,
including the non-retroactivity of criminal law, and the prohibition against
the imposition of harsher penalties. An issue may in particular arise in
respect of newly-introduced extended confiscation provisions which allow for
the confiscation of assets acquired through criminal conduct which occurred
prior to the introduction of the extended confiscation regime. 3) The
confiscation of assets transferred to third parties also affects the
right to property within the meaning of Article
17 of the Charter. Again, the main issue is about proportionality, ie whether
this limitation is proportionate to the objectives being pursued (deterring
crime, restitution to victims). 4) Although freezing
orders are only temporary measures, their consequences can be far reaching,
particularly with regard to the right to property, despite criminal liability
having yet to be established. On the other hand, they are necessary to ensure
the subsequent application of confiscation orders, and have been upheld on this
basis and justified because of public interest. Freezing
orders can also raise issues with regard to the right to private and family
life guaranteed by Article 7 of the Charter, and there is a growing awareness
that to ensure compatibility with this right, as well as with
the respect for human dignity in line with Article 1 of the Charter, Member
States are expected to apply freezing orders in a way which leave people with
their basic means of survival. Freezing orders can also
have effects on third parties since it is often a criminal offence to have any
dealings, commercial or otherwise, with a person on whom such a measure has
been imposed.
5.
Policy objectives
The overall
long-term objective is the substantial reduction of organised crime revenues
and accumulated wealth within the EU. The following general objectives for
the confiscation and recovery of criminal assets, which align to general
objectives of the Union in the Treaty of Lisbon, have been identified: ·
to combat organised crime ·
to achieve justice for victims ·
to raise public confidence in the criminal
justice system. The specific objectives of the EU
intervention aim at both harmonising Member States practices in order to
facilitate mutual recognition and to prompt asset recovey activities at
national level in order to deter more effectively criminal activity. In line
with the underlying components of the problem, four specific policy
objectives can be defined: ·
to further harmonise the confiscation powers of
the Member States ·
to harmonise the preservation powers of the
Member States ·
to enhance the enforcement of freezing and
confiscation orders across Member States' borders ·
to enhance the utilisation of existing tools in
the Member States. The table
below shows the components of the problem, together with descriptions of the status
quo at EU-level and associated specific and operational
objectives. It emphasises that the existing EU legal framework is far from
comprehensive. Table 2: Problem and objectives Problem || Existing EU legal framework || General objectives || Specific objectives || Operational objectives Not always possible to confiscate criminal assets due to gaps in MS powers (barriers to prosecution, insufficient evidence or both) || Rules are contained in FD 2005/212/JHA but many aspects of the problem are not addressed || 1/ combat crime (notably organised crime) 2/ achieve justice for victims 3/ raise public confidence in the criminal justice system || A. Increase the harmonisation of rules allowing to confiscate criminal assets, with due respect of fundamental rights || 1. harmonise confiscation of type 1 criminal assets (ordinary confiscation) 2. harmonise confiscation of type 2 criminal assets (barriers to prosecution) 3. harmonise confiscation of type 3 criminal assets (insufficient evidence) 4. harmonise confiscation of assets of third parties Not always possible to freeze criminal assets, or preserve and manage frozen assets, due to gaps in MS preservation powers || No EU rules || B. Minimum harmonised rules allowing to freeze and manage criminal assets pending confiscation, with due respect of fundamental rights || 1. allow freezing orders for all assets liable to confiscation 2. To have effective mechanisms to preserve assets pending enforcement of freezing 3. To have effective systems for managing frozen/seized assets Not always possible to enforce freezing and confiscation orders across borders due to gaps in MS enforcement powers || FD 2003/577/JHA and FD 2006/783/JHA deal with mutual recognition of freezing and confiscation orders, but are limited in scope || C. Make it easier for MS to freeze and confiscate assets across borders || 1. MS to recognise and enforce (all types of) freezing orders from other MS 2. MS to recognise and enforce (all types of) confiscation orders from other MS Underutilisation of freezing and confiscation procedures and tools by MS agents || No EU rules || D. Raise utilisation of freezing and confiscation tools by MS agents || 1. MS to raise utilisation of freezing powers 2. MS to raise utilisation of confiscation powers 3. MS to raise utilisation of mutual recognition instruments || || ||
6.
Policy options
6.1.
Identification and screening of "policy
actions"
In order to
meet the specific and operational objectives identified above and remedy the
shortcomings resulting from the problem definition identified in Chapter 3. 21
EU-level policy actions were identified (some of which are complementary) which
target particular operational objectives. These 21 policy actions are described
in Annex 3, where they are grouped according to the four specific objectives
they aim to achieve. Given the
high number of envisaged policy actions, the 21 EU-level actions were first
screened individually against the following potential barriers to
implementation: i) adequate conferral of power to the EU; ii) proportionality; iii)
compatibility with fundamental constitutional or criminal law principles of the
Member States. The impact on
fundamental rights was also analysed in detail, based on the relevant jurisprudence
of the European Court of Human Rights. Whilst many of the identified policy
actions affect fundamental rights, only in a small minority of cases it is not
possible to remedy potential negative consequences. On the other hand, in some
cases it appears that appropriate remedies can actually promote fundamental
rights throughout the Union (by inducing a positive impact in Member States
which currently afford low levels of protection).
6.2.
Discarded policy actions
Four of the identified policy actions were
discarded after the screening of the policy actions against the implementation
barriers mentioned earlier: ·
Civil
standard of proof regarding whether an asset is "criminal" (policy action 3): The standard of proof on whether particular
assets are proceeds could be harmonised to a lower "balance of
probabilities" standard, to make it more difficult for convicted criminals
to retain type 1 assets. This action was discarded due to likely
problems with the conferral of powers to the EU and the proportionality principle,
as well as problems of compatibility with Member States' legislation. ·
Designating Asset Management Offices (policy action 11): Further harmonisation could require all Member
States to entrust the management of frozen assets to Asset Management Offices
at a national or regional level. This could increase efficiency and promote
best practice. This action was discarded due to problems with the conferral of
powers to the EU. · Mandatory assets investigation (policy
action 17): The EU legal framework could require investigators to open a
parallel financial investigation, at least for the crimes listed in TFEU
article 83(1). This action was discarded due to problems with the conferral of
powers to the EU and the proportionality principle and problems of
compatibility with Member States' legislation. · Limited judicial discretion (policy
action 18): Judicial discretion could be limited by requiring freezing
to be ordered wherever there is reasonable cause to suspect that an asset may
become liable to confiscation and, in the event of a criminal conviction, by requiring
confiscation to be ordered unless doing so would disproportionately affect
fundamental rights. This action was discarded due to problems with the
conferral of powers to the EU and the proportionality principle and problems of
compatibility with Member States' legislation. Doubts on the compatibility with the above implementation barriers
could be expressed also in relation to other policy actions. However, such
doubts were not so strong as to cause the relevant action to be discarded.
6.3.
Policy actions grouped into policy options
Following the elimination of unfeasible
policy actions, the remaining policy actions are grouped into policy
options representing different degrees of EU-level intervention: a
non-legislative option, a minimal legislative option (correcting deficiencies
in the existing EU legal framework which inhibit it from functioning as
intended) and a maximal legislative option (going beyond the aims of the
existing EU legal framework). Within the latter, two maximal legislative
sub-options are analysed, one with and one without EU level action relating to
mutual recognition. The "do nothing" option forms the baseline
against which all other options are analysed.
6.3.1.
Policy option 1 – Status quo
This policy option
would involve no new action at EU level, but constitutes the continuation of existing
activities. The possible developments of this policy option at EU, national and
international levels are indicated in section 4.3. No new action
at EU level does not mean no change at EU level. Protocol 36 to the Treaty of
Lisbon ensures that the existing EU legal framework (or at least those
provisions which do not exceed the EU’s post-Lisbon competence) will, on 1
December 2014, become enforceable against Member States through infringement
proceedings brought by the Commission before the ECJ. Analysis will need to
account for this step-change, as well as for other factors, including continued
international developments and scrutiny in the forum of mutual evaluations by
Moneyval and FATF.
6.3.2.
Policy option 2 – Non-legislative option
Under the
non-legislative policy option, workshops would be used to encourage Member
States to better transpose the existing EU legal framework into domestic law
(by highlighting its benefits and reiterating its compulsory nature) and to better
utilise their asset confiscation laws (by highlighting benefits and sharing
scientific knowledge and best practice). Better transposition can be achieved
by promoting implementation of existing confiscation obligations (policy
action 1). Although the trends towards compliance with FD 2005/212/JHA
are positive, continued implementation/expert workshops could help ensure
ongoing progress. Better utilisation of national legislation can be achieved by
promoting implementation of existing mutual recognition obligations (policy action 12) via implementation/expert workshops on Framework
Decisions 2003/577/JHA (freezing orders) and 2006/783/JHA (confiscation
orders). Utilisation workshops for government decision-makers in some
Member States on the profitability of asset confiscation work (policy action
15) could increase utilisation of these tools and provide a forum for the
sharing of knowledge and practitioner experience.
6.3.3.
Policy option 3 – Minimal legislative option
This option consists of transposition
and utilisation workshops plus the policy actions aiming at consolidating
confiscation and compensation orders (which concern the return of confiscated
assets as compensation to identifiable victims of crime) and at providing
consolidated mutual recognition forms. These additional
policy actions deal with identified deficiencies in the existing legal
framework on mutual recognition. In relation to the enforcement of
confiscation orders, this option envisages mutual recognition of compensation
orders (policy action 14). The legal framework could be
simplified by consolidating FD 2006/783/JHA and 2005/214/JHA and extending
their scope to include all compensation orders made in the context of criminal
proceedings. With regard to utilisation, this option
would include the introduction of consolidated mutual
recognition forms (policy action 19). A single form
for all types of mutual recognition at the
investigative stage could be provided within the European Investigation Order
(and by suppressing the existing mutual legal assistance alternative). This
option would also entail enforcing the primacy of mutual recognition (policy action 20). The EU legal
framework could suppress the use of mutual legal assistance with respect to
freezing and confiscation by repealing the existing mutual legal assistance
conventions as regards requests between Member States.
6.3.4.
Policy option 4.1 – Maximal legislative option
without mutual recognition
This option would
introduce many new aspects into the EU legal framework. It would consist of the
transposition and utilisation workshops coupled with the policy actions aimed
at further harmonising the confiscation, preservation and, to some extent, enhancing
enforcement, i.e. all policy actions which do not involve legislative action in
relation to mutual recognition. In order to
enhance confiscation powers, this option would foresee the possibility of confiscating
all valuable benefits, including indirect proceeds (policy action 2). The
EU legal framework could harmonise a (wide) definition of criminal ‘proceeds’
in order to ensure the recovery of ‘indirect’ proceeds resulting from the
appreciation in value, or profitable reinvestment, of direct proceeds.
Harmonisation could also ensure that any valuable benefit (including, for
example, the value of liabilities avoided) is liable to confiscation. As a way to address
the foreclosure of confiscation activities when the criminal procedure is
concluded, this option foresees separating confiscation proceedings from
criminal proceedings (policy action 4). The EU legal framework could ensure
that separate confiscation proceedings can be brought also at a later date when
criminal proceedings are finalised. This option
would also include strengthen extended confiscation (policy action 5) by
providing for extended confiscation at least where a court finds it
substantially more probable that the assets of a person convicted of an offence
covered by Article 83(1) TFEU are derived from other similar criminal
activities. With a view to
addressing the identified barriers to prosecution, this option would include
the introduction of non-conviction based confiscation in limited
circumstances (policy action 6). The EU legal framework could make ordinary
confiscation possible in circumstances where a conviction cannot be
obtained because the suspect has died, fled prosecution or sentencing or is
unable to stand trial due to permanent illness. As criminals
often transfer their assets to knowing third parties as soon as they are under
investigation in order to avoid confiscation, this option would also include third
party confiscation (policy action 7) in some cases. Laws could be
harmonised by requiring third party confiscation to be available for assets received
for less than market value and which a reasonable person in the position of the
third party would suspect to be derived from crime Policy actions
5, 6 and 7 have been conceived in a targeted way in order to comply with the
principle of proportionality and take into account of the concerns expressed.
Extended confiscation powers are already provided for in EU legislation (FD
2005/212/JHA). They already can be used only in case of serious crimes and have
been applied in practice in a quite limited number of cases. Action 5 does not
intend to enlarge the scope of extended confiscation. It merely intends to
streamline the existing system of alternative criteria and options for Member
States by providing a single minimum criterion for extended confiscation. The
envisaged provision would not introduce a totally new obligation and would
propose a minimum criterion (which is neither the lowest nor the most extreme)
with which most Member States may be comfortable. If adopted, this provision
would probably require only a few Member States to amend their legislation and
bring it beyond their existing minimum. In order to comply
with the principle of proportionality, non-conviction
based confiscation would not be introduced in all cases (full harmonisation),
but would be allowed only in very limited circumstances where a criminal
conviction cannot be obtained, eg because the suspect has died, fled the
jurisdiction, or is unable to stand trial due to permanent illness. This
provision has been also enshrined in the United Nation Convention against
Corruption (Art. 54.1.c), which
has been ratified by the Union and by 25 Member States. Equally, under
Action 7 third party confiscation is not foreseen in all cases, but only in limited circumstances (ie for assets
which a reasonable person in the position of the third party would suspect to
be derived from crime and which have beenreceived for less than market value). This action would not affect the position of a bona fide
third party who has acquired an asset paying its market value. Moreover, third
party confiscation would take place only after an
assesment, based on specific facts, showing that confiscation of assets
directly from the person who transferred them is unlikely to succeed, or in
situations where unique objects must be restored to their rightful owner. In relation to
the freezing/ of criminal assets, this option foresees the introduction of standards
of universal freezing (policy action 8). Harmonised minimum standards
could ensure that it is possible to preserve any assets and would facilitate the
mutual recognition of freezing orders. It would also foresee mechanisms to
safeguard freezing (policy action 9), so that Member States would be
required to have in place appropriate mechanisms to ensure that assets in
danger of being hidden or transferred out of their jurisdiction can be frozen/seized
immediately. This would include, in appropriate circumstances, the ability to
freeze/seize prior to seeking a court order. With regard to
asset preservation, this option would grant powers to realise frozen assets
(policy action 10). Harmonisation could ensure that, regardless of how
frozen assets are managed, there are powers to realise them at least where they
are liable to decline in value or uneconomical to maintain. In the area of
utilisation of powers, this option would introduce reporting obligations
(policy action 16) for Member States, for example an obligation to report
for all serious crimes covered by TFEU article 83(1), the assets frozen, the
confiscation orders (if any) obtained and the type of order (eg ordinary,
extended, non-conviction based confiscation). This would also help generate
statistics which could be used for evaluation purposes. Policy option 4.2 – Maximal legislative option including mutual
recognition This option
consists of all the envisaged policy actions (but policy actions 19 and
20 partly overlap). Compared to option 4.1, this means that it also includes
important provisions which foresee the mutual recognition of all types of
orders (policy action 13). The EU legal framework could remove existing limitations
on the mutual recognition of freezing and confiscation orders, allowing orders
to better circulate around the Union. This would also make the legal framework
more coherent. This option would also entail the mutual recognition of compensation
orders (policy action 14). The legal framework
could be simplified by consolidating FD 2006/783/JHA and 2005/214/JHA and
extending their scope to include all compensation orders made in the context of
criminal proceedings. As under the
minimal legislative policy option, this option would also provide for consolidated
mutual recognition forms (policy action 19) and for
measures enforcing the primacy of mutual recognition (policy action
20).
7.
Analysis of the impacts of the policy options
The five policy options (including two
suboptions under maximal legislative option) have been assessed against an overall
estimate of their social, economic and environmental impacts. No environmental
impacts were identified. Given the scarcity
of measurable indicators and the lack of a coherent comparative statistics
system on confiscation and asset recovery across the EU, it is almost
impossible to quantify with precision the potential impacts of the policy
options (some including policy actions which are very different in nature). Qualitative
assessment therefore complements the analysis when quantification is not
possible. The figure
below shows the main social and economic impacts and highlights in bold those
which can be analysed meaningfully. Impacts flowing from a reduction in crime
cannot be analysed because there is insufficient evidence that asset
confiscation will reduce crime. Figure 5: Impacts which can be assessed meaningfully
7.1.
Analysis of Option 1 - Status Quo
For the reasons
indicated in Section 3.5, on the ‘do nothing’ option, slow progress
can be predicted towards achieving each of the specific objectives (i.e.
confiscation, preservation, enforcement, utilisation and distribution). Economic impact: Is expected to be low, resulting from natural progression in
assets recovered. The spread between criminally owned assets and assets
recovered by governments is likely to increase. Social impact: Is likely to be negligible, mostly resulting from an increased
application of social reuse practices across Europe and possibly leading to a
slight increase in criminal assets being recovered in favour of crime victims. Impact on criminal
behaviour: Without additional action at EU level,
criminals are likely to continue investing their assets in other Member States,
thereby increasing the need for a cross-border dimension of confiscation
activities. Overall
assessment of Option 1: The analysis in
Section 4.3 revealed significant gaps, mutual recognition instruments would remain
underutilised and the amount of criminal assets confiscated throughout the EU would
remain small compared to estimates of organised criminal turnover. Whilst the
situation without EU intervention would not be static, the pace of change would
be too slow. This option would therefore not achieve the objective of
increasing the recovery of criminal assets in the Union. Member States support
for this option is unlikely. The European Parliament is expected to be totally
dissatisfied with this solution.
7.2.
Analysis of Option 2 – Non-legislative option
Economic impact: Transposition workshops on the EU legislation in force would not
be particularly expensive and could entail a slight positive impact on
transposition (and ultimately on assets recovered) by speeding up the process
for the Member States which have not yet fully transposed the relevant texts.
The costs of utilisation workshop would depend on the scale on which they are
organised and their usefulness would likely be proportional to their scale.
Given the severe underutilisation of confiscation procedures (as evidenced in
the Matrix Study, see footnote 10) utilisation workshops could potentially have
a more significant impact upon utilisation and avoid that decisions may
continue to be made based on the assumption that asset confiscation work is
unprofitable. Their added value would be proportional to the creation of a
suitable evidence base. Transposition workshops on adopted EU legislation are
regularly organised in Brussels. A meeting organised at the Commission
premises, using the Commission interpreters and covering the travel expenses of
two government experts per Member State costs around € 30 000. Utilisation
workshops organised at EU level by the Commission would entail similar costs.
If organised at national level, utilisation workshops are likely to be less
expensive (lower travel costs, no interpretation needed) than those organised
at EU level. Social
impact: The direct impact would be negligible,
as workshops would impact on State authorities. A complete and correct
transposition of EU legislation on extended confiscation and mutual recognition
in the Member States and utilisation of confiscation tools would indirectly
result in more compensation to victims and increased confidence in the criminal
justice system. An increase in the use of extended confiscation would
correspond to an increased limitation of the fundamental rights (right to
property, right to a fair trial, presumption of innocence) of the defendant. It
should normally be balanced by adequate safeguards in national legislation (if
Framework Decision 2005/212/JHA is correctly transposed). Impact on criminal
behaviour: To the extent that this option can be
expected to generate increased utilisation of existing tools, any impact on
criminal behaviour is expected to be quite limited. While it may cause
occasional criminal capital flight, this option will likely oblige criminals to
better hide their assets, for example by increasingly transferring them to a
knowing third party before their conviction in a criminal court. It may
therefore have a feeble negative impact on the illicit economy and on the
economies of third countries[29]. Overall
assessment of Option 2: Overall the added value of
the non-legislative option is likely to be low. Although
transposition remains incomplete, there is only slight scope for
non-legislative action alone to add value in circumstances where the existing
legal framework will become enforceable by 2014 in any event[30].
The organisation of EU transposition workshops could also affect practitioners'
perception and facilitate enforcement. However, the most promising aspect of
the non-legislative option is the utilisation workshops. This option would
hardly achieve the objective of increasing the recovery of criminal assets in
the Union. It would also draw heavy criticism from the European Parliament.
7.3.
Analysis of Option 3 – Minimal
legislative option
Economic impact: the impacts of transposition workshops (Actions 1 and 12) and
utilisation workshops (Action 15) are described above. Improving mutual
recognition instruments by consolidating confiscation and compensation orders (policy
action 14), providing consolidated mutual recognition forms (policy action 19) and/or
enhancing the primacy of mutual recognition (policy action 20) would
clearly increase the number of cross-border enforcement procedures and, to some
extent, the value of the assets recovered. However, it is hard to assess the
economic added value of even a significant increase in the utilisation of mutual
recognition instruments. An increased utilisation in mutual recognition instruments would
shift administrative costs from central authorities (in charge of mutual legal
assistance) to (local) judicial authorities. As mutual recognition is less convoluted
than mutual legal assistance, the administrative cost of handling requests from
other Member States should in principle decrease. The extent of this slight
decrease in direct costs would depend on the relative efficiency of the
different parts of Member State bureaucracies. The time savings resulting from
a wider use of mutual recognition
(as opposed to mutual legal assistance) would allow
faster cross-border execution and increase the chances of successful recovery
by limiting the risks for asset dissipation. The envisaged consolidation of mutual
recognition forms may require some training for the practitioners to use the new
single mutual recognition form. These costs would be likely offset by the benefits in the form
of increased value of assets recovered (resulting from an increased number of
cross-border enforcement procedures). Social
impact: A
moderate increase in the number and value of assets recovered should logically
correspond to a moderate increase in compensation to victims. Better enforcement
of cross-border procedures would likely result in increased confidence in the
national criminal justice systems and in the EU Area of Justice, Freedom and
Security. In relation to fundamental rights, the increase in the cross-border
enforcement of orders will concern ordinary confiscation. Because this is the
procedure with the least impact on fundamental rights, a low impact on the
right to property is expected. Impact on
criminal behaviour: Slight, as it results
from an increased utilisation of existing tools and increased mutual
recognition of orders issued in other countries. As under option 2, it would
oblige criminals to better hide their assets (eg using third parties). A better
enforcement of cross-border procedures may have some displacement effects,
resulting in a net capital flight of criminal money out of the EU. It may
therefore have a slight negative impact on the illicit economy and on the
economies of third countries. Overall
assessment of Option 3: Overall the added value of
the minimal legislative option is likely to be moderate.
In addition to the (low) added value of option 2, the increased enforcement of
freezing and confiscation orders in other Member States resulting from better mutual
recognition instruments would likely produce limited economic and social
impacts. However, policy actions 19 and 20, aimed at facilitating the mutual
recognition of orders, would significantly enhance utilisation of mutual
recognition instruments although action 19 has additional benefits over action
20. Moreover, an enhanced utilisation of mutual recognition over mutual legal
assistance would substantially reduce the time necessary to enforce freezing
and confiscation orders in other Member States. This option would barely
achieve the objective of increasing the recovery of criminal assets in the
Union. It would likely not be considered as an adequate response to the problem
by the European Parliament.
7.4.
Analysis of Option 4.1 -
Maximal legislative option without mutual
recognition
The maximal
legislative option (in its sub-option without mutual recognition)
builds upon the non-legislative option by introducing a number of new aspects into
the existing EU legal framework, i.e. all policy actions which do not involve
legislative action in relation to mutual recognition. Economic
impact: In addition to the impacts of transposition
workshops (Actions 1 and 12) and utilisation workshops (Action 15) described
above, it can be estimated that most of the actions in this policy option,
considered in isolation, would have at least a moderately positive
economic impact. For example, although policy action 10 on new powers to
realise frozen assets would entail implementation costs (introduction of
procedures to sell frozen assets), these would be largely or entirely offset by
the benefits in the form of reduced ongoing costs for asset management and no
decrease in the value of the assets. Policy Action 7 introducing confiscation
from third parties would produce, even in its most limited form[31],
at least a moderate increase in the confiscation powers and hence in the value
of assets recovered. The application of policy action 6 introducing non-conviction
based confiscation, even in limited circumstances has demonstrated that it may
have a substantial impact on organised crime as illustrated in box 5 . Box 5 – Operation "Nemesi": In Italy the application of non-conviction based confiscation provisions to a dead suspect's heirs has allowed in 2010 to freeze, in a single case, assets estimated at € 700 million at least. Dante Passarelli, a businessman suspected of being the "fiduciary person" of the head of the Camorra Casalesi clan, died in unexplained circumstances. He had been convicted of participation in a criminal organisation by a first instance criminal court, but an appeal was pending. The assets frozen (registered in his name or attributed to him by investigators) included 136 apartments, 11 warehouses, 75 land estates, 8 shops, 2 villas, 51 garages, company shares and bank accounts, for a total amount estimated between € 700 million and € 2 billion. In 2008 Italy passed legislation which could prevent the heirs from a deceased defendant, whose assets have been frozen or seized, from legally inheriting the assets and having them released. Mr Passarelli's wife and 6 children were not able to explain the licit origin of all these assets, nor the huge disproportion between their declared revenues and the frozen assets. The reuse of
confiscated assets for social purposes may also have economic benefits,
allowing NGOs to start business activities using confiscated assets[32]
which normally become profitable over time. On the other hand, separating
criminal proceedings from confiscation proceedings (Action 4) would likely
result in slightly increased direct costs (due to additional procedures). These
costs can likely be offset by the expected increase in the assets recovered,
resulting from being able to identify and pursue criminal assets for a longer
time, even when criminal proceedings are over. Because of the severe lack of data
in relation to amounts frozen, confiscated and recovered, and in relation to
the costs of carrying out confiscation-related activities, it is not possible
to provide a quantification of the overall cost of this option. Moreover, in
many cases implementation costs may differ depending on the characteristics of
the Member States, for example for social reuse programmes (Action 21) and in
some cases costs would depend on how Member States would implement an action.
For example, the separation of criminal and confiscation proceedings (Action 4)
could be applied automatically in all cases or only in cases where this is
considered necessary. The administrative burden related to the reporting
obligations (Action 16) would also vary between Member States, depending on the
extent to which they do or do not already collect some of the data required for
reporting purposes. In order to
address the lack of data described earlier, the main economic analysis presented
is an EU27 profitability estimate based on a model which uses proxy
indicators to extrapolate from a detailed analysis of income and cost in the UK
(details in Annexes 4 and 5). The UK is the only Member State for which income
and costs for all elements of the asset confiscation system can be estimated. Its
asset confiscation system is also a reasonable approximation of the maximal
legislative sub-option under consideration. Although only indicative, the
results of this exercise are encouraging: 21 of 27 Member States are indicated
by the model to be profitable (many of them highly profitable) for the maximal
legislative option in its sub-option without mutual recognition. Table
3: Profitability of maximal legislative option without mutual recognition, EU27 Member State || Revenue (€m) || Cost (€m) || Profit (€m) || Profit ratio (profit/cost) || Categorisation Czech Republic || 131.00 || 36.57 || 94.43 || 3.50 || Highly profitable Lithuania || 188.08 || 131.08 || 57.00 || 2.63 || Highly profitable Spain || 167.56 || 124.86 || 42.70 || 2.58 || Highly profitable Latvia || 31.66 || 10.87 || 20.79 || 2.12 || Highly profitable Poland || 19.21 || 4.27 || 14.94 || 1.91 || Highly profitable Slovakia || 32.49 || 18.33 || 14.15 || 1.46 || Highly profitable Slovenia || 105.42 || 91.92 || 13.49 || 1.37 || Highly profitable Romania || 109.13 || 96.73 || 12.40 || 1.16 || Highly profitable Estonia || 19.24 || 13.80 || 5.44 || 1.11 || Highly profitable Bulgaria || 10.78 || 5.77 || 5.01 || 0.87 || moderately profitable Hungary || 8.89 || 4.12 || 4.77 || 0.81 || moderately profitable Netherlands || 12.88 || 8.32 || 4.56 || 0.77 || moderately profitable Portugal || 8.02 || 4.43 || 3.59 || 0.55 || moderately profitable Malta || 5.85 || 2.38 || 3.47 || 0.46 || moderately profitable UK || 21.39 || 19.22 || 2.17 || 0.43 || moderately profitable Cyprus || 2.74 || 0.75 || 1.99 || 0.42 || moderately profitable Greece || 3.43 || 1.45 || 1.98 || 0.39 || moderately profitable Italy || 2.37 || 0.76 || 1.61 || 0.34 || moderately profitable France || 2.11 || 1.49 || 0.62 || 0.15 || moderately profitable Germany || 1.00 || 0.48 || 0.53 || 0.13 || moderately profitable Belgium || 0.26 || 0.18 || 0.08 || 0.11 || moderately profitable Luxembourg || 1.48 || 1.51 || -0.03 || -0.02 || Not profitable Sweden || 7.67 || 8.62 || -0.96 || -0.11 || Not profitable Austria || 7.74 || 9.27 || -1.53 || -0.17 || Not profitable Ireland || 7.66 || 9.89 || -2.23 || -0.23 || Not profitable Finland || 1.99 || 4.33 || -2.35 || -0.54 || Not profitable Denmark || 1.73 || 5.79 || -4.06 || -0.70 || Not profitable The fact that
asset confiscation work appears to be potentially profitable in most Member
States pleads in favour of EU-level intervention For the minority of Member
States for which asset confiscation may be unprofitable (mostly Nordic Member
States where relatively low criminality and commensurately low investment in
policing may results in less assets recovered) this does not detract from the
case for EU-level intervention. In fact, even the maximal legislative options would
oblige all Member States to transpose the new EU provisions into their
legislation, but would not force reluctant Member States to incur the (higher)
costs of increased utilisation of confiscation procedures. (ii) Social
impact: It can be assumed that recovering more
assets in favour of the State will have a significant social impact as it will,
provide funding for public authorities for provision of public services,
including in favour of victims of crime. (iii) Fundamental
rights impacts: Actions having a significant positive impact upon
confiscation tools (eg Action 5 on extended confiscation, 6 on non-conviction
based confiscation or 7 on third party confiscation) are also those with the
biggest impact on fundamental rights. Defence lawyers expressed concerns about
their possible increased use. On the other hand, these measures were considered
extremely important by investigators, prosecutors and other practitioners. A
limitation of the right to property and right to a fair trial of the defendant must
be justified, respect proportionality and be accompanied by adequate
safeguards. While conviction-based
confiscation regimes, as such, are rarely problematic from a fundamental rights
perspective, non-conviction based and extended confiscation regimes are more
contentious. The ECtHR has rendered many decisions, consistently upholding
their application in particular cases. However, it has avoided ruling on the
principled question of their compatibility with the Convention. Since these
regimes do not pursue solely a punitive objective, they have to be justified on
broader grounds. With regard to Articles 47 (right to a fair trial) and 48
(presumption of innocence) of the Charter and to the corresponding Articles 6 and
13 of the European Convention on Human Rights (ECHR), non-conviction based
confiscation regimes have consistently been held to be civil in nature, and the
ECtHR has also refused to qualify extended confiscation as a ‘criminal charge’.
Reversals of
the burden of proof concerning the legitimacy of assets have so far survived
the scrutiny of the ECtHR, so long as they were applied fairly in the
particular case, with adequate safeguards in place to allow the affected person
to challenge these rebuttable presumptions. For example in a specific case
the Italian regime was held to be a proportionate restriction in as much as it
constitutes a “necessary weapon” in the fight against the Mafia. In another
specific case the UK civil confiscation regime was upheld and considered more
generally targeted at recovering criminal assets that did not lawfully belong
to the applicant. The right to
be presumed innocent until proven guilty under Article 48 of the Charter only
applies when a person has been charged under criminal law and not where the
proceedings are civil in nature. Before the European Court of Human Rights, defendants
in non-conviction based confiscation proceedings have argued that these are
criminal and violate the right to the presumption of innocence, but these
arguments have so far failed before the ECtHR. It is also
harder to justify the compatibility of extended confiscation with the right to
property. Indeed, the confiscation order extends to assets beyond those derived
from the offence for which the person was convicted in the main proceedings. It
therefore has to be shown that it pursues a broader legitimate objective to
that of punishing the individual. While the ECtHR has consistently upheld extended
confiscation regimes in specific cases (eg the Italian regime, which is perhaps
the most severe regime in the EU as it combines non-conviction based and
extended confiscation), their compatibility with the Convention is assessed on
a case by case basis. Again, the degree of procedural safeguards afforded to the
defendant plays a determinant role in assessing the proportionality of the
measure. A strong
argument in favour of justifying third party confiscation is the case where assets
are claimed both by the third party and by a victim. If the perpetrator of a
crime has insufficient assets to meet a claim (as is often the case), measures
in favour of the third party would weaken the position of the victim. Temporary measures,
such as freezing orders may, due to their provisional character, justify further
limitations of certain rights and traditional principles of due process,
provided sufficient safeguards or remedies are available and those limitations
respect the essence of those rights and principles (compare Art. 52 of the
Charter of Fundamental Rights). Many States use techniques such as ex parte
or in camera proceedings to ensure that the affected person is not able
to defeat the purpose of the order through prior knowledge of it. So far, the
ECtHR has repeatedly held that the Italian procedural rules for ordering a
preventative confiscation violate the right to a fair hearing as they do not
foresee the possibility for the defendants to ask for a public hearing. It thus
becomes even more pressing to avoid that national measures which may violate the
ECHR or the Charter could benefit from EU rules on mutual recognition. If applied
with proportionality and complemented with adequate safeguards, laid down in
the EU legislative proposals, the measures in this policy option would respect
fundamental rights.[33].
According to the jurisprudence of the ECtHR the existence of effective legal
remedies is a pre-condition to ensure that fundamental rights are respected. Equally,
under the Charter of Fundamental Rights, it is necessary that EU legislation
itself contains sufficient procedural safeguards and remedies (see Box 7). Box 7 – Legal remedies The existing EU legislation (eg Article 4 of Framework Decision 2005/212/JHA) provides that Member States should ensure that adequate legal remedies for the affected persons exist in national legislation. With a view to fully comply with the EU Charter on Fundamental Rights, safeguards are required at EU level in order to guarantee, the respect of the presumption of innocence, the right not to be tried or punished twice in criminal proceedings for the same criminal offence, the right to a fair trial, the existence of effective judicial remedies before a court and the right to be informed on how to exercise such remedies. (iv) Impact on criminal behaviour: Would
be significant, as non-conviction based confiscation (even in limited
circumstances) and third party confiscation would oblige criminals to change
their practices and make it more difficult for them to hide their assets. This
option could cause moderate capital flight of criminal money to non-EU
countries and have a significant negative impact on the illicit economy and on
the economies of third countries. Overall
assessment of Option 4.1: Overall the added value
of the maximal legislative option (sub-option without mutual recognition)
is likely to be significant. The fact that asset confiscation work
appears to be potentially profitable in most Member States is a strong argument
which significantly reduces the immediate need to demonstrate other benefits.
However, significant social benefits can also be expected, provided that the
actions most likely to affect fundamental rights are proportional in their
scope and balanced by adequate safeguards. The immediate impacts of
implementing this option include stronger systems for confiscation, freezing,
managing and redistributing assets. However, this option would also bring an important
impact on utilisation. Member States do not want to be seen to be performing
poorly. While utilisation workshops would inform Member State decision-makers
about the potential profitability of asset confiscation work and thus empower
them to promote change, more powerful legislative tools would encourage
utilisation by concretely raising the chances of successful intervention. Moreover,
harmonisation of confiscation laws can also de facto promote mutual
recognition by ensuring that incoming orders are compatible with the judicial
system of the executing Member State. This option would achieve the objective
of increasing the recovery of criminal assets in the Union. Most likely it
would be moderately welcomed by the European Parliament.
7.5.
Analysis of Option 4.2 - Maximal legislative option including mutual recognition
Economic
impact: In economic terms, adding EU-level action
on mutual recognition (policy actions 14, 19 and 20 aiming to ensure
utilisation of mutual recognition
instruments, the impacts of which are described in
Section 7.3, and policy action 13 which aims at expanding the scope of mutual
recognition to all orders) would improve the results of the EU27 profitability
analysis still further. However, given the scarcity of data on the number and
amounts of orders to be enforced in other Member States, a detailed
profitability estimate by country for this policy option is not possible. The
additional costs for Member States liable to receive many foreign non-conviction
based orders for execution would be fully offset by the existing provision (in
FD 2006/783/JHA) that the Member State enforcing a confiscation order is
entitled to retain 50% of the recovered value[34]. Social
impact: Significant. In addition to the
impacts described in Section 7.4 (more assets recovered in favour of the
victims and victimised communities and increased confidence in the national
criminal justice systems, increased impact on fundamental rights which requires
new provisions to comply with the principle of proportionality and be balanced
by adequate safeguards) the important enhancements on mutual recognition can be expected to
result in increased confidence in the EU Area of Justice, Freedom and Security.
Impact on
criminal behaviour: Significant. The
measures in the maximal legislative option (notably non-conviction based
confiscation in limited circumstances and third party confiscation), coupled
with a significantly improved enforcement of cross-border procedures (resulting
especially from the expansion of mutual recognition to all types of orders,
including non-conviction based orders) would likely oblige criminals to change
their practices and could have displacement effects, resulting in a net capital
flight of criminal money out of the EU. This would result in an even more
significant impact on the illicit economy and on the economies of third
countries. Overall
assessment of Option 4.2: Overall, the added value
of the maximal legislative option (sub-option with mutual recognition)
is likely to be very significant. The combined effects of economic
profitability, significant social impacts (both on victims and victimised
communities through more assets recovered in favour of victims and more social
reuse) and greater utilisation are further enhanced by actions on mutual
recognition which are more far-reaching than those described in Section 7.3.
Together with the other policy actions, the latter will significantly improve
the status quo as regards cross-border enforcement of orders throughout
the Union. This is important because barriers to enforcement are effectively a
dampener on profitability, tending to discourage utilisation in Member States
with non-conviction based confiscation regimes. This option would be fully
consistent with the objective of increasing the recovery of criminal assets in
the Union. It would likely be welcomed by the European Parliament.
8.
Comparing the policy options
8.1.
Comparison of options and justification for
choosing the preferred option
As a reminder,
the table below summarises the objectives, policy actions/options and their
expected impacts. In the table ü indicates that there is no problem, ?
indicates a potential problem, ?? indicates a likely problem, and û
indicates a clear problem, in which case the action itself is struck out
(screening). Impacts (applied vis-à-vis the ‘no change’
baseline) are rated + or – for slight impacts, ++ or –
– for moderate impacts, and +++ or – – – for significant
impacts. Table 4: comparison of policy actions and options against objectives
and with expected impacts The table below shows that the potential impacts of the policy
actions in the Member States could be very different based on the differences
in their legislation, structures and practices. There is a wide gap between
countries which have only basic rules and structures in place, such as Greece,
to countries with very sophisticated and effective systems, such as the
Netherlands. In the table, ü denotes that the measure under consideration is already
implemented, û denotes that it is not, P denotes partial
implementation, A
denotes an alternative approach to the objective, ? denotes a gap in the dataset and P/? denotes at least partial implementation. Table
5 - Location of potential impacts by Member State Bearing in
mind the analysis of impacts, each policy option can be ranked in terms of its
impact against the five specific objectives of enhancing confiscation,
preservation, enforcement, utilisation and social utility from recovered
assets (redistribution). Based on the first four of these rankings,
a ranking can also be derived for impact upon the number of assets recovered
(which corresponds to the problem of insufficient recovery). In the tables
below, rankings are expressed in decreasing order, 1 being the highest score. Table 6: Preliminary ranking of options against specific objectives Specific objective || Policy option rankings No change || Non-legislative || Minimal legislative || maximal without MR || Maximal with MR Confiscation || 0 || 2 || 2 || 1 || 1 Preservation || 0 || 2 || 2 || 1 || 1 Enforcement || 0 || 3 || 2 || 3 || 1 Utilisation || 0 || 4 || 2 || 3 || 1 Redistribution || 0 || 4 || 3 || 2 || 1 Assets recovered* || 0 || 3 || 2 || 2 || 1 * Impact on number of assets recovered is a function of confiscation, preservation, enforcement and utilisation. The maximal
legislative options entail a higher impact on confiscation, preservation and
redistribution with respect to the other options. The minimal legislative
option impacts positively on enforcement and utilisation. The maximal
legislative options entail a higher overall impact on assets recovered. The
sub-option with mutual recognition (which includes all actions in the minimal legislative
option and the maximal option without mutual recognition) would have the
highest impact. The table below
shows the policy options ranked against each other with reference to the
impacts, the potential barriers to implementation and other factors, using the
same ranking criterion (1 being the highest). It finally shows an overall
assessment in the form of a ranking. Table 7: Ranking of options against impacts, barriers and criteria Criteria || Policy option no change || Non-legislative || minimal legislative || maximal without MR || Maximal with MR Economic Impacts || 0 || 4 || 3 || 2 || 1 Social Impacts || 0 || 4 || 3 || 2 || 1 Fundamental Rights || 0 || 1 || 1 || 2 || 2 Proportionality || 0 || 1 || 1 || 2 || 2 MS compatibility || 0 || 1 || 1 || 2 || 3 Simplicity & coherence || 0 || 4 || 2 || 3 || 1 Implementation costs || 0 || 1 || 1 || 2 || 2 Administrative burden || 0 || 1 || 1 || 2 || 2 Geographical disposition || 0 || 1 || 1 || 1 || 1 Overall assessment || 0 || 3 || 2 || 2 || 1 As described in
Sections 7.4 and 7.5, the maximal legislative options entail higher economic
and social impacts than the other options, while having a bigger impact also on
fundamental rights, proportionality, compatibility, costs and administrative
burden. This analysis clearly shows that the preferred policy option is
the maximal option featuring action on mutual recognition. The maximal
legislative option without action on mutual recognition and the minimal
legislative option are ranked equal second.
8.2.
Proportionality and subsidiarity of the
preferred option
The preferred
option respects the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality because it
does not go beyond what is needed to achieve the objectives described in
section 5 whilst respecting fundamental rights. The maximal legislative option
including mutual recognition would considerably enhance the confiscation and
enforcement powers of the Member States, inter alia by amending existing
provisions on extended confiscation and introducing new provisions on non-conviction
based confiscation, third party confiscation introducing the mutual recognition of all types of orders (including non-conviction based orders). However, its policy
actions would be calibrated in order to be proportionate and not unduly affect
fundamental rights. For example the introduction of harmonised non-conviction
based confiscation provisions is not foreseen in all cases, but only in very
limited cases where the defendant cannot be prosecuted (due to death, illness,
abscondence or immunity). Third party confiscation would not be allowed in all
cases, but only when the acquiring third party should have suspected that the
assets are proceeds of crime and paid less than market value. In order to meet
the concerns expressed by defense lawyers, safeguards at EU level are foreseen
with a view to fully comply with the EU Charter on Fundamental Rights. In order
to reach an equivalent outcome, virtually all Member States would have to amend
their national legislation. However, these legislative changes would not be
coordinated and would in any case not address the mutual recognition of foreign
orders (where common rules are required). As a result, effective freezing and confiscation
of assets would not be possible in all cross-border cases.
9.
Implementation, monitoring and Evaluation
The implementation of the preferred
option should be subject to future monitoring and evaluation. This report
has repeatedly highlighted the lack of statistical data on asset confiscation
and the poor quality of available data. As a result of these data gaps, it is
currently not possible to carry out a proper evidence-based assessment of the
impact of new policies/legislation at EU level or at Member State level in most
countries. In addition, information on the extent to which mutual recognition
facilitates cross-border enforcement is not readibly available as a result of
which the role of mutual recognition is poorly understood. For this
reason, the preferred option includes the introduction of reporting obligations
on the Member States in relation to asset confiscation work. Data will be
collected by judicial authorities (courts, prosecution offices) asset
management offices and other authorites in charge of asset disposal, at least
on an annual basis[35]. The data so collected
will feed into monitoring and evaluation activities and will allow the
Commission to assess to what extent the proposed legislation achieves its objectives.
Particular attention should be paid to those Member States where data
collection is relatively under-developed.
Examples of the type of data that could be collected include: · Number of freezing orders executed · Number of confiscation orders executed · Value of assets frozen · Value of assets recovered · Number of requests for freezing orders to
be executed in another Member State · Number of requests for confiscation orders
to be executed in another Member State · Value of assets recovered following
execution in another Member State · Value of assets destined to social use · Number of cases where confiscation is
ordered/ number of convictions for the criminal offences covered by the
Directive. In order to
monitor the effective implementation of the proposed legislation the Commission will prepare an
implementation plan and produce regular implementation reports based on
consultations of the Member States and stakeholders. The first report is in
principle foreseen three years after the entry into force of the legislation. The mapping exercise of the asset confiscation
legislation in the Member States which was carried out in preparation for the
present impact assessment could be used as a baseline for monitoring
developments in law and utilisation in the Member States. Evaluations will also be carried out on a regular
basis, the first report being foreseen five years
after the entry into force of the legislation. The evaluation reports could include a cost-benefit modelling exercise
to assess the current and estimate the future profitability of asset
confiscation work. Transposition
workshops and other expert meetings will also take place to discuss
implementation problems. The exchange of best practices in all the phases of
the confiscation process will continue to take place within the EU Asset
Recovery Offices Platform.
Annex
1 Summary of fieldwork of the external IA study Fieldwork was carried out in situ and/or
by telephone in all 27 EU Member States. In order to understand how Member State
laws operate in practice through the EU, government practitioners (i.e. police,
prosecutors and others) were interviewed in each Member State. Only in Poland
did scheduling difficulties prevent this. This core of interviews was
complemented with other perspectives from judges, defence lawyers, academics
and, in the Italian case, from persons with experience in the social reuse of
confiscated assets. Table 1 summarises this fieldwork. Table
1 Fieldwork in Member States Moreover interviews were held with
representatives of EU and international institutions: ·
Europol ·
Eurojust ·
CARIN
(the Camden Asset Recovery Inter-Agency Network) ·
Moneyval ·
FATF ·
Council
of Europe: European Court of Human Rights ·
Council
of Europe: Venice Commission Annex 2 Confiscation
statistics Statistics are presented for the following
Member States where relevant material was provided or located through fieldwork
and data search: ·
Bulgaria ·
France ·
Germany ·
Hungary ·
Ireland ·
Italy ·
Netherlands ·
United Kingdom Bulgaria Table 2 Bulgarian Statistics, 2006-2010 || Freezing cases p/a || Assets frozen p/a (€m) || Confiscation cases p/a || Costs* (€ millions) 2006 || 100 || 21.8 || 12 || . 2007 || 109 || 66.6 || 33 || . 2008 || 126 || 66.3 || 57 || . 2009 || 155 || 254 || 79 || 6.5 Source: CEPACA Annual Report (2009). As at the end of 2009, of all the
confiscation cases brought to date: ·
133 remained at first instance trial, ·
28 decisions at first instance (CEPACA won 22), ·
13 decisions at second instance (CEPACA won 7), ·
6 cases finalised (CEPACA won 4). Recovered assets from the 4 cases won =
€1.0m. Value of assets in the 29 successful cases
= €10m. France Table 3 French statistics (2005-2009) || Freezings by police (€m) || Freezings by Gendarmerie (€m) || Total freezings (€m) 2005 || . || . || 51.3 2006 || 60.5 || 11.4 || 71.9 2007 || 51.8 || 3.8 || 55.5 2008 || 35.1 || 58.8 || 93.9 2009 || 58 || 127.7 || 185.7 Source: Reports of PIAC (Platform for
Identification of Criminal Assets) Germany Table 4 German statistics, organised crime
(1992-2009) || % of O.C. investigations in which assets seized || Estimated O.C. profit in these cases (€m) || Amount seized (€m) || Total number of recorded crimes 1992 || 5.0% || . || . || . 1993 || 6.6% || . || || . 1994 || 6.8% || . || || . 1995 || 8.3% || . || <20 in mid 90s || . 1996 || 10.5% || . || || 6,647,598 1997 || 12.1% || . || || 6,586,165 1998 || 21.5% || . || . || 6,456,996 1999 || 22.2% || . || 118.5 || 6,302,316 2000 || 30.2% || . || . || 6,264,723 2001 || 30.7% || 760 || . || 6,363,865 2002 || 25.0% || 1,500 || 31 || 6,507,394 2003 || 25.3% || 468 || 69 || 6,572,135 2004 || 24.2% || 1,337 || 68 || 6,633,156 2005 || 25.4% || 842 || 97 || 6,391,715 2006 || 25.9% || 1,815 || 60 || 6,304,223 2007 || 29.1% || 481 || 39 || 6,284,661 2008 || 27.0% || 663 || 170 || . 2009 || 26.9% || 903 || 113 || . Source: Utilisation, freezing, profit (BKA
annual organised crime situation reports); Total number of crimes (Eurostat, 2010) It is important to note that utilisation,
amount seized and estimated profit refer to organised crime as defined in the
BKA. We do not have a precise definition of ‘profit’ in this context. Table 5 German statistics, all crime (1999-2009) || Number of proceedings in which assets confiscated || Total (state and civil) claim (€m) || Total amounts confiscated or forfeited (€m) || Total number of recorded crimes 1999 || - || - || 219 || 6,302,316 2000 || - || - || .536.9 || 6,264,723 2001 || - || - || .332.6 || 6,363,865 2002 || - || - || 294 || 6,507,394 2003 || - || - || - || 6,572,135 2004 || 6045 || 1268 || 306 || 6,633,156 2005 || 6010 || 1191 || 319 || 6,391,715 2006 || 6101 || 1066 || 301 || 6,304,223 2007 || 7050 || 592 || 219 || 6,284,661 2008 || - || - || - || - 2009 || 6725 || 901 || 281 || - Source: Confiscation statistics (Fieldwork,
FATF 2010, Fijnaut & Paoli (2004) Organised Crime in Europe pp752-753);
Total number of crimes (Eurostat, 2010) Hungary Table 6 Hungarian statistics (1999-2008) || Recorded crimes || Convictions (total) || Convictions (property and financial crime) || Forfeiture cases || Amount frozen/seized (€m) 1999 || 505,716 || 95398 || 50840 || 56 || . 2000 || 450,673 || || || || . 2001 || 465,694 || 94538 || 48249 || 14 || . 2002 || 420,782 || || || || . 2003 || 413,343 || 93442 || 45090 || 35 || . 2004 || 418,833 || || || || 41 2005 || 436,522 || 97558 || 44676 || 233 || 69 2006 || 425,941 || || || || 42 2007 || 426,914 || 86705 || 38112 || 598 || 102 2008 || . || || || || 57 Source: Utilisation, Amount frozen seized
(Police interviews and Criminality and Criminal Justice' report of Hungarian
Prosecutor General, 2008); Recorded crimes (Eurostat, 2010) These statistics evidence a rising
utilisation rate (forfeiture cases as a function of convictions). Data is not
available for amounts ordered confiscated or subsequently recovered. Ireland Table 7 Irish statistics (2003-2009) || CAB recovery from NCB confiscation (€m) || CAB recovery from revenue powers (€m) || CAB total recoveries (€m) || Running costs of CAB (€m) || Recorded crimes 2003* || ? || 10 || ? || 5.7 || 103,462 2004* || ? || 16.4 || ? || 5.7 || 99,244 2005 || 2 || 16.3 || 18.3 || 5.2 || 102,206 2006 || 3 || 19.1 || 22.1 || 5.2 || 103,178 2007 || 0.3 || 10 || 10.3 || 5,1 || . 2008 || 6.1 || 5.9 || 12.0 || 7.5 || . 2009 || 1.4 || 5.2 || 6.6 || 6.9 || . Source: CAB data (Annual Reports of the CAB);
Recorded crimes (Eurostat, 2010). The recovery data relates only to the
Criminal Assets Bureau (CAB) which has non-conviction based confiscation powers
and also revenue powers (i.e. the ability to levy tax on previously undeclared
income where even a non-conviction based case cannot be made out on the
evidence. Amounts recovered from non-conviction based confiscation mostly
relate to work from previous years due to a lag between the seizure of assets
and their vesting in the state (unless there is disposal by consent, the law
requires seven years).[36] Monies recovered by victims due to the work of CAB were not
identified and so were not available to add to these figures. Operating costs for the CAB include the
cost of training regular Gardi (police officers) so that conviction-based
confiscation can be performed at local level. No conviction based data is available. Italy Table 8 Italian statistics (1992-2009) || Assets investigated || Assets ordered confiscated || Final orders || Disposals || Recovered value (€) || Social reuse (€m) 1992 || || 0 || 13 || 9 || 1.8 || 0.5 1993 || || 85 || 9 || 3 || 0.4 || 0.1 1994 || || 1 || 27 || 2 || 0.2 || 0.1 1995 || || 0 || 22 || 5 || 1.0 || 0.5 1996 || || 15 || 102 || 18 || 3.7 || 2.7 1997 || || 71 || 340 || 63 || 18.6 || 9.3 1998 || || 155 || 404 || 129 || 18.2 || 8.6 1999 || || 392 || 640 || 216 || 37.2 || 27.2 2000 || || 435 || 575 || 249 || 38.9 || 18.2 2001 || || 203 || 718 || 231 || 47.4 || 35.4 2002 || || 211 || 477 || 329 || 89.9 || 71.5 2003 || || 464 || 300 || 287 || 40.8 || 22.5 2004 || || 660 || 328 || 287 || 47.4 || 27.1 2005 || || 1044 || 400 || 190 || 51.8 || 32.1 2006 || 4427 || 1566 || 414 || 172 || 31.8 || 10.0 2007 || 8040 || 1790 || 325 || 518 || 97.5 || 38.1 2008 || 6173 || 949 || 319 || 804 || 165.5 || 80.8 2009 || 12741 || 2333 || 380 || 544 || 101.3 || 60.7 TOTAL || 62551 || 11067 || 6207 || 4074 || 797.1 || 447.4 Source: Italian Department of Justice (2010) Social reuse data refers to assets used or
allocated for social purposes by municipalities. It does not include and
assets or revenue streams allocated to law enforcement agencies. Netherlands Table 9 Dutch statistics (2003-2009) || Frozen assets under administration (€m) || Amount ordered confiscated (€m) || Amount recovered (€m) || Recorded crimes 2003 || . || . || 10 || 1,369,271 2004 || . || . || . || 1,319,482 2005 || . || . || . || 1,255,079 2006 || . || . || . || 1,218,447 2007 || . || . || . || 1,214,503 2008 || 550 || . || 23.4 || . 2009 || 600 || 70 || 50 || . Source: Amount confiscated (Authors’
fieldwork) ; Recorded crimes (Eurostat, 2010) Data for frozen assets under administration
includes assets frozen in previous years and remaining under administration.
Data for amounts received refers to confiscation orders successfully enforced,
which typically relate to confiscation orders from previous years. United Kingdom Table 10 UK statistics (2001-2009) || Amount confiscated (£m, realised orders) || Recorded crimes 2001 || . || 6,085,903 2002 || . || 6,544,490 2003 || 25 || 6,548,691 2004 || 46 || 6,193,756 2005 || 84 || 6,096,153 2006 || 125 || 5,968,674 2007 || 136 || 5,444,648 2008 || 146 || . 2009 || 154 || . Source: Amount confiscated (UK Home Office);
Recorded crimes (Eurostat, 2010) Annex 3 List of
EU-level actions In order to
meet the specific and operational objectives identified and remedy the
shortcomings resulting from the problem definition, this impact assessment
proposes an analysis of 21 EU-level policy actions (some of which are
complementary) targeting particular operational objectives. They are described
below, grouped by the specific objectives to which they relate. Further harmonising the confiscation powers 1. Promoting implementation of existing confiscation
obligations. Although the trends towards compliance with FD 2005/212/JHA
are positive, the European Commission could help to ensure ongoing progress via
continued implementation/expert workshops. 2. Confiscation of all valuable benefits, including indirect
proceeds. The EU legal framework could harmonise a
definition of criminal ‘proceeds’, to ensure the recovery of ‘indirect’
proceeds resulting from the appreciation in value, or profitable reinvestment,
of direct proceeds. Harmonisation could also ensure that any valuable benefit
(including, for example, the value of liabilities avoided) is liable to
confiscation. 3. Civil standard of proof regarding whether an asset is "criminal". The standard of proof on whether particular assets are proceeds
could be harmonised to a lower "balance of probabilities" standard,
to make it more difficult for convicted criminals to retain type 1 assets. 4. Separate confiscation proceedings.
The EU legal framework could ensure that separate confiscation proceedings can
be brought also at a later date when criminal proceedings are finalised. 5. Strengthening
extended confiscation. The EU legal framework could
be simplified and strengthened by providing for extended confiscation at least
where a court finds it substantially more probable that the assets of a person
convicted of an offence covered by Article 83(1) TFEU are derived from other similar
criminal activities. 6. Non-conviction based confiscation in limited circumstances. The EU legal framework could make ordinary confiscation
possible in circumstances where a conviction cannot be obtained because the
suspect has died, fled the jurisdiction, or is unable to stand trial. 7. Third party confiscation. Laws
could be harmonised by requiring third party confiscation to be available for
assets received for less than market value and which a reasonable person in the
position of the third party would suspect to be derived from crime. Harmonising the preservation powers 8. Universal freezing. Harmonised minimum
standards for freezing could ensure that it is possible to preserve any assets
and would ease the mutual recognition of freezing orders. 9. Mechanisms to safeguard freezing. Member
States could be required to have in place appropriate mechanisms to ensure that
assets in danger of being hidden or transferred out of the jurisdiction are
able to be immediately frozen/seized. This would include, in appropriate
circumstances, the ability to freeze/seize prior to seeking a court order. 10. Powers to realise frozen assets. Harmonisation
could ensure that, regardless of how frozen assets are managed, there are
powers to realise them at least where they are liable to decline in value or
uneconomical to maintain. 11. Designating Asset Management Offices (AMOs). Further
harmonisation could require all Member States to entrust the management of
frozen assets to AMOs at a national or regional level. This could increase
efficiency and promote best practice. Enhancing the enforcement powers (mutual
recognition) 12. Promoting implementation of existing mutual recognition obligations. The
Commission could help to ensure ongoing progress in implementing Framework
Decisions 2003/577/JHA (freezing orders) and 2006/783/JHA (confiscation orders)
via implementation/expert workshops. 13. Mutual recognition of all types of orders. The EU
legal framework could remove existing limitations on the mutual recognition of
freezing and confiscation orders, allowing orders to better circulate around
the Union. This would also make the legal framework more coherent. 14. Mutual recognition of compensation orders. The legal
framework could be simplified by consolidating FD 2006/783/JHA and 2005/214/JHA
and extending their scope to include all compensation orders made in the
context of criminal proceedings. Enhancing the utilisation of existing
tools The existing
EU legal framework neither obliges utilisation nor provides for incentives for
cultural change through the normalisation of asset confiscation activity (where
failure by police and prosecutors through negligence or reticence to recover
criminal assets would be perceived as unacceptable). 15. Utilisation
workshops.
Utilisation workshops on the profitability of asset confiscation work to the
benefit of government decision-makers in some Member States could increase
utilisation of these tools and provide a forum for the sharing of scientific
knowledge and practitioner experience. 16. Reporting
obligations. Reporting obligations could be introduced, for example an
obligation to report, for all crimes covered by TFEU article 83(1), assets
frozen, the confiscation orders (if any) obtained and the type of order. This
would also help generating statistics which could be used for evaluation
purposes. 17. Mandatory
assets investigation. The EU legal framework could require investigators
to open a parallel financial investigation, at least for the crimes listed in
TFEU article 83(1). 18. Limited
judicial discretion. Judicial discretion could be limited by requiring
freezing to be ordered wherever there is reasonable cause to suspect that an
asset may become liable to confiscation and, in the event of a criminal
conviction, by requiring confiscation to be ordered unless doing so
would disproportionately affect fundamental rights. 19. Consolidated
mutual recognition forms. A single
form for all types of mutual recognition at the investigative stage could be provided
within the European Investigation Order (and by suppressing the existing mutual
legal assistance alternative). 20. Enforcing
the primacy of mutual recognition. The EU legal framework
could suppress the use of mutual legal assistance with respect to freezing and
confiscation by repealing the existing mutual legal assistance conventions as
regards requests between Member States . Annex 4 Asset recovery in the UK Utilisation trends As with other EU Member States, the UK’s
traditional approach to criminal justice has been to detect and prosecute
offenders, punishing them with fines and imprisonment. This approach came
under scrutiny following the Cuthbertson case, in which a drug
trafficker sentenced to a lengthy jail term retained £750,000 in proceeds
because the prevailing forfeiture regime in the Misuse of Drugs Act 1971
was too narrow. This led eventually to stronger asset recovery laws in the
form of the Drug Trafficking Offences Act 1986 and the Criminal
Justice Act 1988. These laws extended confiscation to all indictable
offences and introduced value confiscation. Extended confiscation—a reverse
burden of proof regarding the legitimacy of all assets acquired in the
preceding 6 years—was introduced for drug offences and then generalised by the Proceeds
of Crime Act 1995.[37] Visible impacts can be expected to lag the
introduction of such new powers for several reasons: it takes time for
practitioners to learn how to use them; it takes time for cases to progress
through the courts; legal challenges will further slow the first wave of
cases. Yet Levi and Osofsky reported in 1995 that confiscation powers were
still being utilised only occasionally for drug crimes, and rarely for other
crimes (Levi and Osofsky, 1995). Five years later,
the Performance and Innovation Unit of the Cabinet Office reported that: In the last five years, confiscation orders
have been raised in an average of only 20 per cent of drugs cases in which they
were available, and in a mere 0.3 per cent of other crime cases. The collection
rate is running at an average of 40 per cent or less of the amounts ordered by
the courts to be seized. Specially tasked law enforcement officers struggle to
investigate the financial aspects of crime to support this effort, but their
effectiveness is limited by their numbers and modest training.[38] This report’s recommendations included: a
strategic approach aimed at incentivising asset recovery work within
practitioner communities, more resources for financial investigation and a ‘new
legislative attack’. The latter took the form of the Proceeds of Crime Act
2002, which consolidated existing legislation, tightened some aspects and
introduced three new elements: a non-conviction based ‘civil recovery’ power, a
non-conviction based cash seizure/forfeiture regime and new revenue powers to
allow otherwise unrecoverable criminal profits to be taxed.[39] These new powers
were given over to a new Asset Recovery Agency (ARA), while responsibility for
conviction-based confiscation work remained with police forces throughout the
country. A year after the new legislation entered into force, a government
report concluded that there were: pockets of excellent practice but that the
overall application of the powers across England and Wales was patchy, with
money laundering and confiscation seen as complex, specialist activities,
divorced from mainstream business. Activity was often only targeted at the
higher profile ‘crime barons’ and almost exclusively against drug trafficking,
leading to failure to use POCA to its full potential. Opportunities to combat
those engaged in volume crime, street robbery and low-level drug dealing were
being missed.[40] Essentially, whereas ARA had embraced asset
recovery as its raison d’être, it remained alien to the mindset of
ordinary police officers and prosecutors. Part of the solution, beginning in
April 2004, was to raise utilisation within all relevant government
agencies through the Asset Recovery Incentivisation Scheme (ARIS), whereby 50%
of the revenue stream generated by confiscated assets is returned to the
agencies who played a role. Another part of the solution has been a concerted
effort to train and deploy financial investigators. These efforts have led to
increased utilisation, with more than 10% of Crown Court convictions for
acquisitive crimes (fraud, burglary, drug trafficking, etc) now resulting in
confiscation orders. Figure
11: Utilisation in the UK Crown
Court, April 2006 – March 2010 Source:
Data from JARD and other sources, collated by the National Policing Improvement
Agency Although a utilisation rate just above 10%
may seem low, the effective utilisation rate will be somewhat higher
because these total figures included cases in which a confiscation order would
be inappropriate, either because there are no relevant proceeds (despite the
offence being of an acquisitive type) or because there are known to be no
recoverable proceeds (e.g. where the proceeds have been dissipated). Against this,
there are also cases in which ‘nominal’ confiscation orders in the amount of £1
are obtained, to allow the issue to be reopened should proceeds be identified
at a later stage. Another interesting point to note is that,
in the last four years, recoveries in the Crown Court have been rising in
absolute terms (by an average of more than 12% a year) but not as a proportion
of convictions for acquisitive crimes in the Crown Court, because these too are
rising.[41] However, even though the 2006–2010 Crown Court time-series data
does not show an increasing rate of utilisation, a look at past statistics (for
example the 0.3% utilisation rate for non-drug cases quoted above) suggests an
increase in the wake of POCA 2002. Indeed, there is strong evidence of
this in the form of hugely increased treasury receipts, which reached £154m in
FY2009/10 (see Figure 12). This figure is, however, felt by the UK government
to be still too low. In particular, a recent report has bemoaned the UK law
enforcement community’s failure to ‘mainstream’ asset recovery work.
Significantly, it recognised that one of the main barriers may be
profitability: "There is a
dichotomy between the need to mainstream asset recovery if the value recovered
from confiscation is to grow significantly, and the risk that a move away from
specialisation could dilute skills, knowledge and experience, and prejudice
performance if it is not done in a carefully planned manner. One route out of
the conflict would involve a significant commitment to training and performance
management over a sustained period, in order to achieve the necessary shift in
thinking amongst frontline staff in all agencies. Alternatively, the way
forward is to recognise that mainstreaming is unlikely to provide value for
money, and focus resources where they will be most cost-effective, such as in
expanded specialist units. There is also an argument for making the statutory
process leading to a confiscation order more streamlined, so that orders take
less time, and there are fewer procedural steps to take; this could improve the
cost-effectiveness and the commitment to asset recovery at the same time."[42] We now turn to consider the profitability
of asset recovery work in the UK. We take a narrow approach, looking only at
the ongoing costs of asset recovery work and the annual revenue stream
generated, disregarding the value of any other potential economic, social and
environmental benefits. We focus on ongoing costs. We lack the data to
examine one-off costs, which we estimate to be small by comparison, especially
given the period under scrutiny (i.e. several years after the introduction of
the POCA 2002).
9.1.1.
Profitability analysis
The UK maintains a Joint Asset Recovery
Database (JARD) which records all amounts finally recovered in favour of the
state (though not those recovered in favour of victims). Records date back to
the financial year April 2003–March 2004 following the introduction of POCA
2002. Amounts are net of any management expenses payable to private
receivers, but not of agency operating costs. The data in Figure 12 shows a
clear upward trend, reflecting increasing utilisation of powers in recent
years, reaching £154m in FY2009/10. Figure
12: Assets recovered in favour
of the state, England and Wales, 2001-2009 Source:
UK Home Office 2003-2009, interview estimate for 2001 In order to analyse profitability we now
turn to consider the ongoing costs of asset recovery work within the UK. In
the absence of an equivalent system to JARD for
recording costs, we examine the constituent parts of
the UK’s asset confiscation apparatus. In many cases, the agencies concerned
have a reasonably good understanding of their own
costs, as there has been considerable emphasis placed on this politically.[43] Indeed, understanding
costs is essential when negotiating the division of assets returned as
incentives under ARIS.[44] In some cases, agencies have published information which directly
addresses costs and profitability. In other cases, we base our estimates on
expert opinions elicited through fieldwork with senior members of the agencies
themselves. Using this information, we are able to roughly estimate the
ongoing cost of the UK’s asset confiscation apparatus. We begin by reviewing the main ‘frontline’
agencies involved in asset recovery work, examining available cost data and
making assumptions where necessary along the way. ·
Police
authorities.
Police authorities are responsible for financial investigations in support of
criminal confiscation proceedings pursuant to POCA section 6, and also
(using their own legal representation) for the cash seizure/forfeiture
procedure in POCA Part 5. The UK has some 50 police authorities, all of
which are more or less engaged in asset confiscation work, using financial
investigators who receive the standard training. The Metropolitan Police is by
far the largest force. Data for the 2009/10 financial year shows that it spent
£10.7m on asset confiscation activity—including £500,000 funding for community
programmes—whilst it had receipts of £10.9m generated by asset confiscation
activity itself (calculated under ARIS as 50% of forfeited cash plus 18.75% of
conviction-based recoveries).[45] We assume similar levels of
profitability for other police authorities. ·
Her
Majesty’s Revenue and Customs (HMRC). HMRC has an equivalent role to the
police authorities, for cases within its area of responsibility. In the
absence of publicly available data, we make the same assumption for
profitability as per the police authorities, i.e. that it is equivalent
to that of the Metropolitan Police.[46] ·
The
Serious and Organised Crime Agency (SOCA). SOCA’s asset recovery work includes
conviction-based proceedings arising from its own investigations into serious
and organised crime (an equivalent role to the police authorities), non-conviction
based ‘civil recovery’ cases, exercise of revenue (taxation assessment) powers
and, where it seizes cash in the course of an investigation, the non-conviction
based cash seizure/forfeiture process. The civil recovery and revenue work was
previously undertaken by the Asset Recovery Agency (ARA), which was merged into
SOCA from 1 April 2008. As a sui generis entity administering a complex
piece of legislation, the ARA was beset with lengthy judicial processes and
never became ‘profitable’ in the sense that its costs exceeded the income
stream from its asset recovery work in all five years of its existence.
Recently, SOCA’s 2008/09 accounts have been audited in a way which specifically
permits comparison with the work previously performed by ARA (civil recovery,
taxation and some ‘legacy’ criminal confiscation cases).[47] In these comparable areas
(which represent the majority of SOCA’s asset recovery work), SOCA recovered
£20.2m at a cost (including receivers’ fees) of £16.3m. Having not obtained any
data regarding the profitability of the balance of SOCA’s asset recovery work
(additional conviction-based cases), we assume an equivalent level of
profitability. ·
The
Crown Prosecution Service (CPS). CPS brings conviction-based confiscation proceedings on the
back of investigations by the police, HMRC and SOCA, and also works to enforce
some of the more complex orders obtained.[48] On 1 January 2010, the CPS
absorbed the Revenue and Customs Prosecution Office (RCPO), which previously
brought confiscation cases on behalf of HMRC. Expenditure on asset recovery
work is not published; our own fieldwork (conversations with experts) suggests
that it is approximately equal to CPS’s share of ARIS revenue. An unpublished
internal audit of RCPO undertaken prior to its merger with CPS suggested that
its activities had previously been somewhat less profitable, though no figures
are given.[49] ·
Her
Majesty’s Courts Service (HMCS). HMCS enforces the majority of conviction-based confiscation
orders. This work involved writing letters, fixing hearing dates, and then
taking measures following the activation of default judgment by a Magistrate.
An unpublished study showed that in 2008/09, HMCS spent slightly less on asset
recovery work than the ARIS funding it received (at the rate of 12.5% of the
value of the orders enforced). [50] The roles of the agencies described above
(which are the main agencies administering POCA) are summarised in Figure 13. The
assessment of profitability can be summarised as follows: ·
Police,
HMRC, CPS and HMCS: approximately funded with ARIS funding. ·
SOCA:
recovers a little more than what it spends, but not enough to be funded through
its share of ARIS. Broadly speaking, there are two plausible
explanations for SOCA work being less profitable than that of the other
frontline agencies. First, mentioned already, is that SOCA administers
a sui generis regime which generates an additional legal burden as case
law must be generated, at significant expense in terms of legal fees. Second¸
SOCA generates less income through cash seizure/forfeiture powers than the
other investigative agencies. These powers are more profitable than other
powers because they involve abbreviated court procedures, with the entire 50%
of ARIS funding going to the investigative agency. A third explanation—higher
overheads due to smaller agency size, is less relevant following the ARA’s
merger into SOCA. Figure
13: Functions of ‘frontline’ UK
asset confiscation agencies || Investigation || Confiscation || Enforcement Criminal confiscation (including extended)— POCA s6 || Police; HMRC; SOCA || CPS || HMCS; CPS Civil recovery— POCA Part 5 Chapter 2 || SOCA Cash seizure/forfeiture— POCA Part 5 Chapter 3 || Police; HMRC; SOCA Taxation— POCA Part 5 Chapter 6 || SOCA Because the foregoing estimates are
expressed as fractions of amounts recovered and ARIS receipts, an absolute cost
estimate requires disaggregated recovery data. Available data for the 2008/09
financial year is provided in Table 2, for financial year 2008/09. Figure
14 Disaggregated treasury
receipts, FY 2008/09 Agency || Cash Forfeiture || Confiscation [with CPS/HMCS] || Civil Recovery & Taxation || Total Police || £27.51m || £54.03m || - || £81.54m HMRC || £10.51m || £18.91m || - || £29.42m SOCA || £1.78m || £10.05m || £16.83m || £28.66m Other || - || £6.09m || £2.29m || £8.38m Total || £39.80m || £89.08m || £19.12m || £148m It can be seen that the non-SOCA share of
confiscation work amounts to some £120m, including £8m ‘other’, which we will
assume to be similarly profitable to work undertaken by the non-SOCA agencies.[51] Based on the
foregoing assumptions, we therefore calculate the ongoing annual cost of asset
confiscation work performed by frontline agencies in the UK (specifically, in
England and Wales) in 2008/09 to be: 119.34 * 0.5 + 28.66 * (16.3 / 20.2) =
£82.8m In light of the numerous assumptions which
have been made (in particular around the police authorities and HMCS), it is
appropriate to express this amount as a range with ±15% uncertainty, i.e.
between £70.4m and £95.2m. To obtain a complete picture of the costs
of the administration it is also necessary to consider other costs not borne by
frontline agencies. The main such cost is that of an increased caseload for
the court system.[52] This cost is not accounted for within the foregoing analysis,
where the profitability analysis for HMCS refers only to enforcement work, and
not the cost of hearing cases. We begin by considering criminal
confiscation cases, which are typically heard in the Crown Court. In the absence
of any more specific data, we assume that the cost of such a case is the same
as the cost of the average Crown Court case.[53] In 2009, the Crown Court dealt with 147,200 cases, ranging from
guilty pleas to lengthy jury trials.[54] In 2007/08, the cost of operating the Crown Court was calculated
to be £382m.[55] This amounts to some £2,600 per case. Statistics for 2008/09
indicate that there were 4717 confiscation orders made in the Crown Court that
year; this amounts to a total cost of: 2,600 * 4,717 = £12.2m In addition, it is necessary to account for
the costs of civil confiscation cases and taxation cases (both brought by SOCA
in civil courts), as well as for cash seizure/forfeiture cases. The former may
be less costly to the court system than conviction-based cases because civil
courts charge fees, with the aim of making civil procedure cost-neutral to the
state. The latter may also be less costly, because an abbreviated procedure is
employed vis-à-vis conviction-based confiscation, and the cases are able to be
heard in the Magistrates Court, which has lower operating costs. On the other
hand, these non-conviction based cases have raised many new questions of law
which have been appealed to higher courts, causing much additional delay and
expense. Overall, therefore, we make the assumption that these cases present
the court system with a similar level of cost to conviction-based cases.
Applying a ratio of 148:89.1 (based on table 2) we therefore calculate the
overall ongoing annual cost upon courts as: 12.2 * (148 / 89.1) = £20.3m Again, in light of the broad-ranging
assumptions which have been made, it is appropriate to express this amount as a
range with ±15% uncertainty, i.e. between £17.3 and £23.4m. Summing front-line agency and court costs,
we arrive at the following estimate of overall annual ongoing cost (and thus
profitability, based on a known return of £148m) of asset recovery activity in
England and Wales for 2008/09. These calculations are set out in Figure 15. Figure
15 Cost and profit calculations
for FY 2008/09 Element || Low estimate || High estimate Cost (m£) || Profit (m£) || Cost (m£) || Profit (m£) Front-line agencies || 70.4 || || 95.2 || Courts || 17.3 || || 23.4 || Total || 87.7 || 60.3 || 118.6 || 29.4 To be sure, this analysis has examined the
profitability of asset recovery activity on FY 2008/09 only: being the sixth
year after the introduction of POCA 2002, and the fifth year after the
introduction of ARIS. Receipts to the state in that year flow from a
‘pipeline’ of work which includes many cases commenced in previous years;
similarly, many cases commenced in that year will not emerge from the pipeline
until future years.[56] The time taken for cases to progress through the pipeline varies
greatly: cash seizure/forfeiture cases in the Magistrates Court typically take
3 to 6 months (and are often only lightly contested), whilst conviction-based
cases in the Crown Court can take several years (until appeal rights are
exhausted), with convicted criminals often fighting hard to retain their wealth.
An important corollary is that, whereas asset recovery work in the UK appears
now to be profitable, it was not necessarily immediately profitable in the wake
of POCA 2002, due to: the lag in building a pipeline of work from an
initially low base; the costs associated with establishing the ARA from
scratch; and the costs of answering the legal challenges which inevitably
followed the introduction of novel powers. Unfortunately, whilst the ARA’s
financial statements are public, a lack of data for other elements of the
system prevents us from estimating profitability in these early years. Future possibilities We have seen that POCA 2002 and the
attendant focus on utilisation has led to increased asset recovery work, the
current level of which is profitable in the (narrow) sense that receipts into
government coffers exceed the total cost of the work itself. For the purpose
of impact analysis, it is useful to consider now the potential for continued
growth. This requires estimates of future recoveries and costs. Turning first to future recoveries, we
begin by examining the available time-series data in order to estimate the
relationship between past amounts collected and current amounts over the period
2003 to 2009. Statistical tests suggest the amount recovered in the current
year is correlated with the previous year’s amount recovered.[57] As such, we
regress the amount recovered in the current year on the amount recovered in the
previous year (and a constant). Using the mean point estimate for the relationship,
we compare the actual and predicted (or estimated) amounts of asset recovery in
each year from 2003 to 2009. As shown in Figure 16, we can see that the match
between actual and estimated amounts coincide better in more recent years.
There are any number of explanations for this, not least of which is the short
time-series. Figure
16: Illustration of model
estimates and actual values Source:
Authors. Estimates suggest that we can be 95 percent
confident that the mean proportion of last year’s recovery associated with this
year’s is greater than 50 percent and less than 110 percent. Given that there
are many uncertainties and other factors for which we have not accounted, we
use this range (rather than the point estimate we used to compare our model to
the actual amount recovered) to determine the possible range of amounts
collected in the UK through to 2020. As shown in Figure 17, we find that there
may be between £80 million to £1.2 billion collected in ten years time. Figure
17: Potential recoveries
through to 2020, United Kingdom Because these estimations are based purely
on the time-series model, it is useful to discuss the type of scenarios which
they represent. This is particularly so for the maximal prediction, which
involves year-on-year increases which do not diminish with time, thus assuming
not only that the pool of available criminal assets is large enough to support
this, but also that the marginal return on additional investment remains
constant. The first assumption seems likely to be true, given that the annual
turnover of organised crime in the UK is estimated to be £15b, and given also
that extended confiscation powers render previous years gains liable to
confiscation. The second assumption demands closer examination. All of the frontline agencies involved in
financial investigation and bringing confiscation proceedings have finite
resources, necessitating selectivity. Managers and practitioners must decide
how much confiscation work to undertake and also which cases to prioritise.
These decisions should follow a harm-reduction ethos, which should involve (at
least for police) differing approaches in different localities with different
problems. Sometimes, authorities may take on unprofitable cases in order to
deal with specific problems—an example from the UK (and other Member States) is
the confiscation of expensive cars from low-ranking criminals in order to
discourage crime within their communities. Generally, however, the very
purpose of asset confiscation justifies focusing upon profitable cases
(especially those where the assets are more readily recoverable), as the
deterrent effect of confiscation orders is largely a function of the amount
recovered.[58] A more cynical view is that ARIS may encourage agencies to focus
on high-value cases at the expense of a harm-reduction ethos. In any event, it
is reasonable to assume a bias towards ‘low hanging fruit’—i.e. that the most
profitable cases tend to be selected ahead of intractable or low-value cases.[59] All else being
equal, this will cause the marginal (and overall) profitability of asset
recovery work to decline as more work is undertaken. Some countervailing
trends will, however, tend to negate this effect. Frontline agents will become
more efficient at identifying, freezing, confiscating and recovering assets due
to learning effects and economies of scale. Court processes will become more
efficient for similar reasons, and also because legal challenges will be fewer
as the law becomes more settled. Against these trends, success will be met
with increased efforts to hide wealth (as criminals play the ‘game’ against the
state, making asset recovery work more expensive. Ultimately there must come a point at which
the profitability of asset recovery work begins to decline (because all the
low-handing fruit has been picked), and another at which further efforts are
unprofitable. In the absence of a detailed model, however, we have no better
guide than expert practitioner opinions. In this regard, whilst it is
recognised that not every case of acquisitive crime will present an opportunity
for profitable asset recovery (hence the doubt, about ‘mainstreaming’ asset
recovery work expressed in the recent Joint Thematic Review, and discussed
above), there seems to be a general concensus that much more could be
profitably done. Some experts favour a more systematic use of money laundering
laws and confiscation laws to target top-tier criminals. Others consider that
much could be achieved if police simply did ‘more of the same’ by employing
more financial investigators in more of the existing investigations into known
mid-ranking criminals. It is also believed that financial investigation
exposes new crimes and criminals, increasing the pool of assets practically
available to be targeted. These opinions have one thing in common: that a lack
of trained financial investigators is a limiting factor, and will remain so
into the foreseeable future.[60] Turning now to potential future costs,
these are plotted in Figure 18 as minimum and maximum scenarios. The data for
2008 are the low and high estimates in Figure 17, with previous years’ data (in
the absence of any estimate) assumed to be in the same ratio, but reduced in
proportion to the relative amount recovered in each year versus 2008. Looking
forward, the minimum scenario then assumes that costs remain at 2009 levels,
i.e. that asset recovery operations do not expand. The maximum scenario assumes
instead that costs escalate at 15% per year as more and more financial
investigators and other agents are hired, and more cases brought.[61] Figure
18: Potential cost of asset
recovery through to 2020, UK Finally, we combine minimum and maximum
revenue and cost forecasts to produce minimum and maximum profit forecasts,
shown in Figure 19. It should be remembered when
interpreting these data that the maximum scenario assumes that there are no
limitations upon the profitability of asset recovery work through to 2020,
whereas the minimum scenario assumes fixed costs and profitability which
(pursuant to the formula derived from the historical time-series) declines and
then plateaus. Figure
19: Potential profitability to
2020, UK Source:
Authors’ calculation. Annex 5 EU27 profitability
model This Annex includes profitability estimates
for the EU27 by using proxy indicators to generalise the UK estimate in Annex
6. This approach is made necessary by the paucity of useful empirical data,
especially as regards the cost of asset confiscation work. This involves: ·
devising
a logic model by adverting to available evidence about the causes of
(non)utilisation; ·
identifying
proxy indicators and available EU27 datasets for the identified barriers and
drivers within the model; ·
using
the proxy indicators to generate output from the model; and ·
interpreting
the output data. It is worth reiterating the underlying
assumption that the UK situation in 2008/09 approximates the potential impact by
2020 of the maximal policy option (without mutual recognition) upon a Member
State with a currently low rate of utilisation. We shall return to the
implications of this, and other assumptions, when interpreting the results. [?] The starting assumption is the basic
equation that profit = income – cost. Lacking any EU-27 indicators of the cost
of asset confiscation work, we assume this to be a function of overall administrative
efficiency in each Member State. Likewise, lacking any EU-27
indicators of the income generated by asset confiscation work, we assume this
to be a function both of profitable criminality (driving the
amount of assets available to be confiscated in each Member State based on a
given amount of investment) and investment in policing (representing
the latent apparatus which each Member State is able to bring to bear upon
asset recovery work, as well as the level of commitment to combating organised
crime). In addition, the overall size of Member State economies has an impact
on their asset confiscation costs and revenues. This simple logic is appropriate given that
research has revealed what would otherwise be a catastrophic lack of
appropriate data. Had there been more time available, more investment could
have been made in developing the suite of indicators and improving their
reliability and validity. We shall return to this issue in our final
recommendations. Because the logic model assumes that the
maximal legislative option approximates recent measures in the UK, it must be
adjusted (in the case of the maximal legislative option incorporating mutual
recognition) to account for the impact of increased utilisation of mutual
recognition instruments (which has not formed part of the UK’s approach). The
basis of such an adjustment—which takes the form of an adjustment factor
coupled with a sensitivity analysis—is that options targeting mutual
recognition will ease cross-border enforcement and, thus, raise the amounts
recovered by each Member State. The extent of this depends, however, upon the status
quo ante. In particular, Member States which rely upon non-conviction
based orders stand to enjoy a greater impact because they currently struggle to
enforce these orders overseas (whereas, for conviction-based orders, the
potential advantages of mutual recognition relate mostly to speed and
efficiency rather than the more fundamental question of whether an order will
be enforced). To account for this difference we double the adjustment factor
for those Member States which currently rely upon non-conviction based orders
to a significant extent. Two other potentially relevant factors are:
·
the extent to which each Member State is a
popular destination for organised crime profits (relevant because under FD
2006/783/JHA, the default position is that the executing Member State retains
50% of the value of the recovered asset); and ·
the extent to which proceeds derived from crimes
committed within each Member State tend to be retained at home, transferred
elsewhere within the EU, or transferred outside the EU. As there are no reliable data on these
factors, we do not take them into account in our analysis. Nevertheless, as a
matter of logic and in line with the microeconomic decision model for the
rational criminal, we suggest that Member States with relatively efficient law
enforcement systems are likely, all else equal, to experience greater flight of
illicit assets to other States. Conversely, Member States with less efficient
systems will tend to have a greater inflow of criminal assets. In these
countries, criminals are likely to seek ways to transfer their illegal (cash)
wealth into the legal economy (Europol, 2009). An error factor in this
prediction is the fact that in some countries organised criminal groups benefit
from being culturally embedded in particular locations and from being a
recognised ‘brand’ in the local economy. Where this is the case, organised
criminal gangs tend to invest large proportions of their profits in the local
community thus reducing the level of capital flight that might otherwise be
predicted. Proxy indicators The three basic components of the logic
model (administrative efficiency, profitable criminality and investment in
policing) demand internationally comparable proxy indicators. The proxies
employed are outlined in Table 1.4. We reiterate that these indicators refer
to a whole country (e.g. quality of institutions) or a whole institution in a
country (e.g. tax collection efficiency), and are but proxies for narrower
concepts specifically impacting on asset confiscation outputs for which
EU-27 data is not available. Table
20 Components of the model for generalising profitability, with proxy
indicators Component || Proxy || Reason for inclusion || Source Profitable Criminality || Composite Rule of Law indicator (2007) || The Rule of Law indicator is a composite generated by the World Bank’s ‘Unobserved Components Model’. In essence, it rescales 80 individual indicators used to create the composite Rule of Law indicator and places them in common units. It then constructs the composite measure as a weighted average of the underlying individual indicators. || World Bank Costs of organised crime for business (2007) || Perceptions of businessmen about the costs imposed on their business by organised criminal groups is one of the best available indicator of the size of organised criminal business in a country. It is a proxy which more specific than the rule of law indicator, but it also neglecting important aspects of organised crime. Thus, the two indicators complement in each other in gauging the scope of profitable organised crime in a country. || WEF (2008) Administrative efficiency || Wastefulness of government spending (2007) || Inefficient government spending is approximated by perceptions of businessmen who are major consumers of public services thus well placed to formulate informed judgements. || WEF (2008) Aggregate tax collection costs to net revenue collected (2007) || Asset Confiscation is a particular and highly complex and costly form of tax collection. We argue that those States whose taxation systems are less cost effective will tend to resist additional pressures to improve asset confiscation unless it can be demonstrated that asset confiscation regimes will always be profitable. || OECD (2009) Investment in Policing || Expenditure on public order and safety, PPP EUR per 100 000 citizens (2007) || General government expenditure on public order and safety as well as number of police officers indicate the available capacities and sophistication of law enforcement authorities for improved asset confiscation work. || Eurostat Number of police officers per 100,000 citizens (2007) || Eurostat These chosen proxy indicators reflect the
constraints of this short project and suffice to provide headline results for
immediate support of policy decisions, the list of indicators can easily be
expanded and refined in the future in order to develop a more accurate model. Table
21 reports the data as collected from the original sources per table 20.
It should be noted that these data are for 2007, whereas the UK data is for
the 2008/09 financial year. This does not represent an important shortcoming
in our analysis as the institutional and environmental factors underlying asset
confiscation work such as wastefulness of government spending are stable over
time (Kaufmann et al, 2005). For the subsequent data analysis and
predictions these indicators are standardised using Z-scores where the sample
mean is 0 and standard deviation is 1. Furthermore, the standardised values
were transformed in order to eliminate negative values by adding to the
absolute value of the lowest score plus 1 (to avoid adjusting by a factor of
0). By this means, the variable values used for the analysis are rendered of
comparable magnitude. They are also made positive while fully preserving the
relative variance represented by them. This use of Z-scores eliminates bias
caused by underlying variable distributions having different shapes. Table 21
reports two variables additional to the proxies listed in Table 20. The first
is a purchasing power parity (PPP) variable to account for differences in price
levels of Member States relative to the EU-27 average (in 2007), which is
necessary for estimating law enforcement costs in a comparable manner as labour
and capital inputs have different prices in different Member States. The
second is a gross domestic product (GDP) variable which indicates the relative
size of Member State economies. Table
21 EU-27 country scores of drivers and barriers to enhanced asset confiscation
work MS || Rule of law; -2.5 = lawless, 2.5 = lawful (2007) || Cost of OC for business; 7 = significant, 1 = insignificant (2007) || Govt. spending; 7 = wasteful, 1 = efficient (2007) || Ratio of tax collection costs to net revenue (2007) || Public order spending per 100,000 citizens (EUR, PPP) (2007) || Police officers per 100,000 citizens (2007) || PPP within EU; EU27 average = 100% (2007) || GDP at market prices, €m (2007) BE || 1.30 || 1.8 || 4.2 || 1.40 || 4836.9 || 360 || 108.3 || 335,085 BG || -0.08 || 4.2 || 5.2 || 1.29 || 2504.3 || 481 || 46.2 || 30,772 CZ || 0.87 || 2.1 || 5.2 || 1.25 || 4120.3 || 421 || 62.4 || 127,331 DK || 1.96 || 1.2 || 3 || 0.62 || 3079.5 || 193 || 137.4 || 227,534 DE || 1.70 || 1.8 || 3.9 || 0.78 || 4570.9 || 305 || 101.9 || 2,432,400 EE || 1.13 || 2 || 4.1 || 0.86 || 3532.0 || 242 || 73.1 || 15,828 IE || 1.73 || 1.7 || 4.2 || 0.79 || 5738.8 || 290 || 124.5 || 189,374 HE || 0.80 || 2 || 4.7 || 1.69 || 2679.4 || 454 || 90.7 || 225,540 ES || 1.08 || 1.4 || 3.9 || 0.65 || 4908.8 || 469 || 92.8 || 1,053,537 FR || 1.38 || 2.1 || 4.1 || 0.97 || 3526.6 || 371 || 108.1 || 1,895,284 IT || 0.40 || 4.4 || 5.8 || 1.16 || 4576.5 || 178 || 102.9 || 1,546,177 CY || 1.06 || 1.7 || 3.4 || 5.80 || 4881.8 || 647 || 88.1 || 15,951 LV || 0.73 || 1.8 || 4.8 || 1.31 || 3685.1 || 364 || 66.6 || 21,111 LT || 0.64 || 2.1 || 5 || 0.98* || 2423.5 || 334 || 60 || 28,577 LU || 1.76 || 1.5 || 3.4 || 1.18 || 5868.4 || 308 || 115.3 || 37,491 HU || 0.88 || 2.4 || 5.7 || 1.15 || 2981.8 || 263 || 66.7 || 100,742 MT || 1.58 || 1.3 || 4.1 || 0.97 || 2608.0 || 467 || 75.5 || 5,480 NL || 1.74 || 2.1 || 3.2 || 1.11 || 6160.6 || 218 || 101.9 || 571,773 AT || 1.93 || 1.4 || 3.7 || 0.64 || 4588.1 || 319 || 102.2 || 272,010 PL || 0.41 || 3.5 || 5.3 || 1.42 || 2406.4 || 258 || 62 || 311,002 PT || 1.01 || 1.5 || 4.4 || 1.41 || 2869.2 || 487 || 85.7 || 168,737 RO || -0.05 || 3 || 5.2 || 0.91 || 2193.2 || 211 || 63.8 || 124,729 SI || 0.89 || 2.1 || 4.7 || 0.83 || 3467.5 || 392 || 79 || 34,568 SK || 0.49 || 2.6 || 5.2 || 2.41 || 3172.4 || 261 || 63.2 || 54,905 FI || 1.86 || 1.3 || 2.9 || 0.77 || 3540.3 || 153 || 119.9 || 179,702 SE || 1.86 || 1.7 || 3.3 || 0.41 || 4231.7 || 193 || 115.7 || 337,944 UK || 1.66 || 2.7 || 4.7 || 1.10 || 7546.7 || 266 || 112.6 || 2,052,847 Equations The predicted asset confiscation profits
were derived by combining the theoretical model with the available cost and
revenue estimates of the UK. This has been done by assuming that asset
confiscation costs or revenues would surpass the UK’s costs and revenues if the
respective net drivers and barriers scores in the given Member State exceed the
UK values (e.g. if the given Member State has a more efficient tax collection
system than that of the UK, it is expected to achieve the same asset
confiscation revenue under lower costs ceteris paribus). Comparison
takes a linear multiplicative form, i.e. we assumed that drivers and barriers
multiply each other’s impacts. This is justified by the fact that achieving
revenue from asset confiscation work requires a series of institutions such as
police, courts, financial investigators, etc. to function properly simultaneously.
For example, having an excellent judicial system in combination with zero
investigative capacity will result in zero achievement. By implication, the analytical model can be
described by the following: where MSi refers to the ith
Member State and revenue and cost refer to asset confiscation work in financial
year 2008/2009. Revenue of the ith Member State is
generated in the following way: where Profitable criminalityMSi
is the arithmetic average of the Composite Rule of Law (2007) and the Costs of
organised crime for business (2007) indicators; and Investment in policingMSi
is the arithmetic average of Expenditure on public order and safety (2007) and
Number of police officer per 100,000 citizens (2007) indicators, GDP MSi
is the gross domestic product at market prices in 2007. Cost of the ith Member State is
generated in the following way: where Administrative efficiency MSi
is the arithmetic average of Wastefulness of government spending (2007) and
Aggregate tax collection costs to net revenue collected (2007) indicators. Simple
arithmetic averages are used when aggregating constitutive indicators because
we lack reliable knowledge about the relative importance of each indicator;
arithmetic average assigns equal weights to each indicator. Modelling outputs These equations yield the predicted asset
confiscation revenue, cost, and profit figures per member state as highlighted
in table 22 and table 23. Table 22 Predicted profits for the
‘maximal’ legislative option, EU27 Member State || Revenues (€m) || Costs (€m) || Profit (€m) Spain || 131.00 || 36.57 || 94.43 UK || 188.08 || 131.08 || 57.00 Italy || 167.56 || 124.86 || 42.70 Poland || 31.66 || 10.87 || 20.79 Czech Republic || 19.21 || 4.27 || 14.94 Netherlands || 32.49 || 18.33 || 14.15 France || 105.42 || 91.92 || 13.49 Germany || 109.13 || 96.73 || 12.40 Greece || 19.24 || 13.80 || 5.44 Bulgaria || 10.78 || 5.77 || 5.01 Romania || 8.89 || 4.12 || 4.77 Portugal || 12.88 || 8.32 || 4.56 Hungary || 8.02 || 4.43 || 3.59 Slovakia || 5.85 || 2.38 || 3.47 Belgium || 21.39 || 19.22 || 2.17 Lithuania || 2.74 || 0.75 || 1.99 Slovenia || 3.43 || 1.45 || 1.98 Latvia || 2.37 || 0.76 || 1.61 Cyprus || 2.11 || 1.49 || 0.62 Estonia || 1.00 || 0.48 || 0.53 Malta || 0.26 || 0.18 || 0.08 Luxembourg || 1.48 || 1.51 || -0.03 Sweden || 7.67 || 8.62 || -0.96 Austria || 7.74 || 9.27 || -1.53 Ireland || 7.66 || 9.89 || -2.23 Finland || 1.99 || 4.33 || -2.35 Denmark || 1.73 || 5.79 || -4.06 Source: own
calculation Table
23 Distribution of predicted revenues, costs, and profits across EU-27 Member
States, 2008/2009, million EUR source: own
calculation As can be seen from the above table and
graph, enhanced asset confiscation work would yield positive financial profits
in all but 5 EU Member States. Due to imprecision of the data and the
restrictive assumptions used to arrive at predictions, we recommend using a
less refined scale categorising Member States into three broad groups (table
24). This categorisation summarises not only the absolute predicted profit per
EU Member State, but also the predicted relative profitability of their efforts
understood as the ratio of asset confiscation revenues and costs. Table
24 Profitability of the ‘maximal’ legislative option, EU27 Member State || Categorisation || Profit ratio (profit/cost) Czech Republic || highly profitable || 3.50 Lithuania || highly profitable || 2.63 Spain || highly profitable || 2.58 Latvia || highly profitable || 2.12 Poland || highly profitable || 1.91 Slovakia || highly profitable || 1.46 Slovenia || highly profitable || 1.37 Romania || highly profitable || 1.16 Estonia || highly profitable || 1.11 Bulgaria || moderately profitable || 0.87 Hungary || moderately profitable || 0.81 Netherlands || moderately profitable || 0.77 Portugal || moderately profitable || 0.55 Malta || moderately profitable || 0.46 UK || moderately profitable || 0.43 Cyprus || moderately profitable || 0.42 Greece || moderately profitable || 0.39 Italy || moderately profitable || 0.34 France || moderately profitable || 0.15 Germany || moderately profitable || 0.13 Belgium || moderately profitable || 0.11 Luxembourg || not profitable || -0.02 Sweden || not profitable || -0.11 Austria || not profitable || -0.17 Ireland || not profitable || -0.23 Finland || not profitable || -0.54 Denmark || not profitable || -0.70 Source: own calculation The analysis thus far has not yet accounted
for a crucial aspect of the maximal option which transcends national borders:
increased utilisation of mutual recognition instruments. As this is a crucial
aspect of the proposed set of policy options, we are bound to comment on this
important issue. There is, unfortunately, no data which
would allow us to gauge the potential or actual magnitude of utilisation of mutual
recognition either across the whole EU or per individual Member State.
We have therefore been forced to rely on a range of potential parameters in
order to scope the magnitude of impact of mutual recognition on profitability.
It is assumed that Member States where non-conviction based confiscation
constitutes a considerable proportion of asset confiscation work can benefit relatively
more (double the benefit derived by other Member States) from strengthened
mutual recognition as their scope for alternative solutions is more limited
currently. Countries which are considered as such are Bulgaria, Ireland, Italy,
Romania, and the UK. In the following sensitivity analysis, we
assume that mutual recognition would increase the revenues of asset
confiscation, but would also entail a modest increase in costs. We assume that
the former outweighs the latter in a 10:1 ratio, reflecting the fact that by
the time assets have been traced to overseas locations, most of the
investigative effort has been spent, permitting it to be treated as a sunk cost
when analysing the marginal benefits brought by utilisation of mutual
recognition instruments. Parameters used in sensitivity analysis are shown in Table
25. Table
25 Range of parameters used in the sensitivity analysis Scenario || profit aspect || Predominantly conviction-based || Significant NCB element 5% || Revenue factor || 1.050 || 1.100 Cost factor || 1.005 || 1.010 10% || Revenue factor || 1.100 || 1.200 Cost factor || 1.010 || 1.020 15% || Revenue factor || 1.150 || 1.300 Cost factor || 1.015 || 1.030 20% || Revenue factor || 1.200 || 1.400 Cost factor || 1.020 || 1.040 25% || Revenue factor || 1.250 || 1.500 Cost factor || 1.025 || 1.050 30% || Revenue factor || 1.300 || 1.600 Cost factor || 1.030 || 1.060 50% || Revenue factor || 1.500 || 2.000 Cost factor || 1.050 || 1.100 Note: The cost factor is assumed to be 10%
of the revenue factor and the non-conviction based
regimes have double factors compared to the conviction based regimes. The results of the sensitivity analysis
show that the already profitable countries would benefit the most from
utilisation of an efficient and effective system of mutual recognition. Results
are less promising at the other end of the scale, however, four Member State
become profitable upon consideration of mutual recognition impacts, viz: ·
Luxemburg (5%
scenario or higher); ·
Sweden (15%
scenario or higher); ·
Ireland (20%
scenario or higher); and ·
Austria (25%
scenario or higher). Error! Reference source
not found.6 presents revenue, cost and profit data adjusted to
account for mutual recognition. The 5%, 15% and 50% scenarios are shown. Table
26 Profitability for EU27, including mutual recognition ` General points of interpretation
regarding validity Our profitability analyses, as already
noted, presumes increasing utilisation over time, in the absence of which asset
recovery work is likely to be less profitable. However, whilst some policy
actions are designed to directly raise utilisation, we do not necessarily
regard these policy options as sufficient. Rather, they represent steps
which the EU is able to take in the context of the legal framework on the
confiscation and recovery of criminal assets. These mostly target political
will, but there are also some important practical considerations which fall
outside the scope of the EU legal framework. These include the need for
greater financial investigation capacity to generate system throughput (i.e.
cases in the ‘pipeline’). This requires training which, in turn, requires
infrastructure and an up-front commitment of resources. This, according to
many practitioners with whom we spoke, represents a significant barrier to
increased utilisation (especially in Eastern Europe, where there were,
accordingly, questions raised about our policy action #17). Expansion of
financial investigation capacity is, however, not just a matter of quantity,
but also quality. In addition to resources, there is a knowledge input
requirement, which presents as a significant barrier in Member States which do
not yet have sophisticated financial investigation capacities. Both of these
areas are potentially apt for EU-level intervention in support of the options
under consideration in this study.[62] It can be argued pro tem that Member
States in the highly or moderately profitable categories may directly benefit
from adopting an enhanced asset confiscation system with a similar cost-benefit
structure to the UK in 2008/2009. However, this does not mean that Member
States with different political-administrative systems cannot adopt different
institutional solutions to become profitable or increase their profitability
despite our findings. In this regard, it should be reiterated that all of our
proxy variables refer to country level or country institutional level
characteristics, i.e. we could not employ asset confiscation specific
indicators and thus could not take into account the specific characteristics of
asset confiscation work compared to the wider law enforcement environment. It should also be remembered that
unprofitability in the narrow sense considered here does not imply that Member
States will not achieve a net economic benefit once higher-order impacts are
taken into account, to say nothing of the value of social and environmental
benefits. General points of interpretation
regarding timing The foregoing analysis centres on a point
in time (April 2008 – March 2009) during which there is reasonable availability
of UK cost data. As already noted, this data reflects six years of effort to
raise utilisation following the introduction of the Proceeds of Crime Act
2002, prior to which utilisation was minimal.. Several important points
flow from this. First,
whereas asset recovery work in the UK was profitable in the year considered, it
does not necessary follow that it was profitable in each of the preceding six
years. In fact, the opposite is likely to be true, of the UK as of most Member
States, because results take time to manifest as cases progress through the
system resulting, finally, in valuable assets vesting in the state. Costs, on
the other hand, will be more evenly distributed, as capacity is continually
added; they may even be greater in the early stages, as new policies are
implemented and, perhaps, new agencies stood up. Second, the
predicted impacts may take more or less time to manifest in other Member States
than in the UK. This is a question which concerns each aspect of a state’s
asset confiscation apparatus, from time taken to increase financial
investigation capacity, to the time taken for a case to progress through the
judicial system, to the time taken for assets to then vest finally in the
state. As we are mainly focused here on the question of whether asset
recovery work is potentially profitable, we do not make further adjustments to
the data. Third, the
fact that utilisation was previously minimal is critical to properly
interpreting the EU27 profitability results. Essentially, it means that Member
States can achieve the predicted results from a standing start. By
implication, Member States which have already begun to uplift utilisation, they
could exceed the predicted outcome. Fourth, the
foregoing model, fixed as it is upon one point in time, does not predict what
happens next. Whilst it seems reasonable to assume that profitability does not
suddenly decline, we have attempted to take account of uncertainty in
developing a rough (minimum/maximum) prediction for future profits in the UK.
This is presented as Table 27, with the 2008/09 data for UK (converted to €) at
year 6. The projections thus represent what could happen in a country with an
asset confiscation operation the same size as that in the UK; they can be
scaled to account for different sized operations. In any event, the
uncertainty involved is so great that the projections are unlikely to assist
policy-makers. Table
27 Annual profit predictions for UK asset recovery work Source:
Authors’ calculations performed in £ and converted to € using the 2009 average annual exchange rate from European Central Bank as of
11/8/2010, €1 = £0.891. Specific points of interpretation The proxy indicators upon which our results
are based can now be used to interpret the results. We focus here on those Member
States which, according to the profitability model, are moderately profitable
or unprofitable. According to the data available and the theoretical model
developed, the reasons for negative or moderate are essentially threefold. They
are presented, together with country examples, in table 28. Error! Reference source not found. Table 28 Main causes of negative
profitability and potential remedies Reasons for negative or moderate profitability || Relevant indicator || Country examples || Potential remedy low level of potential asset confiscation revenue not enough assets to confiscate || · High level of rule of law · Low level of reported interference of organised crime || Finland, Denmark || · Not available not enough capacity to confiscate || · Low number of police officers · Low spending on public order and safety || Slovenia, Estonia, Lithuania Romania, Hungary || · Increase capacity by training or spending more · More efficient utilisation of available resources high cost of asset confiscation Questionable levels of efficiency in financially oriented law enforcement || · High level of wasteful government spending · Low efficiency of tax collection · || Belgium, Greece, Portugal || · Create specific organisations dedicated to asset confiscation work where efficiency is higher than average public service · Source: own
categorisation However, due to a number of restrictive
assumptions, the narrow focus of the available proxies and the form of the
theoretical model, some countries may do much better than predicted by this
model. For example, in Ireland, asset confiscation work by the specialist
Criminal Assets Bureau (CAB) has proven to be profitable, partly due to a very
effective utilisation of revenue powers (i.e. the ability to levy income tax
owed against undeclared income in cases where its illicit origin cannot be
proved).[63] The work of CAB is, however, complemented by that of local police
officers. Because the capacity of the CAB is limited, there is a strong focus
in Ireland on ‘mainstreaming’ local asset recovery work in this way, but the
profitability of this component is not known. Nevertheless, the Irish example
shows that Member States may be able to establish profitable specialist
agencies irrespective of the profitability of mainstream asset recovery work.[64] On the other
hand, the very promising results for Spain are difficult to reconcile with the
opinion of one expert whom we interviewed that Spain’s (Napoleonic) system of
enforcement through local courts makes it very difficult to recover assets cost
effectively. This may suggest that the proxy indicator for administrative
efficiency takes too little account of enforcement mechanisms and/or efficiency
within the judicial system. This is an aspect of the model which warrants
further research. In any case, we draw attention to an
appropriate way to interpret the foregoing rankings. Non-profitability as
estimated here flows from certain deficiencies in the Member State involved.
Whilst our profitability analysis may disregard many potentially relevant
factors at (including any factors unique to particular Member States) this does
not mean that Member States cannot benefit from attending to any deficiencies
which factor in our analysis. [1] "An
open and secure Europe serving and protecting the citizens", Council document 17024/09, adopted by the European Council on 10/11
December 2009. [2] Council document 7769/3/10. [3] COM(2010) 673 of 22.11.2010. [4] COM(2011) 307, 308 and 309 and C(2011) 3673 final of
6.6.2011. [5] COM(2011) 376 final of 24.6.2011. [6] "Proceeds of organised crime - Ensuring that
'crime does not pay'", COM (2008) 766 final. [7] Framework Service Contract No
JLS/2010/EVAL/FW/001/A1, Study for an Impact Assessment on a proposal for a
new legal framework on the confiscation and recovery of criminal assets. [8] From Austria, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Finland, France,
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Sweden, UK. CARIN
is an international network of asset recovery practitioners which has Members
in over 50 countries and jurisdictions. CARIN foresees one law
enforcement and one judicial contact point per country [9] However, during the discussions some delegations
expressed the wish to have more information on certain issues, such as non-conviction
based confiscation. [10] Available at
http://ec.europa.eu/home-affairs/policies/crime/crime_confiscation_en.htm [11] Report from the Commission pursuant to Article 6 of the
Council Framework Decision of 24 February 2005 on Confiscation of Crime-related
Proceeds, Instrumentalities and Property (2005/212/JHA), COM(2007) 805. [12] Report from the Commission based on Article 14 of the
Council Framework Decision 2003/577/JHA of 22 July 2003 on the execution in the
European Union of orders freezing property or evidence, COM(2008) 885 final. [13] Report from the Commission pursuant to Article 22 of
the Council Framework Decision 2006/783/JHA of 6 October 2006 on the
application of the principle of mutual recognition to confiscation orders,
COM(2010) 428. [14] Report from the Commission based on Article 8 of the
Council Decision 2007/845/JHA of 6 December 2007 concerning cooperation between
Asset Recovery Offices of the Member States in the field of tracing and
identification of proceeds from, or other property related to, crime, COM(2011)
176 of 12 April 2011. [15] Such as the meetings of the CARIN Network or of the
informal EU Asset Recovery Offices Platform. [16] For example the CEART Seminar and the Eurojust
Strategic Seminar held in 2010. [17] For example the Commission services held several
bilateral meetings with representatives of the FLARE (Freedom, Legality and
Rights in Europe) Network and their associated networks [18] For example, substantial differences exist between the
national regimes for third party confiscation and extended confiscation.
Non-conviction based confiscation is heavily used in Ireland, the United
Kingdom and other countries, but is not used in Romania (property is presumed
to be of licit origin and confiscation based on a burden of proof of balance of
probabilities may be perceived as problematic). France introduced a new crime
for "possession of unjustified assets" (in case of evident links with
organised crime activities) which does not exist in other Member States. [19] In Italy the proceeds of organised crime laundered in
2011 were estimated at € 150 billion (Bank of Italy, 2011). [20] For example in 2009 €189m were recovered in the UK and
€60m in the Netherlands. [21] Home Office (2006), referred to in the 2010 Organised
Crime Threat Assessment. [22] This figure is likely to underestimate the proportion
of criminal wealth recovered, because i) it is net of expenses paid to private
receivers, ii) it does not include amounts recovered in favour of victims and iii)
for non-financial assets it records values realised at auction, which may be
less than values reported stolen. Even so, the data suggests that the vast
majority of criminal wealth goes unrecovered, especially given that the £15bn
estimate relates only to organised crime. [23] Respectively by the Bank of Italy and the Italian Court
of Auditors. [24] Annex 2 contains some statistics on the value of assets
recovered, but there is scarce data on organised criminal turnover against
which to compare them. [25] Justice and Home Affairs Council Conclusions on
confiscation and asset recovery of June 2010, Council document 7769/3/10. For
similar statements see also the Executive Summary of the EU Organised Crime
Threat Assessment 2011 and the Eurojust Annual Report 2010. [26] For example the Council of Europe Convention on
laundering, search, seizure and confiscation of the proceeds of crime and on
the financing of terrorism (CETS 198), which to date has been signed by 20 EU
Member States and the European Union, and ratified by 12 Member States. The
United Nations Convention against Corruption (UNCAC), which has been signed and
ratified by almost all EU Member States and the European Union, has a Section
on asset recovery. [27] Some EU legal provisions are not well coordinated. For
example Framework Decision 2005/212/JHA establishes alternative criteria for
extended confiscation as follows: i) A court is convinced that the property is
derived from criminal activities of the convicted person prior to conviction;
ii) A court is convinced that the property is derived from similar criminal
activities of the convicted person prior to conviction; iii) The value of the
property is disproportionate to the lawful income of the convicted person and
the court is convinced that the property derives from criminal activity. The
Framework Decision leaves Member States with the option to transpose one, two
or all three criteria. This provision is not coordinated with the provisions on
the grounds for refusal of mutual recognition of confiscation orders laid down
in Framework Decision 2006/783/JHA. As a result the scope for mutual recognition
of confiscation orders is restricted. The authorities in one Member State are
obliged to execute confiscation orders issued by another Member State only if
these orders are based on the same alternative criteria applied in the Member
State receiving the order. [28] Executive Summary of the EU Organised Crime Threat
Assessment 2011. [29] The impact on third countries is not identified as
positive or negative, as it is not known where assets would be moved or
re-invested and an inflow of (laundered) criminal money may affect different
countries (e.g. a developing country vs. a small country which is known as a
tax haven) in a different way. [30] As stated above the fact that the EU legal framework is
incompletely transposed is only part of the problem. It is also incorrectly
transposed and, above all, insufficient to address the shortcomings identified
in this impact assessment. [31] Which corresponds to recovery only from mala fide
third parties that have paid less than market value. [32] The most recurring example is that of agricultural
cooperatives. [33] The proposed option would introduce non conviction
based confiscation measures and third party confiscation only in a limited way.
[34] The underlying assumption is that Member State agents
would not request the freezing of assets in other Member States (which is more
costly and time-consuming than a national procedure) unless the value of the
criminal assets identified and the chances of recovery are sufficiently high. [35] It is not yet clear whether an authority (such as the
Ministry of Justice) will act as centralised national contact point for the
data collection, nor whether the reporting requirement will also include a
requirement to make the data publicly available. [36] Fieldwork interview. [37] This act provided for extended confiscation wherever a
‘course of criminal conduct’ was identified. [38] PIU (2000), 5. [39] See part of POCA 2002. [40] http://library.npia.police.uk/docs/hmcpsi/AssetRecovery.pdf [41] This is especially interesting because, with the
exception of drug trafficking, the number of acquisitive crimes recorded in the
UK has fallen during the relevant period: see http://rds.homeoffice.gov.uk/rds/pdfs09/recorded-crime-2002-2009rev.xls.
There are many possible ways to reconcile the statistics, but there is no need
to do so here. [42] Joint Thematic Review 2010, paragraph 2.13. [43] Prior to introducing the Proceeds of Crime Act 2002,
the UK government did an estimate of implementation costs. It has since
maintained an interest in the costs and benefits of the legislation.
Profitability is one aspect of this. [44] Under ARIS, agencies receive 50% of amounts the
recovery of which they are solely responsible for. Where responsibility is
shared this amount is apportioned. For example, criminal confiscation pursuant
to POCA section 6 involves contributions from the Police authorities
(financial investigation), the CPS (obtaining confiscation orders following
successful criminal proceedings), and HM Courts Service (enforcement), and
these agencies receive, respectively, 18.75%, 18.75% and 12.5% of the revenue. [45] http://www.mpa.gov.uk/committees/finres/2010/100923/07/#h1000 [46] Data from 2008/09 suggests that HMRC recovers through conviction-based
confiscation and NCB cash seizure-forfeiture in a similar ratio to the police
authorities. This is important for their comparability, as the
seizure-forfeiture regime, by virtue of its simplified procedure, is more
profitable overall. As regards conviction-based proceedings, those of the HMRC
tend to be more complex and expensive to run, but they also tend to involve
higher value proceeds (although these are often too well hidden to be
recovered). [47] The results of this exercise have been tabled in
parliament, see:
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200809/ldhansrd/text/90720-wms0004.htm#column_WS163;
SOCA’s statement of accounts is useful in interpreting these figures:
www.official-documents.gov.uk/document/hc0809/hc08/0870/0870.pdf. [48] Recent legislative amendments have given the CPS the
power to also bring civil confiscation proceedings, but these are yet to be
exercised. [49] Thematic review, para 6.12. [50] Thematic review, para 6.12. [51] Much of this is done by the Department of Work and
Pensions. We understand from expert interviews that this work is likely to be
no less profitable than that of other agencies. [52] There are also some costs borne by the Home Office
(e.g. maintaining the JARD database) but these are negligible in the context of
this analysis. [53] On the one hand, much of the evidence for confiscation
cases has already been heard in the context of the criminal proceeding, and
there are no jury costs. On the other hand, these cases are sometimes heavily
contested. [54] Ministry of Justice statistics. [55] http://www.nao.org.uk/idoc.ashx?docId=9db2d94f-0642-41f7-a697-334b2040ffdd&version=-1 [56] In principle, given unlimited time and access to data
held on JARD, it should be possible to reconstruct this pipeline for a more exact
understanding of the system. However, it is not necessary to do this in order
to assess profitability, given that the UK situation is not unusual (more
complex cases will tend to take longer to finally determine in all Member
States), and also given that profitability is generally assessed with reference
to financial-year accounts. [57] We test current year and one, two and three years
previous. Tests do not find statistical significance with two- and three-year
lags, possibly due to the limited time-series. [58] The purity of this deterrent logic is questioned by
some defence lawyers in the UK and other Member States, on the basis that
confiscation proceedings constitute an oppressive interference against a
defendant’s capacity to defend criminal charges by diverting attention away
from preparing a defence and into rearranging personal finances to deal with
freezing orders. The suggestion is that confiscation proceedings are sometimes
instituted for tactical reasons related to the goal of prosecution. [59] This bias will not be as strong as one would expect
from a rational decision-maker with perfect foresight: it is not always
possible to know in advance which cases are ideal targets for investigation and
prosecution. Even where it is, these cases will not present themselves at [60] Paradoxically, there is evidence that some police
forces may lay off financial investigators in the near future—even though their
work is profitable in the narrow sense considered here—due to financial
constraints. The explanation is that ARIS returns only 50% of recovered
revenues to frontline agencies, making it possible for asset recovery work
which is profitably to the UK government overall to entail opportunity costs
for the agencies involved, i.e. if it is not sufficiently profitable to be
self-financed from ARIS receipts. [61] This reflects the actual increase in the number
of persons trained as financial investigators (from 2283 to 2622) in the period
from 2008/09 to 2009/10. [62] This is already acknowledged within the EU. Consider,
e.g., recommendation 4 in section 6.2 of the Council fifth round report on the
UK: ‘the role and powers of financial investigators as well as their training
system need to be presented at EU level and taken into account when common EU
standards or training projects are being developed.’ [63] Data from CAB annual reports. This data has not been
fed into our profitability model for two reasons: because it does not represent
the whole of the Irish asset confiscation apparatus (it only includes work done
by CAB and even then it does not include court costs and enforcement costs),
and because the Irish NCB system (administered by CAB) employs a 7-year lag
between assets being confiscated and realised, making profitability at a given
point in time difficult to estimate from on the available data. [64] The Netherlands is another example of a Member State
which has established a profitable specialist agency: specifically, the Bureau
Ontnemingswetgeving Openbaar Ministerie (BOOM), which is profitable
according to the website of the Openbaar Ministerie [public prosecution]
although figures to support this claim are not provided.