This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52011SC1067
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Analysis associated with the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient EuropePart I
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Analysis associated with the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient EuropePart I
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Analysis associated with the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient EuropePart I
/* SEC/2011/1067 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Analysis associated with the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient EuropePart I /* SEC/2011/1067 final */
Introduction Our
economic growth has long been coupled with declining resource prices – until
recently. In the last decade, the increasing affluence and size of the world's
population appears to have reversed the trend of falling resource prices. An
ongoing path of ever greater consumption of resources is meeting constraints in
stable, secure availability of some resources. We see unsustainable over-use of
environmental resources and increased price volatility in several markets. Already,
many countries and businesses have responded to these megatrends. Like them, the
has EU recognised the essential role in economic stability and growth played by
both mineral and environmental resources - including rare earth metals, water,
climate, fish, biomass, fertile soils, clean air and ecosystem services. So as
an over-arching goal – set in the Europe 2020 Strategy - the EU has chosen to
move to an economic system that is efficient in the way that it uses all
resources. We now face choices on the pace of change and how to best manage
transition. Good policy offers short and long-term economic, social and
environmental benefits from efficiency gains. It need not create net additional
costs. But there will be winners, and losers. Noting
the progress already made in resource-efficiency, this Staff Working Paper sets
out the evidence behind the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient Europe. It identifies
the barriers to the market delivering on its own and how to remove those
barriers. TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction. 1 1........... Challenges
and opportunities for Europe. 3 1.1........ Why
is economic transition needed?. 3 1.2........ Challenges
and Risks for Europe. 6 1.3........ Opportunities
for the EU.. 9 1.4........ International,
Business and other Stakeholder viewpoints. 9 2........... Costs
and Benefits of the Transition to a Resource-Efficient Europe. 11 2.1........ Potential
benefits of improved Resource Efficiency. 12 2.2........ Potential
Costs around Transition. 15 3........... Making
Europe resource efficient 19 3.1........ Several
problems hold back the EU economy. 19 3.2........ Policy
Objectives in the transition to a resource-efficient, low-carbon economy. 22 4........... Transforming
the economy. 24 4.1........ Actions
in an interconnected world. 24 4.2........ Target
Areas for Action. 25 5........... Governance
and Monitoring: A new pathway to action on resource efficiency. 26 5.1........ Consequences
of Existing Governance Arrangements. 26 5.2........ Governance
change for facilitating transition. 27 5.3........ Other
key areas of governance. 31
1.
Challenges and opportunities for Europe
1.1.
Why is economic transition needed?
1.1.1.
Global resource use is increasing
Global
demand for resources is increasing, driven by population growth and improving
standards of living. In the 20th Century, the world experienced a 4 fold growth
in population and a 23 fold increase in economic output. We increased our
fossil fuel use by 12 times, our fishing catches by 35, and our water use by 9.
Globally, extraction of material resources grew by a factor of 8, ores and
minerals by 23 times. Materials are now harvested at a rate of 47-59 billion
metric tonnes a year.[1] Almost
all predictions are that resource demand will continue upwards, given the
underlying trends driving demand. In particular, the world's population grows
by 200,000 people a day[2] and is expected to exceed 9 billion by 2050,
and by 2030, there will be 3 times the current number of people with ‘middle
class’ consumption levels in the now-developing world[3].
As a
result, demand for food, feed and fibre could increase by 70 % by 2050.[4]
Some predict that global food prices will increase by 120-180% by 2030,
accelerating past trends in price rises.[5]
Global demand for energy and water is expected to rise by 40 % over the next
twenty years, if no major policy changes are implemented. If present trends
continue, 1.8 billion people will be living in water-scarce regions in 2025 and
two thirds of the world population could be subject to water stress.[6]
More
detail on past trends in resource use and their drivers are set out graphically
in Annex 7. As a
consequence, after decades of growth based on declining real resource prices,
there are indications that the world has entered a new phase, of increasing
real resource prices - see Figure below.
1.1.2.
European and global resource use is interlinked
In the
globalised economy, the EU is increasingly impacted by global changes in
resources, including climate, material availability and food prices. We use 16
tonnes of materials per capita/year in the EU, more than 8 billion tonnes/year[7],
of which one-fifth is imported – often the higher value, less bulky resources. Global
scarcity, volatility and shocks are transmitted to the EU economy – as
illustrated by component supply concerns after the 2011 Japan earthquake or price volatility in global commodity markets. Systematic figures are not
available for the importance of resources to business but as an illustration 40%
of total German manufacturing costs relate to material inputs, whilst the
energy share of those costs is around 2%[8]. The
growth in the EU economy is also contributing to pressure on other countries
(our 'footprint').[9] Additionally,
every kg of imported products is responsible for 3 to 6 kgs more materials
outside the EU, amplifying pressures.
1.1.3.
These global megatrends are unsustainable
We can only grow
infinitely in a finite material world by reduction in the material we use to
grow. Several scenario exercises back this view. However, existing trends in resource efficiency are not sufficient
to reduce the material intensity of our economy, even in the EU. Measured
purely by mass of material, the EU’s economy’s resource efficiency has improved
at a rate of between 1 and 2% a year, so below the rate of economic growth. One
result is the unsustainable depletion of environmental resources (fish, timber,
water, fertile soils, clean air, biomass, biodiversity) and the environmental
systems of which they form part. Some resources are already beyond their global sustainable limits or
tipping points.[10]
Crossing
of thresholds can bring about sudden changes in ecosystems (for example, in
forest collapse, climate systems or fish stock collapse). This can lead to similarly
non-linear constraints on growth. 60% of
the world’s major ecosystem goods and services - which underpin livelihoods - have
been degraded or used unsustainably.[11] In these,
economic growth has come by running down natural assets faster than the stocks
can regenerate. In the absence of action, the rate of global biodiversity loss
is not expected to slow. It may get worse as climate
change increases pressures in some regions. For example, changing Mediterranean
rain patterns will put more pressures on water resources and so biodiversity in
the region. Figure
: Global environmental thresholds Earth-system process || Control variable || Boundary value || Current value || Boundary crossed || Preindustrial value 1. Climate change || Atmospheric carbon dioxide concentration (ppm by volume) || 350 || 387 || yes || 280 Change in radiative forcing (W/m2) since the start of the industrial revolution (~1750) || 1.0 || 1.5 || yes || 0 2. Biodiversity loss || Extinction rate (number of species per million per year) || 10 || > 100 || yes || 0.1–1 3. Biogeochemical || Anthropogenic nitrogen removed from the atmosphere (millions of tonnes per year) || 35 || 121 || yes || 0 Anthropogenic phosphorus going into the oceans (millions of tonnes per year) || 11 || 8.5–9.5 || no || -1 4. Ocean acidification || Global mean saturation state of aragonite in surface seawater (omega units) || 2.75 || 2.90 || no || 3.44 5. Land use || Land surface converted to cropland (percent) || 15 || 11.7 || no || low 6. Freshwater || Global human consumption of water (km3/yr) || 4000 || 2600 || no || 415 7. Ozone depletion || Stratospheric ozone concentration (Dobson units) || 276 || 283 || no || 290 8. Atmospheric aerosols || Overall particulate concentration in the atmosphere, on a regional basis || not yet quantified 9. Chemical pollution || Concentration of toxic substances, plastics, disruptors, heavy and radioactive contamination into the environment || not yet quantified Source: "A
safe operating space for Humanity", Rockstrom, et al (2009)
1.2.
Challenges and Risks for Europe
Both the economy and
environmental resources form part of systems in which imbalances present risks,
and we now know of some severe imbalances affecting resources. These include a
mismatch between the use and regenerative capacity of natural systems. Noting
this, the OECD has identified risks of major systemic
collapse in growth[12] due to
changes in resources: ·
Reduced competitiveness of firms, or sectors,
subject to price rises, security of supply or volatility in their resource
inputs, where competitors are more resource efficient. ·
Increasing supply security implications, with
future scarcity in basic resources, including water, food, climate services and
soil being a threats to international stability, ie through immigration, and
social unrest.
1.2.1.
Volatility, Security of Supply and Price rises
Increasing scarcity in
resources can lead to price volatility in globally traded markets. Even for
resources where there may not be geological resource scarcity, then scarcity
may reflect reduced availability due to political issues, and closed or
contracted sales of resources. This scarcity can make global markets shallower,
and more susceptible to price volatility, exposing EU companies to economic
shocks. In
particular, there are risks for some critical raw materials that are essential
components for key industries in the EU, such as the ICT and aerospace and
"green technologies"[13] [14].
For example, platinum is needed for catalysts in vehicles, yet most of the world’s supply of
this critical element is found in South Africa. Other examples are
gallium, indium, Rare Earths (e.g. neodymium, platinum and tungsten). Their
short to mid-term availability is limited, providing good grounds for distortion
of the market, particularly as demand growth may be very high - for rare earth
metals neodynium or germanium demand is predicted to increase more than 5 times
by 2030. Source: "Natural Resources
Consumption and Sustainable Industrial Development", S. Suh, Sustainable
Industrial Development, Fall Issue 2008. Price volatility is shown for different key
elements The
Figure above illustrates both the volatility and the annual price increase for
certain key materials. The one below shows expectations of future prices[15].
In the past five years, 75% of European businesses have experienced an increase
in material costs[16]. A
fuller overview of the risks associated with certain materials can be found in
Annex 7
1.2.2.
The Scale and Nature of the transition required
The scale of improvements
in resource efficiency needed in the EU to respond adequately to global trends
is very large. Whilst different resources have different trends, indications of
the scale of change can be made by references to resources in aggregate: ·
The World Business Council on Sustainable
Development, points to the need for an increase in resource efficiency of
factor 4 to 10 by 2050 (which implies that each unit of production is produced
using respectively 25% and 10% of its current resource inputs).[17] ·
Scientists researching resource trends point to
similarly strong innovation needs, for example, pointing to a Factor 5
improvement[18] by 2050 (20% of today's
material usage/unit of production). This
level of improvement requires a step change in innovation in resource
productivity. This change may be one of the future drivers of global growth. One
popular view of the world economy sees growth as a series of 'Kondratieff
cycles'[19]:
periods of long-term prosperity arising from structural change. The structural
change comes as a response to new conditions or new technologies. Some
commentators believe environmental technology/resource efficiency to be one of
the drivers of profound global structural change that will bring in the next
long-term period of growth.
1.3.
Opportunities for the EU
Megatrends in resources also
bring opportunities. They will bring relative competitive advantage for those
states and those firms that adapt fastest, most fully and most efficiently. Resource
Efficiency is one route to adaptation. It involves the spread of technologies,
business models and behaviours that allows the production of greater value for
the EU with fewer resource inputs. Definitions Resources: are all the resources
that are inputs into our economy - metals, minerals, fuels, fish, timber,
water, soil, clean air, biomass, biodiversity and land and sea. (See Annex 7) Resource efficiency: is a way to deliver more with less. It increases
aggregate economic value through more productive use of resources over their
life cycle. It requires using those resources in a sustainable way, within the
planet's long-term boundaries. This includes minimising impacts of one
resource's use on other resources, including the environment. Resource efficiency can
allow the EU to reduce vulnerability to future resource volatility or scarcity,
whilst reducing costs through productivity savings. Many of the win-wins from
improved resource efficiency arise from the inter-linkages between different
resources that are frequently ignored. For example, McKinsey
Global Institute looked at the strong linkages between resource use and
greenhouse gas emissions. They estimate that resource productivity improvements
in land, water, energy (excluding any changes in primary energy mix) and steel
would achieve in 2030 around 50% of the gap between our current GHG emission
path and the path needed to keep atmospheric concentrations to 450ppm.
1.4.
International, Business and other Stakeholder
viewpoints
1.4.1.
International
The EU
is one of many to identify the benefits of a transition to a more resource-efficient
economy. At the international level: ·
the OECD's Green Growth Strategy[20]
states how economic growth can be combined with avoiding unsustainable
pressures on the quality and quantity of natural assets. ·
the G20 has committed to phasing out inefficient
fossil fuel subsidies as a way to reduce budget deficits, deliver growth and
reduce environmental harm. ·
the United Nation's Environment Programme (UNEP)
Green Economy Report[21], makes the case for
investing two per cent of global GDP in greening ten central sectors of the
economy in order to shift development onto a low-carbon, resource-efficient
path. At the
national level too, many countries have launched strategic plans that put
resource efficiency as their major priority. For example: ·
Japan has introduced a
number of visions and laws that represent a conceptual turn from a throwaway society in order to become a Junkangata Shakai (sound
material-cycle society)[22]
and has reduced its resource use by 14% from 2000-05 on top of previous periods
of reduction. ·
China's latest Five Year
Plan (11th) represents a change in development philosophy, aiming for an
ecologically viable society, with greater industrial efficiency. China's investment in the green economy has been estimated by some to be greater than that of the US and EU combined.[23] ·
The Republic of Korea's 'Framework Act for Low
Carbon Green Growth' establishes a legal framework to foster green technology
and industries, to create new green jobs, to respond to climate change, to control energy targets, to promote a green lifestyle for
citizens and to promote sustainable development. In Europe, several Member States have set out strategies and goals for improving resource
efficiency. Several reports summarise the wide range of resource efficiency
strategies and policy actions taken.[24] [25]
[26]
1.4.2.
Business Action
Corporate action highlights the belief of
companies in greater resource efficiency to generate financial savings, and
reduce exposure to future risks of scarcity. Many multinational companies have
set ambitious goals regarding resource efficiency and eco-innovation. For
example: ·
one consumer goods multinational has committed
to halving the resource impacts of its products over the next 10 years and
source 100% of its agricultural supplies from sustainable sources.[27] ·
a large retailer expects to save $3.4 billion
from its 5 year plan to reduce packaging.[28] ·
two international chemical firms have estimated
that, respectively, they have saved $9 billion over 15 years and $5 billion
over 20 years from energy efficiency. However, many businesses are
not fully aware of the potential risks of potential advantages from natural
resource scarcity on their futures. The
World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD) and the World
Economic Forum are representative of many leading international business
organisations. These organisations see resource efficiency as a strategic
response with short-term benefits. The WBCSD Vision's for 2050 (see Annex 1) sets
out the steps for transition businesses need, with significant changes by 2020.
1.4.3.
Stakeholders' views on resource efficiency expressed to the European Commission
The
Commission sought and received the views of many businesses and interest groups
during the development of its Roadmap, through position papers, personal interactions,
debates and a public internet consultation. Broadly, the views of stakeholders are: ·
Resources are under pressure: the exact nature
of this pressure varies from resource to resource, including the groups
affected and whether the impacts are local, national or global. ·
Pressures are increasing: there is wide
recognition that growing demands and threats to supply make this a timely
moment to have a more strategic view of Europe's resource performance. ·
Resource efficiency is central to many
objectives: different stakeholders put the stress on different issues though,
business of the potential for it to improve competitiveness, NGOs on the
potential for it to improve environment. ·
Industry groups are
concerned about the access to raw materials and proper management of primary
and secondary resources.
Businesses called for the development of a sound knowledge base, more policy
coherence, indicators to measure progress and the application of a full life
cycle perspective. ·
Different stakeholders recognise different
possible synergies and different possible trade-offs, in particular business is
wary of possible impacts on current business plans of environmental policies.
However, there is broad consensus that more coherent policy can be beneficial
for meeting a wide range of policy objectives. ·
Many of the policy tools are already in place or
in the pipeline, and focus is needed on improving their operation and
cross-cutting gap-filling and consistency. More
details can be found in Annex 2.
2.
Costs and Benefits of the Transition to a
Resource-Efficient Europe
The benefits and costs of
the transition depend on how smoothly the EU economy adapts to the changing
megatrends and how the speed of response compares to international competitors.
For example, waiting for sudden or forced change, induced by crisis, or slower
adaptation than competitors would be likely to impose more costs than gradual
change. Our economy is in constant change as innovation introduces new
technologies, consumer preferences change and competition encourages some firms
to grow at the expense of others. The EU's Industrial Policy for the Globalised
Era discusses how the technologies, firms and sectors which are most successful
now will not all be those which are most successful in the future. A transition
to a resource-efficient, low-carbon Europe is part of this ongoing process of
renewal.[29] To assess the benefits and
costs of a transition to resource efficiency, we have to make comparisons
between different growth paths, any of which has costs from continuous renewal
and competition in the economy.
2.1.
Potential benefits of improved Resource
Efficiency
In the
short to medium term[30], a resource efficient growth path would bring: 1.
Improved productivity: as businesses reduce costs and so
improve their competitiveness. 2.
Growth and job creation: a faster pace of technological and
organisational change will benefit the EU and open new global markets,
supporting new jobs. 3.
Environmental benefits and resilience: improved management of
resources can, for example, be an efficient way of reducing carbon emissions at
the same time as strengthening EU resilience to the effects of climate change. 4.
Macroeconomic stability: by reducing security of supply
issues, market volatility in important resources and so reducing pressures from
asymmetries within the Eurozone. It can also support fiscal reform. 2.1.1.
Improved productivity There
is significant untapped potential for resource efficiency to quickly increase
the productivity of the economy by cutting costs for businesses and consumers.
The values of such gains vary from resource to resource, from business to
business. Given this, the potential can only be shown based on examples: At
the level of individual countries: -
UK business could save
around £23bn per year from resource efficiency measures that are either no or
low cost[31]. The majority of these savings come from using raw materials more
efficiently and generating less waste (c. £18 billion). The sectors with
the greatest potential identified were chemicals / minerals (c. £4 billion),
metal manufacturing (c. £4 billion), power and utilities (c. £3 billion),
construction (c. £3 billion) and road freight (c. £2 billion). A further £33bn
per year of annual savings could be realised from expenditure with payback
periods of longer than 1 year. -
Empirical evidence suggests that a 10-20%
reduction in resource and energy use in Germany is possible, with annual cost
savings of 20-30%[32]. The payback period was one year in the case of materials, with estimated
increase in resource productivity of 2.9% per year. For materials, this saving
would be worth up to €160bn/year in Germany alone. At
the European level: -
The Union's energy efficiency target of saving
20% of energy by 2020 could cut consumers’ bills by up to €1000 per household a
year and improve Europe’s industrial competitiveness creating up to 2 million
new jobs by 2020. -
20-40% of Europe’s available water is being
wasted. Losses of water in the supply network are often substantial in
water-scarce regions in Europe. For example, in France and Spain up to 34% of water is lost before it reaches the consumer, but in Denmark only 7%. Water
efficiency might be improved by nearly 40% through technological improvements
alone. Resource efficiency is an
important issue for EU industries, and a study found that some industries have
improved substantially in recent years, although there is still room for
improvement, though the ease of these improvements varies.[33] Many of the gains from resource efficiency for businesses
and consumers can be achieved at low or zero cost or where there are costs they
are not large investment costs. For gains with longer-term payback periods,
investments would be necessary. The absence of available finance is one of the
barriers addressed in Annex 3. 2.1.2.
Growth
and job creation Resource
efficiency that encourages (or is based on) eco-innovation and improves the
productivity of the economy will improve growth and job prospects at the
macroeconomic level.[34] For example: -
estimates of the impact of improved resource
efficiency in Germany suggest that the economic benefits would include a
creation of more than 1 million jobs and an improved growth rate.[35] -
economic modelling[36]
points to the possibility of policy measures bringing about resource efficiency
that could eventually boost GDP by 4% (after 15 years) and significantly reduce
unemployment.[37] Particularly high
employment growth potential has been identified in construction, ecosystem and
resource management, renewable energy, and recycling sectors. In order to build
a sustainable future growth, employment in these sectors needs to be of high
quality and move away from precarious and low-paid working conditions. In this
respect, jobs created in sectors linked to sustainable growth are
often more secure, with high potential for exports and economic value creation.
First-mover advantage in
resource efficiency can capture growing markets. The EU holds roughly one third
of the world market for environmental technologies. Currently, the global
market for six market segments in eco-industries has been estimated at €1.7 trillion
per annum,[38] and is growing by around 5% per annum[39]. The nature of this advantage
is continually shifting. For example, the EU used to be the dominant producer
of solar cells but now China's solar cell industry is the world's largest. According to a recent report by the World
Wildlife Fund for Nature, China's green technology sector growth is
outstripping all other nations. While Denmark earns the biggest share of its
national revenue from clean technologies, China's sector has grown by 77% a
year. China earns more than 44 billion Euros each year (more than any other
country), or 1.4% of its gross domestic product from clean technology. This creates competition,
but also particularly strong export markets as China and other developing
countries move to better manage their resources. Parts of
the EU have moved up the value chain: for example, exporting the equipment used
to make thin-film solar cells rather than the cells themselves, as in the past.[40] 2.1.3.
Environmental Benefits and Improved
Resilience Improving resource
efficiency will help safeguard the environment, and reverse the unsustainable
trends documented in Europe's State of the Environment Report 2010[41]. It will reduce pressure on our 'natural capital': such as biodiversity
and ecosystems, which provide goods and services that benefit the global
economy and are essential for key economy sectors, for example food and drink,
raw materials, medicine, cosmetics. For
a number of other resources (mainly renewable resources), resource efficiency
can help reverse unsustainable trends, for example from pollution. Decreased
material use reduces harm to environmental resources, and therefore improves
the resilience of ecosystems and ability to cope with
natural hazards. This will have
economic benefits, as Member States' exposure to future fiscal risks depends on
the resilience of the natural and man-made infrastructure to extreme events
(flooding, storms and sea-level rise) amongst other factors.[42] Protecting these resources
does not necessarily mean lost short-term opportunities: -
In Scotland, the public benefits of protecting
the Natura 2000 network of protected areas are estimated to be more than three
times greater than costs, including direct management and opportunity costs. -
A programme to restore several wetlands in Danube (37 sites in the Lower Danube Green Corridor) will cost €183 million but will retain
vital adaptive functions of the ecosystem and will likely lead to earnings of
€85.6 million per year. Without restoration, the 2005 flood damages were €396
million. Much EU eco-innovation
should stimulate greater resource efficiency outside the EU (for example
through the sale of technologies) and so reduce the depletion of global
resources. PBL[43] estimate that global energy use could be reduced by over 30%
in 2050 without major changes in consumer habits through such dissemination,
halving the gap between baseline greenhouse gas emissions and the 450 ppm
CO2-eq mitigation scenario. On the
other hand, increased productivity from technology also frequently leads to a 'rebound effect' as improved efficiency translates into higher demand for
resources. Without a well-designed policy mix this offsets the environmental
benefits (and those from reduced resource exposure) (see Annex 5 ). 2.1.4.
Macroeconomic stability Terms of trade and resilience Decoupling economic growth from the use of
natural resources improves the terms of trade and eases current account
pressures. A shift to energy and commodity-efficient production patterns would
also strengthen the resilience of the EU towards price shocks in commodity
markets. Single Market and Eurozone tensions It can also reduce the impact on the single market and eurozone of
commodity price developments asymmetrically affecting European economies due to
the different weight of energy and food in EU Member State's expenditure. Security of supply and market volatility Resource efficiency is a route to tackling security of supply issues
and market volatility in important resources, including critical metals and
minerals, fresh water, fish and food commodities. These issues affect many
sectors of industry, including manufacturing, water and energy supply and their
customers and place strain on the single market and eurozone through asymmetric
impacts of resource price developments. Productivity gains and support for fiscal reform As well as such relatively direct benefits for growth from
productivity gains, resource efficiency can also support fiscal reform and help
balance public finances by finding new sources of revenues and promoting
employment.[44] This can occur both through providing a new source of revenues, and
through the reforming of subsidies cutting public expenditure.
2.2.
Potential Costs around Transition
2.2.1.
Costs of slow or retarded transition
If the EU economy adapts too
slowly, costs arise from exposure to the risks and
volatilities of resource scarcity. Competing firms or countries with relatively
better resource productivity or resilience to resource shocks will gain
competitive advantage, which may slow EU growth. Developing countries may develop
strategic advantage over the EU, as they are less locked into physical
infrastructure and institutional rigidities based on old growth models.[45] Slow
transition now suggests more sudden transition later, in response to crisis or
lack of competitiveness which is likely to incur greater transition costs. Slow
change presents increased damage to environmental resources, making their
recovery more difficult. The opportunities mentioned above are lost. The
OECD has argued the processes of economic restructuring ultimately strengthen
the competitiveness of economies. As part of this, new industries will grow at
the expense of others, implying a reallocation of resources from old industries
to new industries.
2.2.2.
Costs of the process of change
Adaptation
to resource megatrends over time will involve structural economic change. Structural change brings costs from frictions in people or capital
investments moving from one activity to another. It
involves updating of technologies, innovation, skills. The costs of transition
will also crucially depend on three factors: how well change is predicted, the
pace of change, and the flexibility of the economy. A) How well the economy predicts and meets change If businesses and economies are able to predict changes, they can
reduce costs by avoiding investments that are soon obsolete. Instead, they can
pick investments that will thrive in the changed conditions. An example of a stranded investment would be energy
infrastructure that did not factor in future switches in energy sources. There
are short-term actions that are relatively risk-free, but long-term investments
depend on a good understanding of future resource prices and constraints.[46] B) Pace of change Overly-fast rates of change can exceed capacity to adapt and
innovate, leaving firms or countries stranded with mismatching assets and
skills to the new conditions. The ideal rate of adaptation is one that matches
the capabilities of the economy as a whole to adapt. C) Flexibility of the Economy If an economy is more flexible – if it can more easily move workers
and investments into new ways of production – it suffers lower costs from
change than economies that have more inbuilt rigidity. Flexibility comes from
many factors: including labour markets, modernity of infrastructure, the degree
of entrepreneurship and the ability to finance investments. Box : Transition costs in
labour markets The transition to a low-carbon and
resource-efficient economy will involve change as:[47] (1)
Substitution of employment will take place, for
example due to shifting from fossil fuels to renewable energy sources or from
waste land filling to recycling; (2)
Particular jobs may be eliminated without direct
substitution (e.g. when the use of certain packaging materials is discouraged
and their production ends); (3)
Additional jobs will be created in several
areas, such as in the manufacturing of pollution-control devices which are
added to existing production equipment; (4)
Many existing jobs (i.e. plumbers, electricians,
metal workers, and construction workers) may need changed skills due to changed
best practice working methods. The net effect
is expected to be either no or a slight positive impact on the employment
level. However, the overall impact could be negative if structural employment
increases due to workers' existing skill sets not matching future needs. The costs
from structural unemployment will depend significantly on: ·
How well workers and firms look at future skills
needs and train for their future opportunities. ·
Whether change in any region or sector is
gradual, allowing progressive adaptation of skills by individuals or whether
the labour market is suddenly flooded with redundant workers[48]; and ·
How easy it is for workers to re-train or move
to different employment. Where
economies face costs, governments can choose to reduce these by helping in any
of these areas, for example: easing of transitions and the support of
workers during transition. Policies should focus on preserving employment
in the economy, not particular jobs.[49] [50] They can, for example, anticipate future skills
needs for green and greener jobs and adapt education and training systems
accordingly.
2.2.3.
Comparison with the past and other potential
futures
The costs from adaptation
through greater resource efficiency need to be compared against the costs to
the economy from structural change in the past, and compared to other realistic
scenarios of future growth. Structural change is an
ongoing process. Any economy is in constant change with growth and relative
decline of different sectors and skill sets, generating constant costs from
change. Past structural change has shown that new jobs associated with new
businesses are generally more productive than those that have been lost as a
result of new ideas and adaption to market demands.[51] The table below
illustrates this trend of structural change by showing how labour has shifted
between the primary, secondary and tertiary sector between 1980 and 2008. Over
the same period the aggregate size of these economies increased substantially,
with annual average growth rates in GDP or 1.5-2.5%. This indicates that the
'business as usual' of an economy is not to stay static, but to undergo change,
and the costs that come with it. Table: Sectoral Structural
Change in Selected Economies (% of Gross Value Added)[52] Selected economies || 1980 || 2008 Agriculture || Industry || Services || Agriculture || Industry || Services Poland* || 8.2 || 39.4 || 52.0 || 3.7 || 32.0 || 64.2 Spain || 6.3 || 37.0 || 55.7 || 2.6 || 28.4 || 69.0 UK || 2.0 || 40.7 || 57.2 || 0.9 || 23.6 || 75.2 Germany || 2.4 || 41.1 || 59.9 || 0.9 || 29.8 || 69.3 US || 2.9 || 33.3 || 63.7 || 1.3** || 21.8** || 76.9** The ‘baseline’ levels of adjustment could be taken as the
levels that have been seen in past decades – for example, in the UK some 25% of private sector jobs are lost every year but another 25% are created[53]. Whether the costs of
adaptation to resource trends are higher or lower than the costs of continuous
structural change in the past will depend on the factors mentioned in 2.2.2
above. Yet, it seems likely that the transition to resource-efficiency could be
achieved through a change in the focus of innovation in the economy, rather
than in the rate of structural change.
2.2.4.
Identifying winners and losers
In any
growing economy there are winners and losers. Policy makers can help facilitate
transition by identifying potential winners and losers, to help target policy. Potential losers are likely to be particularly
visible, seeking to preserve the status quo to postpone short-term costs: "The
short-term negative consequences of structural change, i.e. those enacted
through the downsizing (or closure) of enterprises, are relatively
identifiable, publicly visible and often strongly concentrated in particular
sectors. The positive effects of structural change, both in terms of new companies
and the expansion in existing companies, are generally less visible, much less
publicised and more evenly spread throughout the economy"[54]. The
potential losers from the transition to resource-efficiency can not be easily
grouped by sector. In any sector, winners will be those firms that adapt
successfully. This will often include those that make investments in innovation
earlier rather than later, even where this implies short-term costs. For
example, greater efficiency in the use of metals (eg, in construction) in the
economy may reduce the mass of a metal sold but simultaneously make the metal
more valuable, as it achieves its purpose (for, instance structural support)
with less. Those firms which adjust to capture the added value will thrive at the
expense of those that have a mass based business model. In general, the losers will be those firms or individuals
who have heavily invested in capital that is not well adapted to a resource
efficient economy, either in terms of their production processes,
infrastructure or the products and services that they offer. In terms of individuals or regions, those facing short-term
losses will be immobile employees without the skills sought in the future
economy, and regions which have invested in resource intensive industry and
which do not have a suitable policy mix to support adaptation. Policies for
managing transitions may require particular support for low-skilled workers. At the same time, the aim of being more resource efficient
is not to drive resource intensive sectors out of Europe. On the contrary, it
is important to keep industry and its supply chain in Europe to maintain growth
and jobs. Policy can respond to changing conditions by altering
the distribution of costs. For example, removing artificially low resource
prices provides the right incentives for productivity gains, but creates
winners and losers between competitors within an economic sector. It changes
the basis of competition – giving added advantages to those firms which adapt
best.
3.
Making Europe resource
efficient
Some progress on resource efficiency is already happening
as businesses, households, Member States and international institutions are
taking action. Resource productivity has improved by around 2% per annum (if
measured by Euros per kg of Domestic Material Consumption); in many contexts we
have relative decoupling of economic growth from environmental harm; and we are
reducing our reliance on fossil fuels by increasing energy efficiency and
developing alternatives.[55] Yet there are a number of problems that reduce the economic system's ability to predict change and its
flexibility to respond to that change. These artificially
slow the EU's rate of transition to greater resource efficiency. They constrain
the EU's natural ability to respond to changing conditions: either to seize the
new opportunities and avoid the costs and the risks to growth, security and
future well-being identified above.
3.1.
Several problems hold back the EU economy
3.1.1.
Constraints on the ability to predict
Knowledge gaps about future risks constrain firms and policy makers from planning
for the future. For example, there are significant uncertainties how
environmental systems (like weather-linked water supplies) will change and the
impacts they will have. Many firms are not aware of risks up their complex,
global supply chains. Consumers, firms, policies
and parts of the economic system (e.g. financial markets) are often shaped by short-termism
in decision making. Firms and households can have short pay-back periods for
investments, which could lead to underinvestment for the future. For example, one study found that in a particular context
firms are so risk averse that returns on investment must be perceived to be
‘air-tight’[56]
with figures of 27% needed[57]. Policies often focus on short-term goals. Ability to Predict + Respond - Policy incoherence - Market failures: externalities, missing markets, not pricing scarcity Figure:
Resource inefficiency: barriers, threats and impacts
3.1.2.
Constraints affecting the ability to predict and
respond
Market
Failures Market
economies are good at making the right purchases and investments when they are
working well, for example, when the price of a good matches its real cost.
Surprisingly often, there are still barriers - market failures - that
hold back markets from working well. This is particularly the case for
decisions or purchases which affect quality of life in the future, or direct or
indirect effects on environmental resources (like climate or ecosystems). The globalisation
of resource supplies has made many impacts and risks more remote, so less well
reflected by markets. These include: ·
Failure to reflect future scarcity of resources
in prices, leading to unsustainable use. ·
Misalignment of incentives along a value-chain.
For instance, the landlord-tenant problem, where the person responsible for
investments (landlord) will not benefit from any increases in energy or
resource efficiency, so will under-invest. This can also apply within supply
chains. ·
Indirect costs or 'externalities': Where there
are indirect consequences of resource use, they are often not considered in public
and private decisions. Many resources are economically valuable, but under-priced
and usually off firms' balance sheets. This leads to the mis-management of
these resources, with weak incentives to improve efficiency of their use or
management.[58]
Many of these are the impacts from the life-cycle (eg. extraction,
processing, use, waste) of one resource on another (for example of metals on
the climate system, or of agriculture on water availability. ·
Problems with management of open access or
shared resources, or 'missing markets'. There are resources with unclear
property rights (e.g. fish stocks, forests) where people have very weak
incentives to collectively manage the resource well for the future. This
mean that market signals, particularly price, often point decisions away from
resource efficiency. Policy
Inconsistency Some policy
interventions do the same, whilst inconsistency between policies reduces
predictability. Policy – made for good reasons in one field - can have
unintended consequences that holds back efficient use of resources, for
example: ·
Subsidies that promote resource use can be very
large and have significant indirect impacts. ·
Market rules and regulatory structures can
unintentionally hold back innovation. For example, bidding systems for power
sales that are conducted one-day ahead hinder the participation of wind-power
generators, who can more reliably predict their output around 3 hours ahead.[59] As
external conditions change, policy is sometimes hard and slow to reform,
leading to policies that hold back transition. For example, tax policies put in
place for one reason, may have increasingly costly distortions on the market
that slow adaptation, but these indirect effects are often not considered by
segmented policy-making governmental structures. Policy inconsistency often
also arises from the complexity of trying to remove market failures, which can cause
high costs of intervention. It also comes from policy being shaped in favour of
groups for whom policy change bring short-term loss of income, rather than longer
time period, more diffuse but larger income gains.
3.1.3.
Constraints affecting the ability to respond
Economies have a tendency
to respond slowly to some changes, because they (and the firms and consumers
that form them) are partly 'locked-in' to paths
determined by past investment decisions, existing economic structures and
prevailing institutions. In addition, firms and people tend to be risk-averse,
which can constrain the ability of firms, consumers and societies to adopt new
innovations[60].
Some examples are: ·
Technological lock-in when established technologies have a price advantage over
innovations, or where the technology forms part of a physical or social system
of which the other parts are not changing. Examples are technologies linked to
infrastructure, as with transport (eg. electric vehicles lacking charging
points) or networks (the advantage of communication technologies is their
ability to communicate with the technologies that other people already have). ·
Lock-in to consumption and behavioural
patterns (eg. food choice, or waste disposal
behaviour). Behavioural studies observe that people tend to stick to habits,
social norms or past behaviours. This holds back diffusion of product and
organisational or social innovation, hindering the creation or expansion of new
markets.[61] ·
Skills and business models may continue to be strongly based on techniques and information
learnt in previous years. ·
Insufficient incentives for innovation in resource efficiency on the scale required in particular to
stimulate greater financial and human resources in these areas
3.2.
Policy Objectives in the transition to a
resource-efficient, low-carbon economy
3.2.1.
The Europe 2020 Strategy
To secure smart, sustainable and inclusive growth into the
future, EU governments have agreed on an economic strategy to take the EU to 2020.
The Europe 2020 strategy recognises that a good transition to resource
efficient Europe requires policy to remove the barriers described above. Across
the EU, a very wide range of policies aiming at improving resource efficiency
are already in place[62]
[63]
However, even with these policies,
current trends – e.g. in the environment - are failing to meet EU objectives.[64]
The OECD argues that leadership is needed from finance and economic ministries,
without which the transition goals will be impossible to achieve, although environmental
policies play a central role.[65] To help
deliver the necessary policy change, one of the Europe 2020 Strategy's key
initiatives[66] established
resource efficiency as the guiding principle for EU policies on energy,
transport, climate change, industry, commodities, agriculture, fisheries,
biodiversity and regional development.
3.2.2.
Objectives of the Roadmap to Resource Efficient Europe
The
Roadmap aims to remove the barriers holding back
transition that are not yet tackled by sectoral policy. It also aims to create
a framework that improves coherency across existing and new policies. This is
partly done by agreeing the long-term goal set out in the Roadmap: By 2050 the EU has grown in a way that respects resource
constraints and within planetary boundaries, thus contributing to global
economic transformation. Our economy is competitive, inclusive and provides a
high standard of living with much lower environmental impacts. All resources
are sustainably managed, from raw materials to energy, water, air, land and
soil. Climate change milestones have been reached, while biodiversity and the
ecosystem services it underpins have been protected, valued and substantially
restored. The Roadmap aims at removing the following barriers: Barriers to the ability to predict ·
Deliver research to fill the gaps in our
knowledge and provide the right information. ·
Creating clear milestones, indicators progress
in resource efficiency and targets to provide guides on the future direction of
the economy and policy. ·
Increasing the flow of information on resource
risks and cost-effective efficiency opportunities between commercial partners
in supply/value chains that leads to the uptake of new sustainable practices and
stimulates breakthroughs in innovation. ·
Encouraging more long-term innovative thinking
in business, finance and politics, including information exchange within
government develops that forward thinking, cost effective regulation. Barriers that hold back both the ability to predict and respond ·
Removing market failures, including improving
management of open access resources. ·
Reduce uncertainty on future returns through
providing clear, consistent, credible market signals on direction of relevant
policies. ·
Promoting exchange of information between
government ministries toward common goals, to improve policy coherence, find
synergies between policy goals and resolve trade offs. ·
To tackle lock-in to existing consumption
patterns and behaviours through policy that take into account most recent
science on the influences on consumer behaviour. Barriers to the ability to respond ·
Addressing taxes and subsidies that distort the
real costs of resource use. ·
Increase public and private investment in technological
innovation, including through increasing the priority and funding for research
and innovation on resources. ·
Increase flexibility in labour markets,
supporting training in the right skills. ·
Ease short-term adaptation cost concerns, with complementary,
transitionary policy measures to facilitate policy reform, - including international
short-term competitiveness concerns of less-adaptive firms and costs for particular
social groups - and seeking a consensus with international partners to move in a
supportive direction.
4.
Transforming the economy
4.1.
Actions in an interconnected world
Very large opportunities
for cost savings coupled to reduction in resource use and impacts remain,
despite past progress towards more resource efficient supply. Seizing these
opportunities could allow the EU to transform its economy whilst improving
competitiveness. The
Resource Efficiency Roadmap covers a wide range of areas - energy, transport,
climate change, industry, commodities, agriculture, fisheries, biodiversity and
regional development. The solutions are proposed to be taken at all levels of
society, by individual businesses, business associations, consumers, regions,
Member States and, where there is added value, at EU level. The
majority of areas already have some targets or objectives that are the product
of longstanding policy discussions between stakeholders. The Roadmap sets out
actions to help these objectives to be met more easily (i.e. at lower social
cost), more quickly or with less chance of failure. Many
of the means to do this lie in exploiting synergies inherent in the
inter-connections between economic sectors and policy areas. There are interlinkages across the economic system, the use of
resources and environmental impacts: supply is related to demand, investment is
related to perceived opportunities, prices for one resource depend on prices of
its potential alternative. Indirect impacts and feedbacks create complex
relationships. The box below illustrates one example, of the important
interlinkages between resources and the economy. One of the main
conclusions in EEA’s State of the Environment Report 2010 states:
‘environmental challenges are complex and can’t be understood in isolation’.
This applies equally to most issues around transition to resource efficiency.[67] Within the web of interconnections, changing one resource (or
policy) may either cause other consequences - e.g. unexpected impacts
elsewhere, or achieve little change to the system. This leads to many potential
synergies: ·
a number of feasible dematerialisation
strategies such as increased recycling, lean manufacturing and prolonging
product lifetimes could save up until 5162.5 PJ of energy. These energy savings
would not only entail a reduction in the EU's GHG emissions of 15.6%, they would
also reduce the need for water for energy generation, reduce the need for land
to produce biofuels, and reduce the pressures on biodiversity from
acidification and eutrophication.[68] ·
a number of strategies including reducing food
losses, improving agricultural practices and reducing power savings in farming
could lead to a reduction of 25% of global warming and respiratory organics, a
reduction of aquatic ecotoxicity of 68% and a reduction of 31% of acidification
and terrestrial eutrophication.[69] ·
mitigating climate change would halt adverse
effects on ecosystems, whereas undisturbed ecosystems have been proven to play
a crucial role for climate change mitigation and adaptation.[70] Many of the interlinkages
can also lead to trade-offs: ·
the production of biofuels: on the one hand the
production and use of biomass can lead to greenhouse gas savings and have
potential benefits to the environment, but on the other hand it can also
increase other environmental pressures.[71] ·
deployment of 'green' vehicles reduces the use
of fossil fuels but increases the demand for electricity and certain raw
materials, some of which are subject to supply restrictions and concentrated in
a few geographical areas (e.g. rare earth elements for electronic components
and fuel cells, lithium for batteries). ·
land used to produce food may compete with land
use for energy and both may compete with land which supports biodiversity or
provides ecosystem services such as absorbing carbon from the atmosphere. ·
some additives used in plastics can extend the
preservability of packaged food, but pose serious challenges to plastics
recycling.
4.2.
Target Areas for Action
The actions to help smooth
transition can be grouped into 6 areas for easier explanation, corresponding to
the main barrier they seek to remove. This can tend to hide the inter- very
significant connections between them. These areas of action are: ·
Improving products and changing consumption
patterns ·
Boosting efficient production ·
Turning Waste into a Resource ·
Supporting Research and Innovation ·
Phasing out inefficient subsidies ·
Getting prices right Issues between
resources differ. The application of these actions is particularly needed on
the where the existing barriers have the greatest effects. In Annex 3 to this
Staff Working Document, the rationale for areas of action and their application
to key resources are described. These are: ·
Ecosystem Services ·
Biodiversity ·
Minerals and Metals ·
Water ·
Air ·
Land and Soil ·
Marine Resources Co-ordination of
actions becomes important because each action has direct and indirect effects
that pass further through the economic and environmental systems.[72]
For example, a change in consumer purchasing has effects on suppliers'
behaviour and, in turn, on their input suppliers. As these indirect effects can
be very significant, bringing coherence would need the most important of these
indirect effects to be considered in policy making. In economic systems,
the primary flow of interactions runs up and down from the final consumer
through intermediary economic actors to raw materials suppliers. (This is
sometimes called the 'value chain'.) Consideration of interactions in these
value chains is a necessary step to finding synergies and new ways to remove
long-standing barriers. The Roadmap considers what would be needed for three
key areas of economic value: ·
Food and Drink ·
Buildings ·
Mobility Annex 3 describes the
rationale behind working with these value chains.
5.
Governance and Monitoring: A new pathway to action on
resource efficiency
5.1.
Consequences of Existing Governance Arrangements
Uncertainty around future
policy and incoherence between policies are one of the barriers that hold back
the economy's ability to predict change in resource scarcity and in its ability
to respond. Weak coordination can lead policies to be
working against each other. This can happen where policy is formed on the basis
of different information or different prioritisation of political interests,
and can leave business and citizens facing contradictory policy and market
signals.[73] Several policy bodies have pointed to the removal of these barriers
as essential. At EU level, the Council has called for integrated approaches
working over the life-cycle of products and materials from extraction to end of
life.[74] The OECD in its 'Towards
Green Growth' strategy refers to broad recognition that further progress can
only be achieved if governments turn to more integrated policy approaches[75].
Business stakeholders have called for clear, unambiguous, credible and reliable
market signals to give security to investment. Experience with existing structures for integrated policy
development at EU level suggests that a change is needed to steer the
transition to a resource efficient economy. Weak coherence has been found to come from: ·
'Silo-based' policy making arrangements - policy
responsibilities relating to the economy's transition to resource efficiency
are spread among different departments with governments and decentralised to
the appropriate level.[76] Departments or regional
administrations can form divergent objectives. ·
Political emphasis on short-term, direct
effects, particularly reactions to negatively perceived change. Together, these reduce the
predictability of change for firms, weakening belief in announced strategic
policy and the implementation of the policies which would deliver it. These
factors also affect the scope of relevant knowledge within policy making
bodies. Knowledge of the existing and future potential for greater efficiency
between sectors in value chains often falls outside the expertise of policy
makers. The focus on particular areas and direct effects tends to reduce
knowledge of indirect effects on systems and the optimal rate of change for
area of the economy.
5.2.
Governance change for facilitating transition
Governance arrangements
are a key factor in the level of policy. The Roadmap sets out actions to change
governance in 3 areas:
5.2.1.
Sharing information on future opportunities,
milestones and targets
Bringing together
information from different parts of the supply/value chain can identify
short-term win-wins that each sector or organisation could not realise without
the co-operation of other parts of the value chain. It can also provide
information for policy makers that allow them to identify the packages of
policy that would need to be provided to give the right market signals and
incentives to support further opportunities. The Roadmap considers
structures that would bring business representatives from across supply/value
chains together with policy makers. These platforms would facilitate
information exchange about resource supply risks, possibilities and barriers
for greater efficiency. The exchange of information can help set commonly
agreed goals for the optimal rate of transition in any particular area of the
economy and identify the most appropriate set of policy reforms to drive
innovation. The discussion of
potential common objectives, for 2020 and beyond, and knowledge of the
potential of increased innovation to achieve them may help change expectations
of future markets (e.g., for innovation) and to lead to increased investment by
reducing barriers to predictability. It can also serve to bring policy makers
with different expertise together in the formation of common goals. Within Europe, many
organisational structures have been set up which attempt to improve policy
coherence and exchange with business with varying success. In Member States' policies some transition is
taking place to integrated resource-efficiency policies (e.g. in Finland) from past segregated policies (energy efficiency, water, waste, etc.) A few Member
States apply a holistic approach to focus on greening the whole economy,
instead of giving attention to particular resources (e.g. United Kingdom) In a
few cases, the whole life-cycle is considered and impacts abroad are taken into
account, through e.g. focusing on sustainable trade (the Netherlands) or the impacts of consumption (Sweden). There are many examples,
at EU and MS level, of structures to shape policy and business action through
co-ordinated discussion. For example: CARS 21 (an EU level grouping of the
vehicle supply chain and policy makers), Member State transition platforms (eg.
in the Netherlands which brought together 5 ministries[77]),
civil society initiatives (eg. the European Re-Building Forum[78]).
Positive and negative experiences with the reform of environmentally harmful
subsidies have demonstrated the importance of this approach.[79]
The successful Covenant of Mayors, which has driven energy efficiency in over
2000 cities and regions, can expand its scope to realise the synergies between
energy efficiency and wider resources efficiency in urban settings. International round tables
bringing together the wide range of relevant stakeholders to promote resource
efficiency along the life-cycle have been established for several
internationally traded goods, notably palm oil, soy, and cocoa. At EU and MS level, existing
structures can be used, with changes where needed. The
nature or participation and engagement in these organisational structures defines
their success. For instance, the technological and
organisation potential for efficiency gains is often outside the knowledge for
some companies, in particular of SMEs[80]. For this reason, the
World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD) points to the
importance of making new alliances to bring trust between government, academia,
business consumers and civil society).[81] It uses the example of the construction industry, where developing
energy efficient buildings on a large scale needs the co-ordination of
professionals along the value chain. Small, progressive
businesses are likely to be under-represented as they do not have the time to
invest in such processes, but their voice is essential for an understanding of
the potential opportunities. Views from business associations may tend to
represent a consensus view influenced by the least progressive companies.
Information on the existence of barriers to change is also needed, so that
these can be reduced. Agreed targets would take
time to discuss. In the meantime predictability can be increased by the
formation of strategies that indicate the direction and pace of transition.
Milestones within these strategies – such as the Roadmap – provide guidance on
appropriate stages for a smoother transition.
5.2.2.
Economic governance
The
effect of policy strategies in reducing uncertainty and incoherence is
dependent on their credibility. This credibility rests on a number of factors,
including their political strength, their incorporation into existing governance
arrangements and their monitoring. Member
States have the lead in defining their economic strategies for greater resource
efficiency. To support those strategies, the Commission
will highlight progress in resource efficiency within its surveillance of economic governance of Member States. This 'European Semester' monitoring of Member
State policy reforms can help strengthen co-operation with Member States,
increasing chances of policy change and the adoption of appropriate governance
structures at Member State or regional level. It will focus
initially on prioritising sustainable growth friendly expenditure and savings.[82]
[83] Agreements on goals and
setting up of governance structures are not a panacea to overcoming obstacles
to reform[84] and experience with the Sustainable Development Strategy and Lisbon
Strategy points to the need for complementary policies and political leadership
if policy reform is to be successful. However, an additional benefit from EU
governance change derives from one of the barriers to progress. A lack of
co-ordination between Member States has given rise to perceived competitiveness
concerns for those who act first. Improving discussion and analysis can help to
overcome this perceived barrier. As
part of its efforts, the EU will add a review of a small, suitable, selection
of indicators for resource efficiency into the European Semester monitoring
exercise during 2012 for full use in the Annual Growth Survey. Those indicators
will complement the existing carbon transition targets.
5.2.3.
Indicators
The identification of
indicators enabling Member States and others to measure progress in how
resource efficiency contributes to economic goals would support political
action and goal setting on resource efficiency. Major barriers to policy
integration are strongly rooted in differing stakeholder perceptions of the
issues involved and indicators can help harmonise understanding. The indicators will provide additional
information on the competitiveness of European nations. Resource productivity can
be estimated by GDP/DMC[85]
(euro/tonne). However, as an indicator this has some shortcomings: for example
it measures resources by weight, whilst the economic value, scarcity and
environmental impact of some natural resources is only not strongly correlated
to their weight. It also takes a national production perspective, which implies
that it is insensitive to changes in environmental pressures that occur outside
the national borders. In addition, Resource Efficiency covers
many different uses of different resources with different economic and
environmental impacts. High level aggregate indicators must be based on assumptions
on that aggregation, and therefore any single indicator has some weaknesses. The recommendations of the Stiglitz-Sen-Fitoussi Commission[86]
point to the benefits of complementing a headline indicator with a concise
dashboard of macro-indicators on water, land and carbon. A range of thematic
indicators can also provide additional information. Further work on indicators
would allow agreement on an indicator on natural capital and environmental
impacts of resource use. A technical discussion of indicators that Commission
proposes to use can be found in Annex 6. In
addition, progress to resource efficiency would be supported by the use of
complementary measures of societal and economic progress in political and
economic debate. The Commission, several Member States and international commentators have
pointed to the need to complement GDP (which measures only some aspects of the
economy). Further integrating environmental externalities into national
accounting and developing a composite index on environmental pressures to help
complement GDP would help align political goals with the policy needed to
remove barriers to transition.
5.2.4.
Factoring knowledge of interactions into policy
decisions
Many
economic policy decisions are informed by modelling results. A review of models
carried out for the Commission highlights the need for economic models that
better factor in (1) the impacts of limits to stocks
and (2) the kind of large scale change or unexpected shocks that the EU faces
from changes in resources in the rest of the world. In particular, given the
interactions between resources, models tend not to factor environmental change
into economic growth, for instance though the feedbacks from climate change, water
shortage or air pollution. Often, computable general
equilibrium (CGE) models are not well set up to model the dynamics of
transition.[87] Whilst some models link energy production and use, agriculture and
land use and related GHG and air emissions[88], and whilst the two way linkages between the economy and energy
demand are common in economic models, most models do not factor in material
demand in the same way. This requires greater understanding of the linkages
from land use, climate and material use back into the economy. These models of
interactions will be able to be improved through increased scientific knowledge
about resources, how environmental systems respond to pressures, potential thresholds
and interactions between resources. They can use different modules that treat
specific sectors in detail, perhaps using a common interface. Work can be
developed by the research and development programmes including international,
European, national and industrial programmes, as well as the European
Environment Agency (EEA), the Joint Research Centre and Eurostat. Improved models will
assist firms and policy makers to shape policies for the transition to resource
efficiency. The Commission's most recent work on this, including a 2011 study
by PBL[89] is described in Annex 8.
5.3.
Other key areas of governance
The application of more
integrated governance is a key factor in finding solutions to barriers in the
areas of: finance, skills, policy action outside the EU and good implementation
of existing policy. Action in these areas is needed as part of the policy mix. For
example, in finance: UNEP estimates that the annual financing needs for making
the world economy more resource efficient are between US$1.05-2.59 trillion -
around 10% of annual global capital investment[90]. In the EU, and elsewhere, this financing will need to
come mainly from private sources[91]. Yet, for the scale of financing necessary, the
current financial systems bias towards the short-term would have to be
reversed, and some unfamiliarity with investments in resource efficiency would
need to be reduced. Public and private sector action to achieve this may be
identified from discussions with EU, and Member State level, round tables on
finance. Meanwhile,
the costs of current environmental legislation not being fully implemented are
estimated at around €50 billion per year. [92] The
significance of barriers and solutions in finance, skills, international action
and implementation is described in Annex 3. [1] "Decoupling natural resource impacts from
economic growth", International Resource Panel (2011) [2] http://www.grida.no/publications/rr/food-crisis/page/3559.aspx [3] WBCSD,
Vision 2050,
http://www.wbcsd.org/templates/TemplateWBCSD5/layout.asp?type=p&MenuId=MTYxNg&doOpe [4] Food and Agriculture Organisation [5] "Expanding Food Price Scenarios towards
2030", Willenbroekel et al, 2011 [6] "The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010", EEA,2010 [7] http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&plugin=1&language=en&pcode=tsdpc230 [8] "International economics of resource
productivity – Relevance, measurement, empirical trends, innovation, resource
policies", R. Bleischwitz in International Economics and Economic Policy,
2010, [9] "The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010", EEA,2010 [10] "A
safe operating space for Humanity", Rockstrom, et al (2009) in Nature 461,
p. 472-475. [11] "Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, Ecosystem and
Human Well-being synthesis", 2005 [12] "Green
Growth Strategy Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [13] COM(2011)25,
The Commission's Communication on Commodities Markets
and Raw Materials [14] "Critical raw materials for the EU: report of the
Ad-hoc Working Group on defining critical raw materials", Fraunhofer ISI
report for DG Enterprise and Industry, 2010,. [15] Eco-Innovation Observatory (EIO), The Eco-Innovation
Challenge: Pathways to a resource-efficient Europe, report for DG Environment,
2010 [16] Eurobarometer survey, see http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/flash/fl_315_en.pdf [17] "Vision 2050", WBCSD, 2010 [18] "Factor Five", Von Wiezsacker et al, 2009 [19] "As Time Goes By. From the Industrial Revolution
to the Information Revolution", Freeman C, Louçã, 2001 [20] OECD, Towards a green growth strategy, forthcoming [21] UNEP, Towards
a green economy - Pathways to sustainable development and poverty eradication,
2011 [22] "Dematerialisation and resource efficiency in Japan", Wüppertal Institute [23] "Systemic
Tools for an EU Resource Efficiency Roadmap", The Resource Efficiency
Alliance 2011 [24] "Economic
Analysis of Resource Efficiency Policies", COWI 2011 [25] http://www.eea.europa.eu/themes/economy/resource-efficiency/resource-efficiency [26] "Analysis of key contributions to resource
efficiency", Bio Intelligence Service 2011 [27] http://www.growingforthefuture.com/index.php [28] http://walmartstores.com/pressroom/news/5951.aspx [29] "Impacts of Structural Change: Implications for
transition to the Green Economy", GHK, 2011 [30] The impacts (positive and negative) will be felt over
time, and there is a natural blurring between what are sometimes termed
short-term (direct) and medium-term (indirect) impacts. [31] "Further
Benefits of Business Resource Efficiency", Oakdene Hollins, 2011 [32] Distelkamp,
M., Meyer, B., Wolter, M.I. (2005) in: Aachener Stiftung Kathy Beys (Hrsg.) Ressourcenproduktivität als Chance, and MaRess Final Report,
Wuppertal et al 2010 [33] "Competitiveness of European Companies and
Resource Efficiency", Ecorys, 2011 [34] "Studies on Sustainability Issues – Green Jobs;
Trade and Labour", GHK, 2011 [35] Fischer,
H., K. Lichtblau, B. Meyer and J. Scheelhaase (2004), ‘Wachstums- und
Beschäftigungsimpulse rentabler Materialeinsparungen [Growth and employment
impulses of profitable material savings]’, Wirtschaftsdiens, 84 (4), 247-254. [36] The EU
Commission funded MOSUS project: http://www.mosus.net/ [37] Other
modelling results are summarised in 'The Economic Benefits of Environment
Policy', GHK, 2009 [38] "Green Tech Survey", BMU, 2009 [39] Roland Berger Consultancy [40] Economist, 3/2/2011 [41] "The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010", EEA, 2010 [42] "The fiscal implications of climate change
adaptation" CEPS and ZEW, 2010 [43] PBL (2011). EU Resource Efficiency Perspectives in a
Global Context: A fast track analysis. Forthcoming,
will be available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/studies.htm [44] A permanent one percentage point reduction in the
average tax burden on labour is estimated to increase the employment rate by
about 0.4% in a typical country. OECD 2006. [45] International
Resource Panel (2011) Decoupling report [46] "Competitiveness of European Companies and
Resource Efficiency", Ecorys, 2011 [47] "Environment and labour force skills", Ecorys, 2008 [48] "Employment in Europe 2009" European
Commission, 2009 [49] "Green Growth Strategy Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [50] "Studies on Sustainability Issues – Green Jobs;
Trade and Labour", GHK, 2011 [51] "Reallocation,
Firm Turnover, and Efficiency: Selection on Productivity or Profitability?",
Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger and C. Syverson in American Economic Review 2008, [52] Note: The three sectors do not add up to 100%, due to
minor errors in original data. *Polish data are for 1992 not 1980.**Data is
from 2007, no data is available for 2008 (Source: OECD Factbook, 2010 (World
Bank data) [53] "Job creation and destruction in the UK: 1998-2008", Anyadike-Danes et al., 2011 (forthcoming) [54] "Restructuring and employment in the EU: Concepts,
measurement and evidence", European Foundation for the Improvement of
Living and Working Conditions, 2006 [55] "Competitiveness of European Companies and
Resource Efficiency", Ecorys, 2011 [56] "Maintaining a Strong Innovation Culture During a
Downturn", Arthur D. Little 2008 [57] http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/quarterlybulletin/qb940308.pdf [58] "Green Growth Strategy Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [59] OECD Smart Grids and Renewable Energy, Competitition
Committee Roundtable 2010 [60] OECD
Green Growth Synthesis 2011 [61] "Lags in the EU Economy's Response to
Change", Ecorys, 2011 [62] "Economic Analysis of
Resource Efficiency Policies", COWI, 2011, and "Review of the Natural
Resource Thematic Strategy", BIO Intelligence Service, 2011 [63] http://www.eea.europa.eu/themes/economy/resource-efficiency/resource-efficiency [64] "The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010", EEA, 2010 [65] "Green Growth Strategy Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [66] "A Resource Efficient
Europe", COM(2011) 21 [67] "Globalisation the environment and you", EEA,
2011 [68] "Links between dematerialisation and energy use",
Bio Intelligence Services, 2010 [69] "Environmental Improvement Potentials of Meat and
Dairy Products (IMPRO)", B.P. Weidema et al., JRC, 2008 [70] "The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010", EEA,2010 [71] "Climate change impacts on water quality and
biodiversity", European Topic Centre, 2010; "The European Environment
– State and Outlook 2010", EEA,2010 [72] "Green Growth Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [73] "Green Growth Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [74] December Council conclusions on Sustainable Materials
Management: Council Document 17495/10 [75] "Green Growth Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [76] "Making reform happen: Lessons from OECD countries",
OECD, 2010 - P. Ekins, Chapter 5 [77] The Dutch government put in
place 'transition management' as national policy in 2001, with five ministries
jointly developing transition polices for mobility, food production, energy and
biodiversity. Referenced in "Towards Resource Efficient Economies in Asia and the Pacific", Asian Development Bank [78] http://www.epe.be/Default.aspx?p=112&n=134 [79] "Competitiveness of European Companies and
Resource Efficiency", Ecorys, 2011 [80] "Competitiveness
of European Companies and Resource Efficiency", Ecorys, 2011 [81] Vision 2050, WBCSD, 2010 [82] Areas such as research and innovation, education and
energy; eliminating environmentally harmful subsidies or tax exemptions;
"green tax reforms“; exploiting the EU's first mover advantage on competitive
environmental goods and services. [83] One tool the EU can use to do this is the
indicator-based assessment framework iGrowGreen, currently being developed by
the Commission with Member
States. It examines the shift to a competitive and greener economy by
evaluating Member States’ performance in domains reflecting the key links from
environmental performance to macroeconomic and fiscal considerations. Quantitative
results are qualified by country-specific qualitative information. Detailed
information is provided at: http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/db_indicators/igrowgreen/index_en.htm [84] "Fostering
structural reforms in industrial countries", IMF, (World Economic Outlook
Chapter 3), 2004 [85] Domestic
Material Consumption [86] "Report of the Commission on the
Measurement of Economic Performance et Social Progress", 2009 [87] European Economy. Economic Papers 413. June 2010. [88] See for examples the modelling work done by the Joint
Research Centre and others for COM(2011)112/ SEC(2011)288, or the work on
linkages between different models done by the EU funded European Consortium for
Modelling of Air Pollution and Climate Strategies (www.EC4MACS.eu) [89] "EU
Resource Efficiency Perspectives in a Global Context: A fast track analysis", PBL,
2011 [90] "Green Economy Synthesis", UNEP, 2010 [91] "Green
Growth Synthesis", OECD, 2011 [92] "The costs of not implementing the environmental
acquis", COWI, 2011 (forthcoming) TABLE OF CONTENTS Annex 1: The World Business Council for
Sustainable Development vision 2050................ 7 Annex 2:
Summary of the Resource Efficiency Public Consultation and other Stakeholders
inputs 8 1........... Public online questionnaire.............................................................................................. 8 2........... Public Policy – Instruments to overcome barriers towards a more
resource efficient economy 10 3........... Position papers and written
contributions....................................................................... 11 3.1........ Companies/business associations................................................................................... 12 3.1.1..... Creating the right framework
conditions......................................................................... 12 3.1.2..... Improving governance................................................................................................... 12 3.1.3..... Competitiveness concerns............................................................................................. 12 3.2........ NGOs and think tanks.................................................................................................. 13 3.3........ Governmental organisation............................................................................................ 13 Annex 3. Target Areas for Removing
Barriers to Resource Efficiency............................... 14 1........... Transforming the Economy............................................................................................ 14 1.1........ Improving products and changing
consumption patterns................................................. 14 1.1.1..... Specific barriers to transition......................................................................................... 14 1.1.2..... Policy Actions.............................................................................................................. 14 1.1.3..... Analysis of strengths and
weaknesses............................................................................ 15 1.2........ Boosting efficient production......................................................................................... 16 1.2.1..... Specific barriers to transition......................................................................................... 16 1.2.2..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 17 1.2.3..... Analysis of strengths and
weaknesses............................................................................ 17 1.3........ Treating Waste as a Resource....................................................................................... 19 1.3.1..... Specific barriers............................................................................................................ 19 1.3.2..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 20 1.3.3..... Analysis of strengths and Weaknesses........................................................................... 21 1.4........ Supporting research and innovation............................................................................... 23 1.4.1..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 23 1.4.2..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 24 1.4.3..... Analysis of strengths and
weaknesses............................................................................ 25 1.5........ Phasing out inefficient subsidies..................................................................................... 26 1.5.1..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 26 1.5.2..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 27 1.5.3..... Analysis of strengths and
weaknesses............................................................................ 27 1.6........ Getting prices right........................................................................................................ 28 1.6.1..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 28 1.6.2..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 29 1.6.3..... Analysis of strengths and
weaknesses............................................................................ 29 2........... Key Natural resources.................................................................................................. 31 2.1........ Ecosystem services....................................................................................................... 31 2.1.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 31 2.1.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 32 2.1.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 32 2.2........ Biodiversity.................................................................................................................. 33 2.2.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 33 2.2.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 33 2.2.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 33 2.3........ Minerals and metals...................................................................................................... 33 2.3.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 33 2.3.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 34 2.3.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 34 2.4........ Water........................................................................................................................... 34 2.4.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 34 2.4.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 35 2.4.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 36 2.5........ Air............................................................................................................................... 37 2.5.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 37 2.5.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 38 2.5.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 39 2.6........ Using land and preserving soils...................................................................................... 40 2.6.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 40 2.6.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 42 2.6.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 43 2.7........ Marine resources.......................................................................................................... 43 2.7.1..... Interlinkages, Significance, Risks................................................................................... 43 2.7.2..... Specific Barriers........................................................................................................... 44 2.7.3..... Actions......................................................................................................................... 46 3........... Key Sectors................................................................................................................. 47 3.1........ Addressing food........................................................................................................... 47 3.1.1..... Significance.................................................................................................................. 47 3.1.2..... Opportunities for Resource
Efficiency............................................................................ 49 3.2........ Improving buildings....................................................................................................... 53 3.2.1..... Significance.................................................................................................................. 53 3.2.2..... Opportunities for Resource
Efficiency............................................................................ 54 3.3........ Ensuring efficient mobility.............................................................................................. 56 3.3.1..... Significance.................................................................................................................. 56 3.3.2..... Opportunities from Resource Efficiency......................................................................... 57 4........... Application of Governance to
Other Key Areas............................................................ 58 4.1........ Investing in the transition............................................................................................... 58 4.2........ Supporting resource efficiency
internationally................................................................. 59 4.3........ Removing skills bottlenecks and
mitigating social costs................................................... 60 4.4........ Improving implementation of EU
legislation.................................................................... 61 Annex 4: Representative European
Ecological Footprints.................................................... 62 Annex 5: The rebound effect and odd price
effects............................................................... 63 1........... Definition...................................................................................................................... 63 2........... Evidence and significance.............................................................................................. 63 3........... Implications for policy................................................................................................... 64 Annex 6: Resource efficiency indicators
and targets............................................................ 66 1........... Introduction.................................................................................................................. 66 2........... The approach............................................................................................................... 66 3........... Lead indicator and dashboard of
complementary macro indicators................................. 66 3.1........ The Lead Indicator....................................................................................................... 66 3.2........ The dashboard............................................................................................................. 67 3.3........ Baselines, latest values and trends................................................................................. 68 3.4........ Further developments................................................................................................... 69 4........... Theme specific indicators.............................................................................................. 69 4.1........ Transforming the economy............................................................................................ 70 4.1.1..... Improving products and changing
consumption patterns................................................. 70 4.1.1.1.. Supporting Green Public Procurement
(GPP)................................................................ 70 4.1.1.2.. Promoting green buying................................................................................................. 70 4.1.2..... Boosting efficient production......................................................................................... 71 4.1.2.1.. Measuring, managing and improving
European companies' resource efficiency................ 71 4.1.2.2.. Registering and substituting
harmful chemicals................................................................ 71 4.1.3..... Turning waste into a resource........................................................................................ 72 4.1.3.1.. Ensuring full implementation of
waste legislation, in line with the waste hierarchy.............. 72 4.1.4..... Supporting research and innovation............................................................................... 73 4.1.4.1.. Increasing investment in research
and innovation on resource efficiency.......................... 73 4.1.5..... Phasing out inefficient subsidies..................................................................................... 73 4.1.4.1.. Phasing out Environmentally Harmful
Subsidies (EHS)................................................... 73 4.1.6..... Getting the prices right.................................................................................................. 74 4.1.6.1.. Increasing the share of
environmental taxation................................................................ 74 4.2........ Natural capital and ecosystem services.......................................................................... 74 4.2.1..... Ecosystem services....................................................................................................... 74 4.2.3.1.. Mapping and assessing the state and
value of ecosystems and their services................... 74 4.2.3.2.. Maintaining and enhancing
ecosystems and their services............................................... 75 4.2.2..... Biodiversity.................................................................................................................. 76 4.2.3.1.. Halting the loss of biodiversity
and ecosystem services in the EU and restoring them as far as possible 76 4.2.3..... Minerals and metals...................................................................................................... 76 4.2.4..... Water........................................................................................................................... 77 4.2.4.1.. Ensuring good quality and
quantities of water................................................................. 77 4.2.5..... Safeguarding clean air................................................................................................... 77 4.2.5.1.. Achieving air quality with no
significant negative impact on health and the environment.... 77 4.2.6..... Land and soils.............................................................................................................. 78 4.2.6.1.. Reducing the anthropogenic pressure
on ecosystems from land take............................... 78 4.2.6.2.. Reducing soil erosion.................................................................................................... 78 4.2.6.3.. Maintaining soil organic matter
levels............................................................................. 79 4.2.6.4.. Identifying and remediating
contaminated sites............................................................... 79 4.2.7..... Marine resources.......................................................................................................... 80 4.2.7.1.. Ensuring fish and shellfish are
within maximum sustainable yield...................................... 80 4.2.7.2.. Achieving good environmental status
in all EU waters..................................................... 80 4.3........ Key sectors.................................................................................................................. 81 4.3.1..... Addressing food........................................................................................................... 81 4.3.1.1.. Making food consumption healthier
and more sustainable............................................... 81 4.3.2.1.. Reducing food waste.................................................................................................... 81 4.3.2..... Improving buildings....................................................................................................... 82 4.3.2.1.. Promoting green buildings............................................................................................. 82 4.3.3..... Ensuring efficient mobility.............................................................................................. 83 4.3.3.1.. Transforming transport.................................................................................................. 83 4.4........ Governance: New pathways to
action on resource efficiency.......................................... 83 4.4.1..... Financing resource efficient
innovation and investments.................................................. 83 Annex 7: Trends in Resource Use.......................................................................................... 93 1........... Introduction.................................................................................................................. 93 2........... Material Use in the EU.................................................................................................. 93 2.1........ Domestic Material Use and Import Dependency............................................................ 93 2.2........ Global Stocks and Imports of Materials........................................................................ 98 2.3........ Waste and recycling.................................................................................................... 100 3........... Key natural resources................................................................................................. 102 3.1........ Water......................................................................................................................... 102 3.2........ Biodiversity................................................................................................................ 103 3.3........ Fish............................................................................................................................ 104 3.4........ Land use.................................................................................................................... 105 3.5........ Air............................................................................................................................. 106 4........... Interactions between Resources.................................................................................. 107 5........... Drivers....................................................................................................................... 110 5.1........ Global Trends and Drivers.......................................................................................... 110 5.2........ Population Growth...................................................................................................... 111 5.3........ Economic Development.............................................................................................. 112 5.4........ Productivity................................................................................................................ 113 Annex 8: Modelling for the Roadmap to a
Resource Efficient Europe.............................. 114 1........... Existing resource modelling –
approaches & tools........................................................ 114 2........... Developing a new modelling
framework...................................................................... 115 3........... Modelling EU Resource Efficiency.............................................................................. 116 3.1........ An Example of an integrated
modelling of resource efficiency....................................... 116 Annex 1: The World
Business Council for Sustainable Development vision 2050 Annex 2: Summary of the Resource Efficiency Public
Consultation and other Stakeholders inputs On 26 January 2011 the European Commission
adopted a Communication on a resource-efficient Europe, a Flagship initiative of
the Europe 2020 Strategy which sets the framework for a series of initiatives
to be adopted in 2011 and 2012. The planned 'Roadmap for a
resource-efficient Europe' will be one of the main initiatives proposed. A
public online consultation was launched with a press release and an
announcement on Your Voice in Europe website on 22 February 2011, with a
closing date of 22 April 2011. The online consultation asked for informed
opinions and suggestions on how to best achieve the transition towards a
resource-efficient Europe.
1.
Public online questionnaire
Out of the total 126 responses on behalf of
organisations, the majority came from companies/business associations (72),
followed by NGOs (27), public authorities (10), "others" (7),
think-tanks (5), academic organisations (2) and one response from a consultancy
(see Figure 1). Most of the respondents felt that impacts
of resource consumption will affect us both in the short and in the long-term
(see figure 2). They felt strongly that unsustainable natural resource
consumption will only affect us in the long-term (76% thought so) but that the
price of materials will affect us significantly in the short-term (76% also
thought so). 54% of respondents believe resource
efficiency has the potential to help in the long-term. 62% believe it will help
creating jobs in the short-term with fewer respondents believing it will relieve
pressures on environmental resources in the short term. Overall, the current use of resources was
rated not efficient (food, fossil fuels, water, biotic materials, ecosystem
services and energy), or only more or less efficient (metals and minerals,
construction materials and chemicals). Responses reflect that the policies with
the highest potential to help make the European economy more resource efficient
were in the fields of agriculture and rural development, climate change, energy
policy, environmental policy, industrial policy, maritime and fisheries policy,
regional policy, research and innovation policy and transport policy. Consumers
and health policy, employment policy, and trade policy were rated as having
some potential as well. In terms of barriers preventing us from
developing a more resource efficient economy, there were differing perspectives
towards where these were relevant. They felt strongly that inadequate market
signals for RE had a global significance for them as well as consumers
purchasing decisions not reflection long term sustainability. They felt that
there is a lack of information (on alternative options) and this affects
institutions also at a global level. Other issues of global importance are lack
of long-term thinking in decision making (for example these could be awareness
of new technologies, working methods and processes among managerial staff), a
large dependence on existing technologies and the current business models. Of EU level importance are the feeling that
there is insufficient public funding/incentives for investment and innovation
promoting resource efficiency, limits in existing infrastructure (e.g. energy,
transport and communication), unhelpful existing EU regulation and lack of
targets and indicators at EU level (and to some extent at a global level too).
It is also felt that there is a lack of prioritisation at EU level and that
there is insufficient R&D funding and investment. Skills gaps in the
workforce and sub-optimal functioning of the labour market were only perceived
to have national relevance.
2.
Public Policy – Instruments to overcome barriers
towards a more resource efficient economy
Respondents concluded that the most
effective ways to promote long-term thinking and planning in the private sector
would be, at a European level to focus on a mix of policies, from R&D
support to binding targets. A similar mix of policy tools should be
employed also at national level. When looking at ways of boosting investment
in innovation for resource efficiency and what measures would be the most
effective, respondents felt that most measures could and should be adopted at a
European level (as opposed to nationally or globally). In responding to how effective different
measures would be in ensuring private investment in a resource-efficiency
infrastructure, the respondents felt that measures would be effective at either
national or European level. For example, market-based instruments and subsidies
were seen as something relevant at a national level by the majority of
institutions. Of national relevance were also the development of demand-side
management strategies in parallel with any major infrastructure projects, and
public-private partnerships. Cap and trade-type quotas combined with
economic incentives were seen as something relevant to EU level by
approximately 40% of the institutions, even though an equal percentage felt
that they were not effective. Current Business Models The factors seen as very significant
barriers to adopting new business models/organisational innovation by private
companies that could contribute to more resource efficiency were the excessive
perceived risks, lack of funds and long payback periods for investments
compared to short term investors' expectations, as well as uncertain market
demand. They also felt that regulations do not proved the right incentives,
that there is a lack of qualified personnel and a lack of adequate infrastructure. More or less significant are limited access
to information, and knowledge, lack of suitable business partners and a lack of
technological and management capabilities. Market domination by established
firms was seen as not being significant. Shifting Business Behaviour In order to shift business behaviour to
resource efficient business models, respondents felt that market-based
instruments (e.g. energy and resource taxes/incentives in support of resource
efficient business models) would be very effective. Education and training of
employees and binding technical regulations and standards would also be very
effective. Enabling access to investment/R&D and
innovation funding, trade measures, as well as introducing a requirement for
public procurement to comply with sustainability and ecological standards were
seen to be potentially very effective. Cap and trade quotas were seen to not be
effective.
3.
Position papers and written contributions
In addition to the responses to the online
questionnaire, the Commission received also some more extensive contributions
and 34 position papers: 25 from industry groups or companies, 6 from NGOs or
think-thanks and the 4 from governmental organisation.
3.1.
Companies/business associations
The points raised by companies and business
associations can be organised along three broad lines: 1) Creating the right
framework conditions, 2) Improving governance and 3) Competitiveness concerns related
to resource efficiency.
3.1.1.
Creating the right framework conditions
Many companies and business associations
highlighted the importance of investing in R&D. One association considered
that Europe's main weak point is the commercialising of innovations, whereas
some others also insisted on the importance of more public funding for R&D
and innovation policy. One business association stated that boosting innovation
is also about creating new business models and targeting the key stages of the
value chain simultaneously. Finally some companies also suggested putting more
effort into researching substitution materials and recycling technologies. Other points raised were the need to ensure
access to finance, designing SME-friendly support instruments and setting up
SME research networks that would enhance research cooperation.
3.1.2.
Improving governance
One concern that is widely resonated by
business is that the Roadmap to a resource efficient Europe should introduce an
integrated approach to policy making to ensure improved policy coherence. Some
industry stakeholders raised the point that there is still room for improvement
with regard to reducing bureaucracy. Many companies and industry associations
also find that, with regard to resource efficiency, it is important to consider
the entire value chain and to adopt a life-cycle perspective to avoid that policy
measures would just shift the environmental impacts from one phase to another. With respect to regulation not all views
were unanimous. Whereas most contributions suggested that more regulation is
not necessary or desirable, two companies argued for more regulation, arguing
that this would increase policy certainty and hence a climate favourable to
investments and the creation of new markets. In general, many respondents
invite the Roadmap to a resource efficient Europe to set out a long-term vision
of resource efficiency and to present a cost-effective step-wise approach towards
this long-term objective. A majority of business organisations
pointed to the need for developing a sound knowledge base, and some also
suggested that this would include the development of appropriate resource
efficiency indicators. Two representative organisations argued against binding
numerical targets.
3.1.3.
Competitiveness concerns
Many of the contributions received also
insist on the importance of ensuring access to raw materials. Better management
of both primary and secondary materials as well as ensuring free trade and
avoiding monopolistic or oligopolistic market structures are considered to be
key in this regard. A significant number of business associations also
expressed their concern about the recent volatility of resource prices. One business association also expressed its
concern about the fact that there is limited consumer awareness about resource
efficiency issues. Many in the business sector expressed the
need to have regard to short-term competitiveness. In particular, some business
and industry associations express concern that resource taxation – if applied
only at the EU level – would negatively affect industry's competitiveness in
the short or even mid-term. One stakeholder stated that there is a need for
more tax harmonisation at the global level.
3.2.
NGOs and think tanks
Nearly all respondents from think tank and
non-commercial interest groups called for Commission proposals for resource
efficiency indicators in its Roadmap, with some demanding that these indicators
would lead to binding resource efficiency targets. Many respondents called for
more effective waste policies. A couple of NGOs found that the EU's
product policy needs to be strengthened as to ensure that our production and
consumption does not negatively affect Europe's resource base. One association
adds that both the supply and the demand side should be equally addressed. It
also points to the importance of taking into account the findings from research
on consumer behaviour. Another association further suggests that green consumer
choices should be made more affordable. One NGO specifically pointed to investment
related issues of resource efficiency policies, such as avoiding lock-in in
large infrastructure works, urban planning and cohesion policy. One think tank
insisted that the Roadmap would address the underlying drivers of increasing
resource use. It also pointed to the importance of policy integration and
developing a better understanding of the links between the different resources
and the environmental impacts.
3.3.
Governmental organisation
The Commission also received 4 position
papers from governmental (national or international) organisations. Several of
them stressed the need for global governance, addressing the geopolitical and
development dimensions of resource use. Other points raised are the need for a
coherent and integrated approach, the need to involve MS and private actors and
the need of addressing the rebound effect. Annex 3. Target
Areas for Removing Barriers to Resource Efficiency Introduction This Annex provides the rationale for
actions in particular areas of the economy, their application to particular
resources and governance problems.
1.
Transforming the Economy
1.1.
Improving products and changing consumption
patterns
1.1.1.
Specific barriers to transition
Behavioural studies show that people often
stick to their previous behaviours and purchasing habits. They are influenced
by social conventions, lock-in to existing, familiar technology and the set of
information available to them. As consumption is the prime driver of
production patterns and some innovation, these issues slow response to changing
conditions. It weakens markets for innovations and traps consumers and
organisations into inefficient resource use (e.g. in energy consumption in
buildings) even if prices rise. New business models such as car-sharing or
'product service systems' can be slow to expand. Many of the barriers come from the way people
are influenced by marketing information on products, much of which fails to
accurately convey the fully life-cycle costs of production and consumption.
This can partly be attributed to knowledge gaps on the life-cycle impacts, and
partly to the way that purchasers wrongly interpret the information is
presented (e.g. getting confused by green claims).
1.1.2.
Policy Actions
·
Practically applicable knowledge of full
life-cycle impacts can come from creating agreed methodologies for life-cycle
impacts (or environmental footprint) and increasing applied research. This can
be used for consumer information, supply chain improvements and policy. ·
Markets for products or services with lower
life-cycle impacts can be increased through changes to labelling and marketing
that, in practice, help consumers choose. Bearing in mind that issues of trust
and image are often more influential than information, greater diffusion of
scientific research into drivers of consumer choice would support this. Other
options to increase market rewards for these products include incentives. ·
Incorporating life-cycle considerations into
public procurement can increase markets and stimulate innovation. Joint public
and private procurement can be used to cost-effectively buy innovations that
would not otherwise be able to break quickly into commercial markets. ·
Setting minimum
environmental performance standards for products as part of integrated policy –
under the Eco-Design Directive – can boost diffusion and markets for more
resource efficient products, by removing the least resource efficient.
Including a wider range of products and looking at recycled content and
durability of products could reduce the market demand for resource-heavy
products, promoting recycling markets. New business models for products that
promote recycling could be promoted by extension of producer-responsibility.
1.1.3.
Analysis of strengths and weaknesses
Strengths ·
Consumption is a very significant driver for
change (or lock-in)[1]
because it is the fundamental driver of up-stream production activities and the
resulting resource use[2].
54% of income is spent in final consumption; public procurement accounts for
roughly 17% of the EU's GDP. It can change firms' behaviour. ·
Greener public and private procurement can
create markets and greater rewards for innovative products and production
changes. For example, actions on private, public or joint procurement can
remove blocks to investment in innovation by creating market certainty, reducing
technological lock-in. This can overcome barriers to innovation. Removing least
efficient products from the market increases the market rewards for innovation
in more efficient products and services. ·
Actions encouraging broader lifestyle changes
can bring significant benefits only be encouraging less-resource intensive
patterns of consumption[3]. ·
Changing purchasing and behaviours has significant
cost saving potential for consumers and public authorities through life-cycle
efficiency gains, often with short payback periods. For example: ·
A 2011 report of the Dutch Ministry of
Infrastructure and the Environment[4]
concludes public sector energy consumption would be reduced by 10% and 3
million tonnes of CO2 would be saved if all Dutch public authorities applied
the national sustainable public procurement criteria. NOx and fine particle
pollution would drop 1%. The UK found it would save £40.7 million (€47.2
million) if proposed Green Public Procurement furniture criteria are applied[5]. ·
A 2009 study found that using a Life Cycle
Costing approach for procurement reduced costs by 1 %, even if initial costs
were higher[6].
·
These actions would be able to overcome some of
the policy and market failures that can not be tackled by measures affecting
price. For example, many of the resource impacts of consumption happen outside
the EU, during production. (Annex 4 shows the Ecological Footprint, a measure
of global resource impacts of EU consumption.) Change in consumption would also
bring changes in global supply chains, bringing benefits outside the EU's usual
policy scope[7]. ·
Using evidence from behavioural science, policy
on consumer choice can counter lock-in biases with more effective policies, and
can boost markets for green products by applying this knowledge to limit any green
claims that wrongly mislead consumers. Weaknesses ·
The rebound effect may offset benefits if not
tackled: as efficiency of a technology improves (and thus lowers the life-cycle
cost), then usually consumers respond to that saving by consuming more (as seen
with energy use). Annex 5 discusses this more. ·
Adequate life-cycle information on resource
impacts on many products and services is not yet available, and will require
additional resources for development on top of existing EU, MS and private
sector programmes. Decisions will only be able to be taken on the basis of
these estimates, ignoring some of the diversity. ·
Knowledge of how consumers actually respond to
alternative policy measures (like billing information or forms of marketing, e.g.
labelling) is limited. ·
Changing government procurement practices – even
to promote choices that save public money will in many cases involve change in
procedures and practices (for example in single-year budgeting) and therefore
training and understanding of the benefits of change.
1.2.
Boosting efficient production
1.2.1.
Specific barriers to transition
(a)
Lock-ins to existing areas of business focus Scarcity of both management time and
accessible expertise holds back efficiency. This particularly applies where
resource use is not the core business area, even though it may be an essential
part of the process. There is an opportunity cost of engaging in efficiency.
However, the judgement on where to spend management time is often based on past
behaviour and current norms, even where external conditions or resource
scarcity are changing[8].
(b)
Suboptimal exchange of information on efficiency
potentials Firms in one part of a supply chain may not be able to
improve the resource efficiency of their production without the co-operation of
other parts of the supply chain[9]. However, inter-actions along the supply chains
to find mutually beneficial efficiency savings, though frequent, are not the
norm. Firms with wastes that could be inputs for other firms tend not to have
the means to find buyers. (c)
Difficulty of comparing resource impacts between
firms The range of different methodologies for reporting resource
impacts makes comparison between firms difficult – and this holds back the
usefulness of resource measures as guides for firms looking to improve, or
investors. (d)
Short-term focus at the expense of long-term
competitiveness Many companies fail to
economise on longer-term resource use because of a short-term horizon
encouraged by current corporate reporting practices and investor pressure. Access
to finance and lack of knowledge and information on opportunities are further
barriers. This holds back success of resource-efficient innovation, in turn
weakening investment in development of beneficial innovations.
1.2.2.
Actions
Firms can become more aware of change and
savings possibilities, for them and in their supply chain. Member States and
the Commission can assist by: improving the availability of expert advice for
SMEs and helping companies work together to realise synergies, for instance in
the sale of waste and by-products as inputs for others – 'industrial
symbiosis'. A methodological guide for corporate
resource footprints, coupled with good incentives for suitable reporting of
resource use (eg. specific measures to get prices right) could increase
comparability on efficiency between firms. Establishing benchmarks of good
performance would increase managers and investors ability to compare relative
performance. Avoiding, wherever possible, the use of
dangerous chemicals can help protect key resources like soil and water, and
make others, like materials, safer, easier and less costly to recycle and
reuse. For example, the approach to chemicals
management promoted by REACH will help identify opportunities for improvement,
particularly in the substitution of dangerous chemicals with safer and
technologically and economically viable alternatives. New innovative technologies and solutions
for sustainable raw materials supply can increase the options for businesses. The
candidate Innovation Partnership Raw Materials for a Modern Society can
stimulate commercial development of these technologies.
1.2.3.
Analysis of strengths and weaknesses
Strengths ·
Businesses will find it easier to seize the
short-term efficiency savings that present easy win-wins, within their
operations and across their value chains. This will create the conditions that
facilitate innovation. Business consultants report that even providing nothing
more than technical advice to companies in the processing sector could bring
savings of around 20% of material costs[10]. ·
Putting in place market and policy incentives
that reward business investments in efficiency by 2020 will stimulate the
spread of new innovations in resource efficient production methods. ·
A number of schemes show the benefits of
increased information flows, and the pay-back from providing advice or bringing
firms together in National Industrial Symbiosis Platforms: ·
Based on the performance of the UK Industrial
Symbiosis Programme, improving the re-use of raw materials through greater
'industrial symbiosis' (where the waste of some firms is used as a resource for
others) across the EU could save €1.4bn a year and generate €1.6bn in sales[11]. ·
Vienna Ecobusinessplan, sent resource-efficiency advisors to 680 enterprises. These saved
about €47.1 million, 114 912 tonnes reduction of solid waste output,
1 214 tonnes reduction of toxic wastes, 175.3m kWh energy savings,
51 470 tonnes of GHG emissions avoided, 85.8 m km reduction of total
transport mileage. ·
EnWorks (A scheme
in NW England) has delivered, on average: 9% reduction in energy costs, 16%
reduction in water costs, 20% reduction in waste management costs. For every £1
spent in the scheme, there are 920 kilograms of materials, 40 kilograms of
carbon dioxide and 450 litres of water saved, and the business saves £11.25. ·
€1 spent on the resource-efficiency advice
scheme 'Stimular' in the Netherlands can save €13.50 in costs (energy
etc) for the SMEs[12]. ·
Improving interactions along supply chains is one of the
most effective ways to create further improvements in resource efficiency[13]. It also helps avoid
lock-in to existing patterns of production. It allows producers
lower in the supply chain to innovate and reduce resource use with support for
firms closer to the consumer, who can better influence consumer demand. ·
Use of information tools, like reporting, have
the power to bring about change in firms’ investments and processes without
heavy handed regulation, facilitating light-touch change. By coupling these
with the provision of information to the financial markets, providing
comparable standards for resource use impacts will allow financial market to
better support investments in resource efficiency. ·
EU level supporting actions can be
particularly valuable where supply chains are international, with resource
impacts and risks outside the EU. Co-ordinated action by firms active across
the Single Market coupled with EU-led discussions on international agreements
can facilitate change where national initiatives may not have sufficient
leverage. The EU's action here will support the Rio+20 Summit in June 2012. ·
These actions would complement the actions to
get prices right and help consumers factor in (and reward) efficient resource
use in purchasing decisions, increasing the mutual effectiveness of all the
actions. Weaknesses ·
The scale of benefit depends significantly on
the scale of Member State action in assisting firms. To set the level of action
at the right level, the benefits to growth and employment of these
interventions need to be compared to other public expenditure and subsidies on
business. ·
Benefits also depend on business mindsets. An
important route for change in business norms around resource management is
through peer networks. Business action on improving their supply chains will
depend on how sectoral and cross-sectoral initiatives are formed by business
themselves and business organisations. ·
At EU level, discussions between representative
organisations from EU sectors or multi-national corporations can only provide
one part of the story. Representation by companies promoting faster rates of
innovation and SMEs needs particular attention. For full effectiveness,
transition platforms need to be set up at Member State level and must include
small, innovative businesses. ·
These actions will work best when combined with changes
to the relative prices facing firms, as these draw attention to the savings
opportunities.
1.3.
Treating Waste as a Resource
1.3.1.
Specific barriers
'Waste' is already a resource in many sectors, particularly
easily recyclable metals. Industrial structures exist for the collection and
reprocessing of waste. Yet, barriers prevent much of
the EU economy from expanding the re-use, recycling and recovery of the
valuable materials in the 3 billion tonnes of waste that is thrown away each
year[14]. Much of the value of which is lost overseas. On average only 40% of our solid waste is re-used or
recycled, the rest going to landfill or incineration. These materials are
available from municipal waste, construction and demolition waste, to sewage
sludge. Our waste streams are increasing[15].
Yet, in some Member States more than 80% of waste is recycled, indicating the
possibilities of securing EU materials. Also, in many cases valuable raw
materials are lost due to low quality 'downcycling' of waste. Those barriers
arise from: Mixed waste streams: valuable material is lost to recycling and
re-use through mixing with other waste in general waste collection and disposal
(rather than being collected as separate streams), from retention in homes even
at end of life (eg. mobile phones), or from illegal trade in waste taking the
end-of-life products and scrap waste outside the EU. The EU recycling and
manufacturing industries view this as a significant loss of resources for the
EU – particularly in those metals where the EU faces insecurity of supplies,
for instance the elements defined as critical to the EU economy, including rare
earth metals, where the level of recycling remains low[16]. Limits to the
recycling ability and capacity in Member States: cost-effective recycling depends on technological
facilities for the separation of different valuable elements out of waste
streams and processing to obtain clean material. Whilst technology has improved
to make this possible for many elements and waste streams in the past decades
(for example, for plastics), many Member States do not have access to modern
facilities and technologies for some waste streams remain unavailable or
costly. Separate collection often depends on either market actors or public
authorities offering the service, and the current limits and incentives of both
authorities and market actors hold back collection. Incomplete markets
for secondary materials: weak
demand for some recycled resources limits the investment in innovation,
collection and diffusion in a ‘chicken and egg’ problem – lack of investment in
supply can leave potential buyers uncertain of secure high-quality supplies,
weakening demand for those considering investments. Environmental harm
from waste treatment: the
recycling of some waste streams (for example waste electrical and electronic
equipment containing greenhouse gas refrigerants) can have environmental
impacts if not recycled to good standards, as required by EU legislation. These
requirements save costs for society (from environmental damage) but raise costs
for recycling. In some cases, avoidance of the legislative requirements is
frequent, distorting markets and disadvantaging legal businesses. Implementation of waste legislation: Legislation plays a key role in market creation and technology diffusion.
However, waste policies are not well implemented in all EU Member States — 19 %
of all new environmental infringement cases in 2006 and 2007 were registered in
the area of waste policies (Zamparutti et al., 2009) — and better
implementation of current waste policies is needed to fully capture the
benefits that could result from them[17].
1.3.2.
Actions
Resolving these will need
a combination of policies, such as
product design integrating a life-cycle approach, better cooperation along all
market actors along the value chain, better collection processes, and
incentives for waste prevention and recycling. Shortage of supply of material for
recycling can be boosted by facilitating the exchange of best practice on
collection and treatment of waste among Member States. Member
States can set minimum targets through their national
waste prevention and management strategies and work in the EU and with international partners to eradicate illegal waste
shipments would boost the legal market. Legislation on the various waste streams
could be aligned to improve coherence and support good implementation, as could measures to combat more effectively breaches of EU waste
rules. The existing prevention, re-use, recycling, recovery and landfill
diversion targets can provide the push for the move towards an economy based on
re-use and recycling, with residual waste close to zero, if properly reviewed. The introduction of minimum recycled
material rates, durability and re-usability criteria and extensions of producer
responsibility for key products could be one action, amongst others, that
stimulated the secondary materials market and demand for recycled materials. Economic
incentives and developing end-of-waste criteria would also support the markets.
Public funding, including the EU budget,
can play a key role through public
investments in modern facilities for waste treatment and high quality recycling,
boosting innovation by giving priority to recycling
plants over waste disposal.
1.3.3.
Analysis of strengths and Weaknesses
Strengths ·
Waste reduction remains the optimal way to
increase resource efficiency, and deliver the greatest economic and
environmental savings. Improving waste management
makes better use of resources and can open up new markets and jobs, as well as
encourage less dependence on imports of raw materials and lower impacts on the
environment. ·
The potential opportunities are very large,
particularly if innovation in recycling methods is considered. ·
It is estimated that 6-12% of all material
consumption (including fossil fuels) is currently saved or avoided due to
recycling, waste prevention and eco-design policies – with a maximum potential
with existing technology estimated between 10 to 17%[18]. Doing so would have an
estimated CO2eq saving potential of 148 million tonnes (equivalent to taking around
47 million cars off the road per year), and a monetary value of €5 billion[19]. ·
Within waste are materials
that constitute a significant loss of resources for the EU – particularly in those metals where the EU faces insecurity of
supplies, for instance the elements defined as
critical to the EU economy, including rare earth metals, where the level of
recycling remains low[20]. This resource can be 'mined'. ·
For example, the EU produces around 24kg of
electrical and electronic waste per citizen per year. This waste contains many
needed metals for the high tech industries, like Gold, Copper, Indium, Lithium,
Palladium. It is increasingly clear that through improved recycling we can satisfy
at least part of the demand for such important metals. Waste electrical and
electronic equipment alone is expected increase by roughly 11% between 2008 and
2014. ·
To show the possibilities, China has many 'city
mines' - its largest is capable of producing 1 million tonnes of copper each
year, twice as much as the largest primary mine. ·
By working with markets, these actions have the
potential to stimulate much greater investment in innovation and uptake of new
practices than legislation alone. By aligning market incentives for recycling,
including the costs of harm to other (particularly environmental resources)
within the calculations of private actors has the potential to stimulate much
faster rates of innovation, and hence secure a greater share of material flows
for EU supply. ·
Recycling has significant potential for reducing
environmental impacts and harm to other resources – mainly from the avoidance
of the life-cycle impacts (eg. in extraction and refining) of the virgin
materials that are substituted by recycled materials. Benefits also come from
avoidance of impacts from alternative treatment or disposal routes, e.g.
avoided methane emissions from landfilled biodegradable waste. ·
The EU is one of the world leaders in recycling
technologies. Further stimulation of the market for recycling, together with
public R&D support can drive innovation in this area to position EU
producers even more favourably in growing world markets. ·
Targets for recycling and waste prevention (for
example for specific waste streams) have been effective at stimulating changes
in collection and partnerships for recycling. Reviewed targets are also likely
to stimulate organisation change and new technological development. ·
The spread of best-practice in waste
implementation and enforcement across the EU should assist Member States to
achieve more and at lower cost. Weaknesses ·
For success, by 2020, waste must be seen and used
as a resource. This requires a mind-shift in business and local authorities, in
addition to the creation of economically attractive functional markets for
secondary raw materials. ·
Given the rate of global increase in demand for
materials, recycling – even at much higher rates – is not a sufficient strategy
to solve predicted problems of relative scarcity or security of supply. Taking
steel as an example, between 2000 and 2020 China will produce as much steel as
the US did during the last 120 years. If aggregate global production continues
at its average growth rate over the period 1950-2007, i.e. 3.5% annually, in
135 years production would have increased by 100 times, so that even high
recycling rates of existing stocks would be marginal compared with new
production[21].
·
This option requires significant public action –
for instance in public, or publicly funded capacity for knowledge in recycling
markets and collection. Whilst that is an opportunity for job creation in
sectors of the future, public spending may be constrained due to the results of
the financial crisis. Policy will be needed that uses the market to provide
sources of finance whilst fairly distributing costs and benefits between
consumers, producers and recyclers - for example through well-designed producer
take-back schemes. ·
Equally, the maintenance of strong market
signals requires a belief in effective enforcement and the avoidance of illegal
free-riding from operators working in the grey or black markets. This will
require capacity in Member States authorities.
1.4.
Supporting research and innovation
The ability of the economy to adapt is
closely related to its rate of innovation. This change can be made by
developing new technological and non-technological solutions, new approaches to
the way we run business or the way we consume and use goods and services.
1.4.1.
Specific Barriers
The current rate of eco-innovation is
suboptimal because of certain barriers. Both radical and
incremental innovations would be needed, and, as they work together, behavioural,
organisational and systemic innovation would be as important as technological[22]. (a)
Path dependency in areas for investment Investors and
entrepreneurs have started realizing the business potential of eco-innovation
in the area of resource efficiency, but there is more to be done. Path
dependency from the current dominance of certain technologies and systems can
make commercial success of innovations very difficult[23]. Greater innovation
would particularly be needed in: environmentally
friendly material extraction, recycling, re-use potentials, substitution of
environmental impacting material, technologies and design for less material and
energy use, green chemistry (reducing the use of other resources) and improved and biodegradable plastics. Diffusion of innovation in
water conservation and sustainable agriculture would also be required. Innovation does not
only rely on technologies but also on "softer" innovations such as
those related to new business models or new process for example. Although the
understanding and policy support to such types of innovation are less
developed, they also have a significant potential, for example in delivery of
the circular economy, as testified by the successful case of the National
Industrial Symbiosis Programme[24]. (b)
Lack of certainty about future markets A particular challenge
comes in creating market certainty about the demand for innovation by bringing
together the stakeholders across value chains within the economy. Co-ordination
must also allow the design and application of integrated policy mixes based on
an appropriate understanding of innovation trends in the areas of resource
efficiency identified as strategic (given the very horizontal and heterogeneous
nature of the resource efficiency concept). Developing such knowledge base
often represents a challenge. (c)
Under-investment in the relevant areas of
knowledge There is a mismatch between the areas of
need highlighted in the Roadmap and the research funding in these areas,
particularly around: so ·
innovative solutions for environmentally
friendly material extraction, for recycling or re-use, and for substitution of
environmental impacting material, for example on smarter design, green
chemistry and improved and biodegradable plastics; ·
knowledge on the natural tipping points and
ecosystems' resilience thresholds; ·
knowledge on changing consumption behaviour for
delivering resource efficiency and on the likely economy-wide rebound effects
from policy interventions. At European level, this knowledge gathering
would build on the work of the EEA, Research Framework Programmes, as well as
Earth observation policies (GMES, Galileo, INSPIRE, SEIS). Additional research
would mainly take place under the cooperation specific programmes of the
Research Framework Programmes, which are already paying growing attention to
eco-innovation, for example, through public-private partnerships for 'Energy
efficient buildings' and 'Green cars'. From 2014 onwards, resource efficiency would become a main theme, a "grand
societal challenge" of the next framework programme.
1.4.2.
Actions
Action will be needed to overcome the
barriers by bringing together the actors, the policy framework and the
incentives to boost innovation in the key areas for resource efficiency. The
Innovation Partnerships and Joint Technology Initiatives under the EU's
Innovation Union Strategy can do this, if designed to meet resource efficiency
goals. EU research funding can be focused on the key resource efficiency
objectives through its funding instruments - in particular, Horizon 2020 These
actions provide specific funding "windows" for eco-innovation and
tackle some of the specific problems holding back eco-innovation, both on the
supply and demand side. The Eco-Innovation Action Plan can help with by
reducing the barriers to innovation, in technologies and behaviours.
1.4.3.
Analysis of strengths and weaknesses
Strengths ·
Scientific breakthroughs and sustained
innovation efforts could bring about by 2020 dramatic improvements in efforts
to reduce, reuse, recycle, safeguard and value resources. ·
The actions set out in the
Roadmap will provide a coherent framework for policy action in these areas of
innovation, to develop a strategic, long-term plan to
accelerate the development and deployment of solutions. A wide range of
policies will contribute, including the Innovation Union, the Eco-Innovation
Action Plan, the Strategic Energy Technology Plan (SET Plan) and assistance
with EU-wide technology verification[25]. ·
'Innovation Partnerships' can provide the
interactions between potential innovators and policy makers that facilitate the
policy framework, funding and clarity of direction needed to meet resource
efficiency goals. These are being developed on water, raw materials, ecosystem
services, smart cities, agricultural productivity and sustainability,
sustainable fisheries, and green chemistry. ·
Joint Technology Initiatives designed to pool
national research efforts into key areas can provide the critical mass of
research and investments that enhances the rate and success of innovation in
different Member States and markets. Weaknesses ·
The drivers of innovation are complex, and a
wide range of supply and demand side measures are needed to respond. Whilst the
Innovation Union and the actions set out above will contribute, they will need
careful co-ordination and to be complemented by other measures (such as price
signals). ·
The allocation of clean technologies venture
capital to resource efficient technologies has increased from 17% in 2006 to
45% in 2010[26].
The percentage can be taken, even if very roughly, as a proxy indicator of the
type of eco-innovation that is being marketed and that might become mainstream
in the near future. Even if the figure looks reassuring it has to be noted that
energy efficiency plays the lion share in such trends while only a marginal
role is played by technologies in areas such as bio-materials, water
conservation, smart production and sustainable agriculture. ·
The current levels of R&D in the EU fall
well below the headline target of 3% set in the context of Europe 2020. Reaching
this target and making sure that resource efficiency issues are mainstreamed
into the resulting innovation push, will be necessary to successfully deliver
the desired eco-innovation boost.
1.5.
Phasing out inefficient subsidies
1.5.1.
Specific Barriers
Distorting price
signals, hiding future change Subsidies for resources
that lead the economy away from greater resource productivity are those which
artificially lower the costs of using resources. Subsidies deter firms and
consumers from adopting efficiency behaviours and technologies that would be
cost-effective in the absence of subsidies. For example, in fishing, subsidies
have led to the creation of global fishing capacity twice as large as current
fish stock's ability to reproduce, resulting in lost global economic benefits
of US$50bn/year (around half the value of the global seafood trade)[27]. These distorted price
signals make it difficult for firms and consumers to predict future resource
scarcities and adapt accordingly[28]. Holding back the
pace of change The size of this kind of inefficient subsidy greatly
reduces the incentives for innovation and so retards the EU's pace of change.
It also leads to reduction in the capital assets – including environmental
resources - that the EU relies on, reducing our growth potential. The table
below illustrates the scale of the barrier[29]:
Table: Aggregate subsidy estimates for
selected economic sectors [30] Sector / Region || Region Agriculture OECD: || US$ 261 billion/year (2006-8) (OECD 2009) Biofuels: || US, EU and Canada US$ 11 billion in 2006 (GSI 2007; OECD 2008b) Fisheries World: || US$ 15-35 billion (UNEP 2008) Energy World: || US$ 500 billion/year (GSI 2009a) US$ 310 billion in the 20 largest non-OECD countries in 2007 (IEA 2008) Transport World: || US$ 238-306 billion/year – of which EHS US$173-233 billion (EEA 2005) Water World: || US$ 67 billion – of which EHS US$ 50 billion (Myers and Kent 2002) The cost of the
subsidies to the public budget exacerbates macro-economic imbalances,
increasing tax burdens or preventing investment in alternative investments that
would have a greater growth and innovation benefits or social effects. EHS lead to higher levels of waste, emissions,
resource extraction, or to negative impacts on biodiversity[31]. Hindering the economy's flexibility Short-term, individual or
sectoral interests in preserving subsidies lock-in past policy decisions,
holding back the economy from responding to change. Fears of sudden losses of
competitiveness of firms and job losses from the abrupt removing of subsidies
without mitigating measures block discussion of appropriate reforms. Political
and bureaucratic interests can also be an internal governmental barrier to
reform, whilst our frequent sectoral approach to policy making does not
prioritise the indirect benefits and longer-term from subsidy reform.
1.5.2.
Actions
Member States are
invited to prepare plans and timetables to phase EHS out as part of their
National Reform Programmes. The Commission will monitor
the phasing out of EHS in the European Semester as of 2012; organise exchange
of best practices on the reform of EHS between the Member States as of 2012;
and will assess in the future revision of the environmental State aid rules as
of 2013 how measures aiming at increasing resource efficiency have been
implemented and to what extent aid for resource efficiency objectives is
necessary.
1.5.3.
Analysis of strengths and weaknesses
Strengths ·
The potential economic pay-off of reform is very
high, corresponding to the level of these subsidies. A study by the OECD found
that ending fossil fuel subsidies could reduce GHG emissions by 10% by 2050[32]. At their September 2009
summit in Pittsburgh, the Leaders of the G-20 officially recognized the harmful
effects of fossil fuel subsidies. They agreed to “phase out and rationalize
over the medium term inefficient fossil fuel subsidies while providing targeted
support for the poorest"[33]. ·
The direct savings and long term economic gains
from subsidy reform can be significant. An example of the possible direct
impacts comes from estimates that reforming subsidies for company cars could
save up to 0.5% of GDP/year[34].
·
Phasing out environmentally
harmful subsidies by 2020 will deliver public budget savings at a time of
public spending pressure, at the same time as improved productivity and, in the
long run, economic, social and environmental benefits. ·
The social goals behind
these subsidies can often be achieved more cost-effectively by other measures
that do not run counter to resource efficiency. ·
Where subsidies affect internationally traded
goods and services, worries of cross-border competition often need mitigation
through co-ordination between Member States, which the EU can support. ·
Many EHS are off-budget, and require
investigation to identify and quantify. Assessment of the harmfulness of
subsidies is sometimes not unambiguous. EU action can support Member States in
carrying out investigation. Weaknesses ·
Reform of the subsidies has been identified as
part of the reforms under the Europe 2020 Strategy. The
OECD has developed an integrated assessment approach on the assumption that
better policies will result when there is an explicit understanding of the
distribution of costs and benefits, and when this information is made
available. This requires systematic analysis of all costs and benefits, winners
and losers, intended and unintended effects (environmental, economic, social)
and highlighting where trade-offs exist. However, despite much rhetorical
support, significant resistance to change remains. ·
Successful reform needs to either review the
initial purpose of the subsidy or find ways to deliver that goal in an
economically more efficient way. The lack of co-ordination between Member
States gives rise to perceived short-term competitiveness concerns for those
who act first. The arguments that reform boosts competitiveness need more
advocacy. ·
Progress on reform will depend on Member State willingness
to tackle political resistance. Distributional and short-tem sectoral
competitiveness concerns are the major factors withholding member states from
introducing market based instruments[35].
Mitigating arrangements may be necessary for the most affected regions,
economic sectors or social groups within policy packages that ease transition
by creating market rewards for greater efficiency.
1.6.
Getting prices right
1.6.1.
Specific Barriers
Distorting price
signals, preventing the market's prediction of future conditions Markets can only bring
about efficient use of resources where the prices match the true cost of the
resources used. Prices that do not match true costs lock in inefficient
technologies and business structures, and hinder investment in clean energy and
other green technologies. In macroeconomic terms, resources and
labour are often substitutes – and if resources are relatively cheap compared
to labour prices, decisions are made to use more resources in place of labour.
The incidence of the burden of taxation significantly affects these relative
prices – and so frequently current tax policy distorts market prices away from
resource efficiency. In microeconomic terms, the cost of externalities can
still remain unreflected in prices, which leads to unsustainable exploitation of
some resources. Reduced flexibility through slow-moving tax policy Mainstream tax policy often does not
consider the effects of the burden of taxation on the nature of innovation in
the economy, and this slows the ability of policy to match changing conditions.
For example, the trend in the proportion of environmental tax revenues is not
promising: broadly on the decline in the EU27[36]. The potential
to reverse this trend and for further rebalancing by Member States is shown in
the figure below by the considerable variation in taxes on pollution and
resources with Denmark generating 2.3% of its tax take through these (and
almost 10% from environmental taxes more widely). Figure: Environmental taxes as
a percentage of total tax revenue (2009)[37]
1.6.2.
Actions
·
The Commission will facilitate greater exchange
and co-operation at EU level between the Member States on taxation issues: in
particular, through engagement with Member State Ministries responsible for
taxation reform for resource efficiency, for example under the Market Based
Instruments Forum. ·
Member States can assess the relative burden of
taxation on labour compared to resources, making this ratio an analytical tool
for policy effectiveness.
1.6.3.
Analysis of strengths and weaknesses
Strengths ·
Well designed tax shifts can be extremely
effective at inducing behavioural change. Shifting the average share of
environmental taxation in public revenues to more than 10% (in line with the
best performing Member States) by 2020 would create a level playing field and
support the economy to achieve greater resource efficiency. There is evidence[38]
that raising energy taxation could drive forward substantial increases in
innovation. Some positive examples of environmental
tax reform: ·
Sweden’s introduction of a NOx emission tax led
to a dramatic increase in firms using existing abatement technology – from 7%
to 62% in the year following the tax and a large number of patents for new
technical solutions[39].
·
Modelling of a Norwegian
tax of 15% on plastic and paper virgin materials, (far below the external
effects) pointed to a reduction in the use of these materials of 11%[40]. ·
Experience in the UK shows that heavier taxation
of virgin materials improves recycling levels for construction and demolition
waste so that virgin resources are saved. ·
Properly taxing resources (including pollution) should
provide revenues that can either be used to cut labour taxes, and so generate higher
employment; or to relieve pressure on public budgets. The OECD has estimated
that a permanent one-percent reduction in average burden on labour may increase
the employment rate by 0.4% over the long run[41].
Another option is recycling revenues to industry to invest in innovation. ·
Currently, most environmental tax revenue comes
from energy (particularly petrol and diesel transport fuels), with significant
potential for taxes on pollution and resources. Revenues from carbon pricing
alone may raise 1-3% of GDP by 2020 depending on the circumstances of each
country[42].
·
The highlighting of these reforms within the
European Semester monitoring of Member State reforms will help strengthen
co-operation between Member States, likely to facilitate more policy change. ·
Improving discussion and analysis will help to
overcome this perceived barrier, and so the Commission will bring together
experts and representatives of Member States to discuss and share best practice
(at minimal administrative cost) in particular areas. Weaknesses ·
Progress on reform will depend on Member State
action, but this will be subject to political resistance. Distributional and
short-term sectoral competitiveness concerns are the major factors withholding
member states from introducing market based instruments[43]. Attention
therefore needs to be paid to anticipate and mitigate against any negative
impacts on growth, employment and competitiveness. Success will depend
on compensatory measures for socially disadvantaged groups and the use of
fiscal reform within packages of policy that ease transition by creating market
rewards for greater efficiency. ·
Those concerns were also raised during a
symposium on "Growth and green tax shifting in an era of fiscal
consolidation" organised in 2010 by the Belgian Presidency, where Hungary
and Belgium explicitly said that resource taxes would harm their countries
competitiveness, given their existing economic structures. They stated that
coordination among EU-Member States and potentially beyond would be crucial to
avoid relocation and competitiveness concerns, deal with cross-border policy
issues and to avoid distortions of the internal market. ·
Before any reform, worries are voiced about
putting a greater burden on existing industry, e.g. the risk of ‘carbon leakage’
to countries outside the EU, and the uncertainty that market based instruments
could create for businesses, and the uncertainty about the strength of the new
industry created (as is the case of carbon price in ETS). Without strong
analysis of the positive effects of change and the transition costs for the
structure of the economy, these arguments can block progress.
2.
Key Natural resources
The resources below all play an important
role in economic growth and determining the environmental impacts of our resource
use. They form a part of the EU's
'natural capital'. This section describes some of the
particular problems which slow our adaptation to managing the resources
efficiently. This indicates where the actions above to transform the economy
should be prioritised or complemented. These resources are part of the economic
and environmental system, with use of one linked to use of others. Increasing
efficiency in one can have multiplier effects. Climate is a key resource:
specific challenges of progressing to a low-carbon economy are addressed in detail in the Commission's Roadmap for
moving to a competitive low carbon economy[44]
and the forthcoming Energy Roadmap 2050.
2.1.
Ecosystem services
2.1.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Ecosystems provide a
number of services that contribute directly and indirectly to human well-being,
including provisioning services (e.g. food, water, fuel), regulating services (e.g.
flood and disease control), supporting/habitat services (e.g. nutrient cycling)
and cultural services (e.g. recreation). These services are of benefit locally,
nationally or globally[45].
The magnitude of global business
opportunities related to natural resources is estimated to be up to $2-6
trillion by 2050[46]. Depending on the spatial scale of ecosystem
services, it can affect people in the neighbourhood of ecosystems, as well as
local authorities and businesses, affect EU citizens as a whole, or have global
consequences. Some business sectors are particularly affected, as they depend
on ecosystem services, either directly or indirectly, including fisheries,
forestry (wood products), agriculture (dependent on services such as
pollination, biological control, soil formation, water availability and genetic
diversity), water supply, pharmaceuticals and cosmetics, chemicals, agro-food,
and growing parts of the tourism sector. Nature-based solutions (green
infrastructure) can be more cost-effective than purely man-made infrastructures
for delivering public and private benefits – for example, green spaces
providing cooling in cities enhancing resilience, for instance by using forest
and wetland ecosystems for flood control and water purification. This
investment in Green Infrastructure and the 'restoration economy' offers
enhanced growth potential. Yet, 60% of the Earth's ecosystems have
been degraded in the last 50 years[47]. In
the EU, only 11% of protected ecosystems are in a favourable state[48]. 88% of fish stocks, for example, are
fished beyond maximum sustainable yields[49].
2.1.2.
Specific Barriers
The TEEB report[50] highlights some of the key
barriers holding-back resource efficiency: ·
Often the benefits of ecosystems accrue to a
wide range of stakeholders over a wide geographical area. These wider benefits
are hard to integrate into decisions taken by individuals or localities, which
tend to focus on immediate, direct winners and losers. ·
Economic incentives – e.g. prices – play a major
role in influencing the use of natural capital but in most cases prices do not
take account of the full value of ecosystem services. ·
Conventional measures of national or businesses'
economic performance and wealth fail to reflect natural capital stocks or flows
of ecosystem services that they rely on. So these are often not factored into
decision making – leading to policy, production and investment decisions that
degrade or ignore eco-system services. ·
There is often a lack of familiarity with
investment in maintaining, restoring or enhancing services provided by
ecosystems, as alternatives to man-made infrastructure (such as wastewater
treatment plants or dykes). This holds back financing and investment decisions.
2.1.3.
Actions
Member States, regions and firms can better
factor in the value of ecosystems by mapping and valuing the ecosystems they
rely on. Changes in these values can be included within accounting and
reporting to allow the assessment of wealth, risks and facilitate investment. The use of innovative financial instruments
can be developed, including payments for ecosystems services and other market
based instruments: at national, EU and international level. The EIB and public
private partnerships can usefully be involved. Giving
those services their appropriate value would induce economic actors to
integrate the external impacts of their activities on the ecosystems. Public
authorities can create policy frameworks that promote investments in natural
capital.
2.2.
Biodiversity
2.2.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Beyond ethical arguments for protecting
biodiversity for its intrinsic value, there are also economic arguments.
Biodiversity underpins many of our ecosystems and is vital to their resilience.
Its loss can weaken an ecosystem, compromising the delivery of ecosystem
services and making it more vulnerable to environmental shocks. It has been estimated that by 2050, the global business opportunities dependent on biodiversity
and the ecosystem services it underpins, could have a value of between $800-2.300
billion per year. However, 30% of species are threatened by
overexploitation[51]
The EU has failed to meet its previous target of halting biodiversity loss by
2010.
2.2.2.
Specific Barriers
·
Many of the barriers for ecosystem services are
also present for biodiversity management. The true value of biodiversity is
only starting to be taken into account in decisions. ·
Biodiversity is often damaged by the result of
the accumulation of many small indirect, harmful acts. So action to halt
biodiversity loss will need to cover a wide range of policy areas, and a high
degree of complexity will be unavoidable. The demands on integration and
mainstreaming place a heavy burden on policy making and institutions, and
explain many of the difficulties in meeting the earlier target of halting the
loss of biodiversity by 2010.
2.2.3.
Actions
The EU has agreed a target of halting the
loss of biodiversity and restoring them as far as feasible to preserve and
increase its value. The 2020 EU Biodiversity Strategy summarises the key
actions to be taken to reach the target, many of them implementing EU
commitments under the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD).
2.3.
Minerals and metals
2.3.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Global trends appear to indicate that an
era of declining resource prices may be over, driven by increasing demand. On
the supply side easily accessible high-grade ore deposits tend to be depleted,
leaving less accessible, lower-grade ore, that requires more energy and risk to
extract. Depending on the resource, the impacts on supply prices are mitigated
by increasing innovation in extraction technology. Volatility of market prices – for those
materials that are internationally traded has increased for some resources and
presents an economic risk. Stocks, availability and market volatility of
minerals and metals differ greatly between each other, even within groups of
related elements, like 'rare earth metals'. The volatility may increase from
increasing contractual arrangements between states and between monopolistic
mineral supply markets that limit the size of the traded market – with this
'shallowness' leaving markets more susceptible to shocks. Some aggregate trends
and indications of recycling rates are given in the separate Annex 7. In general, there are only a few elements
with geological scarcity. However, there can be scarcity (in the sense of
reduced availability) for other reasons. The supply risk is linked to the concentration
of production in a handful of countries, often with low political or economic
stability. This risk is in many cases compounded by low substitutability and
low recycling rates. For instance, the Commission has identified 14 critical
raw materials at EU level that display a particularly high risk of supply
shortage in the next 10 years and which are particularly important for the
value chain. In many cases, a stable supply is important
for manufacturing competitiveness, and often for climate policy objectives and
for technological innovation. For example, rare earths are essential for high
performance permanent magnets in wind turbines or electric vehicles, catalytic
converters for cars, printed circuit boards, optical fibres, electronic and
photonic components, LED lighting products and high temperature
superconductors. The EU is completely dependent on imports, with China
accounting for 97% of world production in 2009.
2.3.2.
Specific Barriers
There is significant lock-in to existing
ways of using materials, for example in construction, where the introduction of
more resource-efficient building elements may require new knowledge by
architects and builders. Declining price trends in the past have led
to weak innovation in ways to use materials more efficiently, and in recovering
valuable material from mixed waste streams. Recycling of some metals and
minerals increases, but global economic growth is now so large that recycling
can only make a small, though significant impact on demand.
2.3.3.
Actions
The actions mentioned in Section 4 to
promote greater innovation in materials, substitution, efficiency of design and
increased values of recycling can mitigate the barriers to optimal use and
management of minerals and resources.
2.4.
Water
2.4.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Water is an essential resource for many
sectors, such as agriculture, tourism, industry, energy and transport, as well
as a fundamental need for citizens. Reduced water availability has a direct
negative impact on citizens and economic sectors. For instance, water is needed
in power stations for cooling, as well as hydropower. By 2020, Europe's water should be of good
quality, efficiently used and available in sufficient quantity but with water
abstraction, as a rule, below 20% of available renewable water resources. While
water is generally abundant in Europe, demand for
water can exceed availability. When water is scarce, meeting human
demands can mean reducing availability to ecosystems. Where this
over-abstraction occurs, it is causing low river flows, lowered groundwater
levels and the drying-up of wetlands, with detrimental impacts on freshwater
ecosystems[52].
This erodes the natural capital and the services (e.g. recreational fishing)
that are provided. Many European river basins and waters
have been altered by water abstraction, land drainage and dams, leading often
to major adverse ecological effects, poor quality water and limited space for
natural habitats[53]. Water availability varies hugely between
regions, and over time. At least 11% of the European population and 17% of its
territory have been affected by water scarcity to date, particularly in the
south with its relative lack of, and high demand for, water. A comparison of
the impacts of droughts in the EU between 1976–1990 and 1991–2006 shows a
doubling in both area and population affected[54].
Similarly, global groundwater depletion has increased from 126 (±32) km3/year
in 1960 to 283 (±40) km3/year. In Europe, the main groundwater
depletion hotspots are south-east Spain and the lower Danube[55]. Under a "business-as-usual"
development, water withdrawals could increase by more than 40%. Climate change
is also projected to exacerbate these impacts, with more frequent and severe
droughts projected for many parts of Europe. In addition, demand for electricity
increases during hot, dry periods, when air conditioning is used – and this
corresponds to the time of increased risks of water scarcity or increased river
temperature, leading to risks of black-out. As well as water quantity, water quality
remains an issue across Europe, with implications for public health and
bio-diversity. Pollution remains a concern for water users and the need to
supply clean water in sufficient quantity and at a reasonable cost remains a
challenge EU wide. For many European countries much of the
'water footprint' of its consumption is indirect, occurring in use wherever
production takes place (virtual water), causing potential water stress abroad.
2.4.2.
Specific Barriers
Policy simulations show a water saving
potential of 65%, and that an ambitious environmental policy could keep the
vast majority of EU river basins out of water stress[56]. 20% to 40% of Europe’s water
is wasted and water efficiency could be improved by 40% through technological
improvements alone[57].
Changes in land use, in production and water consumption patterns could
increase savings further in a cost-effective way and contribute to ensure both water
quality and availability. There are
several reasons why this potential has not yet been
achieved by policy or markets: ·
Water resource management in Europe has tended
to focus investment on ensuring availability through supply side measures[58]. Demand management requires
change of more actors, with more coordination. ·
Water scarcity, droughts, floods and water
quality problems affect most European river basins, the most important of which
– like the Danube and the Rhine – are transboundary and cover the majority of
the European territory. Solutions need to take the entire water cycle into
consideration often needing transboundary action. ·
True costs of water are often not reflected in
prices, reducing the benefits of investment in water efficiency. One user does
not naturally take into account the impacts of his use on the availability of
water for others. Even where prices are right, water costs can be a small part
of total costs for any individual, and outside of core business activities, so
not taken into account. ·
Sustainable management of water resources would
require integration into agriculture, transport and energy policies; and the
application of fair water pricing policies. (For example, water pricing in
agriculture should be closely related to actual volume of water consumption
rather than a fixed amount per irrigated hectare.) ·
Water leakages from distribution networks are as
high as 50% in certain areas of Europe, with big differences across Member
States. However, in some parts of Europe, for example, Germany and Denmark,
leakage rates are less than 10 % and close to what is technically and
economically feasible[59].
The difference is partly explained by lack of prioritisation of investment, due
to under-pricing of the true costs of water.
2.4.3.
Actions
These costs and
benefits of economic activities and water resources
management need to be reflected in prices to allow
water users to make the right choices about efficiency. Further implementation
of the cost-recovery principle, enshrined in the Water Framework Directive and
highlighted in Water Scarcity and Droughts strategy, will be essential. Fostering the integration of water and
other policies and managing trade-offs covering both
water quantity and quality are needed to give clear signals for changing
behaviours. Life-cycle measurement of water use (within and outside the EU) by
companies for the products they produce can identify water risks and
opportunities. Labelling and certification schemes can enhance market rewards
for reduced life-cycle consumption. Member States can also aim at
estimating the right balance between market instruments and public funding to
finance the recovery of environmental and resource costs. Water efficiency can be
improved by properly examining the allocation of water resources in the medium
and longer term. There
is a great potential for increasing the availability of water in a basin through
reuse and recycling of water through land use change that restore water cycles. Leakage reduction programs, and setting cost-effective
targets for leakage reduction can direct investment to where the costs/benefit
ratio is strong. The River Basin Management Plans under the Water
Framework Directive offer a process to better understand the costs and benefits
of both economic activities and water resources management, and so manage
trade-offs. Multi-purpose natural water retention measures, a component of Green
Infrastructure, are under-exploited. They could also provide cost-efficient
responses to extreme events. Redundancies, overlaps and gaps in legislation can
be addressed to give the right frameworks. Additional analysis will provide a more
accurate picture of the vulnerability of water resources in the medium and long
term and the pollution of surface and groundwater. On the basis of new
information on estimated future gaps between water demand and supply for 2020
and 2050, indicative targets could be set at EU, Member State and river basin
level that would help change policy, behaviours and technology.
2.5.
Air
2.5.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
The quality of air is a key factor in
quality of life and in lowering economic costs. The EEA SOER estimates that current
concentrations of fine particles cause 500,000 premature deaths in Europe a
year and that exposure to particulate matter and
ozone is linked to other significant effects such as acute and chronic
respiratory and cardiovascular effects, impaired lung development in children
and reduced birth weight[60]. These concerns were echoed in the latest
World Health Organisation health and environment progress report for Europe which
states that "urban air pollution, especially particulate matter, causes
significant health problems throughout the region, reducing the life expectancy
of residents of more polluted areas by over one year”[61]. Other studies have
shown that the number of working days lost due to air pollution induced
illnesses is higher than the working days required to pay for additional
pollutant abatement measures. Significantly, ecosystems
and agriculture also suffer damage from airborne impacts such as acidification,
eutrophication and ozone damage to vegetation. The annual economic cost in 2020
has been estimated at €537 bn. Whilst the EU is well on
track to resolving the problem of ecosystems damage due to acid deposition,
biodiversity remains under threat due to excess nutrient deposition
(eutrophication) or high levels of ground-level ozone. There are very strong synergies, and some
trade-offs, between air pollution and climate change policies[62]. Certain measures
(e.g. those reducing black carbon), may also yield important short-term
benefits for climate change[63].
For example, future large scale uptake of electric vehicles could lead to
significant benefits from the displacement of air pollutants from urban to
rural areas (where fossil-fuelled power stations often are) so lowering
population exposure. Electricity sourced from non-combustion renewable sources
would lead to further benefits. Up to 62% of Europe's urban population
remains potentially exposed to ambient air concentrations of fine particle
matter (PM 10) in excess of the EU limit value set for the protection of human
health. Several air quality standards are widely exceeded in the EU[64]. Even though, since the nineties,
air emissions have been reduced significantly for almost all pollutants
identified at the time as problematic. For example, compared to 1990 emission
levels, sulphur dioxide emissions came down by almost 80%, those of heavy
metals by between 60-90%, and nitrous oxides by almost 40%. Cost-effective options to move beyond the
present objectives agreed for 2020 as contained in the 2005 Thematic Strategy
on Air Pollution have been identified. Preliminary analysis suggests a revision
of the National Emission Ceilings (NEC) Directive[65] aiming at meeting the 2020
objectives of the Thematic Strategy on Air Pollution would deliver major health
and environment benefits, with the monetised health benefits 12 to 37 times
larger than the costs. Many Member States will likely miss at
least some of their emissions obligations for 2010 under the national emissions
ceilings directive. Meeting the EU's interim air quality standards by 2020,
including in urban hot spots, will contribute to achieving levels of air
quality that do not cause significant impacts on health and the environment.
2.5.2.
Specific Barriers
·
Clean air is a shared 'public' good, without
ownership or a market. So it can not be managed effectively by the market and
legislation is needed to optimise the health and economic benefits. However
such policy, even where it has net economic benefits in addition to health
benefits is often held-back by distinct political groups who may suffer short-term
costs. This retards the predictability of change and the market economy's
flexibility, holding back innovations. ·
Thanks to policy, the EU has held a leading
position in developing and marketing "green technologies" to control
air pollution, a growing global market. This position is increasingly under
pressure from such countries as Japan and Brazil. Whilst this may reduce
competitiveness of EU air pollution control technologies firms, it should allow
for more cost-efficient policy[66]. ·
Ongoing evaluation suggests that many compliance
problems in Member States are related to a number of factors such as the
overestimation of the expected emission reduction of EU-wide measures (e.g. EURO standards for vehicles) or
the misjudgement of the effectiveness of national measures. Other important
factors are the late development and/or implementation of the Member States’
national programmes. ·
Complexity hinders evaluation of harm and
potential benefits from any individual reduction measure. The figure below
shows how several pollutants contribute to the same environmental impact, and
how a broad range of sectors are responsible for the emissions of atmospheric
pollutants, except for ammonia, whose agricultural activities are the
predominant source (94%).
2.5.3.
Actions
Better implementation
of existing legislation and new, science-based standards would help address
these problems and steer innovation. With appropriate lead-times, these can
ensure air quality benefits from transition to a low-carbon economy, and by other actions in this Roadmap, for example
through reductions in waste, through more efficient production methods, as well
as action in agricultural policy and the transport sector. Air pollution policy
can be reviewed to find the synergies with other benefits. Model-based scenario analysis has shown
that reducing GHG emissions in 2020, 2030 and 2050 will further reduce
emissions of PM2.5, SO2 and NOX in the EU
compared to the reference case. An effective decarbonisation can reduce air
pollution cost (of both damage and air pollution control) by some €11 billion
in 2020, €29 billion in 2030 and €85 billion in 2050[67].
2.6.
Using land and preserving soils
2.6.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Land Available productive land is itself a
natural resource, whether used to deliver agricultural produce or eco-system
services. Changes in land-use may be the best use of the land. However, for
this to be the case, the current and future public and private benefits of
alternative uses of the land need to be taken into account. Current EU land cover is
4.2 million km² of which roughly is 40% forests, 44% agriculture, and 4% built
up areas[68].
The SOER notes that "land-use specialisation (urbanisation, agricultural
intensification and abandonment plus natural afforestation) is still a very
strong trend and is expected to continue in the future". On urbanisation, more than 1,000 km² are taken every year
for housing, industry, roads or recreational purposes. About half of this
surface is actually 'sealed'[69], meaning that, at this pace, every ten years we
pave over a surface area equal to Cyprus. Much of the land being converted is
highly agriculturally productive, due the historical location of cities at the
centre of agriculturally productive areas. Current land take results in a
potential food production loss of 440,000 tonnes of wheat per year[70]. The loss of joined up
habitat through fragmentation is also serious. Intensification is
problematic where the impacts of high stocking numbers, inadequate crop
rotation and high water use are not controlled – inputs of nitrates and
pesticides into water, ammonia into air and water stress can result. Agricultural
abandonment is also an issue: potentially 12 million hectares[71], with 8.6%
abandoned by 2020[72].
This can have undesirable consequences for biodiversity, especially related to
the loss of extensively grazed grasslands. Some of these land use risks vary between
regions, and here subsidiarity is important. However, issues such as pressure
on agricultural land or soil sealing are present in all but the most isolated
parts of the EU, and the policy drivers are often from the EU if not
international level. EU policy also has an
impact worldwide. The ongoing work on Indirect Land Use Change in the context
of biofuels suggests a relatively responsive model whereby additional demands
on agricultural output translate into undesirable land use change mainly
outside of the EU (deforestation, ploughing up of grassland). Soil Soil provides
us with food, biomass and raw materials. It serves as a platform for human
activities and landscape and as an archive of heritage and plays a central role
as a habitat and gene pool. It stores, filters and transforms many substances,
including water, nutrients and carbon. Soil captures
about 20% of the world’s manmade carbon dioxide emissions, giving good soil
management significant cost-effective potential for mitigating climate change.
Europe's soils contain an estimated 73 to 79 billion tonnes of carbon in the
form of organic matter. Even a tiny loss of 0.1% of that carbon emitted into the
atmosphere is the equivalent to the carbon emission of 100 million extra cars
on our roads – an increase of about half of the existing car fleet. Conversely, an
increase in soil carbon of the same small amount would be worth some €1.6
billion[73].
It is important to note that about 20% of the European soil carbon stock is in
peatlands, despite the fact that they only cover 8% of the EU-27 surface area[74]. Soil quality and water
issues are linked – soil organic matter can hold 3-5 times its weight in water,
when it is preserved.[75]
In addition, a fully functioning soil reduces the risk of floods and protects
underground water supplies by neutralising or filtering out potential
pollutants and storing as much as 3,750 tonnes of water per hectare[76]. In 2006, the
Commission evaluated that soil degradation in EU-25 was costing the EU economy
some €38 billion per year[77],
with the EEA estimating a cost of agricultural land loss of €53/ha/year. Europe has a problem of soil contamination,
particularly historical contamination. It is estimated that 3.5 million sites
may be contaminated, with 500,000 sites being really contaminated and needing
remediation[78],
at a cost of €17.3 billion per year[79].
Once contaminated, soil functions may be impaired and human as well as
ecological health and food quality may also be prejudiced. 17.5% of the soil is at risk from water
erosion of more than 1 t/ha/y[80];
Economic effects due to erosion-induced on-site income losses (e.g. tourism,
land abandonment) have been estimated at 10 – 90 €/ha/y (2006 value)[81]. The
Commission’s 2050 vision foresees that the soil resource is sustainably
managed. One measure of the health of soils is the level of organic matter. To
make the most of the potential of
this resource, degraded EU soils would have to increase their levels of soil
organic matter. Soils which have lost organic matter to a large
degree have the greatest potential gains for fertility, erosion reduction and
carbon sequestration from increasing organic matter. The Commission has already
indicated that around 45% of soils in Europe have a low or very low organic
matter content, taken to be less than 2% organic carbon, or 3.5% organic
matter. Thus, by 2020, soil organic matter levels should not be decreasing
overall and should increase for soils with currently less than 3.5% organic
matter.
2.6.2.
Specific Barriers
Land As land-use change is frequently long-term,
and often practically irreversible, or costly to reverse (e.g. conversion of natural/agricultural
land into transport infrastructure), decisions made now may not be optimal over
time. The use of land is nearly always a
compromise between social, economic and environmental needs including additional
housing to deal with an aging population and improved infrastructure to
facilitate economic development. Yet many individual decisions often do not
consider the cumulative effects of land-take and longer-term, strategic goals. Most
land is in private ownership and owners, within planning and other legal
limits, and decisions do not consider the indirect or public benefits of
land-use. One of the challenges for land use policies is successful engagement
of the interested parties. For example, if we are to reach a state of
no net land take by 2050, following a linear path, we would need to reduce land
take to an average of 800 km² per year in the period 2000-2020. Although identification of contaminated
sites and their subsequent remediation would facilitate land use, only a
minority of Member States has a proactive policy in this field. Even with
significant increases in activity, only a fraction of the identified sites will
be remediated by 2020. Some land use risks vary strongly from
region to region, and here subsidiarity is important. With regards to
fragmentation and sealing of land, significant infrastructure decisions are
increasingly being taken at the EU level, which means that EU level checks and
balances are required. Much land use change is being driven
by EU legislation - mainly the Renewable Energy Directive. Soil Natural soil formation is very slow: it can
take more than 500 years to form two centimetres, so soil losses over 1-2
t/ha/year are in practice irreversible. Longer-term and public benefits from soil
are often not factored into to private decision making. Member States have a
key role in taking action on soils. However, very few Member States have soil
monitoring schemes in place allowing a quantified evaluation of soil conditions
changes in time[82].
Partially as a result, there is unequal progress among Member States in addressing
soil contamination.
2.6.3.
Actions
Developing the knowledge-base on biotic
material, land-use trends and spatial planning can inform decisions. Research can discover where high erosion rates
take place, as this can identify the most cost-effective measures. (For
example, the EU Strategy for the Danube Region[83],
looks to reduce the surface area where erosion exceeds 10 t/ha/y, by 2020.) The EU can gather estimates of Europe’s consumption globally, including
impacts at global level, and highlight best policy practices
in the Member States. The Innovation Partnership on Agricultural
Productivity and Sustainability can help halt the loss of soil functionality,
for example, by ensuring that EU agricultural land susceptible to water and
wind erosion is managed by practices of conservation farming. It can assist
Member States in the development of organisational and behavioural innovation
on soils, by improving the information flow. EU level checks and balances can integrate
strategic, long-term and environmental aspects into EU decisions affecting
land. This includes indirect land use change from renewable energy, TEN-Ts,
TEN-Es, regional initiatives such as the Danube Strategy and specific projects.
Ongoing CAP reform will continue to play a key role in supporting the sustainable
management of land. The EU and Member States can improve
consideration of land as a resource in policy and planning processes, including
the operation of the Environmental Impact Assessment Directive. Changes in
trading arrangements, such as the proposed MERCOSUR agreement can have a very
large influence on indirect land. Setting goals that accelerate the current
downward trend in per capita land take would support an evolution of national
policies in this direction. This would respect subsidiarity whilst assisting in
reducing the pressures from the EU level. The identification of contaminated
sites and their subsequent remediation would enhance resources at risk from
contamination and facilitate land use.
2.7.
Marine resources
2.7.1.
Interlinkages, Significance, Risks
Marine ecosystems have an important natural regulatory
function and constitute the resource base that underpins the economic
prosperity of many coastal regions. Overexploitation
of natural resources reduces the economic yield that could be derived, e.g.
from fisheries. The European Union represents about
4.6% of global fisheries and aquaculture production[84], and fisheries,
aquaculture and food processing account for around 0.5 million jobs with a
turnover of 32 billion Euros per year[85].
Achieving good environmental status of all EU marine waters by 2020, and
by 2015 fishing within maximum sustainable yields would put the EU fishing
industry on a sustainable basis, and ensuring that marine resources are managed
effectively and are not left at risk. In addition to
sustainable fisheries, the marine environment holds many economic opportunities
stemming from living resources -e.g. in pharmaceuticals and biotechnology -
from mineral resources and both
renewable (wave, wind, ocean energy) and fossil energies (oil, gas). A recent report[86] underlines the economic importance, assessing the
sustainable benefits related to marine ecosystems in the Mediterranean in 2005.
The benefits assessed fall into three groups of ecosystem services: production
services (production of food resources of marine origin), cultural services
(amenities and support for recreational activities) and regulatory services
(climate regulation, mitigation of natural hazards (coastal erosion) and waste
processing). At regional level, the
benefits are assessed at over 26 billion Euros for 2005, more than 68% of which
comes from the provision of amenities and recreational supports. The benefits
relating to the production of food resources account for only 11% of the
overall estimated benefit. The global market for Marine Biotechnology
products and processes is currently estimated at € 2.8 billion with annual
growth of 4-5%. Some estimates predict that annual growth in the sector could
exceed 10 in the coming years, revealing the huge potential, if properly
encouraged and facilitated[87].
2.7.2.
Specific Barriers
There is sub-optimal
management of marine resources. The depletion of fish stocks has severe
economic and social consequences for coastal zones and contributes to
biodiversity loss by disrupting systems. (a)
Fish stocks below maximum sustainable yield In the EU, about 1/3 of
the assessed stocks are being fished outside their safe biological limits[88]: of the assessed commercial stocks in the NE Atlantic, 8% (Baltic Sea) to
80 % (Irish Sea) are outside safe biological limits. For the other areas in the
NE Atlantic the percentages of stocks outside safe biological limits vary
between 25% and 55%. In the Mediterranean the percentage of stocks outside safe
biological limits ranges from 44% to 73%[89].
EU catches have
declined since 1993 at an average rate of 2 per cent per year. The lower productivity of EU stocks means that fishing is
becoming an increasingly costly enterprise. The amount of effort and fuel
needed to land one tonne of fish is higher than it needs to be, and higher than
it would be if stocks were at a sustainable level. It is estimated that UK
trawlers invest 17 times more effort than they did 118 years ago to land an
equivalent catch[90]. Fishery discard practices constitute a
waste of valuable living resources, which plays an important role in the
depletion of marine populations. Based on Eurostat data, it can be estimated
that in European fisheries 1.7 million tonnes of all species are discarded
annually, corresponding to 23% of total catches. On a global level, the
United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) reports that around 28
per cent of stocks are overexploited or depleted, with another 52 per cent
fully exploited[91].
Around the world 27 per cent of fisheries were judged to have collapsed by
2003, meaning that their annual harvests had fallen to less than 90 per cent of
their historical maximum yields[92]. (b)
Increasing reliance on imports The EU is one of the world’s top three importers of fishery and
aquaculture products, importing US$23 billion worth of fish and fisheries
products in 2007[93].
Imports account for around 60 to 70 per cent of the EU’s consumption of fish.[94] The
EU is increasingly reliant on imports, as domestic production is falling, and has
reduced its self-sufficiency for fish by 12 per cent compared to the year 2000[95]. (c)
Under-exploitation of other marine resources Beyond fisheries and
marine ecosystems, the oceans hold a host of valuable resources. Sand and
gravel, oil and gas have been extracted from the sea for many years. In
addition, minerals transported by erosion are mined from the shallow shelf and
beach areas. These are increasingly attractive economically to exploit. Until now, the
expansion of renewable energies, such as wind and solar power, has mainly taken
place onshore. However, now the production of environmentally friendly energy
from the oceans is being promoted worldwide: it is hoped that wind, waves and
ocean currents will meet a substantial share of the world’s electricity needs. Experts
estimate that offshore wind power could in future supply about 5000
terawatt-hours (TWh) of electricity a year worldwide – approximately a third of
the world’s current annual electricity consumption. Offshore wind energy plants
(WEPs) in Europe alone should supply about 340 terawatt-hours a year by 2015[96]. Marine Biotechnology,
which involves marine bioresources, either as the source or the target of
biotechnology applications, is also becoming an important component of the
global biotechnology sector. (d)
Pollution Challenges posed by pollution and climate
change (e.g. acidification), are threatening marine resources. For example,
over 1 million birds and 100,000 marine mammals and sea turtles die each year
as a result of plastic waste[97].
Factors such as marine litter and urban waste water treatment seriously
aggravate pollution in some seas around Europe. Nearly
1 in 10 fish collected in the Pacific Ocean during a recent study contained plastic debris, as one sign of the significant
amount of plastic entering the global food chain[98]. (e)
Inertia in policy and decision making Management of EU fishing, whilst generally
supported, is seen as threatening fishing communities. This can slow down or
block reform, for example, of subsidies, as there are concerns over the
concentrated impact of changes in local communities that do not have easy
access to other jobs. The difficulties of managing EU fish stocks
in a sustainable way indicate the size of the challenge for the global fish
stocks that the EU increasingly relies on, and which are a significant source
of income and food for coastal communities in many developing countries.
2.7.3.
Actions
The reform of the Common Fisheries Policy
to eliminate all fisheries subsidies which do not improve the sustainable management
of marine resources would help align economic incentives with sustainable
fishing. Greater use of consumer sustainability labelling, and the use of
sustainably caught fish by food producers could also create greater rewards for
sustainable fishing, providing incentives for stock management. The creation of
more protected marine areas can provide the biodiversity needed for strong
sustainable fish stocks. Good implementation of the Marine Strategy
Framework Directive by Member States through policy measures on management and
planning as well as support for knowledge and demonstration projects would safeguard
natural coastal and marine capital. Member States can promote eco-system based
strategies and integration of climate risk into maritime activities, whilst
collaboration between Member States bring measures that tackle marine litter.
3.
Key Sectors
Much of the potential for resource
efficiency comes from interactions through the value chains that links
consumers to raw materials, which are best addressed through a focus on key
sectors of the economy. Analysis by EIPRO[99]
identified food, mobility and consumption as the final services that are
responsible for 70 to 80 per cent of environmental impacts.
3.1.
Addressing food
3.1.1.
Significance
The food and drink
industry has a turnover of €917bn[100]. It employs more than 4 million people in around 310 000
companies. Judged by consumer expenditure, purchases of
food and catering services are the most important items for consumers[101]. The EU's production
and consumption of food and drink has global resource implications through
trade. In 2007, trade in both raw and processed agricultural products accounted
for approximately 6% of total EU trade with non-EU countries[102]. It is dependent on the
resources which are subject to the greatest risks. For its inputs it is
dependent on natural systems (including clean water, fertile soil, ecosystem
services from biodiversity), petrochemicals and other mineral inputs (eg.
phosphates). Problems with these resources can send ripples through global
markets that have particularly high impacts on people in developing countries
and lower income groups. It is also one of the
largest contributors to unsustainable use of natural resources, in the EU and
in our global footprint. The relationship between consumption and food and
drink and resource use and depletion is described in the Figure below, looking
along the life-cycle. Resource depletion includes eutrophication, habitat
change, climate change, water use, soil erosion and pollution[103]. The size of these impacts is on an
upward trend. Along the whole life-cycle, consumption of food and drink in the
EU causes 18% of the EU's material use[104]. Estimates of impacts on
environmental resources vary, but are consistently high: ·
One estimate is that around half of all
environmental impacts are attributable to food and drink[105]. This includes 18% of our greenhouse gas emissions[106] or approximately 2 tonnes CO2- equivalents
of greenhouse gases per capita. (equivalent to the quantity which Europeans
will need to budget for all their activities in the long term if we are
to meet the European Commission’s 2050 target of an 80% reduction in GHGs)[107]. ·
According to a study by the European Topic
Center[108] some 15-30% of all key environmental pressures can be allocated to eating & drinking. EU consumption has impacts elsewhere,
through the global markets. For example, EU meat production, which equals about
15-18 % of global meat production and which is almost exclusively consumed
within EU, requires large amounts of high quality protein feed. With only a
minor domestic production, the major share of this feed is based on soybeans
and soybean cake which imported from countries like Brazil and the United
States. The imported amount corresponds to an area of more than 20 million ha
of cropland and shows how European consumption patterns contribute to land use
change elsewhere[109]. Globally, agricultural production accounts
for 70% of global freshwater consumption, 38% of the total land use, and 14% of
the world’s greenhouse gas emissions[110]. The fossil
energy embedded in food is significant.
3.1.2.
Opportunities for Resource Efficiency
The value brought by food and drink can be
realised with lower resource inputs and resource depletion if steps are taken
along the value chain on: food waste, food choices,
production techniques and phosphorous management. Food Waste According to FAO
figures, roughly one-third of food produced for human consumption is lost or
wasted globally, which amounts to about 1.3 billion tons per year[111]. Annual food waste generation in the EU-27 is
approximately 89 million tonnes representing 179 kg per capita[112]. Reductions in the
wastage of food can allow the EU economy to meet citizens' desires for food and
drink with significantly fewer inputs. These cost savings for producers and
manufacturers could either boost their profits or be passed on to consumers.
Reduction in food waste would also cut the resource impacts of unnecessary
production and costs of collection, treatment and elimination of waste food. To
illustrate the scale of potential benefits - food waste represents about 3% of
the GHG emissions of the EU-27, i.e. 170 Mt CO2 eq./year, in which households
contribute 45%. Food waste occurs at different stages of
the supply chain, not only during final consumption. It is affected by interactions
along the supply chain – for example, contractual relations, timings of
delivery, or labelling by retailers. Policy actions that promote interactions
in the supply chain to reduce food waste can manage resources more efficiently[113]. Catering and retail sectors, responsible for part of food waste
(14% and 5% respectively) could often avoid this wastage relatively easily. Considerable improvements can be achieved
through prompting behavioural change for all the
actors of the food chain. A study carried out
in the UK[114] shows
that 60% of the food wasted by households could be avoided, saving more than
€500 per year per household. Significant benefits could
come from small, smart changes many of which can be realised at low costs
through awareness and nudges to behavioural change. For instance, the UKstudy
found out that poor comprehension of date labelling, notably the difference
between "use-by" and "best before" dates, is responsible
for about 20% of the avoidable food waste. The UN has pointed to a target of reducing
avoidable food waste by half by 2020[115]. Food Choices People's selection of the food and drink
they consume has a significant effect on resource use. Different products have
considerably different impacts on resources. In particular, consuming animal
products has much higher impacts than a similar nutritional level of plant based
products. Diets that are high in meat, eggs, milk and cheese has a relatively
large life-cycle impact on resources. The selection of fish also impacts on
sustainability of fish stocks. The greater impacts of animal products come
from: ·
Land degradation: The production of 1
kilogram of meat requires several kilograms of vegetable products, depending on
the livestock product. As a result, the livestock sector accounts for 70
percent of all agricultural land and 30 percent of the land surface of the
planet[116]. This magnifies agricultural impacts. In addition, the livestock
sector may be the leading player in the reduction of global biodiversity through
its demand on land, for example, as the major driver of deforestation, as well
as of climate change. Its resource demand also leads to overfishing,
sedimentation of coastal areas and facilitation of invasions by alien species[117]. In Europe, pastures are a location of diverse long-established
types of ecosystem, many of which are now threatened by pasture abandonment or
intensification[118]. ·
Greenhouse Gas emissions: The livestock
sector contributes 18 percent of greenhouse gas emissions measured in CO2
equivalent looking at life-cycle impacts[119]. ·
Higher Water Footprint: The livestock
sector accounts for over 8 percent of global human water use, mostly for the
irrigation of feedcrops. It is probably the largest sectoral source of water
pollution, contributing to eutrophication, “dead” zones in coastal areas,
degradation of coral reefs, human health problems, emergence of antibiotic
resistance[120]. ·
The consumption of meat and dairy products
contributes on average 24% of the global environmental impacts from the total
final consumption in EU-27[121]. The Figure presents the percentage
contribution of meat and dairy products to the environmental impacts of EU-27
total consumption. However, given current levels of
environmental impact from animal products, these consumption levels are not
sustainable in the face of global trends. Growing global populations, with
increasing dietary intakes and changing food preferences, are rapidly
increasing demand for livestock products. Production of meat and milk is
projected to more than double from 1999/01 to 2050. These consumption trends
are not sustainable. In the EU animal product consumption are
increasing, as incomes grow although EU citizens consume more meat than
necessary from a health point of view (in 2007 the average protein consumption
in the EU-27 (FAO 2010) was 70% more than WHO standards[122] [123]). Having widespread incentives to healthier and
more sustainable food production and consumption by 2020 would drive a 20%
reduction in the food chain's resource inputs. Production
Techniques The same food and drink can be produced
using different methods, using more or less resources, during agricultural
production, manufacturing processes or as waste treatment. The selection of
agricultural impacts can be significantly influenced by the market – through
consumer preferences either acting directly or through influencing intermediary
buyers (e.g. wholesalers and retailers). Co-operation along the value chain can
bring innovation in farming practices that otherwise wouldn't take place,
through the diffusion of information and provision of incentives. These market
incentives can be supported by development of a
methodology for sustainability criteria for key food commodities, which
increases information along the value chain. In the EU, the Common Agriculture Policy
has a very significant effect on choices and value chain impacts. Ensuring that
agricultural production in the EU lowers environmental resource impacts may
sometimes conflict with the other objectives (such as increasing production). The
reform Communication of December 2010 sets out the potential for environmental
improvements in a number of areas, notably in terms of water consumption and
pollution, soil and habitat conservation, preservation of ecosystem services. Changes
made under the new Multiannual Financial Framework should help improve
agricultural production. Changes in the EU are also only part of the
issue, given the impacts on global agriculture and land use. Working to shape
incentives along value chains can reach beyond the EU. Phosphorus
Management Phosphorus is one of the essential
nutrients for plants. There are also numerous animal illnesses associated with
inadequate phosphorus intake, including milk fever in high yielding cows. Between
120 and 170 million tonnes of phosphate rock are used every year. Nearly 90
% of phosphorus use is in agriculture, mainly as fertilizers[124]. There are two major opportunities from
efficiency gains in phosphorus use: ·
Reducing risks from security of supply - most
of the world's current known and accessible phosphate resource is under
Moroccan control in the Western Sahara. Two thirds of the current mining comes
from 3 countries (Morocco, China and the US). There are additional known
resources in areas with difficult access (e.g. Alaska, Amazon forest)[125]. There has been some evidence of recent
short term scarcity – very high capacity utilisation rates in existing
facilities, price spikes etc. In 2007–2008, phosphate rock and fertilizer
demand exceeded supply and prices increased by 700% in a 14-month period[126]. Against this, the demand for phosphorus is
predicted to increase by 50–100% by 2050. ·
Reducing pollution of soils and water - Phosphorus
is, along with nitrogen, a major contributor to eutrophication due to over use
leading to runoff from agricultural land. Also, as cheap and cleaner resources
of phosphate rock are used up, dirtier sources with higher cadmium contents
will be accessed, which will risk cadmium pollution of soils. Globally, we are mining five times the
amount of phosphorus that humans are actually consuming in food, showing scope
for efficiency gains. Estimates suggest that through
resource efficiency, global fertilizer phosphorus use from primary sources can
be reduced by 18%, compared to currently envisaged policies. Total global
phosphorus demand could reduce an additional 8% by banning its use in
detergents[127]. There is no single
‘quick fix’ solution to phosphorus issues, but there are a number of
technologies and policy options that exist today at various stages of
development that together could make a significant difference and deliver other environmental co-benefits on water quality. These
include more efficient use of P-fertilizers and manure in agriculture.
3.2.
Improving buildings
3.2.1.
Significance
By improving
resource efficiency in constructing and use of infrastructure and buildings,
the EU can influence 42%[128] of its final energy consumption, about 35% of its greenhouse gas
emissions and more than 50% of all extracted materials, and save up to 30%
water. Economically, construction is one of
Europe’s largest industrial sectors, with an annual turnover exceeding 1200
billion Euros, and activities that account for 10.4% of the EU GDP. 7.2% of the
EU workforce is directly in the building and construction sector[129]. The aggregated impacts of housing and
infrastructure account for around 15-30% of all environmental pressures of
European consumption. Housing and infrastructure contributes approximately 2.5
tonnes of CO2 equivalent of greenhouse gasses per capita per year. 40% of these
GHG emissions are directly associated with heating and hot water for private
households. The construction of buildings and other infrastructures contributes
another 30% of the total emissions[130]. The resources used along the value chain of
construction are shown in the figure below.
3.2.2.
Opportunities for Resource Efficiency
If buildings and infrastructure are renovated
and constructed to high resource efficiency standard, then the resource impacts
could be significantly reduced. The economic value of the resource savings over
the life-time of the building can be captured by the construction sector, with
increased demand and greater value added. Improvements in buildings
(particularly energy efficiency) have a very large potential for cost savings
with simultaneous reductions of fossil fuel use and greenhouse gas emissions[131], estimated at around 40% cost-effective savings to 2020. Whilst the sector has been hard hit in some
Member States during the financial crisis, this could provide an opportunity
for re-orientation of construction: for example, the Commission estimates that
2 million jobs could be created in renovation of existing building stock. These
opportunities exist because the building sector has particular characteristics which
act as barriers to greater resource efficiency: ·
Buildings are one of the most long-lived
products, meaning that decisions made now lock-in consumption patterns (e.g. of
energy) for decades to come, with adjustment of the initial choices carrying
additional costs. ·
Consumers and investors frequently discount
future pay-offs from investment choices, and focus on the short-term, sometimes
because of uncertainty of future returns. This means that investments in
efficiency with positive net benefits do not get made. ·
Blocks to the flow of information between
constructors, sellers or buyers/renter prevent the market from delivering
investments in efficiency and uptake of available innovation. For consumers,
housing choices are rarely taken, and knowledge about the relative performance
of buildings or components are low. ·
In renovation, consumers frequently rely on the
advice of professionals. However, the building sector is characterised by SMEs,
many of whom do not have the resource to innovate and keep up with innovation.
99.9% of construction enterprises are SMEs, 92% have less than 10 employees[132]. Both in construction and renovation this slows the adoption of new
technologies and processes[133]. ·
Investments in efficiency are also hindered by
the principal-agent problem. In rented buildings, often investment in
efficiency measures must be done by landlords, who cannot recover savings from
tenants, and vice versa. Data from the UK found that 31% of owner-occupied dwellings
were in the top efficiency quartile, only 8% of dwellings with private tenants
indicate a similar performance[134]. Significant improvements in resource and
energy use are possible during construction and demolition, through use of
existing techniques, and greater investment and diffusion of innovation. For
example, changes delivering water are estimated to be able to deliver savings
of a potential greenhouse gas emission saving of 1% of the EU's total. Whilst, research
and development is taking place into new forms of concrete, which can deliver
the same or improved properties with greatly reduced life-cycle greenhouse gas
impacts. Policy already
points the way to some improvements, with, for example, all new and renovated
buildings to be nearly zero-energy[135], the
existing building stock to be refurbished[136] at a
rate of 2% per year; and 70% of non-hazardous construction and demolition waste
will be recycled[137]. Further policy
measures can reach more SMEs, by using market signals as a driver for
innovation. This would require a life-cycle approach to be widely applied. Such
demand facilitates increased investment in innovation by building firms (if
other blocks are removed). For instance: ·
Creating increased market demand for more
efficient ‘greener’ buildings. This can be done through public procurement, in
particular through the uptake of life-cycle costing methodologies by public
procurers that take better account of future running and maintenance costs. ·
The convergence of building codes across the EU
(where appropriate) can increase the market rewards for innovation, both in
products and process. ·
Similarly, ensuring market prices of building
materials and energy reflect their real costs, relative to labour, will act as
a stimulus to innovation. A shifting of taxation from labour as part of this
realignment would be likely to increase employment. An important part
of stimulating demand is freeing up financing for more resource-efficient new
buildings and renovation of existing buildings. This can be helped by the
formation of financial vehicles that increase the awareness of steady returns
from resource savings in buildings. Best practice from
Member States indicates that bringing together firms and policy makers across
the value chain of construction, will facilitate change in practices and
technology that is otherwise locked in to existing patterns[138]. This can be supported by increasing the availability of
information on the resource efficiency of building components and alternative
construction processes. Increasing
investment, both at EU and Member State and regional level, in training in the
skills needed for creation and renovation of more resource efficient buildings,
would remove current skills gaps and so lower costs. Facilitating growth of innovations in the
use of ‘green infrastructures’, as part of integrated spatial planning,
increases the performance of buildings, infrastructure and urban environments.
For example, the use of green roofs has been shown to reduce temperatures in
cities. Measures to increasing awareness, skills and acceptance would reduce
barriers to diffusion of these techniques.
3.3.
Ensuring efficient mobility
3.3.1.
Significance
A modern, resource
efficient mobility system, serving both passengers and freight can contribute
to competitiveness and sustainability through reduced resource dependency, and
reduced impacts from pollution, land use, and noise on climate change,
biodiversity and ecosystems, health and safety. Increasing efficiency in the
transport sector by 2020 could deliver greater value with significantly reduced
needs for resources like raw materials, energy, land use, and impacts such as
climate change, air pollution, noise, accidents, and ecosystem degradation. The Figure below shows
the relationship between resource depletion and transport. Exploitation of these synergies can offer
additional routes to the achievement of goals given the extent of resource
efficiency and decarbonisation needed by 2050. These interactions appear likely
to reduce costs of achievement of those goals, compared to existing scenarios.
3.3.2.
Opportunities from Resource Efficiency
The Transport White Paper[139] aims to increase mobility, dramatically reduce
Europe's dependence on imported oil and cut carbon emissions in transport by
60% by 2050. This involves moving to more resource efficient transport system
in Europe, notably: ·
Developing and deploying new and sustainable
fuels and propulsion systems, for example, halving the use of ‘conventionally-fuelled’
cars in urban transport by 2030; phasing them out in cities by 2050 and
achieving essentially CO2-free city logistics
in major urban centres by 2030[140]. ·
Optimising the performance of multimodal
logistic chains, including by making greater use of more energy-efficient modes. ·
Increasing the efficiency of transport and of
infrastructure use with information systems and market-based incentives,
including: (a) the deployment of the modernised air traffic management
infrastructure (SESAR12) in Europe by 2020 deployment of equivalent land and
water transport management systems and (b) moving towards full application of
“user pays” and “polluter pays” principles. The Commission will seek to ensure
that the initiatives under the Transport White Paper are implemented
consistently with resource efficiency objectives including by moving towards
particular through internalisation of external costs. The OECD points to the complexity of this
area, particularly the indirect effects as a cause for low levels of integration.
This also leads to difficulties of modelling the complex interactions between
all the aspects of the economy, which also has a tendency to exclude
examination of these aspects within model-driven climate, energy and transport
policy. Whether synergies are fully realised
depends on the extent of integration and policy co-ordination, at EU, Member
State, value chain and company level. The structures for co-ordination,
information flow and governance contained in this Roadmap should facilitate
this integration.
4.
Application of Governance to Other Key Areas
4.1.
Investing in the transition
UNEP estimates that the
annual financing needs for making the world economy more resource efficient are
between US$1.05-2.59 trillion - around 10% of annual global capital investment[141]. In the EU, and elsewhere, this financing will
need to come mainly from private sources[142]. This will require a combination of well-designed policies
creating the right market conditions and an evolution of the perspectives on
opportunities held by private investors. The startling growth of
global financing for clean energy shows how this shift in mindset is possible.
In 2010, annual clean energy investment exceeded investment in traditional
energy sources for the first time, exceeding US$230bn. These flows are still
small compared to the volumes required, but show how the right policy mix (for
example emissions trading) can stimulate change. For the investments in the
medium term transition, greater flows of assets will be needed from public and private
institutions that can invest in the long term, whose liabilities are not due
for short-term payment, including pension funds, development banks, sovereign
wealth funds and insurance funds. These institutions are
increasingly seeing the advantages of investments that reduce future
environmental, social and governance risks and moving some of their assets into
portfolios that deliver these profiles. One key element of successful
mobilisation of finance is the development of comparable measures of corporate
resource efficiency and exposure to resource scarcity to assist institutions.
Regulation of investments and accounting may, in some cases, need to be changed
to facilitate greater long-term market investment. Yet, for the level of
financing necessary, the current financial systems bias towards the short-term
would have to be reversed. Investment in the infrastructure needed for
transition can offer the long-term yields with weak correlation to other
economic sectors that could form greater shares of the portfolio of e.g.
pension funds (who currently, in most countries, invest 1% in infrastructure)[143]. The Commission estimates annual EU investment
needs for a move to a low-carbon economy to be around €200 billion over the
longer-term, with both the building/infrastructure/construction and the
transport sector comparatively accounting for the highest investment needs[144]. Eco-innovation
needs also to be supported, in particular as lots of SMEs are active in this
field. A faster pace of eco-innovation and market penetration is hampered by
the lack of risk finance and support for demonstration. Support is needed for
the development of innovative solutions and new technologies, for testing, but
also for entering these technologies in implementation and use phases. Finance for
resource-efficient product innovation and investment in efficiency savings
should become available on equal or better terms than comparable investments.
SMEs in particular need to have better access to finance for resource-efficient
innovation. Public funding has an important role in
assisting SMEs, particularly as market signals are not fully aligned with
resource efficiency. However, access to private funds is essential for the
scale of investment. The combination of public and private action needed to
open up private investment opportunities in resource efficiency can be
identified by suitably focussed discussions between policy makers and
financiers. A Resource Efficiency Finance Round Table,
including representatives from private and institutional banks (such as the
EIB, EBRD), insurance companies and venture capital companies may serve this
purpose and to identify opportunities to develop adapted finance for resource-efficiency.
4.2.
Supporting resource efficiency internationally
The EU is affected by
global resource scarcity through economic and environmental interactions. It
also has significant direct and indirect effects on global resources through
its consumption (and the drivers that provides for global resource use), its
wastes, its pollution, the activities of EU firms overseas and its
international policy interactions. In a globalised
economy, a more globalised view of products and markets is increasingly necessary.
Recent model calculations, quoted by the UN’s International Resource Panel
suggest that CO2 emissions embedded in internationally traded products
accounted for 27% of global energy-related CO2 emissions in 2005, up from 22%
ten years earlier. In addition, unsustainable
resource use also leads to security risks as the competition for scarce
resources becomes more intense. Water, food and soils are essential for basic
subsistence and poverty eradication, with evident links to EU development
goals. The use of
international policy tools is one of the key routes to influence resource use
outside the EU that matters for EU objectives. This complements the EU's impact
through supply chains and leadership in innovation (in technology, policy and
consumption behaviours). The EU has a window of opportunity to take the lead in
a number of areas, by leading by example in environmental performance and
know-how, and by promoting a level playing field among competitors for
resources. A number of EU environmental policies and standards are already being
taken up around the world: electrical/electronic waste and hazardous substances
(e.g. China WEEE, China RoHs, Brazil RoHs). A number of countries
are re-orientating their policies towards resource efficiency; the United
States, China, Korea and some developing countries. The EU can learn from this
experience and help influence their path. As developing countries grow
economically, they have to address a range of resource management issues (e.g.
better waste and water management) and can learn from European know-how in
design and implementation of policy. There are a wide range of actions open to the EU,
including: direct support to and joint initiatives; strengthening the
implementation of existing agreements; using our own consumer power and trade
agreements to influence global consumption and production patterns; using
development aid; cooperating in research and innovation; and working towards
stronger multilateral mechanisms for a global governance of public goods.
Progress in other countries’ resource efficiency in partner countries will not
only enable them to develop sustainably, but will also in turn make it easier
for the EU to reduce its own global footprint. If resource efficiency could become a shared objective of
the international community, it could form the basis of co-operation in many
different fields, including development, trade and technology co-operation. The EU can make
increasing resource efficiency in global supply chains a key part of the EU’s
approach to the Rio+20 Summit in June 2012, where business and global
governments can set goals and pathways to international efficiency providing
strong market signals and tackling international barriers. The Commission has
proposed a wide range of actions, including new international initiatives on
agriculture, land use, forests, chemicals and marine resources, helping
mobilise private and public financing and investment, as well as help with
progress towards a more effective global, multilateral governance system[145]. To bring this
about resource efficiency considerations would need to be more systematically
factored into our external policies.
4.3.
Removing skills bottlenecks and mitigating
social costs
The issue of skills is a key issue. A key factor affecting
transition costs is the number of skill shortages and the potential exclusion
from work of people with obsolete skills. Already there are some reports of
green skill bottlenecks For example, recent OECD work has confirmed that SMEs
face particular challenges in upgrading or adjusting the skills of their
workforce[146].
In order to
build a sustainable future growth, employment needs to be of high quality and
move away from precarious and low-paid working conditions. Jobs
created in sectors linked to sustainable growth are often more secure, with
high potential for exports and economic value creation The European Employment Strategy already offers range of
tools based on principle of flexicurity including anticipation, social support
to restructuring, active labour market policies (ALMP), skills provision and
social dialogue. There is a need to build on the existing range of programmes
trying to fill this gap[147]. As announced in the
‘Agenda for new skills and jobs’, the Commission will develop an EU
skills Panorama to improve transparency and mobility for jobseekers, workers,
companies and/or public institutions by providing information, in the short and
medium term, on current and future skills needs, skills supply and mismatches.
The Panorama will contain updated forecasting of skills supply and labour
market needs up to 2020. As part of this skills panorama, the green skills for
a low carbon a resource efficient economy will be analysed in detail. The Commission
will continue to support the establishment of European Sector Skills Councils.
A European Sector Council on skills for green and greener jobs could, for
example, facilitate the exchange of information between Member States on skills
profiles, training programmes and emerging skills gaps mismatches. Skills and
employment strategies can be developed for promising areas, e.g. the
construction of zero-carbon homes. Closely linked
to this, the European Social Fund is used for green skills promotion, but not
to a great extent and hardly at all in some countries. There is scope to expand
the targeting on green jobs and share best practice in this respect. The vast
majority of this support does and will need to come at Member State and
regional level. Social dialogue is an important part
of measures to anticipate skills and design and provide the right responses.
4.4.
Improving implementation of EU legislation
Poor implementation brings economic costs: the costs of
implementation gaps in relation to currently legally binding targets are
estimated at around €50 billion per year[148]. Poor
implementation also signals uncertainty, which puts business off investing in
resource efficiency. It also impacts on the single market through different
conditions in Member States which can reduce the rewards for innovation, and so
slow the pace of efficiency gains. Good implementation of EU legislation is
crucial for creating clear market signals. It helps create a single market for
innovation that is sufficiently large to encourage R&D and
commercialisation. It also prevents free-riders causing damage to resources
that others use as inputs. At present there are gaps in compliance and
implementation. Correcting these fully by 2020 would support the transition to
resource efficiency. Actions to support implementation will need
to be taken by a wide range of stakeholders working together. The Commission
has a role to play in facilitating action, though the action is ultimately for
Member States. The impacts depend on design and enforcement in implementation, where the record of Member States is
mixed, varying depending on political priority and capacity. For example,
implementation by Member States of recycling policy or the Water Framework
Directive (which calls for many measures promoting efficient use of water) has
been mixed. Annex 4:
Representative European Ecological Footprints This annex shows the 'ecological footprint'
of some EU Member States consumption (not available for all countries) plus
Switzerland – an assumption and data based assessment of the natural resources
consumed by a Member State, measured in hectares/capita[149]. Annex 5: The
rebound effect and odd price effects This
annex summarises a study by Bio Intelligence Service on the rebound effect[150]. The study provides an overview of the main findings from a review
of the literature.
1.
Definition
Although
in the literature there are many definitions of the rebound effect, in general
it can be defined as 'increases in consumption due to environmental
efficiency interventions'. These increases in consumption can occur
through: ·
behavioural effects – when a feel good perception of being 'green' encourages increased
consumption for certain products where 'greener' options are readily available. ·
price effects –
there are three types of price induced rebound effect: (1)
Direct Rebound Effect – where increased
efficiency and associated cost reduction for a product/service results in its
increased consumption because it is cheaper. (2)
Indirect Rebound Effect – where savings from
efficiency cost reductions enable more income to be spent on other products and
services. (3)
Economy wide Rebound Effect – where more
efficiency drives economic productivity overall resulting in more economic
growth and consumption at a macroeconomic level.
2.
Evidence and significance
Evidence on the existence of direct
rebound effects is robust… The existence of the rebound effect is
recognised on the basis of evidence from many credible sources including United
Nations Environment Programme, International Energy Agency, UK Dept of
Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, European Environment Agency, UK Dept for
Energy and Climate Change and the EEA State of the Environment and Outlook
Report[151]. … but the exact size is hard to
measure and extrapolate… Whilst widely accepted, the size of the
rebound effect is still a widely debated subject. The rebound effect is both
hard to measure and varies depending on the intervention (policy, technology,
practice), the type of products/services/resources investigated (energy, food,
transport, etc.), as well as other related factors e.g. income level,
productivity, price elasticity, saturation, location and time[152]. Therefore the evidence is clear that generalising the available
direct rebound effect estimates to all types of rebound effect from all types
of energy efficiency improvement is not appropriate. Even harder to measure are indirect and
economy wide rebound effects, which are difficult to define and distinguished
from other micro- and macro-economic effects[153]. ... we have a number of examples… In general, examples relate to the direct
rebound effect associated with interventions relevant to energy efficiency,
with a smaller number focusing on water, materials and waste. This is a
reflection of the status of the rebound effect topic which has been mostly
measured for energy efficiency as rather than wider resource related impacts.
Examples include: –
direct rebound effects for household energy
efficiency for space heating/ cooling, personal transport, white goods and
lighting are estimated in the range 10- 30% for developed countries[154]. –
direct rebound effects of 30-80% for fuel
efficiency in commercial road transport[155]. –
for policies to reduce the environmental impacts
of meat and dairy consumption in the EU[156] found
negative rebound effects of -10 to -100%[157]. –
for industry sectors, estimates for rebound
effects for energy efficiency in the UK are 15%[158]. –
a recent USA study investigating 30 industry
sectors shows long term direct rebound effects of 20-60% with energy intensive sectors
e.g. utilities, chemicals and agriculture having the highest effects[159].
3.
Implications for policy
The rebound effect can lead us to
miss targets Understanding the size of the reduction in
anticipated environmental savings from the rebound effect is important when
developing policy as it affects the environmental effectiveness. Rebound
effects can be assessed e.g. in Regulatory Impact Assessment (RIA) though, to
date, only the UK government has accounted for ‘take back’ in energy savings in
its policy evaluation. This could relatively easily be done in the short term
for specific policies where direct rebound effects are known to occur e.g.
energy efficiency interventions for energy services, transport, household
heating/cooling heating, appliances and lighting. It could also be considered
in the evaluation and performance monitoring of policy. Need a
policy mix to respond to rebound effects Where the rebound effect is significant, it
is clear that efficiency measures alone will not be sufficient and that other
measures will also be required[160]. The
evidence shows that a policy mix, incorporating technology, fiscal and
behavioural aspects, is best suited to addressing direct rebound effects. For
example, awareness raising through the provision of information on consumption
via SMART metering (or real time displays) gives the consumer the opportunity
to think about their consumption and then reduce it. The use of a mixture of
instruments is already found in the EU Sustainable Consumption and Production
policy, which has both demand and supply facing measures. Annex 6: Resource
efficiency indicators and targets 1. Introduction Indicators and targets are important tools
to measure and foster progress towards the vision and objectives of the
resource efficiency flagship initiative. This annex on indicators and targets
presents in more detail the approach on indicators. The section on theme and
action specific indicators is organised according to the chapters of the
Resource Efficiency Roadmap Communication and includes related targets or
milestones. It complements the already existing and agreed indicators and
targets on climate change, energy and energy efficiency. This annex presents the indicators that are
now ready for use, discusses their scope and limitations and gives information
on ongoing work to improve or develop further indicators. The targets or
milestones mentioned are in various stages of development: some are already in
place, others are presented here as a basis for further discussion and evaluation.
As a whole, further progress and development is needed to better incorporate
the monitoring of resource efficiency in policy making. 2. The
approach To orient decisions, assess state of play and
communicate progress towards the objectives of this roadmap, the Commission
will use a lead indicator, accompanied by a dashboard of complementary macro
indicators. A complementary set of theme specific indicators will be used to
measure progress towards the specific thematic objectives and actions set out
in the roadmap. 3. Lead
indicator and dashboard of complementary macro indicators 3.1. The
Lead Indicator For the near future, while recognising that
it only captures the material resources aspects of resource efficiency, the
Commission will use "Resource Productivity" (GDP/DMC[161] expressed in euro/tonne) as the lead indicator. To compensate for
the limitation in scope of DMC, the lead indicator will be complemented by a
dashboard of macro indicators on water, land and carbon. New indicators on
natural ecological capital[162] and on environmental impacts of resource use[163] will be added as soon as possible. The lead indicator and the dashboard are
closely linked and should normally be used in combination. This is because the
scope of the lead indicator does not cover all relevant natural resources, it
has a national rather than a supply chain perspective (thus not covering shifts
of material use from EU to abroad) and, furthermore, economic value, scarcity
and environmental impacts of a resource are only partially correlated to its
weight. Therefore, there might be situations in which an improvement of the
lead indicator hides some overall unfavourable development. Such a highly
aggregated indicator needs to be complemented by a small set of additional
indicators and this follows the recommendations from the Commission’s
"Beyond GDP" initiative[164] and
the work of the Stiglitz-Sen-Fitoussi-Commission[165].
Monitoring evolution of the lead indicator together with the dashboard of macro
indicators on land, water and carbon can help to disclose potential
unfavourable trends that are hidden by the Resource Productivity indicator. A
disaggregation of the material use in main categories such as biomass, fossil
energy carriers (linking with energy and energy efficiency), industrial minerals
and ores and construction minerals will also be necessary. The proposal described above is based on an
analysis of existing, readily available indicators, indicators that have been
developed and produced but are discontinued, and indicators under development
that are likely to be finalised before 2013 (see Appendix 1). The selection of
a single lead indicator has taken careful account of its quality profile,
purpose and key message. Resource Productivity indicator (GDP/DMC)
relates an important part of the resource input into the economic production
process to the output of economic activity. GDP, as a measure of monetary
values, does not cover non-market goods and services, it focuses on current
economic activities rather than on the developments in natural, social and
economic assets important from a longer term perspective, and it has no concern
for inequality. Despite all its limitations, GDP is still considered as the
best available indicator accounting for the output of economic activity. The
Commission is working under its "Beyond GDP" initiative towards a
more comprehensive measure of prosperity or wealth that might be used in the
long-term. 3.2. The
dashboard As mentioned, DMC covers only material
resources and has a national production perspective, which means that it does
not include material resources used overseas to produce our imports. Thus, it
would not register or 'indicate' if improvements of domestic resource
efficiency are made by delocalisation of resource intensive or less resource
efficient steps in the production chain to countries outside the EU. Indicators
that have a life cycle or value chain perspective are needed to trace such
potential effects. Therefore, the dashboard complementing the lead indicator
needs to comprise both perspectives. The Commission intends to use, improve or develop the following
concrete indicators: || Production / territory perspective || Consumption / global supply chain perspective Land || Artificial land or built-up area (km²) – available with restrictions in time series || Indirect land use / embodied land for agricultural and forestry products (km²) – to be developed Water || Water exploitation index[166] (WEI, %) – available with restrictions on completeness of data and regional/temporal resolution (river basin/intra-annual variations) || Water footprint – to be updated and improved or Embodied water – to be developed Carbon || GHG emissions (t) – available || Carbon footprint – estimates available from scientific sources This dashboard of indicators – in conjunction
with the lead indicator – has the advantage that it focuses on clear stocks or
flows of main resources: materials, land, water and carbon. As such it can be
easily understood, measured and communicated. 3.3. Baselines,
latest values and trends[167] Resource productivity: Resource productivity in 2007 has increased with 7.4% in comparison with 2000. However, in order to achieve
absolute decoupling of economic growth from resource use, resource productivity
needs to grow equally to or faster than GDP, which has not been the case. GDP
has grown with 16.2% over the same period while DMC has grown 7.9%. An absolute
decoupling would mean that DMC should remain constant or decrease. Land:
Artificial land has continued to expand; in the period 2000-2006 at a rate of
920 km² per year. To reach a state of no net land take by 2050 and assuming a
linear reduction from now until then, the average annual land take needs to
decease to maximum 800 km² per year in the period 2010-2020. Water: Trends
in EU average values of the water exploitation index (WEI) have been stagnating
around 13% for the past 20 years. However WEI national values vary from 64% to less than 1% and
decreases of WEI are rare. Values above 20% are considered unsustainable. GHG emissions: After an initial decline starting from the baseline in 1990, GHG
emissions were for almost stable for a decade. Recently a further decline was
observed, reaching 17.4% reduction (compared to 1990) in 2009 (the Kyoto Protocol requires the EU to
reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 8% below 1990 levels by 2008-2012). The challenge will be to keep this trend also in the period of
economic recovery as the EU target for 2020 is a 20% reduction (30% if the
conditions are right). 3.4. Further
developments An indicator on natural ecological capital
and an indicator on environmental impacts of resource use will be added as soon
as possible. Indicators on natural ecological capital are under development by
the EEA as part of their activities to set up comprehensive eco-system accounts
to complement the existing approach on environmental economic accounting. For
example, Landscape Ecosystem Potential and Ecosystem Degradation are indicators
that will be developed and evaluated for inclusion into the dashboard. Also the
life cycle based environmental impact indicators under development by the
Commission's Joint Research Centre will be considered. A further important development underway is
the integration of indirect or embodied material consumption into material flow
accounts in order to reflect the life cycle or value chain perspective. The
indicator that will come out of this improvement is Raw Material Consumption
(RMC). In contrast to DMC, but similarly to the life cycle based indicators, it
will also include the indirect effects outside the EU. In addition, the
Commission will continue working on improving indicators on: ·
Resource availability and consumption, thereby
clearly distinguishing renewable and non renewable resources; ·
Resource productivity, including sustainable
management patterns; ·
Policy instruments, such as environmental taxes
or Green Public Procurement; ·
Benefits of resource efficiency along the
production chain, such as innovation and green jobs; all above listed aspects measured
appropriately at: ·
industry, ·
product, ·
national and European level. 4. Theme
specific indicators This section presents specific thematic
indicators – and where appropriate also milestones and existing targets – that
the Commission intends to use to define existing or potential levels of
ambition and to assess the state of play, the progress towards objectives and
the implementation of actions of the Resource Efficiency Roadmap. The presented
indicators, targets and milestones are related to both 'objectives' and
'actions' from the Roadmap, depending on availability of data or
"measurability". For each indicator a short rationale is
given, including information on any other indicators that have been considered
but rejected. This annex presents the best indicators currently available, some
of which are still under development. For some parts no good indicators exists;
they still need to be developed and produced. As new or improved indicators,
besides the ones suggested, become available, they will be used to replace or
complement those laid out below. As such this will be a continuous process of
improvement. These new and improved indicators could also be used in
iGrowGreen, since there are strong synergies between indicators, areas and
domains covered by iGrowGreen and the indicators considered below. 4.1. Transforming
the economy 4.1.1. Improving
products and changing consumption patterns 4.1.1.1 Supporting
Green Public Procurement (GPP) The Commission will consider developing the following indicators in
2012: ·
Proposed indicator: –
Percentage of the value, and number, of public
procurement contracts that include GPP criteria. ·
A milestone or target will be considered. Rationale Public authorities are major consumers in
Europe with a large purchasing power: they spend annually the equivalent of
around 17% of the EU’s GDP. By greening their purchases, they can make an
important contribution to environmental protection, energy and resource
efficiency, the fight against climate change and the development of
eco-innovation industries. This contributes to achieving a critical mass for
producing and consuming green products and services (products with a low
environmental impact over the life-cycle). A higher uptake of GPP therefore
indicates an overall improvement in resource efficiency. 4.1.1.2 Promoting
green buying The Commission will consider developing the indicators on green
products (products with a low environmental impact over the life-cycle) bought
by households, or on the output of green products by 2012. This includes also
further clarification of the definition of 'green products'. ·
Proposed indicator: –
Number and value of green products purchased by
households; –
Alternatively: output or share of green products
in total output; –
A milestone or target will be considered. Rationale Households in Europe are major contributors
to environmental problems such as climate change, air pollution, water
pollution, land use and waste. The proportion (number and value) of green
products bought by households is an indicator not only of the change in
environmental performance of products on the market, but also in attitudes
towards resource efficiency. Based on work on environmental footprint of
products, products sold in the EU market should communicate their environmental
impact to final consumers. 4.1.2 Boosting
efficient production 4.1.2.1. Measuring,
managing and improving European companies' resource efficiency The Commission will consider developing the following indicators in
2012: ·
Proposed indicators: –
Proportion of companies using environmental
footprint, by sector and size class, within priority sectors, for: ·
measuring, ·
managing, ·
meeting benchmarks, –
Number of companies, by sector and size class,
benefiting from advisory assistance from Member States or regional government
on improving their environmental performance. ·
A milestone or target will be considered for the
share of companies within the priority sectors, which measure their
environmental footprint, to be achieved by 2020. Rationale Based on work on corporate environmental
footprint, and to help European companies become more resource efficient and
lower their environmental impacts, companies need to measure and monitor their
performance (based on an harmonised 'environmental footprint' methodology), and
to improve it against agreed benchmarks. In the long-term and to reduce
significantly their environmental impacts, all companies should measure and
improve the environmental footprint of their operations. In order to set
benchmarks and start trends, by 2020 most of the companies in sectors where
environmental impacts are the highest, should do so. Assistance is essential
especially for SMEs in taking the first steps in managing resource efficiency
aspects of their operations. The availability of such services is uneven across
the EU. The indicator would show progress on this issue. 4.1.2.2. Phasing
out the most harmful chemicals ·
Proposed indicators: –
Number of known 'substances of very high
concern' (SVHC) included on the REACH Candidate list. ·
Targets and milestones: –
Currently there are 53 SVHCs on the REACH
Candidate List. The aim is to have 136 on the Candidate list by 2012 (existing
target), and to include all relevant SVHC by 2020. Rationale REACH has a number of mechanisms (notably,
authorisation/restriction) for dealing with substances of very high concern
(SVHC.) These are substances that are for example carcinogenic, mutagenic or
toxic for reproduction (CMRs) or persistent, bio accumulative and toxic (PBTs).
Substances that are subject to authorisation may not be used in the EU, unless
a company (and their registered users) have been authorised to do so. This will
mean that eventually these substances are phased out of all non-essential uses.
In other words, the more SVHC substances there are under REACH, the higher
control is of their use. Our aim is to achieve the '2020 Chemical Goal' of the
World Summit on Sustainable Development (WSSD). This commitment aims, by 2020,
to use and produce chemicals in ways that do not lead to significant adverse
effects on human health and the environment. REACH generates pressure to substitute
hazardous chemicals of very high concern leading to a reduction in the number
of CMRs and Endocrine Disruptors in the environment. 4.1.3. Turning
waste into a resource 4.1.3.1. Ensuring
full implementation of waste legislation, in line with the waste hierarchy ·
Proposed indicators: –
Total waste generation; –
Overall recycling rate; –
Landfill rate; –
Proportion of secondary raw material used in the
EU economy compared to primary raw material (to be developed based on existing
information). ·
Targets and milestones: –
Waste prevention – a milestone or target will be
considered for the reduction of waste generated by 2020; –
Reuse and recycling – the existing targets of
50% of reuse/recycling of municipal waste and 70% of reuse/recycling/recovery
of construction and demolition waste by 2020 will be reviewed and potentially
raised to their maximum feasible level. New targets for other waste streams
will likely be proposed in 2014; –
Existing landfill diversion target for
biodegradable waste will be reviewed and new targets for other waste streams
will likely be proposed in 2014. Rationale Increasing waste prevention and
re-use/recycling in line with the principles of the 'waste hierarchy' will
contribute directly to improving resource and material efficiency. First,
overall waste generation will be monitored, with a view to progressively
decouple it from economic growth as well as to reduce the absolute quantities
generated. Member States have to draw up waste prevention programmes by 2013
according to the revised Waste Framework Directive, and the experience from the
most advanced Member States has shown that a reduction target of 7% in 7 years
is achievable, although there are still considerable differences between the
waste management performances between Member States. Second, to secure access
to raw materials in the EU, to create new job opportunities and to ensure a
sustainable management of materials, the recycling/reuse targets should be
reviewed and driven to their maximum feasible levels when they are reviewed in
2014, further to an Impact Assessment. The proposed indicators, for example on
overall recycling rate, can be segmented by stream and material type, if
needed. The landfill diversion rates, notably for biodegradable waste, should
be reviewed accordingly to progressively and drastically limit land-filling to
non-recoverable/compostable waste and energy recovery to not
recyclable/compostable waste. 4.1.4. Supporting
research and innovation 4.1.4.1. Increasing
investment in research and innovation on resource efficiency ·
Proposed indicator: –
Number and value of funding (€/year) of research
and innovation projects promoting mainly resource efficiency and sustainable
environmental management, allocated through European financial support
programmes. ·
Milestone: –
A milestone or target has not been set yet. The
aim is to significantly increase funding compared to the sum of (1) funding for
environmental research under FP7 (environment theme), and (2) funding for
research in all other themes of FP7 contributing to the environmental knowledge
base (which is approximately on the order of 5 times the environment theme in
terms of funding). Rationale To
mobilize innovation policy to be more resource efficient, we need to provide
sufficient, targeted funding for relevant research and innovation projects. The
amount of financial support for such projects would be a good indicator,
together with the indicator of the number of such projects supported. However,
investments in research and innovation from the private sector are evenly
important. Related data and indicators are difficult to be set up, but will be
considered as well. 4.1.5. Phasing
out inefficient subsidies 4.1.4.1. Phasing
out Environmentally Harmful Subsidies (EHS) ·
Proposed indicators: –
Annual value of all EHS provided (to be
developed); –
The value of EHS removed measured by last year's
or last years' average annual spending, including tax exemptions where
appropriate. ·
Milestone: –
EHS phased out completely by 2020. Rationale EHS have a negative impact on the levels of
waste, emissions, resource extraction and biodiversity. As such, they prevent
the economy from shifting to greater productivity. The key action is to remove
all EHS, although replacing the social benefits of EHS can sometimes be
challenging. The indicators should measure the value of EHS actually phased
out, as well as the value of EHS still provided (and their share of total
subsidies). A good proxy for the value is the previous year's total spending including tax exemptions where appropriate
on EHS. The decrease in annual spending would represent the amount the public
budget and consumers are directly saving in a given year. It will include both
on-budget and off-budget subsidies (such as tax exemptions) as appropriate.
This indicator should be complemented by a broader indicator on the annual
value of EHS provided which requires to find
objective, statistical criteria to distinguish EHS from non-harmful subsidies
and standardization of different EHS methodologies. 4.1.6. Getting
the prices right 4.1.6.1. Increasing
the share of environmental taxation ·
Proposed indicators: –
Environmental taxes as share of total taxes and
social contributions; –
Total value of environmental taxes paid. ·
Milestone: –
By 2020 the share of environmental taxation in
public revenues will have been increased to an EU average of more than 10%. Rationale Getting the prices of resources right will
create incentives to use them more efficiently and sustainably. These
indicators will provide information about the value of public revenue brought
in by environmental taxes and show their relative weight in the tax system,
thereby showing if the objective of shifting taxation from labour or capital to
environment and resources is being met. The milestone suggests putting the EU
average in line with what is now the level in the best performing
Member States. Note: The indicator 'environmental taxes as
share of GDP' is not suitable to answer this question, as it measures the share
of environmental taxes compared to total economic activity, not in relation to
total taxation. Comparing environmental tax to GDP provides insights into the
tax burden on products damaging the environment, rather than insights into
assessing whether "green" taxes account for an increasing share of
the tax burden. 4.2. Natural
capital and ecosystem services 4.2.1. Ecosystem
services 4.2.3.1. Mapping
and assessing the state and value of ecosystems and their services ·
Proposed indicators: –
Based on the EU 2010 Biodiversity Baseline,
measurable milestones and indicators will be developed within the EU
Biodiversity Strategy to 2020. They will be available by mid 2012. ·
Milestones: –
Map and assess the state of ecosystems and their
services in Member States territory by 2014. –
Assess the economic value of such services, and
integrate these values into accounting and reporting systems at EU and national
level by 2020. Rationale The benefits from ecosystem services or the
costs imposed by their loss are usually not accounted for in the decision
making process. As a result, degradation of these services and depletion of
natural capital continue unnoticed. Mapping and assessing the state of
ecosystems and their services is necessary to establish a baseline and to
develop a prioritisation framework for protection, restoration and sustainable
management. These milestones have been defined in the EU Biodiversity Strategy
to 2020. 4.2.3.2. Maintaining
and enhancing ecosystems and their services ·
Proposed indicators: –
Based on the EU 2010 Biodiversity Baseline,
measurable milestones and indicators will be developed within the EU Biodiversity
Strategy to 2020. They will be available by mid 2012. ·
Milestone: –
Establishing sufficient functional green
infrastructure in all MS for maintaining and enhancing ecosystems and their
services. Rationale Biodiversity and ecosystems are crucial
resources to support societal and individual well-being and economic
prosperity. Solutions relying on natural capital and ecosystem services are in
many cases more cost-effective than engineering options, e.g. for flood
protection and water purification. Such green infrastructure, thanks to its
multi-purpose character, makes most efficient use of the multiple ecosystem
services the same piece of land offers to people. The milestone reflects Target
2 of the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020. It translates the global Aichi
Biodiversity Targets 14 and 15 of the Strategic Plan[168]
agreed under the Convention on Biological Diversity in Nagoya in October 2010,
where the restoration of at least 15% of degraded ecosystems is seen as a means
of contributing to climate change mitigation and adaptation. These have been
defined in the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020. 4.2.2. Biodiversity 4.2.3.1. Halting
the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services in the EU and restoring them as
far as possible ·
Proposed indicators: –
Based on the EU 2010 Biodiversity Baseline and
the Aichi Biodiversity targets, measurable milestones and indicators will be
developed within the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020. They will be available
by mid 2012. ·
Target: –
Halting the loss of biodiversity and the degradation
of ecosystem services in the EU by 2020, and restoring them in so far as
feasible (at least 15% of degraded ecosystems by 2020), while stepping up the
EU contribution to averting global biodiversity loss. Rationale Biodiversity underpins our ecosystems and
is vital to their resilience and is thus a crucial resource to support societal
and individual well-being and economic prosperity. The Biodiversity Strategy is
aimed at reversing biodiversity loss and speeding up the EU's transition
towards a resource efficient and green economy. It is an integral part of the
Europe 2020 Strategy, and in particular the resource efficient Europe flagship. The target reflects the 6 targets of the EU
Biodiversity Strategy to 2020[169]. It
translates the global Aichi Biodiversity Targets of the Strategic Plan agreed
under the Convention on Biological Diversity in Nagoya in October 2010, where
the restoration of at least 15% of degraded ecosystems is seen as a means of
contributing to climate change mitigation and adaptation. These targets have
been set in the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020. 4.2.3. Minerals
and metals ·
Proposed indicators: –
Resource productivity of minerals and metals
(GDP/DMC minerals+metals) ·
A milestone or target will be considered. Rationale The lead indicator (resource productivity
measured as GDP/DMC) takes into account all materials, but can be decomposed in
the main material streams such as minerals and metals.. The indicators
mentioned in the section "Turning waste into a resource" are also
closely related to this field as they point out how the material loops could be
closed and as they often refer to minerals and metals. 4.2.4. Water 4.2.4.1. Ensuring
good quality and quantities of water ·
Proposed indicators: –
Indicators will be presented as part of the 2012
Blueprint[170],
accompanied by a rationale for their choice. –
In the meanwhile, the Water Exploitation Index
could be used. ·
Milestones and targets: ·
All Water Framework Directive River Basin
Management Plans (RBMPs) are implemented by 2012, good status of waters is
attained in all EU river basins in 2015, and good quality and quantities of
water will be ensured by 2020. ·
By 2020, water abstraction stays, as a rule,
below 20% of available renewable water resources. Rationale Water is a key resource necessary for life
– it needs to be preserved and used efficiently. The milestones reflect the
need to integrate resource efficiency actions into EU policies relevant for
water as competing demands for fresh water is putting pressure on the
availability and quality of fresh water. Climate change is another important
factor affecting availability and quality of fresh water and is projected to
have even more severe impacts in the future. Member States are expected to set
water efficiency targets for 2020 at River Basin level, based on a common EU
methodology that takes into account the great variety of situations across
economic sectors and geographic areas. The 2012 Blueprint will also provide
indicative water efficiency targets. These targets will be subject to full
cost-benefit and feasibility studies and developed with full stakeholder
involvement to ensure their credibility amongst those stakeholders that may
bear costs of meeting them. The choice of indicators will be linked to these
specific targets. On the Water Exploitation Index, the warning threshold to
distinguish a non-stressed to a stressed area is around 20%. 4.2.5. Safeguarding
clean air 4.2.5.1. Achieving
air quality with no significant negative impact on health and the environment ·
Proposed indicator: –
Concentrations of Particulate Matter (PM10) in
ambient air; –
Percentage of urban population in areas with
PM10 concentrations exceeding daily limit values. ·
Target: –
Concentrations of Particulate Matter (PM10) in
ambient air, not exceeding 50µg/m3 per 24 hours more than 35 times a year. Rationale Air quality and related emission control
policies have been in place for decades. Legislation required setting up of a
comprehensive monitoring and evaluation system. In addition, impact and sector
specific indicators have been developed and reported annually[171]. Particulate matter is one of the pollutants with the largest
impact on human health and therefore on quality of life (cardiovascular/ lung
diseases, effects on central nervous system etc.). There is no known threshold
for PM10 under which there is no effect on human health. Hence, besides
measuring the concentrations of PM10 in ambient air, an additional indicator
referring to the percentage of urban population in areas with PM10
concentrations exceeding daily limit values would measure the proportion of
urban population exposed to this risk. 4.2.6. Land
and soils 4.2.6.1. Reducing
the anthropogenic pressure on ecosystems from land take ·
Proposed indicator: –
Average annual land take on the basis of the EEA
Core Set Indicator 14 "Land take"[172]. ·
Milestone: –
Annual land take (i.e. the increase of
artificial land) does not exceed 800 km² per year at the EU level by 2020. Rationale Land take is used in this context as a
proxy for soil sealing. Land take, i.e. increase of artificial land, covers
increase of urban, industrial, commercial or transport land, mainly coming from
agricultural land. It thus indicates the total amount of land converted to
urban and commercial, etc purposes in a given time period. Soil sealing causes adverse
effects on, or complete loss of, practically all soil functions. For example,
fluxes of gas, water and energy are cut off; soil biodiversity is affected and
the water retention capacity and groundwater recharge of soil are reduced. This
in turn results in several negative impacts such as a higher risk of floods.
There are also indirect effects, including habitat fragmentation and indirect
land use changes with losses in biodiversity and food production capacity. To
reach a state of no net land take by 2050 and assuming a linear reduction from
now until then, we would need to decrease the average annual land take from 920
km² per year in the period 2000-2006 to 800 km² per year in the period
2010-2020. 4.2.6.2. Reducing
soil erosion ·
Proposed indicator: –
Soil erosion on the basis of the EEA indicator
"Soil erosion by water"[173]
and the PESERA and/or RUSLE models of the JRC[174]. ·
Milestone: –
The area of land in the EU that is subject to
soil erosion of more than 10 tonnes per hectare per year should be reduced by
at least 25% by 2020. Rationale Erosion is a natural process, which can
however be significantly accelerated by human activities. It is a serious
problem throughout Europe, from the Mediterranean zone to Scandinavia (snowmelt
erosion) and Central and Western Europe (wind erosion). As natural soil
formation is extremely slow, losses of over 1 or 2 tonnes/ha/year are
considered irreversible for most soils. In the context of the EU Strategy for
the Danube Region (COM(2010)715), the Commission has proposed to reduce by 25%
the area affected by soil erosion exceeding 10 tonnes per hectare by 2020. On
the basis of existing estimates, there are 100,000 km² where soil erosion (by
water) is higher than that value over the 21 Member States considered in the
PESERA model. This milestone is a first step to decrease erosion in the most
affected areas. 4.2.6.3. Maintaining
soil organic matter levels ·
Proposed indicator: –
Soil organic matter levels, e.g. on the basis of
LUCAS results[175]. ·
Milestone: –
By 2020 soil organic matter levels do not
decrease overall and increase for soils currently with less than 3.5% organic
matter. Rationale Soil organic matter plays a very important
role, not only for soil fertility, but also for soil structure, buffering and
water retention capacity and is crucial for soil biodiversity. It also has a
major role in the global carbon cycle, as soil can at the same time be both an
emitter of greenhouse gases and a major store of carbon. Around 45% of soils in
Europe have low or very low organic matter content (0-3.5% organic matter) and
45% have a medium content (3.5-9% organic matter). Besides climate reasons,
various unsustainable human activities are the most relevant driving forces. By
2020 soil organic matter levels should not be decreasing overall and should
increase for soils with currently low or very low organic matter content. The
proposed indicator will provide relevant information as to the evolution of
soil organic matter levels. 4.2.6.4. Identifying
and remediating contaminated sites ·
Proposed indicator: –
Share of contaminated sites on which remediation
actions have started in the previous year on the basis of the EEA Core Set
Indicator 15 "Progress in management of contaminated sites"[176]. ·
Milestone: –
Member States should have started undertaking remediation
actions on identified contaminated sites by 2020. Rationale Available information indicates that the
number of contaminated sites and surface covered across Europe is very large.
There is a very unequal progress among Member States in addressing the issue.
Soil contamination has far reaching consequences for environment, human health
and sectors as agriculture. As a first step we need to monitor the
identification of contaminated sites, followed by the monitoring of remediation
actions. To allow for proper identification and remediation, all Member States
should set up an inventory of contaminated sites in their territory by 2020 and
should in parallel start remedial actions. This will ease the soil
contamination problem and will also contribute to less land take by increasing
the land bank available for urban and industrial development. 4.2.7. Marine
resources 4.2.7.1. Ensuring
fish and shellfish are within maximum sustainable yield ·
Proposed indicator: –
Share of fish and shellfish populations within
safe biological limits. ·
Target: –
All fish and shellfish populations are exploited
within maximum sustainable yield in all areas in which EU fishing fleets
operate by 2015. Rationale The marine environment offers many economic
opportunities in the use of its resources and it has an important natural
regulatory function. Examples of vital resources are fish and shellfish
populations, which need to be sustained within safe biological limits. The
aforementioned indicator is considered appropriate as it sums up in an easily
understandable and measurable way (necessary data are already regularly
collected) the various aspects which are key to sustainable management of
stocks e.g. discard and by-catch practices and fleet overcapacity. The target
is part of the Biodiversity Strategy[177] and
also in line with the requirements of Common Fisheries' Policy and EU
commitments under Regional Fisheries' Management Organizations (RFMOs). 4.2.7.2. Achieving
good environmental status in all EU waters ·
Proposed indicator: –
The number and area of Marine Protected Areas
(MPAs). ·
Milestone: –
At least 10% of the marine EU area is covered by
a coherent network of MPAs. Rationale The coverage of MPAs is a good indicator in
relation to the preservation of marine habitats and marine biodiversity more
generally. MPAs will contribute to the achievement of Good Environmental Status
under the Marine Strategy Framework Directive and foster regional cooperation
within Regional Seas Conventions. Increasing coverage of MPAs will moreover
facilitate the fulfilment of EU commitments under these Conventions but also
those under the Convention for Biodiversity. The latter included in its
strategic goals adopted in Nagoya in 2010 the target that, by 2020, at least 10
per cent of coastal and marine areas, especially areas of particular importance
for biodiversity and ecosystem services, are conserved through effectively and
equitably managed, ecologically representative and well connected systems of
protected areas and other effective area-based conservation measures, and
integrated into the wider landscapes and seascapes. 4.3. Key
sectors 4.3.1. Addressing
food 4.3.1.1. Making
food consumption healthier and more sustainable ·
Proposed indicator: –
Development in consumption of different meat and
dairy products per capita per year based on ETC/SCP Indicator 13.2 for the EEA[178]. ·
Milestone: –
Amount of animal proteins (including meat and
dairy products) consumed per person is in line with WHO recommendations. Rationale Food production and consumption, in
particular of animal proteins, are responsible for a large part of
environmental impacts, as highlighted, for example, in reports from the
International Resource Panel[179] and PLB Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency[180]. The planet's carrying capacity is limited while the population is
increasing. As an increasing part of the population suffering from health
problems due to unhealthy diets, following the WHO recommendation on the daily
intake of animal proteins would make a significant contribution to ease this
problem. The ideal indicator to measure this would be the 'amount of animal
proteins consumed per person per year' but this is not yet available. Currently
existing indicator, the 'development in consumption of different meat and dairy
products per capita per year' covers large part of animal proteins. 4.3.1.2. Reducing
food waste ·
Proposed indicator: –
Share of edible food waste in households,
retailers and catering. ·
Milestone: –
Decrease of edible food waste in households,
retailers and catering by 50% in the EU. Rationale Reducing our food waste is a clear first
step towards more resource efficiency in the food value chain. To have a
significant impact, we should at least halve our edible food waste. Households count for about 40 % of all food waste; the retail and
catering sector add another 20%. If the same rate of edible food waste of
households (60%) is applied to the retail and catering sector, halving our
edible food waste results in a reduction of total food waste by approximately
18%[181]. After the results of ongoing studies will
be available, expected in 2013/14, the Commission will, together with ESTAT's
Working Group on Waste Statistics, develop proposals on how such an indicator
can be developed and maintained. 4.3.2. Improving
buildings 4.3.2.1. Promoting
green buildings ·
Proposed indicators: –
The rate of nearly zero-energy new buildings (to
be developed); –
Energy consumption per m2 for space heating, per
dwelling and for total housing stock alongside growth in m2 of living space per
capita based on ETC/SCP Indicator 16.1 for the EEA (to be further developed)[182]. ·
Target: –
Member States shall ensure that by 31 December
2020, all new buildings are nearly zero-energy buildings; and after 31 December
2018, new buildings occupied and owned by public authorities are near zero-energy
buildings[183]. Rationale Energy consumption for building-related
services accounts for approximately one third of total EU energy consumption.
One way to reduce energy consumption is to improve energy efficiency. The
proposal for a Directive on energy efficiency[184]
strengthens the energy performance requirements. A target set in this Directive
is to ensure that all new buildings are nearly zero-energy buildings by 2020.
The indicator on the energy consumption per m2 shows developments in
energy use for heating in housing at different scales. It is based on the
reasoning that developments in energy consumption per m2 are
directly influenced by technical improvements in building envelopes and in
heating technology. Average per capita size of living space can offset or
strengthen technological improvements. Increasing living space per capita will,
in general, offset technical improvements[185].
Looking at these trends gives an indication on energy efficiency of new
buildings. 4.3.3. Ensuring
efficient mobility 4.3.3.1. Transforming
transport ·
Proposed indicators: –
CO2 emissions in the transport sector; –
Total energy consumption/km driven as a proxy
for energy efficiency in transport; –
Average CO2 emissions per km for new passenger
cars; –
Pollutant emissions (NOx, VOC, PM) from the
transport sector (available from EEA / Reporting under NECD); –
Energy consumption by fuel type. ·
Milestones and targets: –
The Transport White Paper proposes a target to
decrease GHG by 60% in transport sector by 2050 (EU transport emissions should
drop by 1% annually until 2030, afterwards by 5% annually until 2050). Rationale The decarbonisation of the economy and the
transformation of the efficiency of the transport system are essential aspects
of the move to a resource efficient economy. CO2 is a reasonably
good proxy for how efficiently conventional fossils are being used, because
most emissions occur during the fossil fuel combustion phase, and hence lower
levels of CO2 emissions tend to correspond to reductions in fossil
fuel energy use. Transport remains a significant contributor to persistent air
quality problems, hence the environmental performance of transport with respect
to other key pollutants (such as PM, NOx and VOCs) will be monitored. Energy
consumption by fuel type is another indicator to monitor fuel shifts in the
transport system, i.e. whether we are moving towards more sustainable fuel
types. 4.4. Governance:
New pathways to action on resource efficiency 4.4.1. Financing
resource efficient innovation and investments ·
Proposed indicators: –
Share of total budget spent on the environmental
and resource efficiency measures; –
Capitalisation of ‘Core’ and ‘broad’ Sustainable
and Responsible Investments (SRI) in Europe (billion/€) based on ETC/SCP
Indicator 24.1 for the EEA (to be further developed)[186]. ·
Milestone: –
30% of the EU Regional Budget (i.e. cohesion
policy budget) allocated to environment related expenditure. Rationale The target is set according to the
Sustainable Growth Communication of January 2011, which mentions,
"approximately 30% of the total € 344 billion Regional funding over
2007-2013 is available for activities with a particular impact on sustainable
growth. By the end of 2009, 22% of this funding for sustainable growth had been
allocated to specific projects compared to 27% for the total of Regional
funding." The 30% funding refers to the cohesion policy budget, and
includes both direct and indirect expenditure covering environment, climate,
resource efficiency, clean transport, and others. The indicator on public funding
for the transition can directly track how much of the budget is spent on the
environment and resource efficiency. The indicator on private funding for the
transition shows how funds with social and environmental criteria are
increasing/decreasing, i.e. it represents those financial assets selected by
fund managers according to criteria about the social and environmental
responsibility of emitters. Appendix 1: choice of lead indicator Developing a set of resource efficiency
indicators is a considerable challenge, as measuring the state of and changes
in resource efficiency is much more complex than measuring, say, labour or
energy productivity. Ideally, a set of indicators would cover (i) resource use,
(ii) its efficiency, (iii) related policy measures and (iv) related societal
and economic benefits – such as (green) jobs, free ecosystem services, (cost)
savings and (eco-) innovation – along the full production chain from extraction
to recycling or waste disposal. They should include inter alia information
on availability, scarcity, location, economic value/prices and environmental
and biodiversity impacts of resources. For renewable resources the
sustainability of their management patterns is to be covered. A substantial amount of base data is
readily available, e.g. on mining, agriculture, waste and international trade.
Other data sets, e.g. those on environmental impacts of production and
consumption, are under development. On the other hand the conceptual work on
how to aggregate these detailed statistics into meaningful macro indicators on
resource use and efficiency is still underway. First macro indicators such as Resource
Productivity (GDP/domestic material consumption), Environmentally-weighted
Material Consumption (EMC) or the Ecological Footprint have been developed and
produced and are in principle ready for use. However all of them should be
considered as "proxy" indicators, as all of them cover only part of
the resource efficiency agenda. There is currently no indicator measuring
comprehensively the consumption of natural resources as defined in the roadmap
– and there are considerable methodological challenges to aggregating resources
as different as land, water, oil and ores into one single indicator. For the
selection of the lead indicator the Commission looked at existing indicators on
materials, such as the Domestic Material Consumption; indicators on land use,
such as the Ecological Footprint; indicators related to carbon, such as carbon
intensity; indicators on environmental impacts, such as Environmentally-weighted
Material Consumption (EMC); and resource specific indicators, such as on water,
land, soils and others. The following assessment criteria have been
used as appropriate: ·
Political relevance; ·
Coverage of all relevant categories of resources; ·
Coherence and completeness; ·
Transparency of trade-offs and negative side
effects such as burden shifting; ·
Link to a timeline for production of the data
and calculation of the indicator; ·
Applicability to different levels of economic
activities (EU, Member States, sectors, firms, products); ·
Support by data that can be aggregated and
disaggregated across scales, from products to sectors and countries. Below the key arguments are listed that led
to the proposal to continue using Resource Productivity (GDP/DMC) as the lead
indicator for efficient use of natural resources. DMC Aggregated weight of used domestic extraction
of raw materials, plus direct weight of imports (raw materials and products),
minus exports (raw materials and products) measured in tonnes. Strengths ·
Established indicator; ·
Output of well established integrated
environmental economic accounting methods; ·
Official statistics; ·
Statistical regulation for continuous production
in place; ·
Includes all materials: minerals, metals, carbon
related fossil fuels and (renewable) biomass; ·
Breakdown by materials and sectors and
industries possible. Limitations ·
Material resources only; ·
Economic value, resource scarcity and
environmental impacts of resource use are only partially correlated to their
weight; ·
Statistically not fully consistent with GDP. Ecological Footprint Aggregates the land use caused by human
consumption based on "bio-productive" land (and sea) areas and the
land area theoretically necessary for carbon sequestration. Measured in 'global
hectares'. Strengths ·
Powerful communication tool; ·
Strong link to biodiversity and eco-system
health; ·
Strong link with the thresholds for use of the
renewable resources, or carrying capacity of the planet; ·
Includes renewable materials, land and carbon. ·
Takes account of burden shift issues Limitations ·
Methodology under scientific and statistical
scrutiny; ·
Current version based on weak international data
set while better EU data sets are available; ·
Water and non-renewable materials only
indirectly included. Carbon Intensity Relates economic output to aggregated
emissions of greenhouse gases, measured in tonnes of CO2 equivalent
per euro of GDP. Strengths ·
Good data quality; ·
Proxy for wider environmental impacts; ·
Proxy for use of non-renewable materials; ·
Proxy for unsustainable use of land based
renewable resources (soil degradation, forest loss). Limitations ·
Duplication of information of the already agreed
indicators on 20/20/20 targets; ·
Mainly driven by energy consumption; ·
Does not include consumption of renewable and
nuclear energy; ·
Does not include other resources. EMC Aggregates the contribution of resource use
to specific (or the overall) environmental impacts, such as ground-level ozone
or human toxicity, measured in percentage of total environmental impact. Strengths ·
Aggregates material consumption not only by
weight (as DMC), but according to environmental impacts. Limitations ·
Weighting of environmental impacts cannot be
done scientifically; ·
Methodology under scientific and statistical
scrutiny; ·
Limited data availability and quality. Resource specific indicators Aggregate use or consumption of a specific
resource, e.g. coal, land or water, using their physical unit of measurement. Strengths ·
Concrete; ·
Easy to communicate; ·
Indicate substitution effects / shift of burden. Limitations ·
No overview; ·
Difficult to aggregate into one indicator or
index. Appendix 2: Trends for EU and Member States on
lead and dashboard indicators Table 1:
Resource productivity GDP/DMC (EUR per kg) GEO/TIME || 2000 || 2001 || 2002 || 2003 || 2004 || 2005 || 2006 || 2007 EU || 1,21 || 1,24 || 1,27 || 1,30 || 1,27 || 1,28 || 1,29 || 1,30 Austria || 1,41 || 1,44 || 1,38 || 1,37 || 1,30 || 1,30 || 1,32 || 1,40 Belgium || 1,32 || 1,29 || 1,36 || 1,41 || 1,43 || 1,43 || 1,43 || 1,47 Bulgaria || 0,13 || 0,13 || 0,13 || 0,13 || 0,13 || 0,14 || 0,13 || 0,14 Cyprus || 0,66 || 0,66 || 0,61 || 0,67 || 0,61 || 0,62 || 0,66 || 0,64 Czech Republic || 0,33 || 0,34 || 0,37 || 0,37 || 0,36 || 0,39 || 0,40 || 0,42 Denmark || 1,28 || 1,32 || 1,38 || 1,36 || 1,31 || 1,22 || 1,20 || 1,24 Estonia || 0,32 || 0,34 || 0,32 || 0,25 || 0,28 || 0,31 || 0,31 || 0,27 Finland || 0,76 || 0,76 || 0,78 || 0,76 || 0,79 || 0,80 || 0,78 || 0,79 France || 1,64 || 1,73 || 1,74 || 1,87 || 1,74 || 1,83 || 1,83 || 1,80 Germany || 1,41 || 1,52 || 1,55 || 1,58 || 1,58 || 1,64 || 1,65 || 1,71 Greece || 0,88 || 0,86 || 0,86 || 0,83 || 0,87 || 0,90 || 0,94 || 0,98 Hungary || 0,45 || 0,43 || 0,45 || 0,46 || 0,42 || 0,38 || 0,47 || 0,60 Ireland || 0,63 || 0,63 || 0,67 || 0,67 || 0,68 || 0,68 || 0,66 || 0,66 Italy || 1,25 || 1,36 || 1,46 || 1,62 || 1,52 || 1,49 || 1,52 || 1,60 Latvia || 0,24 || 0,27 || 0,27 || 0,29 || 0,29 || 0,29 || 0,31 || 0,31 Lithuania || 0,44 || 0,53 || 0,47 || 0,38 || 0,42 || 0,43 || 0,46 || 0,43 Luxembourg || 2,78 || 3,01 || 2,95 || 3,01 || 3,33 || 3,33 || 3,04 || 4,32 Malta || 3,00 || 3,26 || 3,04 || 2,81 || 2,32 || 2,42 || 2,18 || 2,14 Netherlands || 2,16 || 2,14 || 2,35 || 2,44 || 2,42 || 2,45 || 2,59 || 2,60 Poland || 0,32 || 0,35 || 0,38 || 0,38 || 0,37 || 0,38 || 0,40 || 0,38 Portugal || 0,66 || 0,64 || 0,68 || 0,75 || 0,70 || 0,70 || 0,62 || 0,62 Romania || 0,18 || 0,15 || 0,17 || 0,16 || 0,16 || 0,16 || 0,16 || 0,14 Slovakia || 0,40 || 0,39 || 0,40 || 0,43 || 0,40 || 0,39 || 0,44 || 0,49 Slovenia || 0,48 || 0,51 || 0,51 || 0,50 || 0,49 || 0,53 || 0,48 || 0,46 Spain || 0,93 || 0,93 || 0,87 || 0,85 || 0,86 || 0,87 || 0,85 || 0,90 Sweden || 1,71 || 1,82 || 1,81 || 1,83 || 1,85 || 1,69 || 1,95 || 1,79 United Kingdom || 2,11 || 2,13 || 2,24 || 2,30 || 2,28 || 2,41 || 2,48 || 2,54 Figure 1: Resource productivity in the EU
(index 2000 = 100) Table 2:
Artificial Surface (hectares) GEO/TIME || 1990 || 2000 || 2006 || Total Surface EU || 17.614.704 || 18.621.100 || 19.173.193 || 432.080.477 Austria || 392.958 || 401.408 || 409.181 || 8.392.463 Belgium || 605.485 || 627.595 || 630.347 || 3.066.430 Bulgaria || 549.815 || 553.385 || 557.529 || 11.096.372 Cyprus || 67.544 || 68.870 || 79.103 || 925.971 Czech Republic || 472.803 || 493.223 || 501.899 || 7.886.893 Denmark || 301.465 || 315.255 || 324.745 || 4.289.089 Estonia || 86.603 || 90.953 || 94.173 || 4.346.186 Finland || 461.581 || 472.234 || 483.422 || 33.702.920 France || 2.588.183 || 2.744.303 || 2.826.586 || 54.881.341 Germany || 2.744.401 || 2.964.561 || 3.012.304 || 35.708.592 Greece || 231.604 || 270.084 || 283.301 || 13.162.924 Hungary || 532.595 || 546.685 || 561.572 || 9.300.074 Ireland || 108.416 || 142.516 || 162.565 || 6.987.857 Italy || 1.362.772 || 1.450.012 || 1.498.303 || 30.150.499 Latvia || 85.011 || 85.241 || 86.224 || 6.461.353 Lithuania || 209.948 || 212.818 || 215.648 || 6.497.798 Luxembourg || 22.303 || 24.003 || 24.171 || 259.741 Malta || 7.402 || 8.171 || 8.178 || 31.586 Netherlands || 406.803 || 475.143 || 510.995 || 3.735.750 Poland || 1.211.876 || 1.243.546 || 1.254.749 || 31.195.005 Portugal || 237.586 || 287.976 || 315.507 || 9.196.404 Romania || 1.490.431 || 1.502.611 || 1.511.699 || 23.845.069 Slovakia || 257.984 || 265.604 || 268.718 || 4.901.397 Slovenia || 53.795 || 55.155 || 56.215 || 2.027.724 Spain || 759.205 || 893.455 || 1.030.762 || 50.672.957 Sweden || 593.125 || 611.383 || 628.929 || 44.911.418 United Kingdom || 1.773.010 || 1.814.910 || 1.836.368 || 24.446.664 Figure 2: Artificial Surface in the EU
(million hectares) Table 3: Water
Exploitation Index GEO/TIME || 1990 || 2002 || 2005 || 2007 EU || 0,131 || 0,132 || 0,13 || 0,13 Austria || 0,05 || 0,04 || 0,04 || 0,04 Belgium || 0,338 || || 0,32 || 0,32 Bulgaria || 0,10 || 0,06 || 0,06 || 0,06 Cyprus || || 0,63 || 0,45 || 0,64 Czech Republic || 0,23 || 0,12 || 0,12 || 0,12 Denmark || 0,08 || 0,04 || 0,04 || 0,04 Estonia || 0,15 || 0,11 || 0,13 || 0,15 Finland || 0,02 || 0,02 || 0,02 || 0,02 France || 0,21 || 0,18 || 0,18 || 0,17 Germany3 || 0,25 || 0,20 || 0,20 || 0,19 Greece || 0,11 || 0,12 || 0,12 || 0,13 Hungary || 0,06 || 0,05 || 0,0545 || 0,0562 Ireland || 0,026 || : || 0,02 || 0,02 Italy || || 0,24 || 0,24 || 0,24 Latvia || 0,01 || 0,01 || 0,007 || 0,006 Lithuania || 0,18 || 0,13 || 0,10 || 0,09 Luxembourg || || 0,04 || 0,04 || 0,04 Malta || 0,32 || 0,24 || 0,21 || 0,21 Netherlands || 0,09 || 0,10 || 0,12 || 0,11 Poland || 0,24 || 0,19 || 0,18 || 0,18 Portugal || 0,10 || 0,15 || 0,15 || 0,15 Romania || 0,08 || 0,03 || 0,02 || 0,03 Slovakia || 0,03 || 0,01 || 0,01 || 0,01 Slovenia || 0,01 || 0,01 || 0,03 || 0,03 Spain || 0,33 || 0,33 || 0,34 || 0,30 Sweden || 0,02 || 0,01 || 0,01 || 0,01 United Kingdom4 || 0,204 || : || 0,22 || 0,13 Note: (1) 1990 data are for average EU24, no data for CY, IT
and LU (2) 2002 data are for average EU24, no data for UK, BE,
and IE (3) Germany includes ex-GDR from 1991 (4) United Kingdom comprises of England and Wales data
only Figure 3: Water
Exploitation Index in the EU Table 4: Greenhouse Gas Emissions (CO2 equivalent
thousands of tonnes) GEO/TIME || 1990 || 1995 || 2000 || 2001 || 2002 || 2003 || 2004 || 2005 || 2006 || 2007 || 2008 || 2009 EU || 5.588.798 || 5.231.962 || 5.085.820 || 5.145.129 || 5.104.918 || 5.177.396 || 5.181.206 || 5.148.753 || 5.128.892 || 5.071.328 || 4.969.052 || 4.614.526 Belgium || 143.344 || 150.070 || 145.415 || 144.863 || 143.564 || 145.899 || 146.713 || 142.729 || 137.737 || 132.908 || 135.155 || 124.440 Bulgaria || 111.401 || 80.814 || 63.344 || 66.359 || 63.052 || 68.300 || 67.560 || 67.110 || 68.297 || 71.763 || 69.029 || 59.493 Czech Republic || 195.523 || 153.632 || 147.420 || 149.612 || 145.343 || 144.419 || 145.331 || 144.711 || 146.036 || 147.055 || 141.131 || 132.925 Denmark || 68.007 || 75.655 || 67.847 || 69.524 || 68.859 || 73.599 || 67.897 || 63.634 || 71.556 || 66.927 || 63.654 || 60.985 Germany || 1.247.901 || 1.119.906 || 1.042.071 || 1.056.941 || 1.036.680 || 1.030.603 || 1.021.218 || 999.776 || 1.002.257 || 979.873 || 981.112 || 919.698 Estonia || 41.053 || 20.249 || 17.811 || 18.200 || 17.531 || 19.479 || 19.835 || 19.164 || 18.710 || 21.603 || 20.071 || 16.837 Ireland || 54.820 || 58.490 || 67.865 || 69.701 || 67.870 || 67.842 || 67.683 || 69.221 || 68.683 || 68.035 || 67.817 || 62.395 Greece || 104.365 || 108.983 || 126.003 || 127.444 || 127.161 || 130.876 || 131.383 || 134.356 || 130.746 || 133.395 || 128.550 || 122.543 Spain || 283.168 || 314.839 || 379.563 || 379.820 || 396.775 || 403.731 || 419.511 || 433.847 || 426.023 || 437.130 || 404.771 || 367.548 France || 562.886 || 559.672 || 566.838 || 569.147 || 563.708 || 565.719 || 566.462 || 568.972 || 552.969 || 544.501 || 539.178 || 517.248 Italy || 519.157 || 529.951 || 551.640 || 557.476 || 558.668 || 573.477 || 576.600 || 574.893 || 563.911 || 554.569 || 541.749 || 491.120 Cyprus || 5.273 || 6.666 || 9.112 || 9.079 || 9.100 || 9.115 || 9.296 || 9.590 || 9.705 || 9.855 || 10.182 || 9.401 Latvia || 26.576 || 12.699 || 10.316 || 10.952 || 10.923 || 11.134 || 11.299 || 11.417 || 11.839 || 12.348 || 11.918 || 10.723 Lithuania || 49.559 || 21.833 || 19.166 || 20.271 || 20.659 || 20.871 || 21.627 || 22.610 || 23.419 || 25.146 || 24.033 || 21.609 Luxembourg || 12.827 || 10.104 || 9.766 || 10.275 || 11.044 || 11.486 || 12.900 || 13.152 || 13.018 || 12.398 || 12.260 || 11.684 Hungary || 96.824 || 78.180 || 76.703 || 78.713 || 76.667 || 79.665 || 78.707 || 79.495 || 77.824 || 75.478 || 73.095 || 66.727 Malta || 2.065 || 2.463 || 2.614 || 2.727 || 2.750 || 2.932 || 2.900 || 2.927 || 2.965 || 3.048 || 3.009 || 2.866 Netherlands || 211.852 || 223.249 || 213.161 || 214.995 || 214.317 || 215.370 || 216.762 || 211.105 || 207.129 || 205.405 || 204.601 || 198.872 Austria || 78.171 || 79.811 || 80.476 || 84.343 || 86.159 || 91.894 || 90.927 || 92.884 || 90.103 || 87.373 || 86.961 || 80.059 Poland || 452.935 || 440.282 || 389.427 || 385.999 || 372.786 || 384.621 || 385.557 || 388.017 || 402.339 || 400.695 || 395.724 || 376.659 Portugal || 59.417 || 69.499 || 81.225 || 82.337 || 86.897 || 81.703 || 84.078 || 85.984 || 81.272 || 79.107 || 77.935 || 74.583 Romania || 250.087 || 187.882 || 142.117 || 147.844 || 154.573 || 161.227 || 160.118 || 155.738 || 160.404 || 156.215 || 153.419 || 130.828 Slovenia || 18.478 || 18.458 || 18.821 || 19.682 || 19.955 || 19.635 || 19.898 || 20.237 || 20.455 || 20.567 || 21.286 || 19.339 Slovakia || 74.112 || 53.311 || 49.203 || 50.590 || 49.754 || 50.983 || 50.751 || 50.087 || 49.864 || 47.836 || 48.166 || 43.404 Finland || 70.364 || 70.783 || 69.162 || 74.383 || 76.524 || 84.278 || 80.269 || 68.477 || 79.711 || 78.144 || 70.420 || 66.336 Sweden || 72.490 || 74.313 || 68.900 || 69.521 || 70.378 || 70.914 || 70.369 || 67.591 || 67.283 || 65.794 || 63.570 || 59.994 United Kingdom || 776.142 || 710.168 || 669.832 || 674.330 || 653.223 || 657.625 || 655.557 || 651.027 || 644.637 || 634.159 || 620.257 || 566.210 Figure 4: Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the
EU (CO2 equivalent millions of tonnes) Annex 7: Trends
in Resource Use
1.
Introduction
To describe trends
in sustainable resource use, it is essential to monitor economic activity, use
of natural resources and, finally, interdependance between natural resources,
in particular how unsustainable use of some resources may lead to the depletion
of others. While complete statistics exists for economic activity, monitoring
is more complex for the use of natural resources and even more so for their
interlinkages. This Annex presents
snapshots of information on resource trends, taken from various data sets.
Given the breadth of different resources, it does not attempt to cover all
trends for all relevant resources, but shows selected examples to give a
representative picture. If focuses mainly on trends in material resources, but
attempts also to present the most relevant data as regards other key natural
resources. Next to that, in analyses some aspects of resource interdependence,
referred to also as environmental impacts. Finally, it reflects briefly on the
drivers of resource use. Wherever possible, EU and global trends are shown
graphically, complementing the information in the two Staff Working Documents
accompanying the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient Europe.
2.
Material Use in the EU
2.1.
Domestic Material Use and Import Dependency
The use of materials
in Europe is closely connected with economic growth. Being a key driver of
material use, it entails the changing structure of the economy with a growing
share of services and a parallel increase of imports of resources including
finished and semi-finished products as well as growing levels of household
consumption. Contrary to most parts of the world, population growth in Europe
has only a limited impact on the use of resources (see section 5). In 2007, the
domestic material consumption (DMC) in the EU amounted to 8.2 billion tonnes,
equalling 13% of the global materials extraction. Minerals including metals
accounted for half of EU consumption, while fossil fuels and biomass for about
one quarter each. With an annual average per capita material consumption of
about 16.5 tonnes/capita/year in 2007, the EU was more than 65 % above the
global average. Having adopted a rigorous resource conservation policy, Japan
was down to an average of 12 tonnes/capita/year; however, the USA reached a level
of 27 tonnes/capita/year. While material use
has stabilised at a high level in the EU-15 (DMC slightly growing but a small
decline for DMC per capita), it is still increasing substantially in the EU-12,
which results in a slow growth in material use in EU-27 overall, at a similar
pace as population. The important increase in EU-12 is probably due to
large-scale infrastructure projects and the construction boom that started in
the late 1990s and later on intensified when joining the EU. Figure 1: Trends in the use of material resources in EU15 and EU12,
1972-2008 (Source: EEA,
2010) The overall trend of
stabilisation of material consumption is based upon stable or even decreasing
domestic material extraction. The latter is the case for metallic ores and
fossil energy carriers, while domestic extraction of biomass and non-metallic
minerals are stable at high levels. In contrast, in order to meet EU's material
demand, trade is rapidly increasing and there is a high import dependency for
many material categories, especially strategically important ones. Net imports
of materials into the EU-27 are now 1.3 billion tonnes, reflecting an increase
of over 25% in the period between 2000 and 2007 and currently between 20 and 30
% of the resources we use are imported. This means that care needs to be taken
when interpreting the observed trends of stabilisation of material use as
upstream material flows are not taken into consideration in import data. Figure 2: EU-27 physical trade balance with the rest of the world (Source: EEA, 2010) Fossil Fuels
Use The current energy
system is heavily dependent on fossil fuels and their share in the total energy
consumption has declined only slightly, from 83 to 79 % between 1990 and 2005.
Oil is still the biggest contributor with over 36 % of the gross inland
consumption in 2007 while gas was up to almost 24 % and solid fuels reached
above 18 %. Renewable energy made up 7.8 %. In this category, wind power
remains dominant and represented 75 % of the total installed renewable capacity
in 2006. The gross inland
consumption of energy in EU27 amounted to about 1800 Mtoe in 2007, having
experienced an annual increase of final energy consumption by 0.6 % between
1990 and 2005. In the same period, the total energy intensity (total energy
divided by GDP) in the EU-27 decreased by an estimated 1.3 % annually, with by
far the fastest decrease taking place in the new Member States. The dependency
on import is particularly high in this sector and over 53 % of all fuels are
imported, showing one of the most dramatic increasing trends in recent years. As
can be seen in Figure 3, oil import dependency in the EU was over 80% in 2006,
and gas import dependency around 60%. Moreover, according to the Netherlands
Environmental Assessment Agency these imports only stem from a limited number
of countries. This restriction of the number of potential import countries is
likely to increase further due to the concentration of world oil and gas
reserves in some of them and the expected depletion of world oil and gas
reserves in other countries[187]. Figure 3: EU-27 Energy
import dependency 1995-2006 (Source:
Eurostat, 2010) Biomass
extraction The EU has a highly
productive land use system and biomass extraction amounted to 1.6 billion
tonnes in 2005, corresponding roughly to 8 % of total global biomass
extraction. Crop harvest accounted for the largest share of total extraction
(42 %) followed by forage and grazed biomass (31 %). The share of timber and
fuel wood was 17 % and that of crop residues 10 %. The use of biomass is
dominated by feeding livestock. Trade of biomass based products is very dynamic
with both imports and exports growing rapidly. Here as well, the EU is an
important net importer, with large imports of feed and animal products as well
as wood and wood-based products. To a large extent, biomass consumption in the
EU affects land use in third countries, where the import of soybean and soybean
cake may serve as an example. The EU meat production, which equals about 15-18
% of global meat production and which is almost exclusively consumed within EU,
requires large amounts of high quality protein feed. With only a minor domestic
production, the major share of this feed is based on soybeans and soybean cake
which is imported from countries like Brazil and the United States. The
imported amount corresponds to an area of more than 20 mio ha of cropland and
this illustrates how European imports are demanding large areas of fertile
cropland in distant regions of the world, with European consumption patterns
contributing to land use change elsewhere. Several studies have attempted to
estimate the drawing of global land use and results vary from about 50% of
domestic HANPP (2000) and upwards. The implementation of the European biofuel
strategy will drastically increase this demand and is likely to further
increase EUs draw on global land resources, with its associated environmental
impacts. Decoupling economic
growth from material resources use The general trend is
of relative decoupling between economic growth and use of material resources. An
absolute decoupling only took place under very limited periods and was always
linked to recession or at least very low economic growth. Absolute decoupling
of material use during economic growth, as has been observed in Japan since
1990, has not been achieved in the EU. Varying trends can
however be seen across member states with most countries achieving relatively stable
DMC and relative dematerialisation. A few Member States have reached absolute
decoupling also in the long run. This has generally been the result of fuel
shifts and deindustrialisation with the fading out of intensive and heavy
industries or mining activities, a process which is often related to the
externalisation of material use and corresponding environmental impacts to
third countries. If taking these aspects into account, the absolute decoupling
may no longer be obvious. At the same time, certain Member States, often with
low level of per capita income but with high economic growth, have seen
particularly the development of built infrastructure contribute to a high
increase in material use and, thus, not even reaching a relative decoupling.
The overall improved resource productivity during the last two decades in the
EU is largely based on more resource-efficient technologies, the transition to
service-based economies but at the same time an increased share of imports in
EU economies, outsourcing early phases in the life cycle which generally have a
lower economic value/weight. Figure 4 shows resource use per person in 2000 and
2007. Figure 4: Resource use per person, by country, 2000 and 2007 (Source: EEA, 2010) Limitations of DMC measurement Current material
flow accounts only consider direct material flows and do not take into account
indirect or hidden resource flows associated with used material extraction
which do not enter the economy (such as overburden from mining operations,
eroded soil or earthen materials displaced during construction). Hidden flows
can be large and can moreover give rise to considerable environmental
pressures. The increasing dependency on imported materials thus risks hiding
increasing material flows and their associated environmental pressures and
impacts taking place beyond the EU. In terms of weight, the EU imports over six
times more materials than it exports, and this ratio is fairly stable.
Considering how overall trade is growing, this means most Member States are
increasingly consuming products for which the majority of the resource use has
taken place elsewhere. In fact, Europe has the highest net imports of resources
per person in the world. Thus, behind a significant part of the improved
figures in EU material productivity lays the increasing dependency on import
for which upstream flows, hidden flows, never enter the material flow accounts
and the statistics of the EU. Pilot studies which quantify these upstream flows
indicate that, for highly industrialised countries, the so called Raw Material
Equivalents are three to six times larger than the direct import flows.
2.2.
Global Stocks and Imports of Materials
Europe is highly
dependent on imports for many raw materials which are increasingly affected by
growing demand pressure from emerging economies and by an increasing number of
national policy measures that disrupt the normal operation of global markets[188]. Import dependency holds for several minerals and metals. 95% of
global 'rare earth' elements production is thought to be located in China,
which has imposed export restrictions on of some of them. Likewise phosphate,
an essential raw material in fertilizer and thus in agricultural production is
only extracted in a limited number of countries: three quarters of total known world
reserves are in China, with the rest coming from Morocco and the Western
Sahara, and minor fractions from the US and South-Africa[189]. There is a
particular concern about the availability of 14 minerals. Figure 5 depicts the
economic importance and supply risk of 41 materials. The minerals in the
upper-right quadrant are labelled as critical because their importance for the
economy is high and they run the risk of supply shortage. An overview of the
sources of these minerals, their producers, substitutability and recycling rate
as well as the EU's import dependency rate[190] can
be found in Figure 6. Figure 5: Economic
importance and supply risk of 41 materials (Source: European Commission – DG Enterprise and
Industry, 2010) Figure 6: Main producers, main sources of imports into EU-27, import
dependency rate, substitutability and recycling rate (Source: Tackling the challenges in the
commodity markets and on raw materials – European Commission, 2011) Geological data on global metals stocks is
scarce, and if available, it is only relevant when used to generate scenarios
for the future, which include use intensity, discard, reuse, etc. Such data and
scenarios are now beginning to appear[191]. From
Figure 7 for example it can be seen that there are only scarcities for a couple
of minerals that are defined as critical by the EU[192]. Figure 7: Global reserves and resources of minerals (2009) (Source: Dutch Environmental Assessment
Agency, 2010)
2.3.
Waste and recycling
In 2006, EU-27
Member States produced some 3 billion tonnes of waste – an average of 6 tonnes
per person[193]. About two thirds (62 %) of the waste generated in EU-27 is mineral
waste, stemming from construction and demolition activities (25-30 %) and from
mining and quarrying 25 %. The rest is from manufacturing (12%), households
(7%) and other activities[194]. Of all the resources consumed in the EU a significant part ends up
as waste. Recycling rates[195] are
above 50% for 18 of 60 metals and the share of old scrap in the total flow is
above 50% only for thirteen metals. End-of-life recycling rates are still
globally low due to the relative abundance of primary material and due to the
absence of performing collection and processing of old metals. Figure 8:
Composition of waste EU-27, 2006 (by weight) (Source: European Commission – Review of the thematic
strategy on waste prevention and recycling, 2011) Figure 9: Average end-of-life functional recycling (Source: UNEP – International Resource Panel (2011)
3.
Key natural resources
Resource efficiency
policies build on a broad concept of resources, including not only raw
materials but also environmental media such as air, water and soil, flow
resources as well as space in the form of land area. Past trends in resource
use have led to changes in the available stocks of resources, with very
different results between resources and regions, depending on the nature of the
resource and varying social and economic conditions.
3.1.
Water
Water is a resource
on which increasing stress has been observed in recent years, with an increasing
number of severe draughts as well as floods. In both cases, climate change is
projected to aggravate this even further. As regards water
quantitiy, a comparison of the impacts of draughts in the EU between 1976-1990
and 1991-2006 shows doubling in both areas and population affected. In many
locations in Europe, water used by agriculture, industry, public water supply
and tourism puts considerable stress on Europe's water resources, and demand
often exceeds local availability[196].
Figure 10 shows the Water Exploitation Index (WEI) in the late 1980s / early
1990s (WEI-90) compared to the latest years available (1997-2005). The WEI is a
measure of the annual total water abstraction as a percentage of available
long-term freshwater resources. The warning threshold, which distinguishes a
non-stressed from a water scarce region, is around 20%, with severe scarcity
occurring where the WEI exceeds 40%[197]. Figure 10: Water exploitation index (WEI) ) in late 1980s / early 1990s
(WEI-90) compared to latest years available (1997-2005) (Source: EEA, 2010) As regards water
quality, despite improvements in some regions, pollution from agriculture
remains a major pressure on Europe's freshwater with nitrogen and phosphorus
being washed to waterways. Improved wastewater treatments and bans on
phosphates in detergents have resulted in a decline of phosphorus levels in
freshwater in recent years, but with this trend slowing down, diffuse sources
need to be targeted for further improvements. Nitrate concentrations are also declining,
but the situation in many rivers is often such that eutrophication is likely to
occur in receiving costal waters with the subsequent depletion of oxygen and
loss of life in bottom waters. Even with measures implemented to reduce this
trend, measurement stations show no change in nitrogen and phosphorus
concentrations in 85% and 80 % of the cases respectively. Oxygen depletion is
particularly serious in the Baltic and Black seas. Just as for material
and land, many European countries have an important share of their water
footprint (an indicator for direct and indirect water use) imported from
wherever production takes place, causing potential water stress abroad.
3.2.
Biodiversity
Changes in habitat
impose the greatest impacts on species in Europe. With grassland and wetland in
decline, urban sprawl and infrastructure fragmenting the landscape, only a
small share of the forest being undisturbed and agro-ecosystems being
characterised by agricultural intensification and abandoned land, biodiversity
is affected negatively. Introducing biofuel crops may further worsen the
situation. Monitoring the status and trends of biodiversity is a challenge and
there are significant gaps in our understanding. As can be seen from Figure 11,
detailed bio-geographical evaluations of the species listed in the EU Habitats
Directive show a favourable conservation status for only 17 %, an unfavourable
status for 52 % and an unknown status for 31 %. Linked to this, only 17 % of
the assessments of the European habitat types were favourable[198]. Moreover,
climate change has started to take its toll and is increasing the ecosystem
vulnerability. Sea surface temperature changes in Europe's regional seas have
been up to six times greater than in the global oceans in the past 25 years. This
leads to changes in the composition of plankton and some fish species, with
consequences on fishing opportunities. Figure 11:
Conservation status of species of Community interest in 2008 (Source: EEA, 2010)
3.3.
Fish
Overfishing
is threatening the viability of both European and global fish stocks. In 2010,
70 % of commercial stocks were fished above the maximum sustainable yield. Looking at the
biological viability of stocks, only 8 % and 11 % of coastal habitats and
species, and 10 % and 2 % of marine habitats and species, respectively, are in
favourable conservation status. The remaining majority either have unfavourable
status or are un-assessed. Figure 12 shows the proportion of fish stocks within
and outside safe biological limits – so at risk of collapse. 21 % of the
assessed commercial stocks in the Baltic Sea are outside safe biological
limits. For the areas of the North-East Atlantic, the percentages of stocks
outside safe biological limits vary between 25 % in the Arctic East and 62 % in
the Bay of Biscay. In the Mediterranean Sea, the percentage of stocks outside
safe biological limits is about 60 %, with four out of six areas exceeding 60
%. Figure 12: Status of commercial fish stocks in European
Seas, 2003-2004 (Source:
EEA, 2010) At the global level the FAO (2007) reports
that the proportion of over-exploited and depleted stocks has been rising
during the last 40 years, e.g. from 10% in 1974 to 25% in 2005, although this
trend has moderated in the last 10-15 years. Excess fishing pressure exerted on
these stocks in the past leaves no possibilities in the short- or medium-term
for further expansion, with an increased risk of further declines or even
commercial extinction[199]. Figure 13 represents the status of world fish stocks in 2005. Figure 13: Status of world fish stocks (2005) (Source: FAO, 2007)
3.4.
Land use
There has been a
change in land-cover type on 1.3 % of the total land stock (68 353 km2 of 5.42 million km2) from 2000 to 2006 across 36 European countries. Although the rate of
these changes has slowed down compared to the period 1990 to 2000, the trend of
land use specialisation (urbanisation, agricultural
intensification and abandonment, together with natural afforestation) is still very strong and is expected to continue. The largest relative
increase was of artificial surfaces: they grew with more than 3 % from 2000 to
2006, mainly due to conversions for economic sites and infrastructures.
Internal conversion has been relatively large for forestry, but total forest
area increased only slightly. It has been noted, however, that due to steadily growing demand for wood and wood products, the
ratio of felling over net annual increment (utilisation
rate) could temporarily increase in some European countries to over 100 %,
causing a decline in growing stock after 2020. A temporary high utilisation
rate is not necessarily unsustainable, but given that much of the forest is
relatively old in many Member States, this could turn forests from a carbon
sink into a temporary source. A high utilisation rate could however at the same
time help decreasing instability of aging stands, reducing saturation effects
in old forests and vulnerability to forest fires, storms and pests and,
thereby, counteracting the risk that EU forests turn into a carbon source. As in many other
industrialised regions, the EU is experiencing a long-term trend of decline in
agricultural areas, which are either reforested or developed as urban or
infrastructure land. Arable land and permanent crops as well as pastures and
mosaics decreased with 0.2 and 0.3 % respectively during 2000-2006. Although
land change rate in Europe has slowed down since the 1990s, biodiversity-rich
natural and semi-natural areas continue to decline, mainly due to conversion to
forest but also because of intensification in agriculture. Land use has impacts
on climate with increasing releases of carbon dioxide when soils and natural
vegetation are disturbed, which has direct impacts on biodiversity and
ecosystem services. Unsustainable use of land is furthermore leading to
increased soil degradation and thereby a loss of a fundamental resource.
Several other factors with a negative impact on the soil quality and
biodiversity are working in parallel; organic matter decline, compaction in
agriculture, salinisation, contamination and sealing. Figure 14: Net
land-cover changes 2000–2006 in Europe: total area in hectares (left) and percentage
change from 2000 (right) (Source:
EEA, 2010)
3.5.
Air
Air pollutants make
their way to soil and water and thus deplete ecosystems and biodiversity. Major
sources of air pollution are still the energy sector and road transport.
Emissions of the main air pollutants in Europe have however declined significantly
in recent decades. For example, in 2008 SOx emissions were 72 % below 1990 levels
and emissions of particulate matter decreased by 13 % since 2000. Primarily SO2
mitigation measures have succeeded in considerably reducing the ecosystems area
affected by acidification. However, in terms of
controlling emissions, only 14 European countries expect to comply with all
four pollutant-specific emission ceilings set under EU and international
legislation for 2010. The limit for NOx is the most challenging, which 12
countries expect to exceed. This is e.g. reflected in the fact that nitrogen compounds,
released as NOx and ammonia, are currently the main acidifying components. In
addition, nitrogen contributes to nutrient oversupply in terrestrial as well as
aquatic ecosystems, leading to changes in biodiversity. The area of sensitive
ecosystems affected by excessive atmospheric nitrogen diminished only slightly
between 1990 and 2010. Thus, despite major improvements, Europe still
contributes significantly to global emissions of air pollutants and the complex
links between emissions and ambient air quality moreover means that lower
emissions have not always produced a corresponding drop in atmospheric
concentrations.
4.
Interactions between Resources
As described above,
the use of resources for production and consumption not only impacts on the resource
stock of the inputs, it drives impacts on other resources and their
availability. For example: ·
emissions from the use of fossil fuels lead to
climate impacts that affect fish stocks, fresh water, soils and ecosystems; ·
biomass use puts pressure on land and water
resources and also contributes to climate change and biodiversity loss in
ecosystems - any land-cover changes may have additional considerable effects on
ecosystems; ·
extraction of industrial minerals and ores uses
significant amounts of fossil fuels and often releases toxins; ·
transport and production of bulk construction
materials (eg. cement) contribute to wastes and CO2 emissions. These interactions
are taken into account by Life-Cycle Analysis of resources, products or
services, where information on the impacts at different stages of the
life-cycle from extraction to end-of-life/waste are brought together. The
complexity of interactions and indirect effects makes it difficult to reach
simple conclusions about direct linear causal links between resource input use
(or product consumption) and inputs on other (eg. environmental) resources.
This is possible for impacts directly related to global warming, acidification and
health effects from fossil fuel consumption. But links get more complex the further
consequent impacts are looked at (eg. consequent effects of the use of an
extracted resource, or impacts on fresh water from climate change). There are 4
main reasons for this: 1) Each
resource used has different impacts on other resources The use of one
resource has impacts of different strength on the other resources. Figure 15
indicates this. For example, oil use has a large impact on global warming and
pollution damaging to health, but a relatively low impact on land use. The
diagram shows the relative importance of the impacts of resources listed on the
right viewed by certain metrics of impact. (It demonstrates that the mass of
materials is not necessarily correlated to their impacts – so mass consumed is
not always a good proxy for resource impacts.) Figure 15:
Environmental impact of materials (Source:
International Resource Panel) In the diagram, the
left-hand column shows the impacts of resource use in the economy judged by
mass, the next column the impacts of the same use of resources judged by impact
on climate, the next on land, and the next on human health. The right hand
column shows an amalgamated indicator of the impact of the use of resources on
environmental resources as a whole. 2) Products
are a combination of different resources, from different sources Products made from
many different materials have a correspondingly increased complexity of
impacts. In addition,
resources can be used and produced in different ways or places that bring
different impacts – for example a material can be produced with more or less
material and energy efficient processes. Hydropower can be used for energy in
one country, coal in another. The local geography (e.g. environmental
vulnerability) also affects the impact a process can have. Tracing impacts along
supply chains is possible, but does require simplifications. This can be
illustrated by Figure 16. Looking at only one resource – steel – it can be seen
that products on the right are made from a mix of steels from various different
processes. Considering that products are made up of many materials, each of
which could come through various supply chains with different impacts, a
complex product can have differing degrees of impact. Figure 16:
Global Steel Flows
(Source: Cullen, Allwood et al., The
efficient use of energy: Tracing the global flow of energy from fuel to
service; Energy Policy38 (2010) 75–81 3) Including
the full life-cycle: global impacts Much of the EU
resource base is now located outside the EU, with more than 20 % of resources
used in Europe being imported. Often, only a relative minor part of the
environmental pressures caused by consumption are emitted during the use phase,
the majority is emitted during production, i.e. elsewhere in case of import. An
important part of the impacts on resources from European consumption occurs in
exporting regions. Although caused by European consumption, these pressures are
less visible to European policy makers and will require different sets of
measures than those that may have been adopted to tackle emissions from
domestic production. 4) Aggregating
trends in Resource Impacts Given the
complexity, it is not possible to present clear trends for the full impacts on
environmental resources that use of natural resources inputs may have. This
pushes the limits of scientific knowledge about indirect impacts, and resulting
impacts of the combination of different pressures (on environmental systems, or
health). This is an area needing more research to clarify the potential
impacts. However, sufficient
attribution is possible to link certain consumption activities to major
pressures on environmental resources. These areas are: eating and drinking,
housing and infrastructure, and mobility. It is also possible
to create aggregate indicators that point to particular causes and important
trends. Data for indicators such as EMC (environmentally-weighted material
consumption) and EF (ecological footprint) exist, even though both are
criticised for the methodological weaknesses mentioned. EMC data from 1992 to
2000 suggest that the impact on environmental resources in Europe has remained
fairly constant per capita while it has decreased in relation to GDP, even
though there are large differences across Member States. EF data, which go
back about 50 years, show the resources that are used expressed in global
hectares per person. In the EU, EF has increased from 3.0 in 1961 to 4.7 in
2006. Such data allow us to identify the single largest contributor to
eco-efficiency in Europe as the reduction in coal use. Investigations claim
decoupled air emissions from growth in production with several related
emissions either decreasing or remaining stable during times of continuous
economic growth. A major reason for this decoupling was the shift towards a
service-based economy. This again shows how apparent improvements in the EU may
have been possible by increasing the pressure on environmental resources elsewhere.
Few sources suggest that global impacts from Europe's resource use are going
down.
5.
Drivers
There are 3 key
drivers of resource use: population, economic growth, and resource productivity,
each of which will be described briefly below.
5.1.
Global Trends and Drivers
Increasing materials
use in the EU is part of a global trend. Figure 17 shows global material
extraction for the period from 1900 to 2005 broken down by the four major
material classes: biomass, fossil energy carriers, ores & industrial
minerals and construction. Total material extraction has increased by a factor
of 8. The strongest increase can be observed for construction minerals, which
grew by a factor 34, ores & industrial minerals by a factor 27, and fossil
energy carriers by a factor of 12. Biomass extraction increased 3.6 times[200]. Figure 17: Global material extraction in billion tons, 1900-2005 (Source: Krausmann et al 2009)
5.2.
Population Growth
During the 20th
century, world population increased from 1.65 billion to 6 billion. The global population
growth rate has fallen from its peak of 2 per cent per year to around 1.3 per
cent today, but the annual growth in people is larger every year[201]. Figure 18 shows the evolution of world population during the last
millennium. Figure 19 shows the evolution of EU-27 population. Figure 18: World population 1000-2000 (Source: http://www.theglobaleducationproject.org/earth/human-conditions.php) Figure 19: EU-27 population 1960-2010 (Source: Eurostat, 2011)
5.3.
Economic Development
The world economy
grew more in the last half century than at any time in the past. World GDP
increased six–fold from 1950 to 1998 with an average growth of 3.9 per cent a
year compared with 1.6 from 1820 to 1950, and 0.3 per cent from 1500 to 1820[202]. Figure 20 represents world GDP from 1960 until 2009, at current
market prices. Figure 20: World
GDP 1960-2009 at current market prices (left scale in units of $1.000 million) (Source: World Bank, 2009)
5.4.
Productivity
European economies
are creating more and more wealth from the resources that we use. Resource productivity
in Europe has improved over the past two decades through the use of more
eco-efficient technologies, the transition to service-based economies and an increased
share of imports in EU economies[203]. Figure
21 shows the evolution of the growth in the productivity of labour, energy and
materials from 1970 till 2008. Figure 21: Growth in the productivity of labour, energy and materials
in EU15 and EU12, 1970-2008 (Source:
EEA, 2010) Annex 8:
Modelling for the Roadmap to a Resource Efficient Europe
1.
Existing resource modelling – approaches & tools
The
Communication on the Resource Efficiency Flagship introduced the ambition to: […]
develop a set of tools to allow policy makers to drive forward and monitor
progress. This will help build the clear support and involvement of national,
regional and local authorities, stakeholders and citizens. A
study was commissioned[204]
to explore the possibility of developing a quantitative modelling framework
that could be used to assess Resource Efficiency scenarios, and identify the
policies needed. The study explored the different scenarios used by different
sustainability exercises. It found that there are some aspects of the scenarios
that cannot be quantified under the current knowledge base. However, the
modelling capabilities to carry out the assessment exist and are reasonably
well established. Whilst
for individual resources, there is often good modelling and data, the focus of
future development should be to build on this and improve the linkages between
resources within a single modelling framework (see Figure 1). Whilst there is
already some modelling of interlinkages, this is the weak point of existing
efforts. The new framework should cover both: the key linkages between
different types of resources like materials, energy and climate, fresh water
and land use, soil and biodiversity but also the link between the economy and
the environment. The study concluded with four recommendations: (1)
economic models should include materials by
default; (2)
economic models should develop a modular
framework to provide better detail of key sectors; (3)
a common interface should be developed for
linking models; (4)
some further research is needed to deepen the
understanding of the linkages from environment to economy. As
regards including materials in economic models, two macroeconomic
models, E3ME and GINFORS, already include a treatment of material demands.
Although both these models are econometric in structure, there is no reason
that this development could not also be brought into Computable General Equilibrium
(CGE) models.
2.
Developing a new modelling framework
If
a new modelling framework is to be developed along the lines set out above,
then this is easiest to do if there is a methodology that is clearly
documented and is generally adopted by model developers, with the underlying
assumptions explored to provide good data. The challenge is partially
one of dissemination. There are 3 particular aspects to tackle: 1) To develop a modular framework for economic models: Previous examples of model linkages have been based on a modular
approach, but this has not usually been generalised to a position where modules
can easily be added or removed for a particular assessment. The academic
literature has increasingly been moving in this direction although putting the
recommendations into practice has in general been less successful. This
could be the subject of a research project, but the focus of the work and the
research outputs must be on the methodology used rather than the results for
particular scenarios. If these outputs defined a standard modular framework,
other models could be adapted on this basis. 2) To design a common interface for linking models, there are some general principles that must be adhered to if the
interface is to be widely accepted and used. For example: –
A system must be flexible so that different
types of models can use it. –
The requirements of model operators from
different backgrounds must be taken into account. –
Issues of differences between models in spatial
and sectoral disaggregation and time steps should be addressed. 3) Understanding linkages from environment to economy. Work in this area is already going on for key linkages and
involves determining the key sectors / regions where these occur, and then quantifying
the linkages.
3.
Modelling EU Resource Efficiency
3.1.
An Example of an integrated modelling of
resource efficiency
There is already some modelling of complex resource efficiency
questions. An example is modelling by PBL for the Commission[205], employing a suite of models that have also been used for the
modelling associated with the OECD Environmental Outlook and OECD's Green
Growth work. The study explores the implications of resource efficiency for
five resource themes: energy, land, phosphorus, fresh water, and fish stocks. The results of the study provide a global, model-based analysis of
the impacts of current and projected resource use up to 2050, in the assumed
absence of any additional, targeted policies. The study provides evidence of the
biophysical potential for boosting resource efficiency, in different contexts
of global and EU coordinated action. It concludes that there is substantial
potential to improve efficiency in the use of the resources analysed, compared
to current policy. As examples of outputs, it illustrates that: ·
Global energy use could be reduced by over 30%
in 2050 (see figure 2), compared to policies continued in line with that
envisaged by the EU. As a result, this would halve the gap between baseline
greenhouse gas emissions and the 450 ppm CO2-eq mitigation scenario. It would
require accelerated adoption of best available technologies in industry, new
buildings, household appliances, power and transport sectors, but without major
changes in consumer habits. ·
Net global agricultural expansion between 2010 and
2050 can be halted, with expansion in Africa reduced by half. ·
Global fertilizer phosphorus use from primary
sources can be reduced by 18%, as compared to currently envisaged policies;
total global phosphorus demand could reduce an additional 8% by banning its use
in detergents. ·
Water withdrawals can be reduced by 25%. ·
Fish stocks can be recovered, and marine
biodiversity improved, sustaining higher catches in the long-term. [1] Policy Studies Institute, 2009. Designing policy to
influence consumers: Consumer behaviour relating to the purchasing of
environmentally preferable goods [online]. London: Policy Studies Institute.
Available from: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/pdf/RealWorldConsumerBehaviour.pdf. [2] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010: Consumption and environment, 2010 [3] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010: Consumption and environment, 2010 [4] De
impact van het programma duurzaam inkopen anno 2011 - Vervolgonderzoek naar de
effecten van duurzaam inkopen op markt en milieu (The impact of the programme
bying sustainably 2011 – Follow-up research about the effects on the market and
the environment) [5] http://archive.defra.gov.uk/sustainable/government/advice/public/buying/products/furniture/spec/furniture.htm [6] Price Waterhouse Coopers, Collection of statistical
information on Green Public Procurement in the EU Report on data collection
results, report to DG Environment, 2009,
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/statistical_information.pdf,
page 69 [7] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook
2010: Consumption and environment,2010 [8] "Lags
in the EU economy's response to change", Ecorys, 2011 for the European
Commission [9] Ecorys 2011 Study on the Competitiveness of European
Companies and Resource Efficiency [10] Fischer et al. 2004; ADL et al. 2005; also Aldersgate
Group, 2010 [11] The Economic Benefits of
Resource Efficiency Policy, COWI 2011, forthcoming [12] EIM, 1996. Stimular naar het jaar 2000, een evaluatie
van 5 jaar Stimular [Stimular to the year 2000, an evaluation of 5 years of
Stimular] [13] Ecorys 2011 Study on the Competitiveness of
European Companies and Resource Efficiency [14] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Material resources and waste (p. 22), 2010 [15] http://www.eea.europa.eu/soer/synthesis
p.79 [16] Critical Raw Materials, Ad hoc group of the EU Raw
Materials Supply Group (2010) [17] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Material resources and waste (p. 41), 2010 [18] Bio Intelligence Service 2011, Analysis of the Key
Contributions to Material Efficiency [19] Friends of the Earth Europe, Gone to Waste: The
valuable resources that European countries bury and burn, 2009 [20] Critical Raw Materials, Ad hoc group of the EU Raw
Materials Supply Group (2010) [21] F. Grosse, 'Is recycling "part of the
solution"? The role of recycling in an expanding society and a world of
finite resources', Institut Veolia Environnement, 2010. [22] OECD, 2004, The Economic Impact of ICT [23] OECD,
Green Growth Synthesis (2011) [24] Industrial
symbiosis brings together traditionally separate industries and organisations
from all business sectors with the aim of improving cross industry resource
efficiency and sustainability; involving the physical exchange of materials,
energy, water and/or by-products together with the shared use of assets,
logistics and expertise. See http://www.nisp.org.uk/what_is.aspx
[25] Environmental Technology Verification Impact Assessment [26] 2010,
"Understanding the state of play in financing eco-innovation in the
EU", Cleantech Group
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/ecoinnovation2010/2nd_forum/presentations_en.htm
[27] World Bank/FAO 2009: The sunken billions – the economic
justification for fisheries reform. [28] OECD, Environmentally harmful subsidies: challenges for
reform, 2005 [29] The table should be treated only as an illustration as
estimates are subject to uncertainty, the definition of an EHS is not always
clear, and figures are not available at the EU level in most cases. [30] TEEB – The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity for
National and International Policy Makers, Chapter 6: Reforming subsidies, 2009 [31] OECD, Environmentally harmful subsidies: challenges for
reform, 2005 [32] OECD, Mitigation potential of removing fossil fuel
subsidies - A general equilibrium assessment, 2011 [33] G20, Leader’s Statement: The Pittsburgh Summit, (Preamble,
para 24), 2009 [34] S. Naess-Schmidt and M. Winiarczyk (Copenhagen
Economics),Company car taxation: Subsidies, welfare and environment, Report to
DG TAXUD, 2009 [35] SEC(2009)53
final [36] As a percentage of GDP, environmental taxes accounted
for 2.4% in 2008 as against 2.9% in 1999, when they reached their peak level
(Eurostat data) [37] Taxation Trends in the European union, 2011, European
Commission [38] Innovation of energy technologies: the role of taxes,
Copenhagen Economics, 2010 [39] Taxation, Innovation and the Environment, OECD (2010) [40] ibid [41] OECD 2006 Boosting Jobs and Incomes, Policy lessons
from Reassessing the OECD Jobs Strategy [42] OECD. Green Growth Synthesis, based on OECD,
ENV-linkages model [43] SEC(2009)53
final [44] COM(2011)112 and SEC(2011)288, in particular sections
2.3 and 5.2.3 [45] The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity.
Mainstreaming the economics of nature. A synthesis of the approach, conclusions
and recommendations of TEEB [46] WBCSD(2010) Vision 2050: New Agenda for Business. World
Business Council for Sustainable Development [47] http://bankofnaturalcapital.com/category/ecosystem-services
[48] EU 2010 Biodiversity baseline. [49] European Commission’s Green Paper on the Reform of the
Common Fisheries Policy [50] The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity.
Mainstreaming the economics of nature. A synthesis of the approach, conclusions
and recommendations of TEEB. [51] International Union for Conservation of Nature (IUCN)
quoted at http://www.eea.europa.eu/themes/biodiversity/where-we-stand/threats [52] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Water, 2010 [53] EEA 2010 State of the Environment Report (SOER), Water,
key messages. [54] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Water, 2010 [55] Source Wada et al. (2010) Global depletion of
groundwater resources
(http://tenaya.ucsd.edu/~tdas/data/review_iitkgp/2010GL044571.pdf) [56] ClimWatAdapt project [57] T. Dvorak et al.(Ecologic - Institute for International
and European Environmental Policy), EU Water saving potential, Report for DG
Environment, 2007 (http://ec.europa.eu/environment/water/quantity/pdf/water_saving_1.pdf) [58] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [59] BDEW, 2010 and Statistics Denmark, 2006 [60] European Environment Agency, 2010. The European
environment – State and outlook 2010: Synthesis pp. 96-100 [61] WHO –Health and Environment in Europe: Progress
Assessment (2010), ISBN 978 92 890 4198 0 [62] COM(2010)
265 final [63] See
UNEP (2010) "Measures to Limit Near-Term Climate Change and Improve Air
Climate: An Integrated Assessment of Black Carbon and Tropospheric Ozone" which
is the first assessment that actually shows this in a quantitative way. [64] European Environment Agency, 2010. The European
environment – State and outlook 2010. Synthesis pp. 96-100. Copenhagen. Via http://www.eea.europa.eu/soer. [65] Directive 2001/81/EC [66] Study on the Competitiveness of the EU eco-industry
–Within the Framework Contract of Sectoral Competitiveness Studies – ENTR/06/054.
Available at
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/eco_industry/pdf/report%20_2009_competitiveness_part1.pdf [67] For a detailed analysis see SEC(2011)288, in particular
section 5.2.14. [68] Land Use/Cover Area frame Survey (LUCAS), conducted in
2009. Land was surveyed in 23 EU Member States, where both the physical
cover of the land and its visible socio-economic use were recorded [69] Prokop et al (2011) [70] Gardi, Ciro,
Claudio Bosco, and Ezio Rusco (2009), Urbanizzazione e sicurezza alimentare, Estimo
e Territorio, 11:44-47. [71] Eurostat Farm Structure Survey 2007 [72] JRC
IPTS AGLINK study [73] (based on 2009 CO2 price, i.e. €20/tCO2). [74] Peatlands
in EU-27: 318,000 km²; EU-27 surface area: 4.2 million km². See also Schils et
al. (2008), Review of existing information on the interrelations between soil
and climate change (CLIMSOIL), Final report to DG Environment (http://ec.europa.eu/environment/soil/review_en.htm),
p. 71. [75] Reflection
paper p. 14 [76] Soil –
a key resource for the EU (http://ec.europa.eu/environment/pubs/pdf/factsheets/soil2.pdf). [77] SEC(2006)
620. [78] SEC(2006) 1165. [79] SEC(2006) 620. [80] PESERA (Pan–European Soil
Erosion Risk Assessment) model, covers 21 Member States [81] SEC (2006) 620 [82] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Thematic Assessment - Soil, 2010 [83] COM(2010) 715. [84] European
Commission, Facts and Figures on the Common Fisheries Policy. Basic Statistical
Data. ISSN 1830-91192010 edition. [85] European
Commission, Facts and Figures on the Common Fisheries Policy. Basic Statistical
Data. ISSN 1830-91192010 edition. [86] The economic value of sustainable benefits from the Mediterranean
marine ecosystems, Blue Plan. Sophia Antipolis, May 2010 [87] Marine
Biotechnology: Marine Board, A New Vision and Strategy for Europe, September
2010, http://www.esf.org/marineboard [88] European Commission (2008) Directorate-General for
Maritime Affairs and Fisheries ‘CFP Reform’. Green Paper: Reform of the Common
Fisheries Policy, COM (2009)163. [89] EEA. Status
of marine fish stocks (CSI 032) - Assessment published Feb 2009. [90] Thurstan, R.H., Brockington, S. & Roberts, C.M.
(2010) The effects of 118 years of industrial fishing on UK bottom trawl
fisheries. Nature Communications, 1(2) p15. [91] The
State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2008. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture
Department, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome,
2009. [92] Worm,
B., Barbier, E.B., Beaumont, N., Duffy, E., Folke, C., Halpern, B.S., Jackson,
J.B.C., Lotze, H.K., Micheli, F., Palumbi, S.R., Sala, E., Selkoe, K.A., Stachowicz,
J.J. & Watson, R. (2006) Impacts of biodiversity loss on ocean ecosystem
services. Science, 314 (5800), p787. [93] FAO Newsroom (2008) Half of world fish trade sourced
from developing countries. [94] Eurostat – includes EU aquaculture
production. Eurostat statistics © European Communities
(1990–2006). [95] Fish dependence, Ocean2012 p.16-18 [96] World
Ocean review : Marine minerals and energy http://worldoceanreview.com/wp-content/downloads/WOR_chapter_7.pdf
[97] UNEP, Ecosystems and Biodiversity in Deep Waters and
High Seas, 2006 [98] "Plastic ingestion by mesopelagic fishes in the
North Pacific Subtropical Gyre", Peter Davison, Rebecca G. Asch, 2011 [99] Tukker, A. et al. (2006).
Environmental Impact of Products (EIPRO). EC Joint Research Centre - IPTS [100] http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/index_en.htm [101] Eurostat Household Budget Survey [102] European Commission, (2009) publication Trade and
agriculture – an overview of EU imports and exports based on EUROSTAT COM,
2008. Available at:
trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/cfm/doclib_section.cfm?sec=175&langId=en [103] UNEP (2010) Assessing the Environmental Impacts of
Consumption and Production: Priority Products and Materials, A Report of the
Working Group on the Environmental Impacts of Products and Materials to the
International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management. Hertwich, E., van der
Voet, E., Suh, S., Tukker, A., Huijbregts M., Kazmierczyk, P., Lenzen, M.,
McNeely, J., Moriguchi, Y. [104] EEA, The
European Environment – State and Outlook 2010: Synthesis, 2010 [105] Van der Voer et al, 2005 [106] EEA, The
European Environment – State and Outlook 2010: Synthesis, 2010 [107] S. Moll, D. Watson et al., Environmental pressures from
European consumption and production: A study in integrated environmental and
economic analysis, ETC/SCP working paper 1/2009 [108] S. Moll, D. Watson et al., Environmental pressures from
European consumption and production: A study in integrated environmental and
economic analysis, ETC/SCP working paper 1/2009 [109] Preparatory
study for the review of the thematic strategy on the sustainable use of natural
resources, Bio Intelligence Services, 2010, http://ec.europa.eu/environment/natres/pdf/BIO_TSR_FinalReport.pdf
[110] UNEP
(2010) Assessing the Environmental Impacts of Consumption and Production:
Priority Products and Materials, A Report of the Working Group on the
Environmental Impacts of Products and Materials to the International Panel for
Sustainable Resource Management. [111] J.
Gustavsson et al., Global food losses and food waste, FAO, 2011 [112] BIO Intelligence Service (2010) Preparatory study on
food waste across EU27 [113] WRAP,
Waste arisings in the supply of food and drink to households in the UK, 2010 [114] WRAP, Waste arisings in the supply of food and drink to
households in the UK, 2010 [115] UNEP,
The Enviornmental Food crises: Environment's role in averting future food
crises, 2009 [116] FAO, Livestock's long shadow, Livestock Environment And
Development (LEAD) Initiative, 2006 [117] FAO,
Livestock's long shadow, Livestock Environment And Development (LEAD)
Initiative, 2006 [118] Some 306
of the 825 terrestrial ecoregions identified by the Worldwide Fund for Nature
(WWF) reported livestock as one of the current threats. In addition 23 out of
35 global hotspots – identified by Conservation International – are reported to
be affected by livestock production. According to the International Union for
Conservation of Nature (IUCN) most of the world's threatened species are
suffering habitat loss where livestock are. (FAO, Livestock's long shadow,
Livestock Environment And Development (LEAD) Initiative, 2006) [119] FAO, Livestock's long shadow, Livestock Environment And
Development (LEAD) Initiative, 2006 [120] FAO,
Livestock's long shadow, Livestock Environment And Development (LEAD)
Initiative, 2006 [121] B.P.
Weidema et al., Environmental Improvement Potentials of Meat and Dairy Products
(IMPRO), JRC, 2008 [122] WHO 2007 [123] See also the Lancet paper of 12th September
2007 "Slash global meat consumption to tackle climate change"
stating that not more than 50 g per day should come from red meat provided by
cattle, sheep, goats and other ruminants. [124] D. Cordell et al., The story of phosphorus: Global food
security and food for thought, Global Environmental Change vol. 19 p. 292-305,
2009 [125] PBL Netherlands Environment Agency, Scarcity in a Sea of
Plenty? Global Resource Scarcities and Policies in the European Union and the
Netherlands, 2011 [126] Minemakers Limited, 2008
quoted in D. Cordell et al., The story of phosphorus: Global food security
and food for thought, Global Environmental Change vol. 19 p. 292-305, 2009 [127] PBL
(2011) EU Resource Efficiency Perspectives in a Global Context: A fast track analysis. Forthcoming
(will be available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/studies.htm) [128] European
Construction Industries Federation [129] ETAP, 2007; BUILD-NOVA, 2006a
quoted in S. Jofre (Technical University of Denmark),
The challenge of a greener European construction sector: Views on
technology-driven (eco)innovation, 2011 [130] S. Moll, D. Watson et al., Environmental pressures from
European consumption and production: A study in integrated environmental and
economic analysis, ETC/SCP working paper 1/2009 [131] Action in line with the Energy
Performance of Buildings Directive alone would reduce direct CO2 emissions by
160 to 210 Mt per year (IA of the EPBD) [132] Sustainable
Competitiveness of the Construction Sector (2010) Ecorys [133] OECD,
Environmentally sustainable buildings: Challenges and policies, 2003 [134] Bell et al., 1996 quoted in OECD, Environmentally
sustainable buildings: Challenges and policies, 2003 [135] Directive 2010/31/EU [136] In line with Art. 9 of Directive 2010/31/EU of 19 May
2010 on the energy performance of buildings [137] In line with Art 11 of Directive 2008/98/EC of 19 November
2010 on waste. [138] E.g. the European Re-Building
Forum, run by the Resource Efficiency Alliance. [139] COM(2011)144,
White Paper: Roadmap to a Single European Transport Area – Towards a
competitive and resource efficient transport system [140] This would also substantially reduce other harmful
emissions [141] UNEP Green Economy Synthesis 2010 [142] OECD
Green Growth Synthesis 2010 [143] OECD Green Growth Synthesis 2011 [144] Roadmap to a Low Carbon Economy (2011) [145] COM (2011) 363 [146] OECD, 2010 Leveraging training and skill development
activities in SMEs – Cross country analysis of the TSME survey, CFE/LEED [147] Programmes
to promote environmental skills (2010) , Ecorys [148] COWI (2011) 'The costs of not implementing the
environmental acquis' [149] Data from from National Footprint Accounts 2010 edition,
WWF and Global Footprint Network., retrievable at www.footprintnetwork.org [150] Bio Intelligences Service, Addressing the rebound
effect, April 2011 (for the European Commission) [151] UNEP, 2002; IEA, 2005; 4CMR, 2006; EEA, 2009; DECC, 2010;
EEA, 2010 [152] Sorrell, 2007; UKERC, 2007 [153] Estimates of indirect and economy wide rebound were only
found for energy efficiency improvements, and are limited due to few published
studies with weaknesses in the measurement approach (Sorrell, 2007; Allan et
al, 2006; Barker, 2005). [154] Greening et al, 2000; Schipper and Grubb, 2000; UKERC,
2007; Sorrell, 2007; Small and van Dender, 2007 [155] Gately 1990, Graham & Glaister 2002, Anson &
Turner 2009 [156] Environmental Improvement Potentials of Meat and Dairy
Products, JRC, 2008 [157] This negative rebound effect means that the net
environmental benefit would be greater than planned. It occurs because the
policy measure increases the production and consumption costs. [158] 4CMR, 2006 [159] Saunders, 2010 [160] Sorrell, 2007; EEA, 2010 [161] DMC is defined as Domestic Material Consumption. [162] E.g. Landscape Ecosystem Potential or Ecosystem
Degradation under development by the EEA [163] The life cycle based resource-efficiency indicators
under development by the Commission's JRC is one key option the Commission will
consider [164] COM (2009) 433 "GDP and beyond" and www.beyond-gdp.eu [165] Report of the Commission on the
Measurement of Economic Performance et Social Progress (CMEPSP), see
http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/en/index.htm
[166] This indicator has limitations; e.g. it aggregates
different water resources, it does not take into account the nature of the
water use after abstraction, the commonly used threshold values are under
discussion. The Commission is exploring alternatives, which are however not yet
fully available. Awaiting improvements, the WEI will be further used. [167] The relevant data is provided in an appendix to this
document. [168] http://www.cbd.int/sp/
[169] "Our life insurance, our
natural capital: an EU biodiversity strategy to 2020". COM(2011)244. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/nature/biodiversity/comm2006/2020.htm [170] The Commission will publish a
Blueprint for Safeguarding Europe's Waters (2012). [171] http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/.
[172] http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/land-take-2/assessment. [173] http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/soil-erosion-by-water/soil-erosion-by-water-assessment. [174] http://eusoils.jrc.ec.europa.eu/library/themes/erosion/. [175] http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/lucas/introduction
and http://eusoils.jrc.ec.europa.eu/projects/Lucas/. [176] http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/progress-in-management-of-contaminated-sites/progress-in-management-of-contaminated-1. [177] COM(2011)244 [178] Developed by the ETC/SCP for the EEA, http://scp.eionet.europa.eu/announcements/ann1298365469,
based on Eurostat data. [179] http://www.unep.org/resourcepanel/Publications/PriorityProducts/tabid/56053/Default.aspx [180] http://www.pbl.nl/sites/default/files/cms/publicaties/Protein_Puzzle_web_1.pdf [181] Calculated based on data in the
preparatory study on food waste in the EU27, http://ec.europa.eu/environment/eussd/reports.htm [182] Developed by the ETC/SCP for the EEA, http://scp.eionet.europa.eu/announcements/ann1298365469.
The data is held by Enerdat Odyssee database and the
indicator is available for 27 EU MS except of one trend line for growth in
floor area available only for 19 EU MS. [183] Article 9 of the Directive
2010/31/EU on the energy performance of buildings (recast) [184] Repealing Directives 2004/8/EC
and 2006/32/EC, see COM(2011) 370 final of 22.6.2011 [185] 2011 Progress Report prepared by ETC/SCP for the EEA, http://scp.eionet.europa.eu/announcements/ann1298365469
[186] The definitions of 'Core' and
'broad' SRI can be found in the 2011 Progress report on SCP prepared by ETC/SCP
for the EEA. To date the
indicator covers 14 EU MS (for 2010) and is based on the data from the Eurosif database.
This indicator would need further processing but is a good proxy for private
funding for the transition. [187] Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, Scarcity
amidst a Sea of Plenty?, 2010 [188] European Commission – DG Enterprise and Industry, Critical
raw materials for the EU, 2010 [189] Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, Scarcity
amidst a Sea of Plenty?, 2010 [190] "Import dependence is calculated as “net imports /
(net imports + production in EU)" European Commission – DG Enterprise and
Industry, Critical raw materials for the EU, 2010 [191] International Resource Panel,, Metal Stocks in Society –
Scientific Synthesis, 2010 [192] Dutch Environmental Assessment Agency, Scarcities in a
sea of plenty: Global resource scarcities and policies in the EU and the
Netherlands, 2010 [193] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [194] Staff Working Document with the Thematic strategy on the
prevention and recycling of waste (2005) [195] Recycling Rates of Metals :
A Status Report, International Resource Panel, 2011 [196] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [197] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [198] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [199] OECD, Environmental Outlook to 2030, 2008 [200] International Resource Panel, Decoupling the use of
natural resources and environmental impacts from economic activity: Scoping the
challenges, 2010 [201] United Nations, The world at six billion, 1999 [202] OECD (A. Maddison), The World Economy: A millennial
perspective, 2001 [203] EEA, The European Environment – State and Outlook 2010:
Synthesis, 2010 [204] Cambridge Econometrics, Wuppertal Institute and SERI
(2011). Sustainability Scenarios for a Resource Efficient Europe. Forthcoming,
will be available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/studies.htm [205] PBL
(2011). EU Resource Efficiency Perspectives in a Global Context: A fast track analysis. Forthcoming, will be available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/studies.htm