This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52012SC0196
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Executive summary of the Impact Assessment Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the protection of the financial interests of the European Union by criminal law
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Executive summary of the Impact Assessment Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the protection of the financial interests of the European Union by criminal law
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Executive summary of the Impact Assessment Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the protection of the financial interests of the European Union by criminal law
/* /2012/0196 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Executive summary of the Impact Assessment Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the protection of the financial interests of the European Union by criminal law /* /2012/0196 final */
1........... Problem definition. 3 2........... Analysis of the
subsidiarity principle. 4 3........... Main policy objectives. 4 4........... Policy options. 5 4.1........ Assessment of the policy
options' impacts. 6 4.2........ The preferred option. 7 4.3........ Monitoring and evaluation. 8
1.
Problem definition
The EU
and the Member States have an obligation to counter fraud and any other illegal
activities affecting the financial interests of the Union. This obligation is
laid down in Art. 310(6) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
(TFEU). Article 325 TFEU further requires the adoption of measures which should
act as a deterrent and afford a level playing field. The EU already
has a set of legal instruments requiring Member States to establish minimum
criminal law rules for the protection of EU financial interests (in particular
the Convention on the protection of the Communities' financial interests of
1995, on fraud, and protocols on corruption and money laundering). Nevertheless,
those instruments have proved insufficient for achieving the desired protection,
thus affecting EU's credibility in its budgetary restraint efforts. In
particular, they only cover a limited sub-section of illegal conduct at the
expense of EU financial interests, therefore missing out on many relevant
phenomena which have been regularly encountered in practical experience. The current framework is not yet strong enough to curb the loss of taxpayer
money allocated to the EU, both on revenue and expenditure side. A good example
of this fact is that a total of 13,631 cases of illegal activities involving EU
funds (so-called "irregularities") took place in 2010. These reported
cases caused a cumulated volume of wrongfully collected and spent EU public
money of approximately € 2 billion. The various
deficiencies in the means of protecting EU public money relate to the following
aspects: · insufficient deterrent effect of provisions protecting EU financial
interests; · enforcement gaps of existing prohibitions, stemming from low
detection capacities of criminal activities and low follow-up levels, as the
outcomes of judicial proceedings are on avarage remarkably modest; and · low recovery rates of money gone astray. From a
substantive criminal law perspective, the underlying causes of the
abovementioned problems are varied. · Firstly, there is an insufficient breadth of existing criminal
offences aimed at protecting EU financial interests, in terms of determining
who is subject to liability and the necessary jurisdictional rules to prosecute
crimes committed abroad. · Secondly, the set of criminal offences is incomplete, not only due
to an insufficient implementation of existing definitions, but also to an
insufficient number of offences at all defined at EU level, which can lead even
to a total lack of protection against certain types of illegal conduct. · Thirdly, the types and levels of sanctions are often too low, and in
any event strongly diverging across the Member States. In addition to the
resulting lack of deterrence and the unfairness of sanctioning discrepancies,
the lack of level playing field also reduces mutual trust of judicial
authorities who need to cooperate to solve cross-border cases relating to EU
financial interests. · Finally, there are excessive impediments to the application of
criminal law. In particular, despite the complex financial investigations which
justify the time taken for prosecution, cases have become time-barred and had
to be closed while trial was already ongoing. The financial interests of the EU have been negatively affected
because money due to the EU is not collected for it, or is misallocated in
breach of legal rules. Illegal activities are serious and frequent enough to
warrant additional safeguards. For all the
reasons described above, a resolute response is required in order to set a
common and proportionate level of protection by deterrence. This will
strengthen the effectiveness of EU budgetary and financing rules and ultimately
benefit the overall credibility of EU finance, and criminal justice, by setting
a level playing field throughout the EU.
2.
Analysis of the subsidiarity principle
The EU financial interests relate to assets
and liabilities managed by or on behalf of the EU. As they are by nature,
placed at EU level, they cannot reasonably be protected by the Member States
alone. Anti-fraud is a shared responsibility of the EU and the Member States. The EU is best
placed to evaluate which measures are needed and proportionate to protect its
financial interests, taking into account the specific EU rules which apply in
this field. This applies
also to the extent that criminal law provisions for the protection of EU
financial interests are to be harmonised. Only the EU is in a position to
develop a level playing field through binding legislation with effect
throughout the Member States, and thus to create a legal framework which would
contribute to overcoming the weaknesses of the current situation. The particular
added value of EU provisions on criminal law in this area could reside in the
novelty of defining relevant additional offences and sanction types and levels,
which would apply equivalently throughout the Member States, thus completing
and learning the lessons from monitoring the implementation of the Convention
on the protection of the Communities' financial interests.
3.
Main policy objectives
Based on the problems identified, a series
of general, specific and operational objectives may be identified: General objectives:
To prevent and reduce loss of money for the EU
To increase credibility of EU budgetary
responsibility
Specific objectives:
To appropriately increase deterrence of
prohibitions relating to the EU financial interests, in compliance with
the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights
To better enforce the prohibitions of certain
conducts illegally affecting EU public money by improving investigation
results, including identification of suspects and detection of
beneficiaries of illegal transactions, in
compliance with the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights
To adequately improve levels recovery of EU
public money subject to illegal acts, in
compliance with the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights
To ensure equivalence and fairness of provisions
protecting EU financial interests across the EU
To contribute to increasing mutual trust between
the Member States' judiciaries
To increase awareness of the rules governing the
protection of EU financial interests among investigators and potential
perpetrators
Operational
objectives:
It should provide
sufficiently wide scope to cover the groups of perpetrators which most
seriously and/or frequently damage EU public money
It should adequately
enlarge the number of offences so as to cover the most seriously damaging
and/or frequent types of conduct affecting EU pubmic money
It should provide for
sanction types and levels sufficient to ensure fairness in the protection
of EU public money everywhere in the EU, whilst ensuring proportionality
It should contain clear
and appropriate flanking rules to facilitate enforcement
4.
Policy options
Five options have been considered in detail:
Option 1: Retention of the status quo (base-line scenario) as combined with a
continued monitoring of the implementation of existing instruments. Option 2: Non-legislative action to raise awareness of relevant provisions
among potential perpetrators and practitioners, and facilitate their understanding
and application including by an exchange of best practices and case
information. Option 3: A legislative instrument converting the PIF Convention and its
protocols into an instrument under the new Treaty rules, while improving
consistency of the provisions contained therein. Option 4: A legislative instrument requiring Member States to approximate
their criminal law rules with a view to appropriate expansion of the scope,
introduction of specific new offence types, strengthening of minimum sanction
types and levels for the protection of EU financial interests. Option 5: A legislative instrument with directly applicable substantive
criminal law provisions for the protection of EU financial interests, including
precise sanction brackets (with minimum and maximum levels).
4.1.
Assessment of the policy options' impacts
Option 1: The effectiveness of this option in meeting the purported
objectives is, however, very low, if not inexistent. This policy option is not
expected to impact upon fundamental rights, the domestic justice systems, or
the economic and financial fields more than the current legal framework. Option 2: The effectiveness of this option is deemed to be low because
additional deterrence and enforcement effects cannot be created where criminal
law now does not apply. The impact on fundamental
rights is expected to be low to medium.The economic and
financial impacts are estimated to be + € 37 million at EU level due to more
efficient follow-up of cases by Member State judiciaries leading to better
recovery levels, with € 3 million extra costs, in particular for training
measures, for the Commission. This policy option fulfils the proportionality
requirement. Option 3: This policy option is only modestly effective and is not expected
to impact upon fundamental rights, nor on the domestic justice systems,
substantially more than the current framework. A
positive impact on EU budget of an estimated € 17 million as a result of better
enforcement and recovery in return for an estimated € 3 million cost of the
legislative process at Member States level can be estimated. Balancing the great structural relevance for the integrity,
spending capacity and reputation of the EU and the minimal additional
intrusiveness compared to the existing framework, it is possible to assert that
the measure is proportionate to the objective pursued. However, its added value
for the protection of the taxpayer’s money is very limited. Option 4: This option can be expected to have medium
to high effectiveness in reducing losses of EU money and in restoring
credibility of budgetary restraint efforts, without however taking all theoretically
possible criminal law measures nor fully harmonising the sanction types and
levels. Wider definitions of existing offences improve
equivalence of the sanctioning playing field across the EU, mutual trust
between the judiciaries is improved and thus facilitate enforcement and recovery
in cross-border cases. Defining broader and new relevant criminal offence
types, as well as and more stringent sanction types and levels concerning the
losses of EU financial resources, will mean that deterrence from such
acts is likely to be very high. These common definitions and minimum sanction
rules also improve equivalence of the sanctioning playing field across the EU
and thus mutual trust between the judiciaries, which facilitates enforcement
and recovery in cross-border cases. The option would
have a medium impact on fundamental rights , in that new criminal offences and
extended scope of application for existing offences are defined, while the
minimum sanction types and levels are being strengthened. These measures serve
to meet objectives of general interest recognised by the Union (see Article 52
para. 1 of the Charter), and in particular to provide effective and deterring
measures for the protection of EU financial interests. In the context of
increasing amounts of irregularities and fraud suspicion and in light of the
ineffectiveness of the current measures under the PIF Convention, the measures
do not go beyond what is necessary to achieve this objective. A high return of
€ 471 million at EU level is estimated due to better deterrence (reducing the
money lost), enforcement and recovery (increasing the money returned), for a relatively
low organisational and administrative cost of € 29 million, in particular for
legislative work, at Member State level. Given the
weighing between the great structural relevance of protecting EU public money
for the integrity, spending capacity and reputation of the EU, on one hand, and
the adequate increased coverage by criminal offence definitions and credible
minimum sanction levels, on the other hand, the proportionality criterion is
respected. As this policy
option considerably impacts on deterrence, enforcement capabilities and
recovery levels, it is deemed to have medium to high effectiveness. Option 5: The effectiveness of this option is considered to be as high as
option 4 in that it would apply broader and new definitions of offences,
provide for sufficient sanctions types and levels and contain rules
facilitating application of the criminal offences. This would considerably
positively impact upon deterrence, enforcement capabilities and recovery
levels. The impact on fundamental rights and criminal justice systems of this
policy option is medium as for option 4, with the additional impact that an EU
legislation as such would become directly applicable for criminal prosecution
and conviction. The domestic
justice systems would be substantially impacted upon, since national criminal
justice authorities would need to directly implement EU criminal law Offences.
Economic and
financial impacts are expected to similar as for option 4. Given the
weighing between the great structural relevance of protecting EU public money
for the integrity, spending capacity and reputation of the EU, on one hand, and
the adequate increased coverage by criminal offence definitions and credible
minimum sanction levels, on the other hand, the proportionality criterion
should be complied with, although the intrusiveness and fundamental rights
impact is higher than in Option 4 for no noticeably higher positive financial
impact.
4.2.
The preferred option
A comparative
assessment of the impacts mentioned above leads to the conclusion that both
Options 4 and 5 are effective in achieving all the general and specific objectives.
In terms of efficiency, however, option 4 is less intrusive with respect to
Member States' judicial systems. → The main difference between option 4 and option 5 lies in the varying leeway for Member States, who under option 4 may largely maintain for PIF offences their normal criminal law system and drafting approach and surpass the severity of the EU text, whilst option 5 is characterised by exhaustive rigidity of the EU rules, which would have to be applied as such by the Member States' prosecutors and criminal courts Policy Option 4 || Policy Option 5 · Directive || · Regulation · would ensure widened protection, whilst allowing Member States to go further || · would provide a single, immovable set of rules on the criminal law protection of EU financial interests · would provide minimum definitions of offences, on which Member States can expand, for instance by adding serious cases or liability for negligent conduct || · would impose exhaustive definitions of the offence types covered · would contain minimum rules on sanction types and levels || · would lay down rigid sanction types and levels · would contain ancillary provisions to be transposed by the Member States in keeping with their legal traditions || · would contain an exhaustive and isolated set of ancillary provisions, in some cases possibly different from national criminal legislation traditions, and to be found elsewhere than in the national criminal code · Member States' prosecutors and courts would apply the national transposing measures in the national criminal legislation || · Member States' authorities would apply the provisions of the Regulation directly Therefore,
option 4 is the preferred option. The preferred
option would increase the protection of EU financial interests, both by
expanding criminal law protection into areas of serious and/or particularly
harmful illegal activities which are not now covered by the PIF Convention, and
by providing for appropriate minimum sanction levels applicable for both the
existing and new offence types, thus ensuring a level playing field and clarity
of legislation across the EU. Option 4 is
proportionate in relation to its legitimate objectives, as none of the
alternative options display an equal level of efficient combination of limited
costs and effectiveness in reaching the objectives identified in section 3
above. Whilst the preferred option of legislative action is likely to require a
number of Member States to introduce changes to their criminal laws in order to
implement the Directive, there does not appear to be another equally effective
means of achieving the general and specific policy objectives.
4.3.
Monitoring and evaluation
Potential risks
to implementation by Member States in keeping with the transposition period are
set out and addressed in an implementation plan accompanying the proposal. An adequate
monitoring and evaluation mechanism is envisaged, whereby Member States would
be required to report on the effective implementation of legislative or
non-legislative measures based on the nature of the proposed changes. Data
provided by the Member States (in accordance with Article 325(5) TFEU) Eurostat,
Eurobarometer, the future European Criminal Records System (ECRS) and the
Council of Europe will enable the formation of a useful baseline for monitoring
the situation, and allow ex post assessment of the impact of this initiative by
comparison to figures reported by Member States before its entry into force.
Besides quantitative data provided by Member States, other possible sources of
qualitative information on legislative and practical compliance will be
gathered from the Member States reporting on fraud, the Justice Forum, The
European Anti-Fraud Office (OLAF) and Eurojust. A specific
empirical study with emphasis on data collection will be carried out by the
Commission, one to three years from the date of implementation of the proposal.