This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52011SC1565
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Impact Assessment
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Impact Assessment
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Impact Assessment
/* SEC/2011/1565 final - */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER Impact Assessment /* SEC/2011/1565 final - */
Annex 1 Scenarios – assumptions and results Part B: Decarbonisation scenarios. 2 1. Assumptions. 2 1.1 Macroeconomic and demographic assumptions. 2 1.2 Energy import prices. 2 1.3 Policy assumptions. 3 1.4 Assumptions about energy infrastructure development 7 1.5 Technology assumptions. 7 1.6 Drivers. 9 2. Results. 9 2.1 Overview: outcome for the four main strategic
directions to decarbonisation. 9 2.2 Energy consumption and supply structure. 13 2.3 Power generation. 20 2.4 Other sectors. 31 2.5 Security of supply. 34 2.6 Policy related indicators. 36 2.7 Overall system costs, competitiveness and other
socio-economic impacts. 39 2.8 Conclusions. 53 Attachment 1: Numerical results. 56 Attachment 2: Assumptions about interconnections and
modelling of electricity trade. 78 Attachment 3: Short description of the models used. 85
Part
B: Decarbonisation scenarios
1.
Assumptions
1.1 Macroeconomic and demographic
assumptions
On the basis of
the European Council's objective for EU decarbonisation of at least 80% below 1990 by 2050 in the context of necessary
reductions by developed countries as a group[1]
it is assumed that competitiveness effects throughout decarbonisation would be
rather limited. Therefore, the decarbonisation scenarios are based on the same
demographic and macroeconomic assumptions as the Reference scenario and Current
Policy Initiatives scenario. Such an assumption also facilitates comparison of
the energy results across scenarios. These macro-economic (sectoral production)
assumptions also hold for energy intensive industries. However, under
fragmented action, measures against carbon leakage may be necessary. The
analysis of this particular case (see below) deals with energy and emission
effects of such measures, but does not address potential changes in sectoral
production levels under fragmented action. The aim of measures against carbon
leakage is indeed to avoid such relocation of energy intensive production.
1.2 Energy import prices
The
decarbonisation scenarios are based on "global climate action" price
trajectories for oil, gas and coal[2]
reflecting that global action on decarbonisation will reduce fossil fuel demand
worldwide and will therefore have a downward effect on fossil fuel prices. Oil,
gas and coal prices are therefore lower than in the Reference scenario and
Current Policy Initiative scenario. Their trajectories are an outcome of the
global analysis in the Low carbon Economy Roadmap, which is similar to recent
IEA projections that assessed the impacts of ambitious climate policies[3]. Figure 18: Fossil fuel prices in the decarbonisation scenarios
1.3 Policy assumptions
In addition to
policy assumptions in the Current Policy Initiatives scenario, the following
policies and measures were added to scenarios: Table 15 Measures included in all
decarbonisation scenarios 1 || Climate policies for respecting carbon constraints to reach 85% energy related CO2 reductions by 2050 (40% by 2030), consistent with 80% reduction of total GHG emissions according to the "Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050" (including achievement of cumulative carbon cap) in a cost effective way || Supplementary to specific energy policies in the scenario, ETS prices and carbon values for non ETS sectors are determined in such a way as to reach the 2050 reduction goal; ETS and non ETS sectors use equal carbon prices/values (from 2025 onwards); cumulative emissions are similar across scenarios 2 || Stronger RES facilitation policies || Represented by higher RES-values in the model. These facilitating RES policies include for example the availability of more sites for RES, easier licensing of RES installations, greater acceptance and support deriving from the improvement of local economies and industrial development; operational aids remain at the same level as in the REF/CPI scenarios. 3 || Transport measures || Energy efficiency standards, internal market, infrastructure, pricing and transport planning measures leading to more fuel-efficient transport means and some modal shift Encourage the deployment of clean energy carriers by establishing the necessary supporting infrastructures[4] 4 || Guarantee funds for all low carbon generation technologies || The model reflects support to early demonstration and first of a kind commercial plants for all innovative low-carbon technologies in the energy sector (nuclear, RES and their infrastructure needs, CCS, etc.). 5 || Storage and interconnections || Higher penetration of variable generation leading occasionally to excess electricity is dealt with by increased pump storage and more interconnection capacity. Moreover, large parts of such excess electricity generation from variable sources is transformed into hydrogen, which is fed, up to a certain degree, into the natural gas grid, thereby providing a means for (indirect) storage of electricity and reducing the carbon content of gas delivered to final consumers enabling deeper emission cuts. Where for technical or economic reasons, simulated in the model, feeding into the natural gas grid is not feasible, excess electricity (mainly from RES) is stored in form of hydrogen at times of excess supply and transformed back into electricity when demand exceeds supply. (Hydrogen storage is used to a different degree in various decarbonisation scenarios, see also measures under Scenario 4). Scenario 2: High energy efficiency This scenario is driven by a political commitment of very
high primary energy savings by 2050. It includes a very stringent
implementation of the Energy Efficiency Plan and aims at reaching close to 20%
energy savings by 2020. Strong energy efficiency policies are also pursued
thereafter. Table 16 Policies/measures included (in
addition to measures in table 15): || Measure || How it is reflected in the model 1 || Additional strong minimum requirements for appliances || Progressive adaptation of modelling parameters for different product groups. As requirements concern only new products, the effect will be gradual. 2 || High renovation rates for existing buildings due to better/more financing and planned obligations for public buildings (more than 2% refurbishment per year) || Change of drivers (ESCOs, energy utilities obligation, energy audits) influence stock – flow parameters in the model reflecting higher renovation rates (higher than 2% pa), with account being taken of tougher requirements for public sector through specific treatment of the non-market services sector 3 || Passive houses standards after 2020 || All new houses after 2020 comply with passive house standards - around 20-50 KWh/m2 (depending on the country) which might to a large extent be of renewable origin 4 || Marked penetration of ESCOs and higher financing availability || Enabling role of ESCOs is reflected in lower discount rates for household consumers (from 17.5% to 16% in 2015, 14% in 2020, 13% in 2025 and 12% from 2030 onwards) and for industry, agriculture and services (from 12% to 11% by 2015 and to 10% from 2020 onwards) 5 || Obligation of utilities to achieve energy savings in their customers' energy use over 1.5% per year (up to 2020) || Induce more energy efficiency mainly in residential and tertiary sectors by imposing an efficiency value for grid bound energy sources (electricity, gas, heat) 6 || Strong minimum requirements for energy generation, transmission and distribution including obligation that existing energy generation installations are upgraded to the BAT every time their permit needs to be updated || Higher efficiency of power plants through removing less efficient items from the generation portfolio, allowing however for efficiency losses where CCS is deployed Less transmission and distribution losses 7 || Full roll-out of smart grids, smart metering || Enabling more efficiency and decentralised RES; Reflected as costs in the distribution grid costs, electricity prices and overall costs of the energy system 8 || Significant RES highly decentralised generation || More advanced power dispatching and ancillary services to support reliability of power supply Higher penetration of small wind, solar and hydro Scenario 3: Diversified supply technologies scenario This option is
mainly driven by carbon prices and carbon values (equal for ETS and non ETS
sectors). Carbon values are a still undefined proxy for policy measures that
bring about emission reduction. They do not represent a cost to economic actors
outside EU ETS (where they coincide with the EU ETS price), but are economic
drivers that change decision making of the modelled agents. Yet, the changes
triggered by carbon values may entail costs (e.g. for investment in energy
savings or for fuel switching), which are accounted for in the modelling
framework. They are applied to all sectors and greenhouse gas emissions, covering
ETS and Non ETS sectors. As economic drivers, they influence technology choices
and demand behaviour. Their respective level is not an assumption but a result
of the modelling depending among other things on the level of ambition in GHG
reduction. The modelling applies equal carbon values across sectors and ensures
thereby efficient reductions across sectors. This option assumes acceptance of nuclear and CCS and development of
RES facilitation policies. It reproduces the "Effective and widely
accepted technologies" scenario used in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap and
Roadmap on Transport on the basis of scenario 1bis. Table 17 Policies/measures included (in
addition to measures in table 15): || Measure || How it is reflected in the model 1 || MS and investors have confidence in CCS as a credible and commercially viable technology; acceptance of storage and CO2 networks is high || 2 || MS, investors and society at large have confidence in nuclear as safety is considered adequate and waste issues are solved || Applicable for all countries that have not ruled out the use of nuclear, i.e. Germany and Belgium for the longer term and the currently non-nuclear countries except for Poland Scenario 4: High RES This scenario aims at achieving very high overall RES share and very
high RES penetration in power generation (around 90% share and close to 100%
related to final consumption). Recalling security of supply objectives, this
would be based on increasing domestic RES supply including off-shore wind from
the North Sea; significant CSP and storage development, increased heat pump
penetration for heating and significant micro power generation (PV, small scale
wind, etc.). Regarding assumptions for the demand sectors, scenario 4 is
similar to scenario 3, with the exception that RES are more intensively
facilitated. Table 18 Policies/measures included (in
addition to measures in table 15): || Measure || How it is reflected in the model 1 || Facilitation and enabling policies (permitting, preferential access to the grid) || Represented by significantly higher RES-values in the model than in other decarbonisation scenarios; these RES facilitating policies include for example lower lead times in construction, and involve greater progress on learning curves (e.g. small scale PV and wind) based on higher production. 2 || Market integration allowing for more RES trade || Use of cooperation mechanisms or convergent support schemes coupled with declining costs/support result in optimal allocation of RES development, depending also on adequate and timely expansion of interconnection capacity (point 4); 3 || Stronger policy measures in the power generation, heating and transport sectors in order to achieve high share of RES in overall energy consumption in particular in household micro power generation and increased power production at the distribution level. || Higher use of heat pumps, significant penetration of passive houses with integrated RES reflected through faster learning rates (cost reductions), higher penetration rates (e.g. due to RES building/refurbishing requirements) 4 || Infrastructure, back-up, storage and demand side management || Substantial increase in interconnectors and higher net transfer capacities including DC lines from North Sea to the centre of Europe. Back-up functions done by biomass and gas fired plants. Sufficient storage capacity is provided (pumped storage, CSP, hydrogen). Smart metering allows time and supply situation dependent electricity use (peak/off-peak) reducing needs for storing variable RES electricity. All these measures allow for exploiting greater potentials for off-shore wind in the North Sea. Scenario 5: Delayed CCS The delayed CCS
scenario shows consequences of a delay in the development of CCS, reflecting
acceptance difficulties for CCS regarding storage sites and transport; large
scale development of CCS is therefore assumed feasible only after 2040. Table 19 Policies/measures included (in
addition to measures in table 15): || Measure || How it is reflected in the model 1 || Acceptance difficulties for CCS regarding storage sites and transport, which allow large scale development only after 2040. || Shift of cost-potential curves to the left (higher costs reflecting delays and public opposition). The learning curve for CCS is also delayed accordingly, resulting in higher capital costs for CCS than in scenario 3 2 || MS , investors and society at large have confidence in nuclear as safety is considered adequate and waste issues are solved || Low risk premiums for nuclear Applicable for all countries that have not ruled out the use of nuclear, i.e. Germany and Belgium for the longer term and the currently non-nuclear countries except for Poland Scenario 6: Low nuclear This scenario shows consequences of a low public acceptance of
nuclear power plants leading to cancellation of investment projects that are
currently under consideration and no life time extension after 2030. This leads
to higher deployment of the substitute technologies CCS from fossil fuels on
economic grounds. Table 20 Policies/measures included (in
addition to measures in table 15): || Measure || How it is reflected in the model 1 || Political decisions based on perceived risks associated with waste and safety (especially in the aftermath of the Fukushima accident) leading to no new nuclear plants being build besides the ones presently under construction: 1600 MWe in Finland, 2x1600 MWe in France and 2x505 MWe in Slovakia. Moreover, the recourse to deciding instead on nuclear lifetime extension is available only up to 2030. || No extension of nuclear lifetime on economic grounds after 2030 No new nuclear plants are being built besides reactors under construction : 1600 MW in FIN; 2*1600 MW in FR and 2*505 MW in SK 2 || MS and investors have confidence in CCS as a credible and commercially viable technology; acceptance of storage and CO2 networks is high || Low risk premiums for CCS
1.4
Assumptions about energy infrastructure development
Infrastructure
modelling for decarbonisation scenarios was done similarly to the approach
described in Part A, section 1.4 for the Reference and Current Policy
initiatives scenarios. For
decarbonisation scenarios the analysis done showed that except for very high
RES penetration, the 2020 interconnection capacity would allow for most
intra-EU electricity trade provided that some bottlenecks would be dealt with.
The identified bottlenecks concerns interconnections around Germany, in Austria-Italy-Slovenia, Balkans and Denmark-Sweden. Greater investment and capacity for
these specific links were assumed. For very high
RES penetration, which involves much more RES based electricity trade, stronger
growth of interconnection capacity will be required. Under the assumptions of
this scenario, full exploitation of off-shore wind potential at North Sea is foreseen. It is assumed that a dense DC interconnection system will develop
mainly offshore but also partly onshore, to facilitate power flows from the North Sea offshore wind parks to consumption centres. In this scenario, the links of Sweden with Poland, Sweden with Lithuania, Austria with Italy, France with Italy and links in the Balkan region appear to be congested and need to be reinforced mainly with DC
lines. For more details
on the modelling approach and results see Attachment 2.
1.5 Technology
assumptions
Many technology
assumptions are the same as in the Reference scenario and Current Policy
Initiatives scenario (with revised assumptions about nuclear). In the
decarbonisation scenarios, however, there are additional features and
mechanisms that produce high decarbonisation and technology penetration. Whereas all
decarbonisation scenarios rely on technologies that exist today, they might
become commercially mature only over time supported also by decarbonisation
requirements. The uptake of the technologies is endogenous in the scenarios with
their large-scale deployment leading to lower cost and higher performance,
which correspond to a fully mature commercial stage. All scenarios
simulate merit order dispatching for power generation with contribution of
variable generation from renewables. Electricity balancing and reliability is
ensured endogenously by various means such as import and export flows (in case
of high RES it is facilitated by expanding interconnections), investment in
flexible thermal units, pumped storage and if required hydrogen based storage.
In this latter case, excess variable generation from RES at times of lower demand
may be used to produce hydrogen via electrolysis which is then used to produce
electricity in turbine based power plants when electricity demand exceeds
production from RES and other available sources (e.g. in situations of high
demand). The modelling
approach also considers the possibility to mix hydrogen produced through
electrolysis in the low and medium pressure natural gas distribution system (up
to 30%) in order to reduce the average emission factor of the supplied blend,
thereby contributing to the decarbonisation of final energy consumption. Photovoltaic in
High RES Scenario evolves along more optimistic trajectories than in the
Reference scenario, as it is presumed that the higher penetration of the
technology leads to stronger learning by doing. The higher uptake of RES
technologies is driven mainly by the lower cost potentials for RES power, which
are due to policies facilitating access to resources and sites. A further change
is in the Delayed CCS scenario where the development of CCS is delayed, and
does not reach the same levels of development as in the other scenarios. There is also faster
progress in energy efficiency related technologies due to bigger scale and
carbon prices effects. The energy technologies on the demand side follow a
different development from the Reference scenario variants. In any situation
there are different choices to consumers regarding the energy performance of
appliances, buildings and equipment (evident from e.g. energy labelling where
such transparency is provided by legislation). In decarbonisation scenarios,
there are stronger shifts towards the more efficient technology vintages, which
improve the average energy efficiency of a given energy use (e.g. of the
average lighting appliance) compared to the Reference scenario variants. Energy
efficiency progress is therefore supported by consumer choice effects similar
to increased learning by doing driven by consumers opting for the more
efficient available technologies. The assumptions on the battery costs for the
transport sector were developed along the lines of the White Paper on a Roadmap
to a Single Transport Area. Efficiency improvements of ICE vehicles also occur
in response to carbon values, making the overall vehicle fleet more efficient
than in the Reference scenario and its variants. However, the following
decarbonisation scenarios do not produce the same energy related transport
outcome due to the fact that these scenarios do not handle the same transport
details and that the overall framework conditions are different according to
the scenario. In particular, the penetration of some alternative propulsion
technologies (electric vehicles, hydrogen, etc.) might be somewhat different.
1.6
Drivers
An internal
greenhouse gas emission reduction contribution of around 80% in 2050 is taken
as the key constraint for exploring different scenarios. To ensure that
decarbonisation efforts are comparable across options and scenarios, the
equalisation of cumulative emissions across scenarios is used as an additional
constraint, underlining the importance of the climate impacts of cumulative
emissions over the whole period until 2050 (and beyond). The corresponding
decarbonisation effort from energy related CO2 emissions is 85% CO2 reductions
compared to 1990, as demonstrated by the modelling underlying the Low Carbon
Economy Roadmap of March 2011. Common carbon
values applied to all sectors and greenhouse gas emissions, covering ETS and
Non ETS sectors, are used as key driver to reach the emission reductions and to
ensure cost efficient reductions across sectors. As economic drivers, they
influence technology choices and demand behaviour, in addition to the energy
policies mirrored in the various scenarios for the Energy Roadmap. The
respective level of carbon values is not an assumption but a result of the
modelling. Another
important driver concerns international energy prices. Given that these
scenarios assume global action, significantly lower fossil fuel prices are
assumed than those in the reference and Current Policy Initiatives scenarios.
Their order of magnitude has been set at a similar level as the results of the
global analysis done for the Low Carbon economy Roadmap and recent IEA
projections which assessed the impacts of ambitious climate policies. To increase the
penetration of renewable energy sources the RES-value was increased compared to
the Reference scenario. In 2050, the RES-value in the decarbonisation scenarios
is twice as high as in the current trend cases: instead of 35 €/MWh in
Reference and CPI it amounts to 71 €/MWh in all decarbonisation scenarios,
except for the high RES scenario, in which RES support is much more pronounced
(RES-value of 382 €/MWh). The RES-value is a modelling tool used to reflect the
marginal value of not explicitly modelled facilitation RES policies. These
facilitating RES policies include for example the availability of more sites
for RES, easier licensing of RES installations, benefits deriving from the
improvement of local economies and industrial development. In High RES scenario
the RES-value is the shadow value associated with the additional target of
maximisation of the RES share in power generation and in the overall energy
mix.
2.
Results
2.1 Overview: outcome for the four
main strategic directions to decarbonisation
Decarbonisation can be achieved through
energy efficiency, renewables, nuclear or CCS. Pursuing each of these main
directions can bring the energy system a long way towards the decarbonisation
objective of reducing energy related CO2 emissions by 85% below 1990 by 2050. The
policy options (scenarios) proposed explore 5 different combinations of the
four decarbonisation options. Decarbonisation options are never explored in
isolation as interaction of different elements will necessarily be included in
any scenario that evaluates the entire energy system. Moreover, the climate
change issue is about atmospheric concentrations of GHG, i.e. with the long
lifetimes of gases involved it is essentially about cumulative emissions. All
scenarios achieve also the same level of cumulative GHG emissions. This makes
energy, environmental and economic impacts comparable across the scenarios. Energy Efficiency Energy Efficiency is
a key ingredient in all the decarbonisation pathways examined. Its contribution
is most important in the Energy Efficiency scenario (Scenario 2). Energy
savings in 2050 from 2005 (virtually the peak energy consumption year) amount
to 41%, while GDP more than doubles over the same period of time (+104%). The
lowest contribution from energy efficiency towards decarbonisation comes in the
Delayed CCS scenario, having a high nuclear contribution, in which primary
energy consumption declines 32% between 2005 and 2050. As GDP does not change
between scenarios, these energy savings from 2005 are entirely due to energy
efficiency gains in a broad sense (including structural change), but not
involving income losses. In the Energy
Efficiency scenario, one unit of GDP in 2050 requires 71% less energy input
than in 2005. The average annual improvement in energy intensity (primary
energy consumption / GDP) amounts to 2.7% pa, which is almost a doubling from
historical trends (1.4% pa in 1990 to 2005 including the major efficiency
raising restructuring in former centrally planned economies). All the decarbonisation
scenarios have energy intensity improvements around 2.5% pa given e.g.
synergies between energy efficiency and RES. Energy savings in the High RES scenario are almost as high as in the
Energy Efficiency case (minus 38% for energy consumption in 2050 compared to
2005 instead of minus 41%), this is however achieved by different means: the
energy efficiency scenario focuses on direct impacts on final demand, whereas
energy savings in the high RES case come largely through highly efficient RES
technologies replacing less efficient nuclear and fossil fuel technologies. A clear result
concerning the strategic energy efficiency direction is that a substantial
speeding up of energy efficiency improvements from historical trends is crucial
for achieving the decarbonisation objective. RES RES, too, are a key ingredient in any decarbonisation strategy. The
RES share in gross final energy consumption (i.e. the definition for the
existing 20% target) rises to at least 55% in 2050. In the High RES scenario the RES share in gross final energy
consumption reaches 75%, up 65 percentage points from current levels. The RES
share in transport increases to 73%. The RES share in power generation reaches
86%. RES in electricity consumption account for even 97% given that electricity
consumption calculated in line with the procedure for the calculation of the
overall RES share excludes losses related to pump storage and hydrogen storage
of electricity, the latter being necessary to accommodate all the available RES
electricity in particular at times when electricity demand is lower than RES
generation. The second highest RES contribution (58%) materialises in the Low
nuclear scenario. The RES share is also rather high under strong energy
efficiency policies (57%). The High RES scenario is the most challenging scenario regarding the
restructuring of the energy system including major investments in power
generation with RES capacity in 2050 reaching over 1900 GW, which is more than
8 times the current RES capacity and also more than twice today's total
generation capacity (including nuclear, all fossil fuels and RES) (for
more details see under power generation) Nuclear There is also a
rather wide range with regard to the contribution of nuclear towards
decarbonisation. The nuclear share is highest in the scenario that models the
delayed availability of CCS (Scenario 4), given in particular issues arising
with transport and storage of CO2 and has no additional policies on renewables
and energy efficiency giving rise to an 18% share for nuclear in primary energy
demand in 2050, which is 4 percentage points more than is projected under
Current Policy Initiatives. Least use of the
nuclear option is made in the Low Nuclear Scenario (Scenario 6), which mirrors
a hypothetical Europe-wide sceptical approach to nuclear deployment and
investment. This scenario has still a nuclear share in primary energy of 3% in
2050 for reaching 85% CO2 reduction in 2050 similar to all the other
decarbonisation scenarios. The Diversified
supply technology scenario (the other scenario, in which technologies compete
on their economic merits alone) for reaching decarbonisation has a nuclear
share in 2050 of 16% despite of nuclear phase-out in some Member States, which
is still slightly higher than the current share. The High RES scenario would
leave only little room for nuclear, bringing its share down to 4% in primary
energy supply. CCS The energy
contribution of CCS towards decarbonisation is contingent upon the level of
fossil fuel consumption[5]
in sufficiently large units to justify economically the deployment of this
technology. Hence the CCS share in e.g. gross electricity generation is limited
by the degree of energy efficiency and decentralisation of energy supply as
well as by the level of RES and nuclear penetration. The highest
share of CCS materialises in the Low Nuclear scenario (scenario 6). This case
gives rise to a 32% share of CCS in gross electricity generation in 2050. CCS
can substitute for nuclear in the case that this option was available only to a
very limited extent. The CCS share would be particularly small in a scenario,
in which almost all power generation stems from RES, i.e. Scenario 3, in which
the CCS share drops to a mere 7%. The other scenarios have around 19-24% CCS
share in gross electricity generation in 2050, with the lower end of the range
stemming from delays in CCS technology introduction (mainly linked to storage
issues). Decarbonisation
requires substantial progress on both energy intensity and carbon intensity The 4 decarbonisation dimensions,
explored in 5 decarbonisation scenarios, can also be expressed in terms of
energy and carbon intensity. Energy efficiency reduces energy intensity (energy
consumption divided by GDP) while the other three options (RES, nuclear and
RES) impact overwhelmingly on carbon intensity (CO2 divided by energy
consumption). Substantial progress needs to be made on both indicators- energy
and carbon intensity – which are to some degree substitutes for each other. The
more successful policies to reduce energy consumption are the less needs to be
done on fuel switching towards zero/low carbon energy sources, and vice versa[6] (see Figure 19). The five
decarbonisation scenarios show substantial improvements in energy intensity
which sinks 67%-71% compared with 2005 and 73%-76% compared with the higher 1990
level in terms of energy intensity (1990 had lower energy consumption, but also
much lower GDP). Fuel switching continues in the decarbonisation scenarios up
to 2050 and carbon intensity would improve substantially falling 76%-78% from
1990 (73%-75% from 2005). Figure 19: Decarbonisation scenarios:
Improvements in carbon and energy intensities (reductions from 1990) With ongoing economic
growth, decarbonisation poses a formidable challenge given that meeting higher
demand for energy services (heating and cooling, lighting, cooking, process
energy, mobility, communication, etc) is part of increasing welfare. Upward
pressure on energy consumption and CO2 emissions from economic growth is
substantial given that GDP might increase almost threefold between 1990 and
2050 (see figure 20). The 80% GHG reductions objective by 2050 will however
require deep cuts into energy related CO2 emissions, which in turn require
energy consumption to decrease substantially as well. Figure 20: Decarbonisation scenarios:
development of GDP, primary energy consumption and energy related CO2
emissions: 1990 = 100
2.2 Energy consumption and supply
structure
Primary
energy consumption is significantly lower in all
decarbonisation scenarios as compared to the Reference scenario. This is also
true for the Current Policy Initiatives scenario that shows 6 and 8% lower
demand in 2030 and 2050, respectively than in the Reference scenario reflecting
effects of energy efficiency measures in the Energy Efficiency Plan. The
biggest decline of primary energy consumption comes in Energy Efficiency scenario
(-16% in 2030 and -38% in 2050) showing effects of stringent energy efficiency
policies and smart grid deployment. Compared with the actual outcome for 2005,
primary energy consumption shrinks by 41%. The decrease in energy consumption
compared with Reference for the decarbonisation scenarios spans a range from
11% - 16% in 2030 and from 30% to 38% in 2050. Energy efficiency is therefore
an essential building block in all decarbonisation scenarios. Table 21: Total Primary energy
consumption, changes compared to the Reference scenario (Mtoe) 2020 || 2030 || 2050 Reference || 1790 || 1729 || 1763 Current policy Initiatives || 1700 || 1629 || 1615 % difference to Reference || -5.0% || -5.8% || -8.4% Energy efficiency || 1644 || 1452 || 1084 % difference to Reference || -8.1% || -16.0% || -38.5% Diversified supply technologies || 1681 || 1534 || 1217 % difference to Reference || -6.1% || -11.3% || -31.0% High RES || 1679 || 1510 || 1134 % difference to Reference || -6.2% || -12.7% || -35.7% Delayed CCS || 1682 || 1532 || 1238 % difference to Reference || -6.1% || -11.4% || -29.8% Low nuclear || 1687 || 1489 || 1137 % difference to Reference || -5.8% || -13.9% || -35.5% It is
important to note that these levels of reduced primary energy demand do not
come from reduced activity levels (which remains the same across all
scenarios). Instead they are mainly the result of technological changes on the
demand and also supply side: from more efficient buildings, appliances, heating
systems and vehicles and from electrification in transport and heating, which
combines very efficient demand side technologies (plug-in hybrids, electric
vehicles and heat pumps) with a largely decarbonised power sector. Some changes
related especially to fuel switching also contribute to reducing primary energy
demand, such as switching from lignite or nuclear power generation to gas or
wind based electricity production, which is associated with higher conversion
efficiencies. In addition, behavioural change, triggered by e.g. changes in
prices, information, energy saving obligations, etc, contributes to better
energy efficiency. Energy intensity of GDP (primary energy divided by GDP)
reduces by 53% between 2005 and 2050 in the Reference scenario; the CPI scenario
scores significantly better by improving energy intensity 57%. Energy intensity
diminishes further in all decarbonisation scenarios: by at least 67% in the
delayed CCS scenario. It improves 70% in the high RES and the low nuclear
scenarios and even 71% in the energy efficiency scenario. Under
decarbonisation, a unit of GDP in 2050 requires only one third of the energy
needed today (or slightly less under e.g. a strong energy efficiency focus).
By 2030, energy intensity would improve around 45% from current levels under
decarbonisation, while this improvement would amount to some 40% under current
policies. Absolute energy savings, not considering the
doubling of GDP between now and 2050, show still impressing numbers. Compared with the recent peak in energy consumption in 2005/6, the
energy efficiency scenario depicts 41% less energy consumption, which means a
substantial energy saving with respect to the levels reached just before the
economic crisis. Figure 21: Primary energy savings in 2050 compared to 2005 It is important to note that these levels of reduced primary energy
demand do not come from reduced GDP or sectoral production levels (which remain
the same in all scenarios). Instead they are mainly the result of technological
changes on the demand and supply side, coming from more efficient buildings,
appliances, heating systems and vehicles and from electrification in transport
and heating. All decarbonisation scenarios over-achieve the 20% energy saving
objective in the decade 2020-2030. The scenarios are based on model assumptions, which are consistent
with the input for the 2050 Low Carbon Economy Roadmap. Recognising the
magnitude of the decarbonisation challenge, which implies a reversal of a
secular trend towards ever increasing energy consumption, this Energy Roadmap
has adopted a rather conservative approach as regards the effectiveness of
policy instruments in terms of behavioural change. However, the Roadmap results
should not be read as implying that the 20% energy efficiency target for 2020
cannot be reached effectively. Greater effects of the Energy Efficiency Plan
are possible if the Energy Efficiency Directive is adopted swiftly and
completely, followed up by vigorous implementation and marked change in the
energy consumption decision making of individuals and companies.[7] Not only the
amount, but also the composition of energy mix would differ significantly in a
decarbonised energy system. Figure 22 shows total energy consumption as well as
its composition in terms of fuels in 2050 for the various scenarios. Figure 22: Total Primary Energy in 2050, by fuel Low and zero
carbon content energy sources are strongly encouraged by going the various
decarbonisation routes, each of them focusing on different aspects. This has
different repercussions on the fuel mix. Energy efficiency encourages primary
sources that can be used with small losses (e.g. many renewables or gas) and
electricity at the level of final demand. CCS strategies affect the fuel mix by
largely neutralising the high carbon content of fossil fuels, notably coal and
lignite, through removal of the associated emissions. RES and nuclear routes
are directly targeting the fuel mix. The modelling leads to rather wide ranges
for primary energy sources with these fuel mixes in the decarbonisation cases
all satisfying the decarbonisation requirement by 2050. Moreover, the
development of all the fuel mixes under decarbonisation give rise to the same
cumulative GHG emissions from 2011 to 2050. Table 22: Share of fuels in primary energy consumption
in % || || Reference scenario || Current Policy Initiatives || Decarbonisation scenarios 2005 || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Solids || 17.5 || 12.4 || 11.4 || 12.0 || 9.4 || 7.2-9.1 || 2.1-10.2 Oil || 37.1 || 32.8 || 31.8 || 34.1 || 32.0 || 33.4-34.4 || 14.1-15.5 Gas || 24.4 || 22.2 || 20.4 || 22.7 || 21.9 || 23.4-25.2 || 18.6-25.9 Nuclear || 14.1 || 14.3 || 16.7 || 12.1 || 13.5 || 8.4-13.2 || 2.6-17.5 Renewables || 6.8 || 18.4 || 19.9 || 19.3 || 23.3 || 21.9-25.6 || 40.8-59.6 Renewables increase their share significantly under adopted policies and would
substantially rise in all decarbonisation scenarios to reach at least 22% of
primary energy consumption by 2030 and 41% by 2050. The RES share is comparably
low in those scenarios, in which nuclear plays a rather strong role (scenarios
4 and 5). The RES share is highest in High RES scenario reaching 60% in primary
energy by 2050. It is also pretty high (44% and 46% in primary energy in 2050)
in the Energy Efficiency and Low nuclear scenarios, respectively. The RES share is
higher when calculated in gross final energy consumption (indicator used for
the 20% RES target). It represents at least 28% (2030) and 55% (2050) in all
decarbonisation scenarios and rises up to 75% in 2050 in the High RES scenario. Figure 23: Range of Fuel Shares in Primary Energy in 2050
compared with 2009 outcome Nuclear developments have been significantly affected by the policy
reaction in Member States after the nuclear accident in Fukushima (abandoning
substantial nuclear plans in Italy, revision of nuclear policy in Germany). These reactions and the forthcoming nuclear stress tests have been reflected in
the modelling assumptions for the Current Policy Initiatives scenario (1bis).
The downward effects for nuclear penetration in CPI are also present in the
decarbonisation scenarios, since the modelling of these cases also included the
recent policy adjustments on nuclear. The share of nuclear varies depending on assumptions taken. In the
scenario without new nuclear investment (except for plants under construction)
and extension of lifetime only in this and the next decade, the nuclear share
declines gradually to 3% by 2050. In the most ambitious nuclear scenario -
Delayed CCS, the share rises to 18%[8].
The share of gas
under Current Policy Initiatives is higher than in the Reference scenario
reflecting abandon of the nuclear programme in Italy, no new nuclear power
plants in Belgium and higher costs for new plants and retrofitting. The gas
share increases slightly to 26% in 2050 in the Low nuclear scenario where the
CCS share in power generation is around 32%. The oil
share declines only slightly until 2030 (and even 2040) due to high dependency
of transport on oil based fuels. However, the decline is significant in the
last decade 2040-2050 where oil in transport is replaced by biofuels and
electric vehicles. The oil share drops to around 15% in 2050 when following any
of the examined main directions towards decarbonisation. The share of solid
fuels continues its long standing downward trend already under Reference
and CPI developments. Under substantial decarbonisation the solids share
shrinks further to reach levels as low as 2% in the High RES scenario in 2050
and only 4% and 5% under Energy efficiency and Delayed CCS, respectively. The
solids share would remain rather high only in the Low nuclear scenario (10% in
2050) with a high CCS contribution which allows a continued use of solids in a
decarbonisation context. Final energy
demand declines similarly to primary energy demand.
Current Policy Scenario shows around 5% decrease (in 2020-2050) compared to the
Reference scenario. In the Energy Efficiency scenario the reduction on
Reference in final energy demand is -14% in 2030 and -40% in 2050. The decrease
in the decarbonisation scenarios is at least -8% in 2030 and -34% in 2050.
Compared with actual 2005 outcome, final energy consumption decreases in 2050
by 37% in the High Energy Efficiency scenario and by around 32% in all the
other decarbonisation scenarios. Sectors showing
higher reductions than the average are residential, tertiary and generally also
transport. Table 23: Final energy demand, changes compared to the
Reference scenario || Reference scenario || Current Policy Initiatives || Energy efficiency || Diversified supply technologies || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || Final Energy Demand (Mtoe) || 1227 || 1187 || 1221 || -6% || -4% || -5% || -9% || -14% || -40% || -7% || -9% || -34% || Industry || 330 || 333 || 369 || -4% || -5% || -5% || -4% || -5% || -30% || -4% || -5% || -26% || Residential || 318 || 299 || 288 || -9% || -6% || -4% || -13% || -20% || -43% || -9% || -12% || -35% || Tertiary || 181 || 174 || 181 || -8% || -5% || -7% || -13% || -25% || -53% || -8% || -15% || -42% || Transport || 398 || 382 || 383 || -4% || -2% || -6% || -7% || -12% || -40% || -7% || -9% || -38% || || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear || || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || Final Energy Demand (Mtoe) || -7% || -8% || -34% || -7% || -10% || -35% || -6% || -10% || -35% || Industry || -4% || -4% || -25% || -4% || -5% || -26% || -3% || -6% || -26% || Residential || -9% || -9% || -34% || -9% || -12% || -35% || -9% || -13% || -36% || Tertiary || -8% || -13% || -44% || -8% || -16% || -42% || -7% || -17% || -43% || Transport || -7% || -8% || -38% || -7% || -9% || -39% || -7% || -9% || -39% || There is a lot
of structural change in the fuel composition of final energy demand. Given its
high efficiency and emission free nature at use, electricity makes major
inroads already under current policies (increase by 9 pp between 2005 and 2050
in CPI). The electricity
share soars further in decarbonisation scenarios reaching 36% - 39% in 2050,
reflecting also its important role in decarbonising further final demand
sectors such as heating and services and in particular transport. The
electricity share would almost double by 2050. The crucial issue for any
decarbonisation strategy is therefore the full decarbonisation of power
generation (see below). Table 24: Final energy consumption by fuel
in various scenarios Also RES make major inroads
under current policies including the 2009 RES Directive. The direct use of RES
in final demand (i.e. not counting here the RES input to power and distributed
heat generation) rises strongly to 2030 coming close to a doubling of the
share. However, without additional policy push beyond the current RES/climate
change measures, this RES share could be stagnant. On the contrary, in
decarbonisation scenarios the share of directly used RES (e.g. biomass, solar
thermal) would go up to 24% in 2050 in almost all decarbonisation cases, except
for the high RES scenario, where this share reaches even 30%. Oil has been dominating final energy for many
years and might continue doing so until 2030 even in the decarbonisation
scenarios, when is would still account for one third of energy deliveries to
final consumers. The big changes come after 2030 when more and more parts of
final energy consumption based on oil, especially in transport, are replaced by
electricity (e.g. electric and plug in hybrid vehicles, heat pumps). The oil
share in 2050 would drop to around 15%. The gas share has been
declining in recent years and would be lower than today under both current
policies and decarbonisation in 2030, when gas would account for not more than
a fifth in final demand. The gas share after 2030 would be decreasing further
in particular in decarbonisation scenarios, which is due to the greater role of
electricity in both heating and for providing energy in productive sectors. Distributed heat would deliver 7-8% of final
energy demand in 2030 under both current policies and decarbonisation, raising
its share substantially from current levels. The heat share in 2050 would be
highest (10%) in the Low nuclear scenario where high electricity production is
ensured by CCS equipped generation from gas and solids, often in a CHP mode. Solid fuels become rather obsolete in final
energy demand under current policies (falling to around 3% in 2030-2050). The decline of the solids share reflects higher use of electricity
and gas in heating and industry. Solid fuels become marginal under decarbonisation, especially
by 2050, when most solids base processes have been replaced by electricity or
other fuels. The solid fuel share in 2050 would shrink to 0.3-0.4%. Figure 24: Shares of Electricity in Current Trend and
Decarbonisation Scenarios
2.3 Power generation
Electricity
demand increases in all scenarios compared to 2005
levels, following greater penetration of electricity using appliances, heating
and propulsion systems. The increased use of electric devices is partly compensated
by the increased energy efficiency of electric appliances as well as increased
thermal integrity in the residential and service sectors and more rational use
of energy in all sectors, but overall the effect from emerging new electricity
uses at large scale for heating and transport is decisive. The development of
electricity consumption varies between sectors. Transport
electricity demand increases strongest. The increase of electricity use in
transport is due to the electrification of road transport, in particular
private cars, which can either be plug-in hybrid or pure electric vehicle;
almost 80% of private passenger transport activity is carried out with these
kinds of vehicles by 2050. Despite substantial progress regarding energy
efficiency of appliances and for efficient heating systems, such as heat pumps,
household electricity demand in 2050 under decarbonisation exceeds the current
level given the additional deployment of electricity in heating and cooling. Electricity
demand in the other sectors decreases or remains flat under decarbonisation.
Electricity demand in services/agriculture diminishes in all decarbonisation
scenarios as a result of strong energy efficiency policies, although there is a
substitution from other energy carriers to more efficient electric devices e.g.
heat pumps. . Industrial electricity demand remains broadly at the current
level by 2050 under decarbonisation. Table 25: Electricity final energy demand || 2005 || 2050 || Reference || Scenario 1bis || Scenario 2 Final energy demand (in TWH) || 2762 || 4130 || 3951 || 3203 Industry || 1134 || 1504 || 1426 || 1109 Households || 795 || 1343 || 1230 || 913 Tertiary || 759 || 1184 || 1041 || 518 Transport || 74 || 100 || 255 || 663 || 2050 || Scenario 3 || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || Scenario 6 Final energy demand (in TWh) || 3618 || 3377 || 3585 || 3552 Industry || 1211 || 1169 || 1201 || 1191 Households || 1026 || 938 || 1019 || 1013 Tertiary || 707 || 605 || 696 || 677 Transport || 675 || 664 || 669 || 671 Power
generation: level and structure by fuel Given the assumed
limited electricity import possibilities from third countries, the increased
electricity demand will have to be generated nearly exclusively within the EU. Moreover,
electricity production has to cover also power plant own consumption (e.g. for
desulphurisation), the consumption of the other energy producing sectors
(energy branch) as well as transmission and distribution losses. Furthermore,
additional electricity generation is appropriate under strong decarbonisation
objectives to produce hydrogen mixed in low and medium pressure gas networks
(bringing down emission factors in final demand) and for producing hydrogen,
which is used for balancing in the case of high RES scenarios. Therefore,
similar to electricity demand there is a strong increase from current levels
for power generation in all scenarios. Under decarbonisation, power generation
will be lower in 2050 compared with Reference and CPI scenarios. The highest
electricity generation level in 2050 among the decarbonisation cases comes
about in case of CO2 reduction focussing particularly strongly on RES. The structure of
power generation changes substantially between the scenarios. The Reference
scenario and the Current Policy Initiatives scenario show renewable shares in
2050 reaching 40 and 49% respectively and fossil fuels still having a share of
33 and 31% respectively. Among the decarbonisation scenarios, only the Low
nuclear scenario has a share of fossil fuels above 30%, as it makes substantial
use of CCS. In the other scenarios the fossil fuel share lies below 25% and is
particularly low in High RES scenario, where fossil fuels account for under 10%
of electricity generation. Under
decarbonisation, power generation in 2050 is based on renewables for at around
60%-65%, except for the high RES case, in which this share is much higher. Wind
alone accounts for about one third of power generation in most decarbonisation
scenarios. In the high RES case, the wind share reaches even close to 50% in
2050. The nuclear share falls from the present level in all decarbonisation
scenarios. This share is highest in 2050 under delayed CCS, in which case it is
around 20%. On the contrary, in the low nuclear scenario, nuclear would account
for just 2.5% of power generation. Table 26: Power generation || || 2005 || 2050 || || Reference || Scenario 1bis || Scenario 2 Electricity generation || TWh || 3274 || 4931 || 4620 || 4281 Nuclear energy || Shares (%) || 30.5 || 26.4 || 20.6 || 14.2 Renewables || 14.3 || 40.3 || 48.8 || 64.2 Hydro || 9.4 || 7.6 || 8.5 || 9.2 Wind || 2.2 || 20.1 || 24.7 || 33.2 Solar, tidal etc. || 0.0 || 5.1 || 7.0 || 10.6 Biomass & waste || 2.6 || 7.3 || 8.4 || 10.9 Geothermal heat || 0.2 || 0.2 || 0.2 || 0.3 Fossil fuels || 55.2 || 33.3 || 30.6 || 21.6 Coal and lignite || 30.0 || 15.2 || 11.1 || 4.8 Petroleum products || 4.1 || 2.2 || 2.1 || 0.0 Natural gas || 20.3 || 15.1 || 16.7 || 16.7 Coke & blast-furnace gasses || 0.9 || 0.7 || 0.7 || 0.0 Other fuels (hydrogen, methanol) || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.0 || || 2050 || || Scenario 3 || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || Scenario 6 Electricity generation || TWh || 4912 || 5141 || 4872 || 4853 Nuclear energy || Shares (%) || 16.1 || 3.5 || 19.2 || 2.5 Renewables || 59.1 || 83.1 || 60.7 || 64.8 Hydro || 8.0 || 7.7 || 8.1 || 8.1 Wind || 31.6 || 48.7 || 32.4 || 35.6 Solar, tidal etc. || 9.9 || 16.4 || 9.9 || 10.8 Biomass & waste || 9.3 || 9.6 || 9.9 || 9.8 Geothermal heat || 0.3 || 0.6 || 0.4 || 0.4 Fossil fuels || 24.8 || 9.6 || 20.1 || 32.7 Coal and lignite || 8.1 || 2.1 || 5.1 || 13.1 Petroleum products || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.1 Natural gas || 16.6 || 7.5 || 14.9 || 19.5 Coke & blast-furnace gasses || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.0 || 0.0 Other fuels (hydrogen, methanol) || 0.0 || 3.9 || 0.0 || 0.0 NB: power generation is presented in the most
comprehensive way in this table involving in a sense some "double
counting" in the denominator of shares for the high RES scenario: first
electricity generation from RES is counted including those parts of RES based
generation that, in case supply exceeds demand, are transformed into
hydrogen for later use by producing electricity for a second time from these
original renewables sources. This specific representation for showing also the magnitude
of hydrogen based RES electricity storage (4% in 2050) leads to total
electricity generation numbers that are in a sense inflated, which in turn
gives rise to lower RES share numbers in this specific representation that
counts production from RES once as such and secondly under hydrogen based
generation (shown separately) for the part that is not lost in transformations
into hydrogen and back from hydrogen to electricity. Power
plant investments by fuel type (e.g. RES, nuclear, fossils with CCS, fossil
without CCS) The installed
capacity increases in all scenarios compared to the Reference scenario due to
the additional balancing and power reserve capacities needed for the variable
RES which increase in all scenarios. The scenario with the least increase is Energy
Efficiency scenario which requires the least amount of electricity and
therefore also the least amount of installed capacity. All scenarios still have
fossil fuel fired power plants as installed capacity, which are used mainly as back-up.
The share of CCS
capacity in thermal power plants for the decarbonisation scenarios ranges from
48% in Low nuclear scenario to 12% in High RES scenario. The share in the other
scenarios is between 35 and 44%. Table 27: Installed power capacity || || 2005 || 2050 || || Reference || Scenario 1bis || Scenario 2 Net Installed Power Capacity || GWe || 715 || 1454 || 1502 || 1473 Nuclear energy || 134 || 161 || 117 || 79 Renewables (without biomass/geothermal) || 147 || 681 || 784 || 1012 Hydro (pumping excluded) || 105 || 121 || 122 || 125 Wind power || 41 || 382 || 432 || 548 Wind on-shore || 40 || 262 || 291 || 370 Wind off-shore || 1 || 120 || 140 || 177 Solar || 2 || 171 || 224 || 330 Other renewables (tidal etc.) || 0 || 6 || 7 || 9 Thermal power || 434 || 613 || 601 || 382 Solids fired || 187 || 131 || 104 || 70 Oil fired || 62 || 168 || 38 || 15 Gas fired || 167 || 226 || 366 || 187 Biomass-waste fired || 18 || 87 || 92 || 108 Hydrogen plants || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 Geothermal heat || 1 || 1 || 1 || 2 || || 2050 || || Scenario 3 || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || Scenario 6 Net Installed Power Capacity || GWe || 1621 || 2219 || 1639 || 1721 Nuclear energy || 102 || 41 || 127 || 16 Renewable (without biomass/geothermal) || 1081 || 1749 || 1093 || 1193 Hydro (pumping excluded) || 126 || 131 || 126 || 127 Wind power || 595 || 984 || 609 || 674 Wind on-shore || 398 || 612 || 408 || 452 Wind off-shore || 197 || 373 || 200 || 222 Solar || 351 || 603 || 348 || 381 Other renewables (tidal etc.) || 10 || 30 || 10 || 11 Thermal power || 439 || 429 || 419 || 513 Solids fired || 94 || 62 || 73 || 125 Oil fired || 19 || 19 || 18 || 18 Gas fired || 218 || 182 || 210 || 255 Biomass-waste fired || 106 || 163 || 115 || 112 Hydrogen plants * || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 Geothermal heat || 2 || 4 || 2 || 2 || || 2005 || 2050 || || Reference || Scenario 1bis || Scenario 2 Total CCS capacity || GWe || 0 || 101 || 39 || 149 Solids || 0 || 64 || 33 || 28 Oil || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 Gas || 0 || 37 || 6 || 121 || || 2050 || || Scenario 3 || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || Scenario 6 Total CCS capacity || GWe || 193 || 53 || 148 || 248 Solids || 50 || 18 || 30 || 79 Oil || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 Gas || 142 || 34 || 118 || 169 * Hydrogen capacity in the above table refers only
to plant technologies dedicated to specific hydrogen use, such as fuel
cells. Capacity for generating electricity from hydrogen, serving only the
purpose of storing RES based electricity that was previously produced at times
when electricity supply exceeded demand, is accounted for under gas fired
capacity, given that hydrogen would be burnt is such types of plants,
including as a mixture with natural gas. The high RES scenario is a particularly challenging scenario
regarding the restructuring of the energy system involved; RES policy related
challenges in this scenario include the following:
Huge investments in RES power capacity need to be ensured with
wind capacity alone reaching over 980 GW in 2050, this is 20% more than
today's (2010) total power generation capacity (including nuclear, fossil
fuels and all RES); similarly, solar capacity would need to soar to 600
GW, which amounts to almost three quarters of our present total generation
capacity; all RES power generation capacity (Renewables + biomass/waste +
geothermal in table 27) would need to increase to over 1900 GW, which is
more than 8 times the current RES capacity and also more than twice
today's total generation capacity.
It might be a challenge to ensure the raw material needed for
RES technologies and there may be upward pressure on e.g. steel prices,
which could be a challenge to such a development (not modelled with the
energy model); other logistic challenges would relate to ensuring the
maritime equipment to install and maintain the off-shore wind capacity
that rises from just close to 5 GW today to over 370 GW in 2050;
In order to accommodate RES production from remote sites with
respect to consumption centres and to take advantage of the cost
differences across Member States for cost-effectiveness reasons, the grid
needs to be extended substantially and also smartened to deal with
variable feed in from many dispersed sources (e.g. solar PV); the scenario
analysis identified needs for grid extension beyond 2020 under a
decarbonisation agenda and in addition a set of additional DC links
(electricity highways) needed to accommodate a very high RES contribution
to electricity supply (see attachment 2 to this Annex);
Another challenge relates to the skilled workforce required,
the lack of which can lead to a stalled development unless a major RES
related education and training strategy is pursued taking account of
ageing EU population over the next decades, which is even shrinking after
2035. Skilled workforce will also be needed for the construction of
expanded, smart grids, which will also be necessary for the penetration of
other low carbon technologies.
In addition to economic, logistical, resource security and
manpower challenges, there is the acceptance issue for new transmission
lines and perhaps also regarding the substantial expansion of (on-shore)
RES installations;
It will also be
challenging in the other decarbonisation scenarios to ensure the required RES
capacity in 2050 and to accommodate it by the grid. The Energy Efficiency
scenario poses the least challenge given the lowest electricity demand, but
nevertheless, RES power generation capacity would need to soar to 5 times the
current level, exceeding today's total electricity generation capacity
(nuclear, fossil fuel and RES combined) by more than a third. On the other
hand, increased energy efficiency and decentralised RES might require more
sophisticated solutions for distribution level. Other scenarios
pose also substantial challenges throughout the transition. For example, higher
nuclear deployment in the delayed CCS scenario leads to more requirements for
nuclear fuel and more nuclear waste that needs to be safely transported and
stored. Electrification of passenger transport involves many changes in car
production and infrastructure provision. A smooth transition from a
petrol/diesel to an electricity based system for mainly urban transport
requires a lot of logistical changes. Widespread
penetration of CCS will require dedicated CO2 transport grids that need to be
financed, constructed and accepted. Acceptance challenges could be particularly
pronounced for nuclear and CO2 storage. As carbon capture, transport and
storage require significant quantities of electricity that need to be generated
in addition to electricity for final use, there would be higher input demand
also for fossil fuels. This effect would be particularly pronounced if global
decarbonisation includes an important contribution from CCS for energy
consumption and also for abatement of industrial process emissions. This could
exert upward pressure on the level of world fossil fuel prices. All scenarios
involve substantial changes in production, transformation, smart transmission/distribution
and consumption patters for energy, requiring a skilled workforce against the
background of ageing population. Enhancement of the European capacity for
innovation, appropriate RTD as well as education and training will be
instrumental for a cost-effective transition to a low carbon economy that
fosters competitiveness and security of supply. Decarbonisation
requires also considerable capacity for CCS, except for the high RES scenario.
The other scenarios involve around 150 GW – 250 GW CCS capacity in 2050, with
the upper end materialising in Low nuclear scenario, which is the case with the
greatest use of CCS for power generation (32% share In Table 28 the capacity investment per decade
for the scenarios can be seen; as can be observed the highest investments take
place in RES in all scenarios. As can be seen no new investment is undertaken
in nuclear in Low nuclear scenario after 2030; only Delayed CCS sees higher
nuclear investment than in the Reference scenario for the last two decades of
the projection period. Investment continues in thermal power plants throughout
the projection period in all scenarios; it is lowest in High RES and Energy
efficiency scenarios. These investment numbers
include lifetime extensions of existing plants, refurbishments and replacement
investments on existing sites, which is particularly relevant for nuclear.
These investment numbers must not be confused with additional new plants of
e.g. nuclear. Table 28: Net Power Capacity Investment in GWe per decade || || 2011-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2040 || 2041-2050 Reference || Nuclear energy || 15 || 64 || 46 || 62 Renewable energy || 192 || 169 || 192 || 259 Thermal power fossil fuels || 100 || 78 || 184 || 183 of which: CCS || 5 || 6 || 48 || 41 Thermal power RES || 37 || 17 || 14 || 24 Scenario 1 bis || Nuclear energy || 12 || 42 || 41 || 49 Renewable energy || 187 || 169 || 245 || 309 Thermal power fossil fuels || 101 || 72 || 169 || 198 of which: CCS || 3 || 0 || 19 || 17 Thermal power RES || 38 || 17 || 13 || 29 Scenario 2 || Nuclear energy || 11 || 24 || 34 || 22 Renewable energy || 204 || 222 || 318 || 436 Thermal power fossil fuels || 86 || 23 || 92 || 92 of which: CCS || 3 || 0 || 56 || 90 Thermal power RES || 38 || 19 || 27 || 29 Scenario 3 || Nuclear energy || 12 || 46 || 36 || 35 Renewable energy || 214 || 250 || 348 || 463 Thermal power fossil fuels || 90 || 37 || 130 || 101 of which: CCS || 3 || 1 || 91 || 98 Thermal power RES || 40 || 20 || 27 || 25 Scenario 4 || Nuclear energy || 12 || 30 || 12 || 0 Renewable energy || 215 || 396 || 588 || 817 Thermal power fossil fuels || 88 || 35 || 66 || 91 of which: CCS || 3 || 0 || 19 || 30 Thermal power RES || 38 || 22 || 55 || 53 Scenario 5 || Nuclear energy || 12 || 47 || 56 || 39 Renewable energy || 214 || 256 || 354 || 464 Thermal power fossil fuels || 89 || 36 || 79 || 115 of which: CCS || 3 || 0 || 35 || 110 Thermal power RES || 39 || 20 || 37 || 23 Scenario 6 || Nuclear energy || 11 || 4 || 0 || 0 Renewable energy || 213 || 281 || 385 || 515 Thermal power fossil fuels || 90 || 50 || 163 || 121 of which: CCS || 3 || 5 || 121 || 118 Thermal power RES || 39 || 25 || 26 || 27 Investment in generation capacity entails substantial cumulative
investment expenditure in all scenarios over the period 2011-2050. Cumulative
investment expenditure for power generation is most pronounced in the high RES
scenario amounting to over 3 trillion € in real terms up to 2050. Among the
decarbonisation scenarios cumulative investment expenditure for power
generation is lowest in the Energy Efficiency scenario given the marked savings
in electricity consumption. Figure 25: Cumulative investment expenditure in 2011-2050 for power
generation (in € of 2008) These investment expenditure
results impact on electricity generation costs in the different scenarios (see
below) Impacts on infrastructure Infrastructure
requirements differ in scenarios. Decarbonisation scenarios require more and
more sophisticated infrastructures (mainly electricity lines, smart grids and
storage) than Reference and CPI scenarios. High RES scenario necessitates
additional DC lines mainly to transport wind electricity from the North Sea to
the centre of Europe and more storage. The biggest share of costs relate to the
upgrade and improvement of distribution networks including smartening of the
grid. Investments needed in transmission lines are much lower and new
interconnectors represent only a fraction of these transmission costs. Table 29:
Grid investment costs (Bn Euro'05) || Grid investment costs 2011-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2050 || 2011-2050 Reference || 292 || 316 || 662 || 1269 CPI || 293 || 291 || 774 || 1357 Energy Efficiency || 305 || 352 || 861 || 1518 Diversified supply technologies || 337 || 416 || 959 || 1712 High RES || 336 || 536 || 1323 || 2195 Delayed CCS || 336 || 420 || 961 || 1717 Low nuclear || 339 || 425 || 1029 || 1793 Euro'05 || Transmission Grid investment (bEUR) 2011-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2040 || 2041-2050 || 2011-2050 Reference || 47.9 || 52.2 || 53.5 || 52.0 || 205.7 CPI || 47.1 || 49.6 || 64.8 || 66.6 || 228.2 Energy Efficiency || 49.0 || 63.1 || 80.3 || 80.1 || 272.5 Diversified supply technologies || 52.8 || 70.2 || 88.0 || 86.8 || 297.8 High RES || 52.8 || 95.5 || 137.8 || 134.4 || 420.4 Delayed CCS || 52.7 || 71.0 || 88.6 || 87.6 || 299.9 Low nuclear || 52.9 || 73.8 || 95.2 || 94.8 || 316.6 Euro'05 || Distribution Grid investment (bEUR) 2011-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2040 || 2041-2050 || 2011-2050 Reference || 243.7 || 263.5 || 280.5 || 276.0 || 1063.7 CPI || 245.0 || 239.3 || 317.6 || 325.9 || 1127.8 Energy Efficiency || 256.3 || 289.1 || 408.4 || 291.8 || 1245.5 Diversified supply technologies || 284.2 || 345.9 || 454.3 || 329.8 || 1414.1 High RES || 283.5 || 440.0 || 619.8 || 431.5 || 1774.8 Delayed CCS || 283.4 || 349.4 || 445.1 || 339.6 || 1417.5 Low nuclear || 286.4 || 350.8 || 472.5 || 366.5 || 1476.3 Euro'08 || Investments in new electricity interconnectors 2006-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2050 Reference || 13.1 || 0.3 || 0.0 CPI || 21.9 || 9.7 || 0.6 High energy efficiency || 21.9 || 9.7 || 0.6 Diversified supply technologies || 21.9 || 9.7 || 0.6 High RES || 21.9 || 21.2 || 50.8 Delayed CCS || 21.9 || 9.7 || 0.6 Low nuclear || 21.9 || 9.7 || 0.6 The model
assumes that grid investments, that are prerequisites to the decarbonisation
scenarios in this analysis, are undertaken and that costs are fully recovered
in electricity prices. The reality might differ from this model situation in a
sense that current regulatory regime might be more short to medium term cost
minimisation oriented and might not provide sufficient incentives for long-term
and innovative investments. There might also be less perfect foresight and
lower coordination of investments in generation, transmission and distribution
as the model predicts. Power
generation costs Fixed
operational and capital costs for power generation increase over time in all
scenarios. The increase in capital costs is more pronounced in decarbonisation
scenarios, notably in the High RES case. A substantial RES contribution (high
RES scenario) leads to an increase of fixed and capital costs of 155% in 2050
compared with 2005 (81% rise by 2030) due to the additional investment needs in
generation, grid, storage and back-up capacities. On the contrary, the increase
in variable and fuel costs over time under Reference and CPI developments would
be more or less cancelled in the decarbonisation cases. This effect of shifting
variable and fuel costs towards capital costs is most pronounced in the High
RES scenario. In this decarbonisation case, the substantial RES contribution
leads to a decline of variable and fuel costs by 45% below Reference in 2050
and also a decrease by 21% on the 2005 level. Unit costs of
transmission and distribution increase substantially in all decarbonisation
scenarios. The High RES case has the greatest increase. Due to the
decarbonisation of the power sector in all scenarios in the last two decades of
the projection period, the costs related to ETS auction payments decrease
substantially. These effects on
cost components allow for a decrease in electricity prices between 2030 and
2050 in all decarbonisation scenarios, except for the High RES scenario. This
is in stark contrast to the period up to 2030, in which electricity prices
increase due notably to increases in capital cost, grid costs and auctioning
payments. The High RES case is an exception from other cases because of the
very high investment requirements combined with stronger requirements on the
electricity grid extension, which is not fully compensated by savings in fuel
and other variable costs. Therefore the
High RES case features the highest electricity prices among the decarbonisation
scenarios, as it would not allow for the flattening out of the strong price
increase up to 2030 (observed in all scenarios) but continues with major
capital intensive changes to the power system. Table 31: Electricity prices and cost structure
[9] It is important
to note that, as explained in the assumptions part, the PRIMES model makes sure
that the full costs of electricity production and distribution are recovered
through electricity prices. Both marginal costs and the appropriate portion of
fixed capital and operation costs are allocated to the various sectors
according to the Ramsey Boiteux methodology taking into account price
elasticities in the allocation of fixed costs. This procedure is necessary to
ensure a sustainable modelling solution because in internally consistent
scenarios electricity sector investments need to be financed by the revenues
from selling electricity. However, power
exchanges in wholesale markets work on the basis of marginal costs for
determining spot prices with suppliers having lower marginal costs that the
equilibrium price being able to cover (parts of) fixed costs. In a situation
with a very high contribution of capital intensive low carbon technologies with
marginal costs close to zero, such as RES, all suppliers succeeding to place
bids might be bidders with such RES power plants and competition at power
exchanges would drive this electricity price down close to zero. Obviously, close
to zero prices over very long time segments every year would not be a sustainable
solution in such a scenario, as the necessary capital expenditure and
investment under such market structure could not be financed from selling
revenues and such a scenario would not materialise. While PRIMES, presenting
functioning scenarios, presents economically sustainable electricity prices,
this issue appears to be an institutional challenge for the transition to a low
carbon electricity system, especially for one that is nearly entirely based on
RES.
2.4 Other sectors
Heating
and cooling: distributed heat/steam and RES Demand for
distributed heat in the decarbonisation scenarios rises compared to current
level but is 2%-10% lower by 2030 as compared to the Reference scenario, with
the greatest decline occurring in the high RES scenario. The decrease is more
pronounced towards 2050 with 46% decrease as compared to Reference scenario in
the High RES scenario; 26% decrease in the Energy Efficiency scenario and at
least -20% decrease in other decarbonisation scenarios. The High RES scenario
shows lowest distributed heat demand after 2025 due to the highest penetration
of RES in power generation which leads to decrease of CHP[10] and due to the shift towards
electricity use for heating reducing especially district heating from fossil
fuels. When comparing
results for distributed heat between Reference and decarbonisation scenarios,
it is important to note that final energy demand in the decarbonisation
scenarios is 34% - 40% lower in 2050 than under reference developments (around
10% lower in 2030). The biggest
decrease as compared to the Reference scenario in 2050 occurs in the
residential sector (-63% in High RES scenario and -32-42% in all other decarbonisation
scenarios) reflecting stringent energy efficiency policies in buildings. Demand
stays at current levels of around 240 TWh until 2015 and then gradually
declines to 69 TWh in the High RES scenario and 126 TWh in the Low nuclear by
2050, showing the higher distributed heat demand among the decarbonisation
cases. The decrease in
the tertiary sector is important as well with -43% in the Energy Efficiency
scenario and at least -31% in all other scenarios. The demand peaks in 2015 at
120 TWh and goes down to 52 TWh in Energy Efficiency scenario and around 60 TWh
in other decarbonisation scenarios. Contrarily to
residential and tertiary, industrial demand for heat increases massively from
160 TWh in 2005 to reach 503 TWh in High RES scenario and up to 733 TWh in Low
nuclear/High CCS scenario by 2050. Industrial demand is still lower as compared
to Reference scenario by at least 17% in all decarbonisation scenarios and by
-43% in High RES scenario. However, industry needs steam for some processes
that can hardly be substituted by other fuels. Heat consumption
is also rising in the energy branch from 54 TWh in 2005 to 71-77 TWh in 2050,
with the Energy Efficiency and delayed CCS scenarios at the lower end of the
range and the Low Nuclear scenario at the upper one. Following the
diverging trends in different sectors the shares of sectors in total
distributed heat changes significantly up to 2050. Table 32: Heat/steam final consumption || 2005 || 2050 Reference scenario || Decarbonisation scenarios Industry || 161TWh || 31% || 880 TWh || 76% || 503 - 733 TWh || 81- 80% Households || 240 TWh || 46% || 186 TWh || 16% || 69 - 126 TWh || 11 - 13% Tertiary || 116 TWh || 22% || 92 TWh || 8% || 52 - 64 TWh || 8 - 7% Final demand || 517 TWh || 100% || 1.159 TWh || 100% || 627 – 923 TWh || 100% With lower final
energy demand under decarbonisation, the share of distributed heat in total
heating in the residential, services and agriculture sectors rises somewhat
from current level of slightly over 11% in most scenarios, except for the High
RES scenario. This decrease in the share of distributed heat is compensated by
the increased direct use of biomass for heating, which soars from approx. 13.5%
in 2010 to approx. 33% in 2050 in the High RES scenario. Table 33: Share of distributed heat in total heating for
residential and tertiary || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || CPI || 11.6% || 12.0% || 12.0% || Energy Efficiency || 12.0% || 12.8% || 13.3% || Div. Supply Technology || 11.6% || 12.4% || 13.4% || High RES || 11.6% || 11.4% || 8.5% || Delayed CCS || 11.6% || 12.4% || 12.4% || Low Nuclear || 11.6% || 12.5% || 13.7% || Heat and steam
generation Heat from CHP
rises from 473 TWh in 2005 to 1030 TWh by 2025 in the High RES scenario and
then declines to 682 TWh by 2050. In other scenarios, including Energy
Efficiency, the rise continues until 2035 with the highest CHP generation in the
Low nuclear scenario at 1113, exhibiting a slight decline thereafter. CHP heat
production in 2050 covers a range from 682 TWh in the high RES scenario to 1019
TWh in the low nuclear case. As in the Reference scenario the growth is driven
by support policies resulting from the application of the CHP directive and ETS
carbon prices. CHP share in
power generation is the highest in the Low nuclear scenario reaching 22% in
2030. This share in 2030 is the lowest in the High RES scenario at 19%. By
2050, CHP share decline in all scenarios to 18% in Low nuclear and to 11% in
High RES scenarios reflecting higher penetration of wind and solar in power
generation (no combined production of heat possible) and electrification of
heating in combination with energy efficiency policies to reduce demand for
heat. District heating
is already declining from its 2000 levels of almost 190 TWh and this decline
continues in the Reference scenario as well as in decarbonisation scenarios to
109 TWh in the Reference scenario and 29 -52 TWh in decarbonisation scenarios.
The development of district heating is due to its benefits in reducing
emissions in the short and medium term but in the long run, similarly to CHP
plants, if district heating boilers do not use biomass, they emit GHG. RES in
heating and cooling The modelling of
energy demand formation by sector includes heating and cooling requirements as
well as a detailed coverage of various ways of satisfying these needs including
distributed heating and cooling from co-generation and district heating. As can
be seen from table 34, there is very significant progress in all
decarbonisation cases regarding the share of RES in heating and cooling. The
RES share in heating and cooling doubles between 2005 and 2020 in all scenarios,
reaching at least 44% by 2050 under decarbonisation. The highest share of well over
50% in 2050 is achieved in the High RES scenario. Table 34: Percentage share of RES in gross final consumption of
heating and cooling % share || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 CPI || 20.9 || 22.7 || 23.8 Energy Efficiency || 21.0 || 23.3 || 44.9 Div. Supply Technology || 20.9 || 23.8 || 44.0 High RES || 20.9 || 26.8 || 53.5 Delayed CCS || 20.9 || 24.2 || 44.9 Low Nuclear || 20.8 || 24.3 || 44.6 Transport In the decarbonisation scenarios, transport energy
demand is projected to decline by close to 40% below Reference in 2050 due to
active policies for tightening CO2 standards (essentially impacting on fuel
efficiency), taxation, internal market and infrastructure measures[11]. The highest energy
savings, in order of 155 Mtoe, are achieved in the Energy Efficiency scenario
but all decarbonisation scenarios deliver savings in the same order of
magnitude (around 150 Mtoe). Over 60% of these energy savings originate from
passengers transport. Energy intensity in passenger transport improves by
slightly over 60% between 2005 and 2050 in the decarbonisation scenarios,
mainly due to the enforcement of such efficiency standards. For freight
transport, the efficiency standards together with measures encouraging a shift
in modal choices lead to around 40% decrease in the energy intensity. The EU transport system would remain extremely dependent
on the use of fossil fuels in the Reference scenario. Oil products would still
represent 88% of the EU transport sector final demand in 2030 and 2050 in the Reference
scenario. Consumption of oil would decrease by 11% by 2050, relative to the
Reference scenario, in the Current Policy Initiatives scenario mainly driven by
the revision of the Energy Taxation Directive. In the decarbonisation scenarios, final consumption of
oil by transport is expected to decrease by almost 70% in 2050, relative to the
Reference scenario; the oil share in final demand would amount to around 45%.
This decline is compensated to a certain extent by the rise in the electricity
demand by road and rail transport and the increased demand for biofuels,
especially in aviation, inland navigation and long distance road freight, where
electrification is not or less an option. Biofuels would represent slightly
below 40% of energy consumption in aviation and inland navigation and 41% in
long distance road freight by 2050. The role of biofuels in energy demand by
passenger cars and light duty vehicles would be more limited, ranging between
13% and 15%. Electricity would provide around 65% of energy demand by passenger
cars and light duty vehicles in all decarbonisation scenarios. Electro-mobility
would need to be supported by the upgrade of Europe’s networks towards a
European super grid and decarbonisation of electricity sector. As a result of the higher demand for electricity and sustainable
biofuels, the share of renewables in transport would increase by 2050, ranging
between 62% and 73%. This difference between the decarbonisation scenarios can
be explained by the different power generation mix, despite similar shares of
biofuels and electricity demand in energy consumption by transport mean.
Therefore, the highest share of renewables in transport is achieved in the High
RES scenario.
2.5 Security of supply
Import
dependency in 2030 does not change substantially in decarbonisation scenarios
as compared to Reference scenario and Current Policy Initiatives scenario due
to decline in both gross inland consumption and imports. There is however a
substantial decrease in 2050, driven by increased use of domestic resources,
mainly renewables. Import dependency is only 35% in High RES scenario (compared
to 58% in the Reference scenario and Current Policy Initiatives scenario) and
39-40% in all other decarbonisation scenarios besides Low nuclear scenario (45%)
where it is higher due to significant use of fossil fuels with CCS.
Decarbonisation will significantly reduce fossil fuel security risks. Table 35: Import dependency % || 2009 || 2030 || 2050 1.Reference || 53.9 || 56.4 || 57.6 1 bis Current Policy Initiatives || 57.5 || 58.0 2. Energy efficiency || 56.1 || 39.7 3. Diversified supply technologies || 55.2 || 39.7 4. High RES || 55.3 || 35.1 5. Delayed CCS || 54.9 || 38.8 6. Low nuclear || 57.5 || 45.1 Large scale
electrification combined with more decentralised power generation from variable
sources brings other challenges to high quality energy service at any time. An
adequate stability of
the grid is a precondition for the consistent modelling of all scenarios; that
is why differences in indicators such as reserve margin are rather small. Utilisation
rates of electric capacities decrease from 49% in 2005 to 36% in 2050 in the
Reference scenario and to a range of 25% (High RES) to 33% (Diversified supply
technologies scenario) in decarbonisation scenarios. This reflects higher
requirements for reserve power and balancing services in order to keep supply
of electricity reliable and secure in all scenarios. All scenarios
see a high increase in the share of variable RES in the electricity supply;
this naturally leads to higher balancing requirements in the system. In the
long term the balancing is met to the greatest extent by increased pumped
storage (to the extent there is still increased potential available), the
development of flexible gas-based units, higher import-exports and in the case
of very high RES penetration with hydrogen based balancing. Thermal power
plants, mainly gas fired ones, remain available as reserve power and provide
ancillary services. The reduction in utilisation rates of thermal power plants
is driven by economic considerations, not by predetermined exogenous inputs. Utilisation
rates for steam stay stable in the Reference scenario at around 43% but
decrease to a range of 26% (High RES) and 36% (Diversified supply technologies
scenario) in decarbonisation scenarios. Energy savings and electrification in
heating which takes place in the decarbonisation scenarios limits the scope for
further expansion of distributed heat/steam and CHP, except in cases of
production with carbon free (or very low carbon content) resources (e.g.
biomass, gas mixed with hydrogen). Import-export
flows of electricity are also driven by economic considerations in the internal
market, for which simulations were carried out separately for every scenario.
This allows for trade between countries and therefore for optimal use of the
interconnections and generation capacities across countries, taking into
consideration the limits of the interconnector capacities, which have been
adapted according to the challenges posed by the different scenarios. . The
simulation thus allows for a better cost optimisation of the power generation
system across the EU Member States in the context of stable grid operations at
European level at any time. It emerges
clearly from table 36 that decarbonisation would involve greater electricity
trade among Member States, which is most pronounced in the case that
decarbonisation focuses overwhelmingly on RES. Table 36: Grid stability related
indicators Power Reserve Margin (%) || || Volume of electricity trade (TWh) Ratio of dispatchable nominal capacities with RES contributing with (small) capacity credits divided by total peak demand (EU net imports not included) || || Sum of all export and import flows of electricity as simulated by the model (lower than in reality) || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || || || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 Reference || 24,1 || 16,0 || 17,7 || || Reference || 212,1 || 217,6 || 222,3 Scenario 1bis || 26,8 || 19,1 || 22,0 || || Scenario 1bis || 255,8 || 307,5 || 322,8 Scenario 2 || 29,1 || 24,6 || 27,8 || || Scenario 2 || 303,1 || 450,8 || 618,9 Scenario 3 || 25,7 || 21,2 || 23,8 || || Scenario 3 || 326,6 || 476,1 || 623,6 Scenario 4 || 25,6 || 21,7 || 32,2 || || Scenario 4 || 304,4 || 602,8 || 1040,9 Scenario 5 || 25,7 || 21,7 || 25,9 || || Scenario 5 || 322,8 || 489,0 || 648,6 Scenario 6 || 25,1 || 20,4 || 26,3 || || Scenario 6 || 317,8 || 482,5 || 599,1 || || || || || || || || Contribution of electricity storage (%) || || Volume of electricity trade as % of gross final electricity demand Extraction of electricity from storage systems as percentage of gross final demand of electricity || || Sum of all export and import flows of electricity as simulated by the model (lower than in reality) as percentage of gross final electricity demand || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || || || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 Reference || 1,2 || 1,1 || 1,3 || || Reference || 6,0 || 5,7 || 4,9 Scenario 1bis || 1,1 || 1,1 || 1,1 || || Scenario 1bis || 7,4 || 8,6 || 7,4 Scenario 2 || 1,1 || 1,3 || 1,0 || || Scenario 2 || 9,0 || 13,7 || 15,4 Scenario 3 || 1,1 || 1,2 || 1,0 || || Scenario 3 || 9,4 || 13,2 || 13,6 Scenario 4 || 1,1 || 1,2 || 6,5 || || Scenario 4 || 8,8 || 17,0 || 24,3 Scenario 5 || 1,1 || 1,2 || 1,0 || || Scenario 5 || 9,3 || 13,6 || 14,3 Scenario 6 || 1,1 || 1,2 || 1,1 || || Scenario 6 || 9,1 || 13,7 || 13,4 || || || || || || || || Share of decentralised power generation (%) || || Investment in electricity grids (bn EUR'08) Share of generation by small scale power plants which are connected to low voltage and medium voltage grid over total net power generation || || Investment expenditure on electricity networks over the indicated time period || 2020 || 2030 || 2050 || || || 2006-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2050 Reference || 6,3 || 9,1 || 10,6 || || Reference || 389,9 || 308,0 || 649,0 Scenario 1bis || 6,5 || 10,0 || 13,9 || || Scenario 1bis || 387,3 || 291,1 || 773,6 Scenario 2 || 7,1 || 13,1 || 21,8 || || Scenario 2 || 405,4 || 352,2 || 860,5 Scenario 3 || 7,2 || 13,0 || 20,9 || || Scenario 3 || 436,8 || 416,1 || 958,9 Scenario 4 || 7,2 || 17,3 || 31,3 || || Scenario 4 || 434,4 || 535,5 || 1323,5 Scenario 5 || 7,2 || 13,1 || 21,4 || || Scenario 5 || 436,2 || 420,4 || 960,9 Scenario 6 || 7,1 || 14,0 || 24,3 || || Scenario 6 || 438,9 || 424,6 || 1029,0
2.6 Policy related indicators
Emissions and
ETS prices All decarbonisation scenarios
achieve 80% GHG reduction and close to 85% energy related CO2 reductions
(83.4-84.4%) in 2050 compared to 1990 as well as equal cumulative emissions
over the projection period. In 2030, energy-related CO2 emissions are between
38-41% lower, and total GHG emissions reductions are lower by 40-42%. In 2040,
energy related CO2 emissions are 63-66% below their 1990 level, while total GHG
emission fall by 61-63%. Power generation would be almost
completely decarbonised with CO2 emissions in 2050 plummeting 96-99% compared
with 1990. CO2 emission reductions by 2050 are particularly high (minus 86-88%)
also in the services/agriculture sector as well as in households (minus
85-87%). Energy related CO2 emissions in industry fall 77-79% below their 1990
level. Transport CO2 emission are 60-62% lower in 2050 compared with 1990. The ETS price rises moderately from current level until 2030 and
significantly in the last two decades providing support to all low carbon
technologies and energy efficiency. Concrete policy measures such as those
pushing energy efficiency and/or those enabling penetration of renewables
depress demand for ETS allowances which subsequently lead to lower carbon
prices. Carbon prices are the lowest in the Energy Efficiency scenario where
energy demand is the lowest followed by High RES scenario (second lowest in
2030 and 2040) and the Diversified supply technology scenario (second lowest in
2050). Delay in penetration of technologies (CCS) or unavailability of one
decarbonisation option (nuclear) put an upwards pressure on demand for
allowances and ETS prices. Table 37: ETS prices in €'08/t CO2 || 2020 || 2030 || 2040 || 2050 Reference scenario || 18 || 40 || 52 || 50 Current Policy Initiatives || 15 || 32 || 49 || 51 Energy Efficiency || 15 || 25 || 87 || 234 Diversifies supply technologies || 25 || 52 || 95 || 265 High RES || 25 || 35 || 92 || 285 Delayed CCS || 25 || 55 || 190 || 270 Low nuclear || 20 || 63 || 100 || 310 The same carbon
value as in the ETS applies also to non-ETS sectors after 2020 assuring
cost-efficient emissions abatement in the whole economy. CCS storage needs Making use of the CCS option will require considerable storage
capacities for CO2 over time. The Reference scenario developments, including a
more optimistic picture on CCS demonstration and availability of storage sites,
would require storage capacity for the cumulative CO2 emissions captured up to
2050 of 8 billion tonnes of CO2. In the CPI scenario, CCS penetration is more moderate leading to
storage requirements of 3 bn t CO2 up to 2050. The lowest storage needs come
about under high RES scenario, in which case the additional storage
requirements over CPI amount to 0.5 bn t CO2. The highest storage needs comes
in the Low nuclear scenario leading to considerable CCS penetration, which
requires almost 13 bn t CO2 storage capacity up to 2050. Also the Diversified
Supply Technology scenario would require considerable storage capacity. Table 38: CCS storage needs for power
generation and industrial processes up to 2050 (in bn t CO2) RES targets and
biomass The Reference scenario
assumes that the RES target is reached in 2020. The RES share (as % of gross
final energy consumption according to the definition of the RES directive) is
slightly higher in all decarbonisation scenario in 2020 (21%), rises to at
least 28% in 2030 and 55% in 2050. In the High RES scenario this share is at
31% in 2030 and 75% in 2050. The share of renewables in
power generation is even higher and stands at 86% in 2050 in the High RES
scenario. The share in consumption is even higher, since with much more
variable supply and demand some electricity produced needs to be stored and
losses linked to such storage processes lead to lower consumption compared to
production, i.e. reducing significantly the denominator of such a share. When
calculating the RES-E share in line with the calculation of the overall RES
share in gross final energy consumption, i.e. excluding energy losses linked to
pump storage and hydrogen storage of electricity, the RES share in electricity
consumption amounts to 97% in 2050 in the High RES case. The share of renewables in
transport (target of 10% for 2020 in the RES directive) is 1 percentage point
higher in all decarbonisation scenarios in 2020; it rises to 19%-20% in 2030
and to 62%-73% in 2050. The share of renewables in transport in the High RES
scenario is 20% in 2030 and even 73% in 2050. The increase between 2030 and
2050 as well as the difference to the Reference scenario and Current Policy
Initiatives scenario of almost 50 percentage points in 2050 for the
decarbonisation scenarios is remarkable and shows the importance of RES based
decarbonisation of transport, either directly via biofuels or indirectly via
RES based electricity. Decarbonisation efforts and RES share in transport are
rather moderate till 2030 but rise significantly from 2030 to 2050. The large share of RES in
the scenarios is driven by a strong support for RES in the form of an implicit
facilitation of RES in the scenarios. These lead to shifts in RES potential
curves in the decarbonisation scenarios, allowing for more RES exploitation at
a given deployment cost level, compared to the Reference scenario. This
includes facilitation policies such as: - For biomass: agricultural policies stimulating the production of
energy crops, increased residue collection, and/or increased yield of crops; - For wind: regarding on-shore it comprises the availability of more
land area and a facilitation of the licensing requirements; for off-shore it
also represents a facilitation of licensing and the development of technologies
that allow placing off-shore power plants in deeper areas or further offshore;
and - For small scale solar PV and wind: development of smart grids and
other facilitation policies. The total use of biomass in the various scenarios is shown in table
39. Whereas the Reference and CPI scenarios have about 100 Mtoe more biomass
use in 2050 compared with today's level, there is around 70-80 Mtoe additional
biomass use in most decarbonisation scenarios in 2050, except for the high RES
case, in which the additional biomass use amounts to around 120 Mtoe. Table 39: Use of biomass and biofuels ktoe || 2005 || Reference scenario || Current policy Initiatives 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Total domestic biomass || 86285 || 179649 || 185863 || 175987 || 188914 of which biofuels || 3129 || 35255 || 36957 || 34295 || 38912 Biofuels in bunkers || 0 || 0 || 0 || 133 || 2325 Total use of biomass || 86285 || 179649 || 185863 || 176120 || 191239 || || Energy efficiency || Diversified supply technologies || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Total domestic biomass || || 162716 || 241476 || 172145 || 253209 of which biofuels || || 25033 || 68393 || 26174 || 71047 Biofuels in bunkers || || 553 || 18062 || 553 || 17995 Total use of biomass || || 163268 || 259538 || 172698 || 271204 || || High RES || Delayed CCS || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Total domestic biomass || || 188675 || 301805 || 172953 || 252893 of which biofuels || || 26296 || 72453 || 26112 || 69370 Biofuels in bunkers || || 553 || 18060 || 552 || 17523 Total use of biomass || || 189227 || 319865 || 173505 || 270415 || || Low nuclear || || || || 2030 || 2050 || || Total domestic biomass || || 175360 || 257226 || || of which biofuels || || 26135 || 70794 || || Biofuels in bunkers || || 553 || 17981 || || Total use of biomass || || 175913 || 275206 || || Biofuel
consumption rises by a factor of more than ten between 2005 and 2050 under
current policies to reach 37-39 Mtoe in 2050. Decarbonisation of transport
requires substantially greater biofuels use, which increases to 68-72 Mtoe in
2050, with the highest levels being reached in the High RES and Diversified
Supply Technology scenarios.
2.7 Overall system costs,
competitiveness and other socio-economic impacts
This section
deals with the costs for providing the energy services to the EU economy and society.
One key element of such costs is the external fuel bill, i.e. the amount of
money that they EU economy has to pay to the outside world for procuring all
the net imports of oil, gas and solid fuels from the rest of the world. The external
fuel bill arising from the net imports of fossil fuels decreases below 2005
levels in all decarbonisation scenarios by 2050. This result stems from the
pursuit of this major decarbonisation as a part of a global effort with
industrial countries as a group reducing GHG emissions by 80%. In such a global
setting, fossil fuel import prices will be much lower (see part on assumptions)
and actual imports of fossil fuel will be much lower, too. These both effects
reduce the expenditure for each of the fossil fuels and thereby the total
external fuel bill of the EU. The decrease of the fuel bill in the
decarbonisation scenarios is smallest in the Low Nuclear scenario at 31% and
highest in the high RES scenario with 43% with RES replacing most fossil fuels. Compared with current
level, all decarbonisation scenarios increase the external fuel bill in 2030,
but to much lower levels than the Reference and Current Policy Initiative
scenarios. While the external fuel bill would double between 2005 and 2030
under Reference and Current Policy Initiatives developments, this increase
would be limited to around 40% under these decarbonisation policies. Table 40: External fossil fuel bill (in bn
€ (08)) || 2005 || Reference || CPI || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Bn. EUR'08 || 269.1 || 549.2 || 752.2 || 531.9 || 704.2 Diff. to 2005 || || 104% || 180% || 98% || 162% || || Energy Efficiency || Diversified supply technologies || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Bn. EUR'08 || || 364.5 || 165.7 || 379.0 || 180.1 Diff. to 2005 || || 35% || -38% || 41% || -33% || || High RES || Delayed CCS || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Bn. EUR'08 || || 374.8 || 154.2 || 377.0 || 180.4 Diff. to 2005 || || 39% || -43% || 40% || -33% || || Low nuclear || || || || 2030 || 2050 || || Bn. EUR'08 || || 382.0 || 186.4 || || Diff. to 2005 || || 42% || -31% || || Savings in the external
fuel bill are most striking in 2050. Compared with Current Policy Initiatives,
the EU economy could save in 2050 between 518 and 550 bn € (08) by going this
strong decarbonisation route under global climate action. The largest energy
bill savings come about in the high RES scenario. Such fuel bill savings have
strong impacts on overall energy system costs. Total costs for the entire
energy system include capital costs (for energy installations such as power
plants and energy infrastructure, energy using equipment, appliances and
vehicles), fuel and electricity costs and direct efficiency investment costs
(house insulation, control systems, energy management, etc), the latter being
also expenditures of capital nature. Capital costs are expressed in annuity
payments. Total costs exclude disutility and auction payments. Auction payments are expenditures for
individual actors/sectors that are not costs for the economy as a whole, since
the auctioning revenues are recycled back to the economy. Disutility costs are
a concept that captures losses in utility from adaptations of individuals to
policy impulses or other influences through changing behaviour and energy
consumption patterns that might bring them on a lower level in their utility
function. Such disutility costs correspond to a
monetary estimation (income compensating variation) of lower utility from
useful energy services (lighting, heating, mobility, etc.) resulting from a
more rational use behaviour by consumers who for example adjusts thermostats,
switch lighting off or travel less in order to adapt to higher costs of useful
energy services. Such costs monetisation captures relevant issues
regarding new consumption patterns especially for a short to medium time
horizon, but becomes more challenging and uncertain in the long term, given
that monetisation requires the comparison with a
counterfactual development assuming unchanged tastes, habits and values
over up to 40 years.[12]
Table 41: Energy system costs Average annual energy system costs 2011-2050 || || || Bn. EUR'08 || Ref || CPI || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Capital cost || 955 || 995 || 1115 || 1100 || 1089 || 1094 || 1104 Energy purchases || 1622 || 1611 || 1220 || 1295 || 1355 || 1297 || 1311 Direct efficiency inv. costs * || 28 || 36 || 295 || 160 || 164 || 161 || 161 Total system cost excl. all auction payments and disutility ** || 2582 || 2619 || 2615 || 2535 || 2590 || 2525 || 2552 || || || || || || || Absolute Difference to Reference || || || || || || Bn. EUR'08 || || || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Δ Capital cost || || || 160 || 145 || 134 || 139 || 149 Δ Energy purchases || || || -402 || -327 || -267 || -325 || -312 Δ Direct efficiency inv. costs * || || || 267 || 132 || 135 || 133 || 133 Δ Total system cost excl. all auction payments and disutility ** || 33 || -47 || 8 || -57 || -29 || || || || || || || Absolute Difference to CPI || || || || || || || Bn. EUR'08 || || || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Δ Capital cost || || || 120 || 105 || 94 || 99 || 109 Δ Energy purchases || || || -391 || -316 || -256 || -314 || -300 Δ Direct efficiency inv. costs * || || || 260 || 125 || 128 || 126 || 125 Δ Total system cost excl. all auction payments and disutility ** || -4 || -84 || -29 || -94 || -67 || || || || || || || Percentage change to Reference || || || || || || % || || || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Capital cost || || || 16,8 || 15,2 || 14,0 || 14,6 || 15,6 Energy purchases || || || -24,8 || -20,2 || -16,5 || -20,0 || -19,2 Direct efficiency inv. costs * || || || 937,3 || 462,4 || 475,0 || 466,9 || 465,5 Total system cost excl. all auction payments and disutility ** || 1,3 || -1,8 || 0,3 || -2,2 || -1,1 || || || || || || || Percentage change to CPI || || || || || || || % || || || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Capital cost || || || 12,0 || 10,5 || 9,5 || 10,0 || 10,9 Energy purchases || || || -24,3 || -19,6 || -15,9 || -19,5 || -18,6 Direct efficiency inv. costs * || || || 729,5 || 349,8 || 359,9 || 353,4 || 352,2 Total system cost excl. all auction payments and disutility ** || -0,1 || -3,2 || -1,1 || -3,6 || -2,5 * Include costs for insulation, double/triple
glazing and for efficiency enhancing changes in production processes not
accounted for under energy capital and fuel/electricity purchase costs; ** These macroeconomic costs do not include ETS
auctioning payments that represent a cost from the individual economic actors
point of view, but do not present a cost to society given that auctioning
revenues are recycled back to the economy (societal perspective); auctioning payments are partly included
in energy purchase costs (e.g. in electricity prices) and partly paid directly
by actors subject to ETS; total costs in table 41 differ from the sum of the
items shown; table 42 on additional information below gives more detail Table 42: Additional information on auctioning
payments, disutility and total costs from the individual economic actor's
point of view (bn € (08) per year on average in 2011-2050) Bn. EUR'08 || Ref || CPI || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Auctioning payments || 30 || 28 || 20 || 27 || 24 || 36 || 30 Total energy system cost (a) || 2612 || 2647 || 2635 || 2562 || 2614 || 2561 || 2583 Disutility costs (b) || 92 || 112 || 153 || 174 || 181 || 211 || 190 Total energy system costs including auction payments and disutility (c) || 2704 || 2759 || 2788 || 2735 || 2795 || 2773 || 2772 (a) From the individual
economic actors' point of view, including direct and indirect (via purchase of
e.g. electricity) auctioning costs, but excluding disutility costs; (b) Disutility costs are
costs stemming from behavioural change, such as changing lighting quality,
lowering thermostat temperature, replacing fuel consuming mobility with other
types of mobility (e.g. bikes) or telecommunication that are not accounted for
by expenditure flows in the model, but change the level of utility of
consumers; such changes are linked to carbon values in non-ETS (which do not
represent a cost in cash terms), but are a proxy for policy measures bringing
about such behavioural change; direct costs of such change in terms of
investment and fuel bills are accounted for in the normal modelling procedure;
given the long time horizon and possibly changing preference, the estimation of
disutility costs is surrounded with uncertainty. (c) From the individual
economic actors' point of view, including direct and indirect (via purchase of
e.g. electricity) auctioning costs as well as disutility costs; NB: The lower system cost (without
auctioning revenue and disutility) in the Delayed CCS scenario compared with
the Diversified supply technologies scenario (that is unrestricted regarding
technology) is not present when auctioning revenues and disutility costs are
included, i.e. the point of view of the economic actors is taken (numbers
denoted with (c) above). In this case, the Diversified Supply Technology scenario
has the lowest costs. The modelling approach simulates the system from the
point of view of economic actors, who perceive auctioning payments and
disutility as cost to them that they want to minimise. Disutility costs are however
surrounded with uncertainty given the long time horizon and their dependence on
preferences and values. Moreover they represent a monetary equivalent in terms
of imputed income compensation of changes in utility and are not associated
with payments represented in the process of modelling (e.g. energy purchases,
investment sums). Given the uncertain and somewhat controversial nature of
disutility costs for a 40 year time horizon this long term assessment of
economic impacts reports on costs without disutility. Furthermore, taking a
macro-economic perspective auctioning revenues can be seen as transfers as they
are supposed to be recycled, justifying their exclusion from the macro-economic
cost evaluation. The average
additional energy system cost per year from 2011 to 2050 compared with the
Reference and Current Policy Initiatives scenario are rather small due to the
pursuit of this major decarbonisation as a part of a global effort. Given that
the Current Policy Initiatives scenario is the most up to date current trend
scenario and that all decarbonisation scenarios base themselves on this updated
baseline, the following comparison starts from the CPI scenario (1bis). The Delayed CCS
scenarios and the Diversified Supply Technologies have the lowest level of
average annual energy system costs, representing even a cost saving compared
with CPI (of 94 bn €(08) and 84 bn €(08), respectively) given the large fossil
fuel import cost savings discussed above. These are scenarios, in which there
is a rather high nuclear penetration in addition to substantial RES penetration
and strong energy efficiency progress. Given these fossil fuel import bill
effects, also the Low Nuclear Scenario would produce average annual fuel bill
savings of 67 bn € (08) when compared with CPI. The High RES scenario gives
rise to a annual energy system cost saving of 29 bn € (08) when compared with
CPI, while the annual cost savings for the Energy Efficiency scenario amount to
4 bn €(08). The cost savings
in the Energy Efficiency scenario are smaller (4 bn €) given that very high
energy efficiency progress requires strong action on the building stock
entailing major expenditure for accelerated building renovation, in addition to
costs for other energy efficient equipment including the costly transition to
electric and plug in hybrid vehicles. High renovation rates are one of the salient
features of the energy efficiency scenario. Electro-mobility also provides for
greater energy efficiency in the system. However, this higher cost does not
disqualify energy efficiency policies as such, as strong energy efficiency
policies leading to substantial improvements and energy savings, are present in
all scenarios. The Energy efficiency scenario just shows that there are certain
limits from where on other decarbonisation routes are less costly than further reductions
of energy consumption. All scenarios
show higher annual costs in the last two decades 2031-2050 reflecting mainly
increased investments in transport equipment as the major transition to
electric and plug in hybrids vehicles is projected after 2030. In High RES
scenario costs are also linked to significant expansion of RES based power
generation capacity. Cumulative
auction payments are lowest in Energy efficiency
scenario due to the reduced energy consumption, decreasing emissions and
therefore the necessity to buy ETS permits. The scenario with the highest
auction revenues is Delayed CCS where the delay in the use of CCS leads to high
carbon prices in the long-term to ensure the achievement of the decarbonisation
target via the uptake of this technology in these later years. The PRIMES model
works with perfect foresight in the supply side module, therefore the high
carbon prices are expected, influencing choices already in previous years. The
auction revenues represent an equivalent of around 1% of total cumulative
energy system costs. When relating
the cumulative costs to the GDP (which remains constant in these
scenarios) the ratio of costs to GDP is similar across the scenarios (around
14.1% to 14.6%) exhibiting costs at the low end of the range in case of
diversified supply technologies and delayed CCS. Table 43: Energy system costs (without auction payments and
disutility) related to GDP || Cumulative costs as percentage of GDP (*) Reference || 14.37% CPI || 14.58% Energy Efficiency || 14.56% Diversified Supply Technology || 14.11% High RES || 14.42% Delayed CCS || 14.06% Low Nuclear || 14.21% Change in cost
structure: fixed costs versus variable costs The composition of energy costs changes
over time and varies across scenarios. The share of fixed cost (capital costs
including for e.g. insulation) rises in all scenarios. Following larger capital
expenditure for e.g. power generation, grids, energy efficiency investment over
time energy, the progress in energy efficiency, greater use of technologies
with low operating costs (most RES) and lower world fossil fuel prices in the
decarbonisation scenarios bring lower fuel and emission allowances costs.
Consequently, the share of capital costs increases over time, especially in the
Energy Efficiency and High RES scenarios, which have the highest fixed cost
shares (see table 44). Table 44: Share of fixed costs* in total energy costs** (averages
over the time periods indicated) Energy related costs for companies Energy related costs in relation to
sectoral value added rise from 5.8% in 2005 to 7.8% in 2030 in the
Reference/CPI cases and to around 7.5% in the decarbonisation scenarios. In
2050, under current policies, this indicator declines to 7.5% and even more so
in the decarbonisation scenarios falling to under 7%. Long term energy costs relative
to value added of companies under decarbonisation are lower in the
decarbonisation cases than under current policies thanks to substantial global
decarbonisation efforts. Whereas relative costs for stationary use (heating,
process energy, appliances, lighting, etc) in the decarbonisation scenarios
remain at the current level by 2030, there is a strong increase in costs
related to value added for transport services. After 2030, both stationary and
transport energy costs decline somewhat when related to value added. Overall,
energy costs relative to value added in 2050 are only somewhat higher than they
were in 2005 under decarbonisation, whereas there would be a much more
pronounced increase of such costs in the absence of such decarbonisation under significant
global climate action. Table 15: Energy related costs of companies % || 2005 || Reference || Scenario 1 bis 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Ratio of energy related costs to value added || 5.8 || 7.8 || 7.5 || 7.8 || 7.5 of which stationary uses || 4.3 || 4.8 || 4.5 || 4.6 || 4.3 of which transportation uses || 1.5 || 3.0 || 2.9 || 3.1 || 3.1 || || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Ratio of energy related costs to value added || || 7.6 || 6.6 || 7.4 || 6.4 of which stationary uses || || 4.4 || 3.9 || 4.2 || 3.8 of which transportation uses || || 3.2 || 2.7 || 3.1 || 2.6 || || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Ratio of energy related costs to value added || || 7.3 || 6.9 || 7.4 || 6.3 of which stationary uses || || 4.3 || 4.1 || 4.2 || 3.8 of which transportation uses || || 3.0 || 2.7 || 3.2 || 2.5 || || Scenario 6 || || || || 2030 || 2050 || || Ratio of energy related costs to value added || || 7.5 || 6.5 || || of which stationary uses || || 4.3 || 3.8 || || of which transportation uses || || 3.2 || 2.7 || || Energy
intensive industries face particularly high energy costs for their highly
energy consuming production processes. Five industrial sectors (iron and steel,
non-ferrous metals, non metallic mineral products, chemicals, paper and pulp
industries) have such high energy costs and are therefore
particularly concerned by potential changes from decarbonisation in the energy
component of their costs. Table 46 shows for these energy intensive industries
combined the ratio of energy related costs for production processes and
other stationary use, on the one hand, and their value added, on the
other. Table46: Ratio of energy related costs to value added for energy
intensive industries || 2005 || 2030 || 2050 Reference || 33.7% || 40.8% || 40.5% CPI || || 39.4% || 39.5% Energy Efficiency || || 35.6% || 30.6% Diversified Supply Technologies || || 36.4% || 32.4% High RES || || 36.1% || 34.8% Delayed CCS || || 36.5% || 33.2% Low Nuclear || || 37.1% || 33.5% Energy costs of energy
intensive industries relative to value added would increase under Reference and
CPI developments. This development stems also from rising world fossil fuel
prices under current trends. It is worth noting that under global climate
action bringing with it lower energy import prices and due to substantial
energy efficiency progress, the ratio of energy costs to value added in energy
intensive industries would decline in all decarbonisation scenarios – most markedly
in the Energy Efficiency scenario Effects of fragmented climate action:
competitiveness and energy consequences of safeguards for energy intensive
industries This Energy
Roadmap has assumed the implementation of the European Council's decarbonisation
objective that includes similar efforts by industrialised countries as a group.
The analysis presented focuses on energy consequences. A more comprehensive
analysis of different global paths to decarbonisation was presented in the Low
Carbon Economy Roadmap 2050[13]
exploring impacts of three global climate situations: a) business as usual; b)
global climate action and c) fragmented action. Fragmented action assumes
strong EU climate action that is however followed globally only by the low end
of Copenhagen pledges up to 2020 and afterwards the ambition level of the
pledges is assumed to stay constant. It analyses impacts on energy intensive
industries (EII) both in a global macroeconomic modelling framework to address
carbon leakage issues and by means of energy system modelling to address
effects of fragmented action, including electricity costs for companies.
Electricity costs are, in fact, higher in the fragmented action scenarios as
compared to global action scenarios due to higher energy import prices. On the
other hand, carbon prices are lower under fragmented action. A
"fragmented" action scenario including measures against carbon
leakage was not analysed in this IA report as the challenges for the energy
sector arising from decarbonisation are the biggest under "global climate
action" assumption, given that fragmented action with measures against
carbon leakage will deliver lower GHG reductions by 2050. Decarbonisation
scenarios that accommodate action against carbon leakage under fragmented
action would either go for lower ambitions in terms of GHG reduction or would
have measures included that imply such lower efforts for energy intensive
industries and consequently for the total energy system[14]. With action on carbon leakage
the challenge for the transition in the energy system would be smaller given
lower efforts in parts of the system. Such results are however modified through
countervailing effects from lower world fossil fuel prices under global action
that encourage somewhat higher energy consumption and emissions. In any case,
the implementation of measures will be crucial. The real difference for
industrial and thereby climate policy might come from the concrete design of
policy instruments that is not discussed in this Energy Roadmap Impact Assessment
(e.g. special provisions on ETS for EII). From the
analysis undertaken for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap it can be concluded that
under fragmented action with the EU reducing emissions much more than other
regions, certain industries supplying low carbon technologies would benefit
from improved competitiveness due to higher internal demand and first mover
advantages. However, EII would suffer from higher costs for allowances and/or
significant mitigation costs in order to avoid the need to purchase such
allowances. Furthermore, under fragmented action they would not benefit from
the fuel and electricity price reductions stemming from a global climate deal
that lowers world fossil fuel prices. This situation
of fragmented action might require countervailing action to combat carbon
leakage, which was investigated in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap, notably by
exploring a scenario, in which energy intensive industries (iron and steel,
non-ferrous metals, chemicals, non metallic minerals, paper and pulp
industries) would benefit from the same ETS prices that prevail in the
reference scenario, whereas other sectors would be exposed to higher carbon
costs. These provisions have only a limited impact on the CO2 emission
reduction of all sectors, which instead of reaching minus 86% on 1990 under
fragmented action (85% under global action) would amount to 78% with these
specific provisions for EII. Clearly, the CO2 emission reduction for EII, i.e.
their level of effort, would be reduced more markedly, falling from 87%
reduction below 1990 under fragmented action (88% under global action) to only
51% by 2050. These measures
keeping the ETS price for energy intensive industries at the reference case
levels lead to significant cost savings for purchasing fuel, electricity, steam
and energy using equipment. Compared with the reference case situation with no
additional climate action, the average costs in 2011-2050 decrease by 6 bn €
(08) annually over 40 years. Higher energy, especially electricity prices from
decarbonisation action together with the still significant carbon price signal
lead to significant energy savings in energy intensive industries (22.7% in
2050 from Reference). These cost
savings take into account that electricity prices rise significantly under
fragmented action (7% in 2050 compared with Reference) and this to a higher
degree than under global action given that the cost reducing effect through
lower fossil fuel input prices (global action reducing world fossil fuel
demand) would not materialise. Electricity prices in 2050 would be 6 % lower on
average under global climate action compared with fragmented action with specific
measures for EII. Under global
action, the energy saving effect of energy intensive industries is reinforced
through higher carbon prices, entailing even greater energy savings. Combined
with lower fossil fuel import and therefore final consumer prices, there would
be additional cost savings, amounting to 21 bn € per year from 2011 to 2050
when comparing global climate action with fragmented action with less effort
for EII.[15] Table 47
compares the energy related results of decarbonisation scenario under
fragmented action with specific carbon leakage measures for energy intensive
industries with the Reference case. It includes also a comparison between
global action and fragmented action with these specific measures for energy
intensive industries. The energy results for this analysis are taken from the
energy modelling results for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap, which includes, in
addition to the Reference scenario, the Fragmented action, effective technology
and less effort for EII scenario and the Effective Technology Global Action
scenario. The effective
technology scenarios are driven by carbon prices and assume the absence of
significant obstacles for technology penetration, especially CCS and nuclear,
as well as the absence of specific strong push for RES and energy efficiency.
The rationale of these scenarios is similar to the Diversified Supply
Technologies scenario, which includes however recent policy initiatives,
especially on energy efficiency and energy taxation as well as recent changes in
nuclear policies. The most relevant comparison of energy results when dealing
with carbon leakage in the case of Fragmented action, effective technology and
less effort for EII is therefore in relation to Reference (no additional
climate action), on the one hand, and Effective Technology under global climate
action, on the other. Table 47: Comparison of energy results for
2050* between fragmented action with specific measures for energy intensive
industries (FAEII) and Reference as well as between global action and FAEII || Less effort for EII compared with Reference || Global action compared with less effort for EII Final energy consumption EII Other sectors Primary energy consumption Gross electricity generation ** Average electricity prices Energy related CO2 emissions Import dependency RES share in gross final energy demand Cumulative investment expenditure in power generation Average annual fuel, electricity and equipment costs || -22.7% -33.6% -24.1% +10.3% +7.2% -72.4% -26.2 pp +26.6 pp +30.1% -6 bn || -11.2% +1.6% +2.5% +6.6% -5.7% +1.2% +1.3 pp -0.3 pp +1.2% -21 bn * For investment
expenditure and costs this comparison relates to the 40 year period up to 2050 ** including new uses,
such as hydrogen as a means for electricity storage and for feeding into the
gas grid thereby contributing to decarbonisation by lowering the carbon content
of the gas supplied Climate action
with specific measures for EII against carbon leakages leads to quite
significant energy consequences in 2050 compared to reference regarding energy
consumption, fuel and electricity costs, prices and emissions. Import
dependency would fall strongly, whereas the RES share would rise to a large
extent. Investment in power generation would also need to rise strongly while
average costs would fall significantly. Energy
consumption of EII would drop further significantly when undertaking
decarbonisation in the context of global action, as EII would face higher
carbon prices in this case (the same as other sectors). The small increase of
energy consumption and emission levels (outside EII) when moving to global
action stem from the markedly lower fossil fuel prices under globally reduced
demand. Energy related results are either reinforced, if the policy response to
climate change moved from fragmented action with specific carbon leakage
measures for EII to global action without such measures, or they are modified
reflecting the impacts from lower fossil fuel prices. Energy related expenditures of households Affordability of energy services as regards fuel and electricity
costs but also equipment (insulation, more efficient appliances, etc) is one of
the essential elements of the analysis. The sector that is mostly concerned is households.
All decarbonisation scenarios show significant fuel savings compared to the
Reference and CPI scenarios but also higher costs for energy appliances, boilers
and insulation. Energy related expenditures for heating and cooling of
households as well as for lighting and appliances almost double from around
2000 EUR'08/year today to 3800 to 3900 EUR'08 in 2050 in the Reference and CPI
scenarios reflecting rising fuel and electricity prices and increasing direct
household investments in energy efficiency. Expenditures per household amount
to some 4500 EUR'08 in most decarbonisation scenarios in 2050, with expenditure
per household reaching some 4800 € (08) and almost 4900 € (08) in the Energy
Efficiency and high RES scenarios respectively. It is important to note that per capita income in 2050 will also
almost double from today's level, but also that households will be composed of
fewer members reflecting aging and changing lifestyles. Energy costs per
household exceed the Reference/CPI case level by 16-17% in 2050 in most
decarbonisation scenarios. They are 25-27% higher in the Energy Efficiency and
High RES scenarios, as these scenarios are particularly intensive in
investment. While these costs might be affordable by an average household,
vulnerable consumers might need specific support to cope with increased
expenditures due to decarbonisation. Households spend money on transport services, too. Such costs
concern expenses on tickets for rail, bus, metro, air and other travel as well
as costs for purchasing privately owned vehicles and paying for other fuel and
operational expenses. These transport costs per household would even almost
triple by 2050 reaching 3900 € (08) and 4100 € (08) in the Reference and CPI
case, respectively. The strong growth of such costs reflects rising oil prices
as well as changes in the vehicle fleet towards more efficient cars (hybrids,
plug in hybrids, electric cars) that involve higher costs[16]. In the
decarbonisation scenarios, transport related energy costs per households are
lower in 2050 than under Reference or CPI developments, markedly so (broadly
around 10%) under Diversified Supply Technologies and delayed CCS, given
substantial improvements in energy efficiency in transport and limited price
increases with respect to reference for transport fuel. Relating the costs of households for
stationary energy use (heating, appliances, etc) plus those for transport to
household expenditure gives the following picture. The share of energy in household expenditure rises over time in all scenarios
from 10% in 2005 to around 16% in 2030, decreasing thereafter to around 15-16%
by 2050. Among the decarbonisation scenarios, the Delayed CCS and the
Diversified Supply Technology scenarios have costs at the lower end of this
range, whereas the High RES and Energy efficiency scenarios show 2050 costs at
the upper end of the range. Table 48: Energy related expenditures of household for stationary use
and transport % || 2005 || Reference || Scenario 1 bis 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Share of energy related costs in household expenditure || 9.9 || 15.9 || 14.6 || 16.1 || 15.1 of which stationary uses || 5.7 || 8.0 || 7.3 || 7.9 || 7.3 of which transportation uses || 4.2 || 7.9 || 7.3 || 8.2 || 7.8 || || Scenario 2 || Scenario 3 || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Share of energy related costs in household expenditure || || 16.5 || 16.1 || 15.9 || 15.4 of which stationary uses || || 7.9 || 9.1 || 7.5 || 8.4 of which transportation uses || || 8.6 || 7.0 || 8.4 || 6.9 || || Scenario 4 || Scenario 5 || || 2030 || 2050 || 2030 || 2050 Share of energy related costs in household expenditure || || 15.8 || 16.4 || 15.9 || 15.1 of which stationary uses || || 7.7 || 9.2 || 7.5 || 8.5 of which transportation uses || || 8.1 || 7.1 || 8.4 || 6.6 || || Scenario 6 || || || || 2030 || 2050 || || Share of energy related costs in household expenditure || || 16.1 || 15.5 || || of which stationary uses || || 7.5 || 8.5 || || of which transportation uses || || 8.6 || 7.0 || || Whereas
companies enjoy long term energy costs relative to value added that are lower
(or at most as high) as such costs under current policy initiatives, the 2050
energy costs of households relative to household expenditure generally exceed
such costs without strong decarbonisation albeit only to a rather small extent,
especially under Delayed CCS and Diversified Supply Technologies. Electricity
prices Another
important indicator on costs relates to final consumer prices especially the
prices of electricity for industrial, household and services consumers as well
as the average price. Electricity prices are calculated in such a way that
total costs of power generation, balancing, transmission and distribution are
recovered, ensuring that investments can be financed. Table 49 shows the
average price for electricity in the EU27 for different sectors; the
residential sector has the highest user price and industry the lowest as it is
currently the case. In 2050, average electricity costs are highest in High RES
scenario reaching 199 €/MWh. The lowest electricity prices are in Diversified
supply and Energy efficiency scenario, with prices below the Reference and
Current Policy Initiatives scenarios because of cheaper procurement of fossil
fuels under global climate action. Average prices
of electricity are rising compared to current levels until 2030 and continue
increasing in the High RES scenario. In the Energy Efficiency and Diversified
Supply Technology scenarios, electricity prices remain similar to those in the Reference/CPI
scenario up to 2030 thanks to lower fossil fuel input costs with lower world
market prices. With somewhat higher investment or ETS costs, the other
decarbonisation scenarios have slightly higher costs in 2030, exceeding Reference/CPI
by around 5%. By 2050, the average price exceeds reference/CPI level markedly
in the High RES scenario (around 30%) to recover costs for the high generation
capacity needs including for back-up and for greater grid and storage
capacities, while it remains almost at that level in the Low nuclear case (+4%).
In the Diversified Supply Technologies and Energy Efficiency scenarios,
electricity prices in 2050 are even below those in the Reference/CPI cases,
whereas beneficial effects from lower import prices are compensated by effects from
restricted choices on nuclear or delayed penetration of CCS in the respective
scenarios. Electricity prices are already slightly higher than reference in
Current policy Initiatives scenario reflecting less nuclear in power generation
at somewhat higher costs. It should also
be noted that prices rise strongly up to 2020/30, but that after 2030 prices
either fall or show an average annual price increase that is much smaller than
in the period 2005-2030, which applies in particular for the High RES scenario.
Table 49: EU27 average electricity prices [17] Diesel
prices Another
pertinent indicator on costs across scenarios is the price of diesel, which is
relevant for both passenger transport (in private cars and buses/coaches) and
freight transport. Prices for
diesel in transport in CPI and the decarbonisation scenarios reflect the new
energy taxation directive as well as different bio-diesel blends. The energy
system changes between scenarios cause only limited changes to end-user diesel
prices. The strong decline in diesel prices between CPI and decarbonisation
scenarios in 2030 reflects oil and product import price savings. This effect is
compensated in 2050 by the impact of a significantly higher biofuel penetration
in the diesel market. Table 50: Average EU27 diesel (including blended biodiesel) end
–user prices for private transport[18] || || 2005 || 2030 || 2050 Reference || (EUR(08)/toe) || 1271 || 1877 || 2250 CPI || % diff. to Reference || 0% || 20% || 16% Energy Efficiency || 0% || 3% || 17% Diversified Supply Technology || 0% || 3% || 19% High RES || 0% || 3% || 21% Delayed CCS || 0% || 2% || 18% Low Nuclear || 0% || 3% || 22%
2.8 Conclusions
The Commission
services conducted a model-based analysis of decarbonisation scenarios
exploring energy consequences of the European Council's objective to reach 80% GHG
reductions by 2050 (as compared to 1990), provided that industrialised
countries as a group undertake similar efforts. These scenarios explore also
the energy security and competitiveness dimension of such energy developments.
Businesses as usual projections show only half the GHG emission reductions
needed; increased import dependency, in particular for gas; and rising
electricity prices and energy costs. Several decarbonisation scenarios
highlighting the implications of pursuing each of the four main decarbonisation
routes for the energy sector – energy efficiency, renewables, nuclear and CCS -
were examined by modelling a high and low end for each of them. The model
relies on a series of input assumptions and internal mechanisms to provide the
outputs. The most relevant assumptions and mechanisms of the model Ø All scenarios were conducted under the
hypothesis that the whole world is acting on climate change which leads to
lower demand for fossil fuel prices and subsequently lower prices. Ø The model assumes perfect foresight
regarding, policy thrust, energy prices and technology developments which
assures a very low level of uncertainty for investors, enabling them to make
particular cost-effective investment choices without stranded investments.
There is also no problem with uncertainty on whether all the infrastructure and
other interrelated investment (e.g. grid connections) needed to make a
particular investment work will be in place in time. Ø Regulatory framework in model allows for
investments to be built and costs fully recovered. Ø The model assumes a
"representative" or average household or consumer while in reality
there is a more diversified picture of investors and consumers. Ø The model assumes continuous improvements
of technologies. The model-based
analysis has shown that decarbonisation of the
energy sector is feasible; that it can be achieved through various combinations
of energy efficiency, renewables, nuclear and CCS contributions; and that the
costs are affordable. The aim of the analysis was not to pick preferred
options, a choice that would be surrounded with great uncertainty, but to show
some prototype of pathways to decarbonise the energy system while improving
energy security and competitiveness and identify common features from scenario
analysis. Common elements to scenario analysis Ø
There is a need for an
integrated approach, e.g.; decarbonisation of heating and transport relies
heavily on the availability of decarbonised electricity supply, which in turn
depends on very low carbon investments in generation capacity as well as
significant grid expansions and smartening. Ø
Electricity (given its high efficiency and emission free nature at
use) makes major inroads in decarbonisation scenarios reaching a 36-39% share in
2050 (almost doubling from current level and becoming the most important final
energy source). Decarbonisation
in 2050 will require a virtually carbon free electricity sector in the EU, and around
60% CO2 reduction by 2030. Ø
Significant energy
efficiency improvements happen in all decarbonisation scenarios. One unit of
GDP in 2050 requires around 70% less energy input compared with 2005. The
average annual improvement in energy intensity amounts to around 2.5% pa. Ø
The share of renewables
rises substantially in all scenarios, achieving at least 55% in gross
final energy consumption in 2050, up 45 percentage points from the current
level (a high RES case explores the consequences of raising this share to 75%). Ø
The increased use of
renewable energy as well as energy efficiency improvements require modern,
reliable and smart infrastructure including electrical storage. Ø
Nuclear has a
significant role in decarbonisation in Member States where it is accepted,
especially if CCS deployment were delayed. Ø
CCS contributes
significantly towards decarbonisation in most scenarios with a particularly
strong role in case there were problems with nuclear investment and deployment.
Developing CCS can be also seen as an insurance against energy efficiency, RES
and nuclear (in some Member States) delivering less or not that quickly. Ø
All scenarios show a
transition from high fuel/operational expenditures to high capital expenditure.
Ø
Substantial changes in
the period up to 2030 will be crucial for a cost-efficient long term transition
to a decarbonised world[19].
Economic costs are manageable if action starts early so that the restructuring
of the energy system goes in parallel with investment cycles thereby avoiding
stranded investment as well as costly lock-ins of medium carbon intensive
technology. Ø
The costs of such deep
decarbonisation are low in all scenarios given lower fuel procurement costs
with cost savings shown mainly in scenarios relying on all four main
decarbonisation options. Ø
Costs are unequally
distributed across sectors, with households shouldering the greatest cost
increase due to higher costs of direct energy efficiency expenditures in
appliances, vehicles and insulation. Ø
The external EU energy
bill for importing oil, gas and coal will be substantially lower under
decarbonisation due to substantial reduction in import quantities and prices dependent
on global climate action lowering world fossil fuel demand substantially. When considering these scenario results it might be useful to
consider as well that energy supply structures are being transformed. Today we
have, for the most part, concentrated rather invisible items, such as mines,
import terminals, large power plants outside towns, and underground pipelines
for energy dense fossil fuels and nuclear energy. Under decarbonisation we
would increasingly have well visible land consuming configurations, such as
very large numbers of wind turbines, solar devices, biomass plantation, and
additional transmission lines. This might raise issues with public
acceptance and local opposition. Deployment of nuclear technologies is fraught with acceptance
problems in a large number of Member States. CCS is already now experiencing
local opposition in some Member States. Temporary delays in CCS were modelled
but not the complete unavailability of this option. Permanent unavailability of
CCS could mean that decarbonisation would almost entirely hinge upon very
strong progress with RES penetration (and energy efficiency) given the existing
limitations to nuclear with many Member States having opted out. In the high
RES scenario with much energy efficiency (discussed above), the CCS role is
very small, given the predominance of RES, requiring in turn large efforts in
terms of financing and finding accepted sites for very substantial investments
in production and transmission. Some policy
relevant conclusions can be drawn based both on the results of the scenario
analysis as well as on a comparison of the hypothetical situation of ideal
market and technological conditions needed for modelling purposes and what is
found in the much more complex reality. Implications for future policy making Ø
Successful
decarbonisation while preserving competitiveness of the EU economy is possible.
Without global climate action, carbon leakage might be an issue and appropriate
instruments could be needed to preserve the competitiveness of energy intensive
industries. Ø
Predictability and
stability of policy and regulatory framework creates a favourable environment
for low carbon investments. While the regulatory framework to 2020 is mainly
given, discussions about policies for 2020-2030 should start now leading to
firm decisions that provide certainty for long-term low-carbon investments.
Uncertainty can lead to a sub-optimal situation where only investment with low
initial capital costs is realised. Ø
A well functioning
internal market is necessary to encourage investment where it is most
cost-effective. However, the process of decarbonisation brings new challenges
in the context, for example, of. electricity price determination in power
exchanges: deep decarbonisation increases substantially the bids based on zero
marginal costs leading in many instances to prices rather close to zero, not
allowing cost recovery in power generation. Similarly, the necessary expansion
and innovation of grids for decarbonisation may be hampered if regulated
transmission and distribution focuses on costs minimisation alone. Building of
adequate infrastructure needs to be assured and supported either by adequate
regulation and/or public funding (e.g. financed by auctioning revenues). Ø
Energy efficiency tends
to show better results in a model than in reality. Energy efficiency
improvements are often hampered by split incentives, cash problems of some
group of customers; imperfect knowledge and foresight leading to lock-in of
some outdated technologies, etc. There is thus a strong need for targeted
support policies and public funding supporting more energy efficient consumer
choices. Ø
Strong support should
be given to R&D in order to bring down costs of low-carbon technologies. Ø
Due attention should be
given to public acceptance of all low carbon technologies and infrastructure as
well willingness of consumers to undertake implied changes and bear higher
costs. This will require the engagement of both the public and private sectors
early in the process. Ø
Social policies might
need to be considered early in the process given that households shoulder large
parts of the costs. While these costs might be affordable by an average
household, vulnerable consumers might need specific support to cope with
increased expenditures. In addition, transition to a decarbonised economy may
involve shifts to more highly skilled jobs, with a possibly difficult
adaptation period. Ø
Flexibility. The future
is uncertain and nobody can predict it. That is why preserving flexibility is
important for a cost efficient approach, but certain decisions are needed
already at this stage in order to start the process that needs innovation and
investment, for which investors require a reasonable degree of certainty from
reduced policy and regulatory risk. Ø
External dimension, in
particular relations with energy suppliers, should be dealt with pro-actively
and at an early stage given the implications of global decarbonisation on
fossil fuel export revenues and the necessary production and energy transport
investments during the transition phase to decarbonisation; new areas for
co-operation could include renewable energy supplies and technology development.
Attachments
Attachment
1: Numerical results
1. Reference
scenario Reference scenario
with Low energy import prices Reference scenario
with High energy import prices Reference
scenario with High GDP Reference
scenario with Low GDP 1bis.
Current Policy Initiatives scenario 2.
Energy Efficiency scenario 3.
Diversified supply technologies scenario 4.
High RES scenario 5.
Delayed CCS scenario 6.
Low nuclear scenario
Attachment
2: Assumptions about interconnections and modelling of electricity trade
Short description of the model
The electricity
trade model of PRIMES covers all countries in the European continent except
countries of the CIS and Turkey. Interconnector capacities at the various
country borders are determined exogenously. The model
performs unit commitment, endogenous use of interconnectors (with given
capacities and Net Transfer Capacities (NTC)) and also optimal power generation
capacity expansion planning in a perfect foresight manner until 2050.
Simulations of different electricity demand levels with the model allow
identification of bottlenecks and of the amount of investment in
interconnectors necessary to remove such bottlenecks. The model covers
demand both for electricity and CHP steam/heat, as given from results of the
entire PRIMES model. Demand for electricity and for steam/heat is supposed to
be given and is represented through two typical days (for winter and summer). Investment in
new power plants is endogenous. The rate of use of power capacities and
interconnectors is endogenous. Regarding the use of interconnectors the model
performs a linear Direct Current optimal power flow under oriented NTC
constraints defined per each couple of countries. The model makes distinction
between AC lines and DC lines, the use of the latter being controlled by
operators. All interconnectors existing today or planned to be constructed in
the future are represented (one by one) in the model. Among the
inputs, the model considers non linear cost-supply curves for fuels used in
power generation and non linear investment cost curves for nuclear and
renewable energy power plants, which are a function of total installed capacity
(unit investment costs increase as approaching the potential). The electricity model, used in stage 1, is identical to the
model used in the entire PRIMES model, but could be used with endogenous
electricity trade only for the work during stage 1 because of very long
computing times for each model run when iterations are performed between demand
and supply and for meeting carbon targets. Assumptions for the modelling exercise All data about
NTCs and interconnection capacities were taken from ENTSOe databases.
Information on new constructions was taken from the latest “Ten-year network
development plan 2010-2020”, complemented, where necessary, with information
from the Nordic Pool TSOs and the Energy Community (for South East Europe).
Some of the planned new constructions would justify increase of NTCs values
until 2020, as mentioned in the ENTSOe’s TYNDP document. Other mentioned new
constructions regard directly the building of new interconnection lines which
are introduced as such in the model database. According to
assumptions agreed with the Energy DG of the European Commission, the following
three cases were formulated regarding the NTC values: a)
NTC-0: keeping the NTC values of 2020, which are
much higher than today, unchanged until 2050; the projection of NTC values to
the year 2020 from today levels follows a study by KEMA, except few cases
either because the links were not included in that study or because ENTSOe’s
NTC values announced for 2010-2011 were exceeding the KEMA’s values. This
assumption does not use the TYNDP information about new constructions aiming at
increasing the NTC values in the future, except indirectly if in some cases the
KEMA values for 2020 increase from today’s levels. b)
NTC-2: apply a doubling of 2020 NTC values
between 2020 and 2050 and interpolate linearly between 2020 and 2050; increase
capacities of interconnectors where necessary so as to keep NTC values lower
than total interconnection capacity by individual couples of countries. Some
additional DC lines were added (linking Italy with western Balkans). c)
NTC-4: apply a quadrupling of 2020 NTC values by
2050 and interpolate with extension of interconnection capacities where needed. Two energy
demand and pricing contexts were considered to analyze the implications from
the above mentioned NTC assumptions, which are as follows: 1.
Reference scenario: demand, prices, taxes and
ETS carbon prices are taken as identical to the DG ENER Reference scenario.
Some adjustments on electricity demand figures were made only for year 2010,
based on monthly statistics for 2010, in order to be able to simulate the true
NTC values for this year. 2.
Decarbonisation scenario: demand, prices and ETS
carbon prices, as well as the parameters mirroring RES facilitation and other
policies, are taken from the DG CLIMA “Decarbonisation scenario under effective
technologies and global climate action” scenario. Discussion of model results for the
Reference scenario with three NTC value cases The model
results show that the NTC values retained for the year 2020 do not lead to
substantial changes compared to results for the standard Reference scenario,
i.e. the Reference scenario referred to in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap). The
countries projected to be net exporters in the standard reference scenario
remain so in the model results presented here; the same applies to countries
projected to be net importers in the standard reference scenario. There are
differences in the magnitude of exports or imports for the year 2020, as for
example for Belgium, Portugal, Lithuania and Latvia (higher net imports), for Hungary and Denmark (lower net imports) and for Slovenia, Slovakia, Sweden and Bulgaria (more net exports). It is reminded that for the standard Reference scenario import-exports
of electricity were derived following a different methodology, which applied
common balancing by region, contrasting the pan-European balancing applied for
the model runs presented here. NTC-0 case. Regarding the
scenario with NTC values remaining unchanged at the year 2020, the model
results provide information about congestion by considering whether the NTC
constraints are binding or close to be binding for couples of countries. The
findings from this analysis regarding the projected NTC values for 2020 are
summarized below ·
Link Switzerland-Germany: appears congested and
NTC is 32% of capacity ·
Link Germany-Poland: appears congested and NTC
is 17% of capacity ·
Link Denmark-Sweden: appears congested and NTC
is 54% of capacity ·
Link Austria-Italy: appears very congested and
NTC is 16% of capacity ·
Link Italy-Slovenia: appears congested and NTC
is 15% of capacity ·
Link Austria-Hungary: appears congested and NTC
is 31% of capacity ·
Link Slovenia-Croatia: appears congested and NTC
is 18% of capacity ·
Links in the Balkans (FYROM-Greece, Albania-Greece, Bulgaria-Greece, Serbia-FYROM, Romania-Serbia, Serbia-Albania, Bulgaria-FYROM)
appear very congested and NTC are below 30% of capacity, except Greece-Bulgaria
NTC which is 68% of capacity Congestion is
detected in the model runs due to NTCs that are only a small part of existing
capacities. One option for dealing with congestion would be to increase NTC
without necessarily construct new lines. From the above overview it can be seen
that the congestions after 2020 remain between Germany and neighbours to the
east and south, between Austria, Italy, Slovenia, and Hungary, and finally in the Balkans, both within the Balkans and the linkages with northern
neighbours. NTC-2 and
NTC-4 cases The NTC-2 and
NTC-4 cases assume doubling and quadrupling of NTC values, respectively from
2020 to2050, with linear interpolation applied between 2020 and 2050. The model
results show that this way of uniformly increasing the NTC values does not
really solve the problem of systematic congestions mentioned above for the case
NTC-0. These congestions are removed only in the case NTC-4 and after 2030,
with the exception of the Austria-Italy and Germany-Poland links, which remain
congested until 2050 despite the quadrupled NTCs. The congestion problems in
the Balkans are removed only in the NTC-4 case after 2030, but the area remains
strongly congested under the NTC-2 assumptions. The congestions in links with Germany (Switzerland, Poland, Czech Rep. and Austria) are not removed in the NTC-2 case. The doubling and
quadrupling of NTCs values do not provide any advantages concerning the large list
of links, which are not found congested under the NTC-0 assumptions. The doubling of
NTCs under the assumptions of NTC-2 case lead to lower rates of use of
interconnection capacities (reported as percentage of NTCs), compared with
NTC-0 results in the following cases: ·
UK-Ireland: 17 percentage points less use ·
France, Belgium, Netherlands, Luxembourg, Germany: between 15 and 30 percentage points less use ·
Nordic area: around 15 percentage points less
use ·
Czech Rep., Slovakia, Poland, Hungary, Romania, Croatia: between 20 and 30 percentage points less use ·
Latvia-Estonia: 20 percentage points less use Passing from the
doubling to the quadrupling implies even lower rates of use of interconnection
possibilities. Both cases NTC-2
and NTC-4 have adverse implications on the rate of use of DC lines leading to
lower rates of use compared to case NTC-0, which under NTC-4 are close to zero
in some cases. The NTC constraints help using the DC links for which the NTC
values are usually equal to the interconnection capacities. Excessively high
NTC constraints, which also mean more AC links, imply much less use of DC
lines, which of course is unrealistic, as the DC lines correspond to today
known constructions and are furthermore expensive. So the companies would not build
so many new AC lines as the ones corresponding to NTC-4 on economic grounds
including the adverse effects on DC lines. A major issue
with NTC-2 and NTC-4 cases regards the investment cost implicitly associated
with the increase of interconnection capacities stemming from the doubling and
quadrupling of NTC values. Total interconnection capacity is projected to
increase by 43% in 2020 compared to 2010 levels, as a result of implementing
the construction program of the TYNDP. In NTC-0 the capacity remains roughly
unchanged until 2050. But in NTC-2 the capacity has to increase by 95% in 2050
compared to 2020 levels and in NTC-4 this increase is 277%. Such a construction
program exceeds by far capacity requirements and would unnecessarily penalize
costs and electricity prices in the scenarios. According to the
model results, we obtain the following changes in energy terms from NTC-2 and
NTC-4 assumptions compared to NTC-0 results: ·
Total volume of electricity traded increases by
5% in NTC-2 and by 8% in NTC-4 compared to NTC-0 in cumulative terms for the
period 2015-2050. It is evident that the additional cost of interconnectors
cannot be justified by such small increases in total traded volumes (i.e.
adding absolute values of flows between countries). ·
Total electricity production costs decrease by
0.13% in NTC-2 and by 0.23% in NTC-4 compared to NTC-0 in cumulative terms
2015-2050 ·
CO2 emissions from electricity production
decrease by 0.8% in NTC-2 and by 0.9% in NTC-4 compared to NTC-0 in cumulative
terms 2015-2050 ·
Nuclear and RES cumulative production are found
slightly higher in NTC-2 and NTC-4 compared to NTC-0, but the changes are less
than 1% in cumulative terms. It can therefore
be concluded that the NTC expansion
according to the NTC-2 and NTC-4 assumptions are not needed for the functioning
of the electricity system and would entail high unnecessary cost without
providing any noticeable benefit. These assumptions do not solve the serious
congestion issues, do not provide gains for the non congested areas and have
adverse effects on the economics of DC lines. The conclusion
for a Reference or Current Policy Initiatives framework is therefore to follow
an approach that focuses on identified bottlenecks. For stage 2 of the
modelling it is appropriate to increase NTC
values and interconnection capacities after 2020 in a selective way, with
priority to areas that would be congested in the future according to the
reference scenario results. Such areas are the southern and eastern connections
of Germany, the area linking Italy, Austria and Slovenia, the linkages of
Balkans with northern neighbours and the linkages within Balkans. Some NTC
additions should be also made for the linkages Denmark-Sweden and
Latvia-Estonia. With lower electricity demand due to the assumed
strong energy efficiency policies, these results also hold for the Current
Policy Initiatives scenario. Discussion of model results for a Decarbonisation scenario with
three NTC value cases Under the
assumptions of the decarbonisation scenario, total demand for electricity (in
the 32 countries included in the model) increases by 15% in 2050 compared to
the Reference scenario for year 2050. , It is assumed
that the renewable facilitation policies develop in all countries in favour of
domestic renewable potential. The scenario does not assume inflows of RES
electricity from outside EU countries (e.g. North Africa) and does not include
the possibility of exploitation of offshore wind located at long distance from
the coasts. The results from
the model show that the NTC values retained for the period until 2020 do not
alter the electricity trade pattern projected in previous decarbonisation
exercises and compared to the Reference scenario. The congestions
identified in the context of the decarbonisation scenario for the year 2020 are
the same as in the context of the reference scenario (see previous section). Under the
assumptions of the NTC-0 case the results show congestions similar to those
found for the reference scenario, i.e. in south and east of Germany, in the Balkans, in the northern connections of the Balkans, in the linkages between Italy, Austria and Slovenia. Some additional congestion cases, found in the context of
decarbonisation, relate to the link Germany-Sweden, Norway-UK and Germany-UK
which are based on DC-links and do not concern the NTC values. The doubling of
NTC values under the assumptions of the NTC-2 case does not help removing the
congestions. The quadrupling of NTC values (NTC-4 case) helps removing the
congestions only in the long term, after 2040. So the linear interpolation
method seems not to be useful as it brings little benefits and entails high
costs for building new interconnectors. Increase of NTC values in a selective
way and at an early stage after 2020 seems more suitable. In the context
of the decarbonisation scenario, the NTC-2 case allows increase of total
volumes traded by 12% when compared to NTC-0. The increase obtained for the
NTC-4 case is 14% (up from NTC-0). NTC-2 reduces total power generation costs
roughly by 0.85% in cumulative terms compared to NTC-0. In NTC-4, the
additional effect on power generation costs is smaller, NTC-4 power generation
costs are 0.2%) lower compared with NTC-2. It is important to note that these
statements related to power generation costs, and that the move from NTC-0 to
NTC-2 and even more NTC-4 involves large costs for grid investment. NTC-2 has
small impacts favouring slightly more nuclear and RES generation, whereas NTC-4
add very little to NTC-2 effects. Overall conclusions on decarbonisation
scenarios (except for those with very strong reliance on RES) Following these
economic modelling results, the approach for further modelling was chosen to
start fromNTC-0 assumptions and to increase in selective way NTC values immediately
after 2020 for the linkages found to be congested. This concerns
interconnections around Germany, in Austria-Italy-Slovenia, Balkans and
Denmark-Sweden. For very high
RES penetration, such linkages may not be sufficient. Therefore, this case has
been examined separately. The results of this analysis are reported in the
following chapter. Assumptions about interconnections
in the Decarbonisation scenario with High RES deployment both domestically and
in the North Sea Under the
assumptions of this decarbonisation scenario, full exploitation of off-shore
wind potential at North Sea is foreseen. In this modelling, exploiting the
highest possible offshore wind potential is envisaged for Denmark, the UK,
France, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden, Norway, Belgium and Ireland, according to
the division of the sea in economic zones. Data on potentials come from
published reports (e.g. EEA); the additional potentials, compared to standard
RES scenario, are remarkably high for Norway, UK and Netherlands. It is assumed
that a dense DC interconnection system will develop mainly offshore but also
partly onshore, to facilitate power flows from the North Sea offshore wind
parks. After several
model runs with different DC topology configurations and after considering
elimination of congestions arising from wind offshore power flows, we have
concluded to the following assumptions about the additional DC
interconnections: In MW || Investment in additional new interconnectors in the 4.1 scenario – North Sea || || 2030 || 2035 || 2040 || 2045 || 2050 || Total Ireland || UK || 0 || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 1000 Spain || France || 1000 || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 2000 France || Germany || 0 || 0 || 1000 || 1000 || 0 || 2000 France || Belgium || 0 || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 1000 Belgium || Netherlands || 0 || 0 || 1000 || 1000 || 0 || 2000 Netherlands || Germany || 0 || 500 || 1000 || 1000 || 0 || 2500 UK || France || 1000 || 0 || 1000 || 500 || 0 || 2500 UK || Belgium || 1000 || 0 || 500 || 0 || 0 || 1500 UK || Netherlands || 0 || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 1000 UK || Germany || 1000 || 0 || 1000 || 1000 || 0 || 3000 Norway || Belgium || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 5000 Norway || Netherlands || 1000 || 1000 || 500 || 500 || 0 || 3000 Norway || Germany || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 5000 Germany || Denmark || 0 || 1000 || 2000 || 1000 || 500 || 4500 Norway || Denmark || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 1000 UK || Norway || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 1000 || 0 || 2000 Norway || Sweden || 1000 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 0 || 1000 Sweden || Poland || 1000 || 2000 || 2000 || 2000 || 3000 || 10000 Netherlands || Denmark || 500 || 500 || 1000 || 500 || 0 || 2500 Denmark || Sweden || 500 || 500 || 1000 || 1000 || 1000 || 4000 Germany || Poland || 0 || 1000 || 1000 || 1500 || 1500 || 5000 Denmark || Poland || 0 || 1000 || 2000 || 2500 || 500 || 6000 || Total || 11000 || 10500 || 21000 || 16500 || 8500 || 67500 The NTC values
are identical to the DC capacities, as assumed for all DC lines. The congestions
in this scenario are related to the wheeling of electricity from the North Sea region to consumption centres. The links of Sweden with Poland, Sweden with Lithuania, Austria with Italy, France with Italy and links in the Balkan region
appear to be congested. In this
scenario, the electricity trade changes drastically. The United Kingdom,
Netherlands, Denmark, Sweden, Norway export large amount of electricity while
France, Belgium Germany, Italy, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland become or
remain importing countries. This changes the results for the decarbonisation
scenario as regards several countries.
Attachment
3: Short description of the models used
The scenarios
were derived with the PRIMES model by a consortium led by the National Technical
University of Athens (E3MLab), supported by some more specialised models (e.g.
GEM-E3 model that has been used for projections for the value added by branch
of activity and PROMETHEUS model that has been deployed for projections of
world energy prices).
GEM-E3 The GEM-E3 (World and Europe) model is an applied general
equilibrium model, simultaneously representing World regions and European
countries, linked through endogenous bilateral trade flows and environmental
flows. The European model is including the EU countries, the Accession
Countries and Switzerland. The world model version includes 18 regions among
which a grouping of European Union states. GEM-E3 aims at covering the
interactions between the economy, the energy system and the environment. It is
a comprehensive model of the economy, the productive sectors, consumption,
price formation of commodities, labour and capital, investment and dynamic
growth. The model is dynamic, recursive over time, driven by accumulation of
capital and equipment. Technology progress is explicitly represented in the
production function, either exogenous or endogenous, depending on R&D
expenditure by private and public sector and taking into account spillovers
effects. The current GEM-E3 version has been updated to the GTAP7 database (base
year 2004) and has been updated with the latest Eurostat statistics for the EU
Member States.
PRIMES model The PRIMES model
simulates the response of energy consumers and the energy supply systems to
different pathways of economic development and exogenous constraints and
drivers. It is a modelling system that simulates a market equilibrium solution
in the European Union and its member states. The model determines the
equilibrium by finding the prices of each energy form such that the quantity producers
find best to supply match the quantity consumers wish to use. The equilibrium
is forwarding looking and includes dynamic relationships for capital
accumulation and technology vintages. The model is behavioural formulating
agents’ decisions according to microeconomic theory, but it also represents in
an explicit and detailed way the available energy demand and supply
technologies and pollution abatement technologies. The system reflects
considerations about market competition economics, industry structure, energy
/environmental policies and regulation. These are conceived so as to influence
market behaviour of energy system agents. The modular structure of PRIMES
reflects a distribution of decision making among agents that decide
individually about their supply, demand, combined supply and demand, and
prices. Then the market integrating part of PRIMES simulates market clearing. PRIMES is a
partial equilibrium model simulating the entire energy system both in demand
and in supply; it contains a mixed representations of bottom-up and top-down
elements. The PRIMES model covers the 27 EU Member States as well as candidate
and neighbour states (Norway, Switzerland, Turkey, South East Europe). The
timeframe of the model is 2000 to 2050 by five-year periods; the years up to
2005 are calibrated to Eurostat data. The level of detail of the model is large
as it contains: ·
12 industrial sectors, subdivided into 26
sub-sectors using energy in 12 generic processes (e.g. air compression,
furnaces) ·
5 tertiary sectors, using energy in 6 processes
(e.g. air conditioning, office equipment) ·
4 dwelling types using energy in 5 processes
(e.g. water heating, cooking) and 12 types of electrical durable goods (e.g.
refrigerator, washing machine, television) ·
4 transport modes, 10 transport means (e.g.
cars, buses, motorcycles, trucks, airplanes) and 10 vehicle technologies (e.g.
internal combustion engine, hybrid cars) ·
14 fossil fuel types, new fuel carriers
(hydrogen, biofuels) 10 renewable energy types ·
Main Supply System: power and steam generation
with 150 power and steam technologies and 240 grid interconnections ·
Other sub-systems: refineries, gas supply,
biomass supply, hydrogen supply, primary energy production ·
7 types of emissions from energy processing
(e.g. SO2, NOx, PM) ·
CO2 emissions from industrial processes ·
GHG emissions and abatement (using IIASA’s
marginal abatement cost curves for non CO2 GHGs). For further
information see http://www.e3mlab.ntua.gr/e3mlab/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=58%3Amanual-for-primes-model&catid=35%3Aprimes&Itemid=80&lang=en
Prometheus model A fully
stochastic World energy model used for assessing uncertainties and risks
associated with the main energy aggregates including uncertainties associated
with economic growth and resource endowment as well as the impact of policy
actions (R&D on specific technologies, taxes, standards, subsidies and
other supports). The model projects endogenously to the future the world energy
prices, supply, demand and emissions for 10 World regions. World fossil fuel
price trajectories are used for the EU modelling as import price assumptions
for PRIMES. Annex 2 - Energy Roadmap 2050 – Selected Stakeholders' Scenarios 1. Introduction 2. Scanning
of Stakeholder Scenarios 3. Comparative Analysis of Scenario Studies 3.1 Policy Assumptions and Targets 3.2 Economic Assumptions 3.3 Assumptions on Social Issues 3.4 Further Technology Assumptions 3.5 Key Results of Scenarios 3.6 Models Used and Interdependencies Between
Studies 4. Summary of comparison References 1. Introduction Stakeholders are continuing their work on scenarios for long term
transformation of energy systems. These analyses, using a variety of models and
assumptions and exploring a variety of constraints, all help in assessing the robustness
of conclusions on policy actions needed in the coming years. The bulk of this report, chapters 2-4, is a systematic
presentation of a representative sample of European long term energy scenarios.
Their policy targets, assumptions on various economic, social and technological
factors, and resulting outcomes of model-based analyses are compared. The
purpose is not to judge the outcomes of the scenarios but to try to understand
and clearly describe the similarities and differences in the scenarios[20]. This work was completed in
April 2011. Since then, several scenarios this year explore consequences of the Fukushima accident and unconventional gas. In the IEA[21]'s global scenario to 2035
entitled The Golden Age of Gas, ample availability of gas, much of it
unconventional, keeps average gas prices well below levels assumed in WEO-2010.
Especially in growing economies in China and other non-OECD countries, gas
consumption increases throughout the energy system, driven by price, improved
access to supplies, efficiency improvements in technologies, also emissions
benefits. Its flexibility is a distinct benefit in a perspective of much change
in energy systems and much uncertainty about how drivers will play out. In Europe, scenario analyses by the European Gas Advocacy Forum[22] and Eurogas[23] underline this flexibility and
how it can be used. EGAF argues that with greater use of gas in the short to
medium term, to 2030 or so, implementation risks in the early years of a
long-term strategy focused on renewables[24]
can be reduced as well as overall costs. Eurogas similarly argues that the
balance which will emerge between renewables and CCS/fossil fuels cannot be
known today and that investing in gas keeps these long-term options open. The
importance of CCS in these strategies in the long term is evident in the
IEA scenario which does not assume availability of CCS by 2035. In this
scenario, the long-term trajectory for CO2 emissions is towards 650ppm, thus a
probable temperature rise well above the 2 degrees C target. The European Climate Foundation in this year’s phase of its Roadmap
2050 work, concentrates on trade-offs in the period till 2030,
exploring coherent policy actions needed to keep the European energy system on
track to 2050. With further analyses of its 60% renewables and high renewables
scenarios for the power sector[25],
trade-offs among additional grid infrastructures, generation capacities and
their location, storage and demand side management are examined. Additional
grid investments beyond 2020, although substantial, are low compared to
generation investments. If these grid investments are not made, the result is
an increase in back-up and operational costs amounting to far more than the
grid investments saved. Demand response, within day, reduces the need for
additional transmission infrastructure. The deployment of renewables in order
of productiveness across Europe reduces cumulative generation capital costs by
over a fifth by 2030 compared to a Member State by Member State approach. ECF
also examines price setting in regional markets and utilisation rates of
additional back-up plant, crucial for understanding market design issues. Greenpeace concentrated on grids in its
2011 scenario analyses[26],
building on its earlier Renewables 24/7 study. Looking beyond 2030, a High Grid
scenario encompassing much trade and North African solar resources and a Low
Grid scenario with more local solutions within Europe are explored. With
adequate transmission, both would imply shrinking utilisation rates for coal
and nuclear plants and later for gas fired plants, which could then be
converted to biogas. Scenarios for sustained transformation of the energy system are now
being developed by a whole range of organisations, at local, Member State and European level[27].
Many look explicitly at the European market and policy context[28]. The conclusions of these scenario analyses and the analyses by
the Commission are consistent on many but not all issues. All agree on the
importance of energy efficiency in any strategy. The increased reliance
on capital investments in the transformation of the energy system and in
energy efficiency improvements is evident in all scenarios, raising financing,
risk management and cost of capital issues to the top of the agenda. All see a
much stronger reliance on renewables than currently, which raises issues
notably for the power system. Flexibility from all sources is
increasingly important. Grid investments and the market developments
that go with them look like a no-regrets policy, at least in the period to
2030. Areas of difference among scenarios often concern timing. They
include the degree of early reliance on electrification as
opposed to direct use of, notably, gas, in heating, transport and industry.
Estimates of total system costs in scenarios are still very
different. They are not easy to compare. 2. Scanning of Stakeholder Scenarios A variety of international organisations, industry
associations, individual companies, NGOs and research/academic institutions have
put forward mid- and long-term energy scenarios. In order to make a
representative sample, 28 studies were identified by screening contributions
and publications from stakeholders. A representative set of 7 studies was selected (see Table 1).
The criteria used were time horizon until at least 2030, geographical coverage
of EU-27 (or Europe[29]),
public availability of main results in a quantitative form, coverage of at
least the electricity sector, level of detail, and the scenarios being well
known and discussed internationally. For example, studies covering only the
world as a whole without defining Europe as a region were not selected. The
time horizon, geographical and sectorial coverages, as well as the level of
detail, vary greatly among the scanned studies. Table 1: Scanning of Energy Scenario Studies The 7 studies selected to be compared in detail are,
as follows (see full references at the end of this report): ·
European
Commission Reference Scenario to 2050, published in 2011, [1]: o
"The 2050
Reference scenario depicts energy and greenhouse gas (GHG) emission
developments on the basis of policies implemented up to March 2010, mirroring
as well the achievement of the legally binding 2020 targets on renewables (RES)
and GHG and the implementation of the ETS Directive. It shows the magnitude of
the additional effort needed for EU policies to achieve the European Council's GHG
mitigation objective." ·
European Climate
Foundation (ECF) – Roadmap 2050, 2010, [2]: o
"The objectives
of the Roadmap 2050 are: a) to investigate the technical and economic
feasibility of achieving at least an 80% reduction in greenhouse gas emissions
below 1990 levels by 2050, while maintaining or improving today's levels of
electricity supply reliability, energy security, economic growth and
prosperity; and b) to derive the implications for the European energy system
over the next 5 to 10 years." ·
Greenpeace/EREC –
Energy [R]evolution (+EREC (2010), Re-thinking 2050), 2010, [3]: o
"The report
demonstrates how the world can get from where we are now, to where we need to
be in terms of phasing out fossil fuels, cutting CO2 while ensuring energy
security. This includes illustrating how the world's carbon emissions from the
energy and transport sectors alone can peak by 2015 and be cut by over 80% by
2050." ·
International Energy Agency
(IEA) – Energy Technologies Perspectives (ETP), 2010, [4]: o
"The goal of
the analysis in this book is to provide an IEA perspective on the potential for
energy technologies to contribute to deep emission reduction targets and the
associated costs and benefits. It uses a techno-economic approach to identify
the role of both current and new technologies in reducing CO2 emissions and
improving energy security." ·
IEA – World Energy
Outlook (WEO), 2009,
[5]: o
"The results of
the analysis presented here aim to provide policy makers, investors and energy
consumers alike with a rigorous, quantitative framework for assessing likely
future trends in energy markets and the cost-effectiveness of new policies to
tackle climate change, energy insecurity and other pressing energy-related
policy challenges."
(Reference scenario); o
"More
specifically, this report is intended to inform the climate negotiations by
providing an analytical basis for the adoption and implementation of
commitments and plans to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions." (450 Scenario). ·
Eurelectric –
Power Choices, 2009,
[6]: o
"The
Eurelectric Power Choices study was set up to examine how the vision, of
cutting Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions by 75% in 2050, can be made reality.
Power Choices looks into the technological developments that will be needed in
the coming decades and examines some of the policy options that will have to be
put in place within the EU to attain a deep cut in carbon emissions by
mid-century." ·
FEEM[30] et al., EU-RTD
Project PLANETS: Probabilistic Long-term Assessment of New Energy Technology
Scenarios, 2010, [7]:
o
"PLANETS is a
research project funded by the EC under the 7th Framework Programme with the scope
of devising robust scenarios for the evolution of energy technologies in the
next 50 years. The project aims to assess the impact of technology development
and deployment at world and European levels, by means of an ensemble of
analytical tools designed to foresee the best technological hedging policy in
response to future environmental and energy policies."
3. Comparative Analysis of Scenario Studies 3.1 Policy Assumptions and Targets All scenario
studies analysed use a "baseline scenario" to show the impact
of presently implemented policies (e.g. until 2009). These baseline scenarios
are used as a basis for assessing impacts of alternative scenarios. The "alternative
scenarios" all aim at reducing GHG or CO2 emissions
(and are generally in line with the EU 2020 target of -20% and to the long term
target of -80% to -95% by 2050). Most models
concentrate on the electricity sector and are much less detailed (or provide no
details) on developments in the heating and transport sectors (except insofar
as they may assume major electrification in these sectors). Table 2 gives an overview of main pre-defined policy assumptions and
targets across the scenarios (for EU-27 or OECD-Europe, depending on study)
for: ·
GHG or CO2 emissions reduction
(economy-wide), ·
Share of renewables (RES), ·
Role of nuclear, ·
Efficiency, ·
Emission Trading System (ETS) and remarks on status
of policies taken into account. Table 2: Overview of Main
Policy Assumptions and Pre-Defined Targets in the Scenarios Short name scenario || GHG or CO2-emissions reduction, economy-wide || Share of renewables in gross final energy consumption || Share of nuclear in power generation || Reduction in primary energy by improved energy efficiency || Carbon policy WEO Ref || § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 for EU || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § Policies until mid 2009 § ETS WEO 450 ppm || § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 and -80% by 2050 || § 20% by 2020 || § || § 20% by 2020 || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS (OECD+, OME) ETP BL OECD Europe || § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 for EU || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS ETP Blue Map OECD Europe || § CO2eq: -74% below 2007 levels by 2050 § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 for EU || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS (OECD+, OME) EC Reference Scenario to 2050 || § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 (in Reference scenario) || § 20% by 2020 (in the Reference scenario) || § Economic modelling with currently non nuclear MS remaining non nuclear except Poland and Italy; phase-out in 2 MS || § || § Implemented Policies until March 2010 & achievement of legally binding targets § Revised ETS Directive applied until 2050 ECF BL || § GHG: -20% below 1990 levels by 2020 for EU || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS ECF 80% RES || § GHG: -80% below 1990 levels by 2050 || § 80% RES of power generation by 2050 || § 10% nuclear of power generation by 2050 || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § ETS (OECD+OME) ECF 60% RES || § GHG: -80% below 1990 levels by 2050 || § 60% RES of power generation by 2050 || § 20% nuclear of power generation by 2050 || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § ETS (OECD+OME) ECF 40% RES || § GHG: -80% below 1990 levels by 2050 || § 40% RES of power generation by 2050 || § 30% nuclear of power generation by 2050 || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § ETS (OECD+OME) E[R] Ref || § || § || § || § || § No specific targets or policies mentioned E[R] || § CO2: -80% below 1990 levels by 2050 || § || § Phasing out || § || § No specific targets or policies mentioned E[R] Adv || § CO2: -95% below 1990 levels by 2050 || § High RES share: "Close to fully renewable energy system" by 2050 || § Phasing out || § || § No specific targets or policies mentioned Eurelectric BL || § || § || § Germany and Belgium phased out || § || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS Eurelectric Power Choices || § GHG: -40% below 1990 levels by 2030 and -75% by 2050 || § 20% by 2020 || § Germany and Belgium phased out || § 20% by 2020 for EU || § Policies until mid-2009 § ETS (all sectors) FEEM-WITCH || § || § || § No exogenous constraint || § || § Prognos 2011
Abbreviations
used:
ETS: Emissions Trading System, GHG: Greenhouse Gas, OME: Other Major Economies
(Brazil, Russia, South Africa and the countries of the Middle East), MS: EU
Member States. From Table 2 it can be seen that: In relation to reduction of GHG emissions, ·
Most of the studies do not take into account negative
or positive effects of climate change on the economy in the models used.
One exception found are the FEEM-scenarios where the WITCH-model incorporates
an integrated assessment module which is able to take into account a dynamic
linkage of climate change and economic activity. ·
In general, some form of European Emissions
Trading (ETS) is considered in most studies (exceptions are Greenpeace/EREC
and FEEM), some models used for scenarios development even have specific
modules which simulate a market for emission allowances[31] (e.g. PRIMES used by both
Commission services and Eurelectric). ·
The scenarios differ in their assumptions about future
emissions trading markets. There is a large consensus about the sectors
included, but not about the geographical coverage. Some studies assume
no extension of the current EU emissions trading, others assume an expansion of
the market from OECD+ up to a global dimension. With the Clean Development
Mechanism (CDM), another possibility to enlarge the geographic coverage of the
allowances market exists. The EU DG ENER scenarios focus on this issue, other
scenarios give little information. Finally, some scenarios envisage small
deviations from the current status of the allocation process, assuming full
auctioning in the power sector and grandfathering in the other sectors. Other
scenarios tend towards a general full auctioning of allowances. Carbon pricing
in the different scenarios is shown in Table 3: Table 3: Comparison of Carbon Pricing in the Scenarios Scenario || Sectoral coverage || Geographical coverage || Auctioning or grandfathering || CDM IEA – WEO || Existing EU-ETS, including aviation || n/a || n/a || CDM taken into account IEA – WEO 450 ppm || n/a || OECD+ in 2013, major economies as of 2021 || n/a || CDM taken into account IEA – ETP Reference || n/a || n/a || n/a || n/a IEA – ETP Blueline || n/a || n/a || n/a || n/a EU DG ENER Reference || Existing EU-ETS including aviation || n/a || Auctioning in power sector, grandfathering for other-sectors || CDM taken into account EU DG ENER Baseline || n/a || n/a || Auctioning in power sector, grandfathering for other-sectors || Limited use of CDM-credits ECF Roadmap Reference || Industry, power sector, aviation || n/a || n/a || n/a ECF Roadmap Pathways || Industry, power sector, aviation || Until 2020 OECD-countries, from 2020 including developing countries || n/a || n/a Energy [R]evolution || n/a || Global CO2 trading system in the long term || n/a || n/a Energy [R]evolution Advanced || n/a || Global CO2 trading system in the long term || All allowances should be auctioned || n/a Eurelectric Baseline || n/a || n/a || Full auctioning as of 2015 (except some new Member States) || n/a Eurelectric Power Choices || ETS extended to all major economic sectors after 2020 || International carbon market after 2020 || Full auctioning as of 2015 (except some new Member States) || n/a FEEM et al. - Planets || n/a || n/a || n/a || n/a In relation to future energy mixes,
A few
studies use pre-defined future energy mix targets, by preferring or
excluding certain technologies from the beginning (in a
"back-casting approach"):
Predetermined
Role of Renewables (RES): Only Greenpeace/EREC
and ECF make specifications on the desired shares of RES energies in 2050:
o Greenpeace/EREC sets in its advanced Energy [R]evolution scenario
the 2050 RES target share at 100% (all sectors). o ECF sets in its alternative scenarios the 2050 power sector RES
target share at 40%, 60% and 80%, respectively.
Predetermined
Role of Nuclear Energy (NUC) and Carbon Capture & Storage (CCS): Greenpeace/EREC and ECF specify pre-defined shares of NUC and
CCS in 2050:
o Greenpeace/EREC sets in its advanced Energy [R]evolution scenario
the 2050 NUC as well as CCS target shares to 0%. o ECF focuses on the RES share. For the purposes of the analysis,
particularly of infrastructure needs, it divides the remaining share equally
between NUC and CCS, thus 30%, 20% and 10% for each, in the three alternative
scenarios[32].
The other scenarios determine the contribution of NUC
and CCS on the basis of cost assumptions and optimisation rather than
pre-defined policy targets. In relation
to sustainability aspects other than GHG reduction, Economic
constraints or the issue of maintaining high levels of grid stability and
overall system reliability are in most cases either not considered or at least
not fully quantified: ·
Economic constraints, e.g.: o Minimisation of private financial costs (investment in new
generation capacities and infrastructure (an exception is e.g. ECF)), o Minimisation of social costs, such as environmental externalities
(costs of GHG avoided, other environmental pollution, land use, etc.)[33]. Maintaining
high levels of grid stability and overall system reliability[34], e.g.: The high relevance of this issue is due to the fact that scenarios
with high shares of RES energy sources, particularly wind and solar energy,
increase the need for backup capacity or other means of ensuring grid
stability. Substitution of electricity for FOS fuels in buildings and
transportation, results in higher electricity demand but also expanded
possibilities for demand management. These challenges are addressed by all of
the studies in one way or another. Several approaches can be identified in the
scenarios: o Flexible thermal power plants (NUC, FOS) for load-following
operation and back-up capacity, o Greater use of non variable RES energy (biomass, solar with storage,
geothermal, hydro with pumped storage facilities), o Transmission expansion. This approach is constrained in some of the
scenarios by model limitations. In PRIMES, interconnections are exogenous. The
model used in ECF's scenarios derives transmission needs, o Large-scale storage o Smart grids and demand side management developments. Maintaining high levels of system reliability and thus high levels
of power supply security is qualitatively mentioned across most studies as a
key objective and in some studies also as a key challenge. Regarding realisation, particularly studies with ambitious GHG
reduction targets implicitly assume significant progress in grid technology (ECF
maintains that they use existing technologies) and social acceptance related to
transmission expansion to be able to achieve their targets. However, analysis
is typically not taken further[35]
from such largely qualitative statements and it is usually concluded that
financing needs to be found for the large increases in pan-European
transmission and storage capacities to be able to cope with the expected large
future shares of intermittent generation. Implications for distribution networks are not addressed by most of
the studies. This is particularly concerning as almost
all studies emphasize at the same time the relevance of technologically
advanced smart grids and smart metering, especially those confronted with ambitious
emission reductions (Energy [R]evolution, ECF Pathways, ETP Blueline,
Eurelectric Power Choices). In relation to security of supply of energy
resources, ·
All scenarios expect reserves of natural gas to
be sufficient to meet future demands. Unconventional oil reserves are expected
to be deployed in some scenarios without ambitious emission reductions (e.g.
ETP Reference). No indictors of security of supply are developed. Possible
indicators (diversity of imports, stability of exports, reliability of supply,
diversity of supply, etc.) are not developed. 3.2 Economic Assumptions Regarding general
economic assumptions, ·
The scenarios assume a steady increase of GDP
of ~1-2%
per year until 2030/2050. The recent financial crisis is taken into account in
the projections of GDP. Regarding fossil
fuel prices, ·
Fossil fuel prices are often exogenously determined (in PRIMES scenarios by using a
separate modelling framework). ECF and Greenpeace/EREC use price developments
from WEO 2009. In WEO 2009, international fossil fuel prices are based on a
top-down assessment of prices which would create enough investment to meet
energy demand over the projection period (global balance of supply and demand).
Therefore, fossil fuel prices in WEO are endogenously determined and sensitive
to scenario assumptions. ETP takes prices up to 2030 from WEO 2009 and
calculates prices for the period beyond 2030 by taking into account the
long-term oil supply cost curve. ·
Recent studies suggest a range of ~90-120
USD/barrel until 2030 and 2050 for the oil price. Only Greenpeace/EREC
considers an oil price that increases to 150 USD/barrel in 2030. Oil prices in
Greenpeace/EREC and ECF are assumed to stay constant after 2030. ·
Until 2030 most scenarios presume an increasing gas
price. In the IEA alternative scenarios the prices of gas, as for oil,
stabilise or decrease after 2030 due to weaker energy demand, while in the
reference case gas prices increase in respond to increasing demand (e.g. from
additional gas-fired power plants). ·
Most studies agree on the idea that gas
prices will keep their linkage with oil prices,
i.e. the ratio of gas and oil prices remains quite constant[36]. Main exceptions are the
Greenpeace/EREC Energy [R]evolution and – to some extent – the alternative scenario
of the PLANETS-WITCH project (see Figure 1). The PLANETS
alternative scenario assumes a higher increase of gas prices than oil prices,
motivated by the high gas demand and relatively low oil demand. Figure 1: Development of Gas to Oil Prices, in % ·
A moderate increase of coal prices is
assumed in most of the scenarios. Some differences exist in expectations of
future gas-to-coal price ratios. Most of the studies (e.g. Eurelectric) expect
coal prices to increase at far lower rates than gas prices. A slight decoupling
can be observed in most of the scenario studies. In contrast to the other
studies, the Energy [R]evolution of Greenpeace/EREC and the alternative
scenario of the PLANETS-WITCH project show a stronger increase of coal than oil
prices in the long run. Regarding incentives
for RES, ·
Some studies (e.g. Eurelectric Power Choices)
explicitly assume decreasing direct incentives for RES in the future due to
assumed increasing cost-competitiveness. Regarding CO2-certificate
prices, ·
Different developments for
the (typically assumed) CO2-certificate prices are to some part also
determined by targets set and the resulting CO2-emissions development. As shown
in Figure 2, emissions in the ECF Pathways and the WEO 450 ppm show
a faster decline than emissions in the Eurelectric Power Choices scenario,
which seems to allow a higher degree of flexibility to reach the targets set
for 2050. Furthermore, the sharp increase of CO2-certificate prices in the Eurelectric
Power Choices scenario from 2030 onwards partly results from the assumed removal
of mandatory RES-targets after 2020. Therefore, carbon prices gain high
importance to deliver required emission reductions by 2050. Figure 2: Development of CO2-certificate prices, in EUR2008/t CO2 On the other hand, assumed geographical
extension of emission trading systems (e.g. in the ECF Pathways, WEO 450 ppm
and the Power Choices scenario international carbon markets are assumed not
later than 2020) can be interpreted to prevent carbon prices from rising
unlimited. This effect is due to more abundant and cheap opportunities for
emission reduction outside the EU/OECD. Relatively low prices for emission
certificates in the Greenpeace/EREC study may be partly determined by the idea
that the process of emission trading remains unclear and is not able to help
RES energy expansion (and is thus not considered adequate to become an
important parameter for Greenpeace/EREC in their model). In summary, the pre-defined importance of carbon
prices as an instrument in different scenario studies may also explain their
different resulting price levels
(e.g. in the Power Choices scenario, carbon prices are assumed to be important
to reach emission targets). Regarding investment
costs, ·
All scenarios confronted with high emission
reduction requirements estimate a considerable increase in capital expenditure. Even baseline scenarios suggest an increase in capital expenditure
in the coming years. The somewhat higher estimation in the emissions reduction
scenarios is generally based on several effects: higher capital intensity of
RES technologies in terms of costs per power produced and the need for higher
power transmission capacity due to intermittency of most of the expected new
RES (investment in power transmission capacity is roughly estimated to be 20-50
% higher in most of the alternative scenarios, compared to Baseline or
Reference scenarios); higher capital intensity of new NUC and CCS investments.
The scenarios also agree in the estimation of lower expenses for FOS fuels in
due course due to large substitutions of RES for FOS fuels and energy
efficiency improvements. ·
Overall, these effects lead to somewhat different
total cost results across scenarios with large methodological uncertainties,
strongly influenced by different modelling mechanisms (e.g. cost-optimization
vs. accounting frameworks), framework parameters (e.g. price developments; see
above) and conventions for cost-estimations. Furthermore, results are often not
available for the same timeframes and geographical boundaries. ·
Results on future investment costs are also strongly
influenced by the chosen assumptions on technological developments in
energy transformation and end-user applications. A lot depends on learning
rates For example, in ECF, learning rates are 5% for wind offshore/onshore, 15%
for solar PV and 12% for CCS and yearly reductions in investments costs per
capacity are estimated at 1% for biomass and geothermal plants, compared to
0,5% for FOS-fired plants. ·
Table 4
shows compliance costs available in alternative scenarios, differentiated into
total costs and grid costs or investment: Table 4: Comparison of Compliance and Grid Costs/Investment in Alternative Scenarios
Scenario || Estimated compliance costs/investment || Estimated grid costs/investment || Comments IEA – WEO 450 ppm || § EU-27: +1600 bn USD (vs. Ref.) cumulative investment in the energy sector (incl. grid costs) till 2035 || § Global: 5100 bn USD (20% lower vs. Ref.) cumulative investment till 2035 || § External costs not included (except GHG) § Grid investment (Ref.): 25% transmission, 75% distribution IEA – ETP Blue Map || § EU-27: additional cumulative investment (energy sector) compensated by cumulative fuel savings: 7100 bn USD vs. 13100 bn USD till 2050 (vs. Bas.) || § Global: 12300 bn USD (incl. smart grids) cumulative grid-investment till 2050 (+50% vs. Bas.) || § Grid investment (Ref.): 30% transmission, 70% distribution § Back-up costs may be considered implicitly EU DG ENER Ref. || § ~175 bn € p.a. (2030) capital and O&M costs in power generation (i.e. 51,0 €/MWh) || § EU-27: grid costs of 10,8 €/MWh (2030) vs. 7,4 (2010), i.e. ~165 bn € cumulative grid costs || § Distribution grid not included § Back-up costs considered implicitly § ECF Roadmap 80% RES || § Lower fuel costs dominate capital cost expenses: overall -80 bn € in 2020 (-205 bn € in 2030) vs. Ref. || § Cumulative additional transmission capex: 95-129 bn €, additional back-up capex: 63-99 bn € (vs. Ref.) § Cumulative additional distribution capex: 200-300 bn € || § Amount by which distribution costs are incremental to the Ref. is unclear Energy [R]evolution Advanced || § Global: 292 bn USD add. investment p.a. 2007-2030 (vs. Ref.) § 42 bn € additional investment p.a., fuel savings of 62 bn € p.a. (2007-2050, vs. Ref.) || § Costs of 209 bn € p.a. for the assumed new European "Supergrid" || § Grid costs estimated externally, cost structure of grid costs not further specified Eurelectric Power Choices || § Capital and O&M costs of 53,3 €/MWh in 2030 || § Grid-costs rise from 7,3 to 12,6 €/MWh (2050) § Cumulative grid investment: 1.500 bn € (+35% vs. Baseline) || § No external costs besides CO2-costs § Not clear if back-up costs are considered implicitly FEEM et al. - Planets || § Global: ~800 (2030) and 2500 (2050) bn € yearly costs (i.e. 1-2,5 % of GDP) || § n/a || § Costs are measured as consumption losses vs. the Reference scenario ·
Table 4 shows
that: o A comparison of total cost results from the different scenario
studies is hardly possible as the underlying assumptions on methods and data
used are in most cases not presented sufficiently transparently to give a clear
picture on the dependability of figures presented
(see also above discussion about grid costs). o Macroeconomic costs or benefits are not provided, so the net
economic cost or benefit (e.g. including the gains or losses from
competitiveness factors) are not available. o Distribution costs are hardly ever estimated although they seem to
represent the majority of necessary grid investments. This makes it doubtful
that costs for infrastructure changes are realistically included in most
scenarios. Regarding electricity
prices, ·
Electricity prices increase in most of the
studies at least in the medium term (up to 2030).
Some studies with high emission reduction targets expect a decrease of
electricity prices in the long term (up to 2050), mainly driven by lower
consumption of FOS fuels in the power sector in combination with assumed technological
improvements for RES power plants. Not all studies actually calculate
electricity prices for a market environment with supply of and demand for
electricity. Therefore Table 5, providing an overview on
electricity prices and their main drivers, displays electricity generation
costs as a proxy for electricity prices in these cases. Table 5: Comparison
of Properties of Electricity Prices in the Different Scenarios Study and scenario || Electricity price/cost developments || Main drivers IEA – WEO Ref and 450 ppm || § No data for Europe || § No data for Europe IEA – ETP Ref and Blue Map || § No data for Europe || § No data for Europe EU DG ENER Reference || § 1.4% average annual rise 2000-2030, declining after 2025 || § Increasing fuel prices, higher capital costs of RES, NUC and CCS, auctioning of CO2-allowances EU DG ENER Baseline || § 1.5% average annual rise 2000-2030, declining after 2025 || § Increasing fuel prices, higher capital costs of RES, NUC and CCS, auctioning of CO2-allowances ECF Roadmap Reference || § n/a || § Carbon prices, fossil-fuel prices, technology learning rates ECF Roadmap Pathways || § Higher levelised costs of electricity (LCOE) than in the Ref. (short term), slightly higher LCOE by 2050 || § Carbon prices, fossil-fuel prices, technology learning rates Energy [R]evolution || § Generation costs increase up to 2020, upward tendency until 2050 || § Fossil fuel prices, technology improvements of RES-technologies, costs for CO2-allowances Energy [R]evolution Advanced || § Generation costs increase up to 2030 and decrease afterwards (-34-43 % 2050 compared to the Baseline) || § Fossil fuel prices, technology improvements of RES-technologies, costs for CO2-allowances Eurelectric Baseline || § Strong increase up to 2025, stabilization afterwards || § Fossil fuel prices, restructuring of the power plant fleet Eurelectric Power Choices || § Strong increase up to 2025, slight decrease afterwards || § Fossil fuel prices, restructuring of the power plant fleet, lower fossil fuel consumption and lower demand for CO2-allowances) FEEM et al. – Planets || § Electricity prices stay almost constant || § Restructuring of power generation FEEM et al. – Planets Fb 3.2 || § Increase until 2015, stagnation 2015 to 2035, sharp increase after 2035 || § Restructuring of power generation, increasing electricity demand Key points: ·
The economic performances of all energy
technologies – FOS, NUC and RES – are reflected by their specific generation
costs which are heavily influenced by assumed future fuel and carbon prices,
and assumed technology learning rates. ·
Technology-neutral studies, such as from IEA, DG
ENER or Eurelectric, give high importance to the carbon price as a key driver
to deploy the most competitive low-carbon technologies and leave it then to the
market to develop the future energy mix. ·
Comparison of total costs for developing a more
sustainable EU energy system by 2050 is hardly possible due to lack of
transparency in most scenarios on methodological and data assumptions. ·
Most scenarios seem to lack a realistic
consideration of the costs for necessary infrastructure changes. For example,
although investments in the distribution grid represents the majority of
necessary grid investments, in almost all scenarios only transmission costs (if
at all) are considered. ·
Electricity prices increase in most of the
studies at least in the medium term (2030). 3.3 Assumptions on Social Issues The most
important effect in the EU social structure considered in the scenarios is change
in size of population. Throughout the studies, a slight increase of the EU
population is expected in the medium term (immigration), with the tendency to a
stabilised population in the long term. Some studies also assume a significant
decrease in the size of households. However, in
none of the scenarios analyzed evidence on fundamental changes in the
behavioural patterns of the economic agents was found. Some studies
(e.g. PRIMES-based Eurelectric, DG TREN, FEEM) apply fixed microeconomic
decisions of economic agents concerning demand for energy related products and
investment in energy supply equipment. These scenarios partly take into account
different levels of risk-awareness of agents (higher levels for individuals
than for enterprises, reflected by high discount rates for individuals), lack
of information, market barriers for new technologies and rebound-effects in
energy-efficiency investments. Investment decisions are modelled under full
information and perfect foresight assumptions. Only very little
information concerning trends and effects on the labour market was found in
the studies. However, in some scenarios (ECF pathways, Energy [R]evolution)
sectorial shifts on the labour market from traditional energy sectors (e.g. FOS
fuels) to sectors linked to RES installations are expected. Magnitudes of these
effects are very differently estimated, usually ignoring the related loss of
employment and market leadership in more traditional sectors. The risk of
loss of global competitiveness of energy intensive industries and related
deindustrialisation in Europe is usually not considered explicitly. Issues of
public acceptance regarding deployment of new power
plants (large-scale RES, new NUC, low-carbon FOS), new RES-support
infrastructure (pan-European grid, large storage) or new enforced consumer
behaviour (smart metering) are nowhere explicitly modelled (implicitly
only for NUC by assuming e.g. growth rates being much more limited than
economic optimisation would suggest). Key points: ·
Only few studies explicitly model changes in the
behaviour of economic agents with regard to changes in consumer behaviour or
public acceptance of deployment of new power generation plants and RES-support
infrastructures, ·
Effects on the EU labour market and the economy
as a whole (e.g. risk of deindustrialisation) as a consequence of visions of a
future EU energy mix are not consistently modelled in any scenario study and
are usually limited to presenting short-term positive effects of preferred
technological solutions. 3.4 Further Technology Assumptions The following conclusions on technology assumptions in
the different scenarios are in addition to the technology-related assumptions
already evaluated and compared under Sections 3.1 (Policy Assumptions and
Targets) and 3.2 (Economic Assumptions): ·
In all of the studies, a Baseline or Reference
scenario is compared with scenarios which are more ambitious in reducing
GHG-emissions. These "GHG-ambitious scenarios" mostly assume
significant growth rates in RES energy sources for power generation (up to
shares of e.g. 50% in the ETP Blueline and 97% in the Energy [R]evolution
scenario by 2050) and agree on the main RES electricity generation
technologies: onshore/offshore wind, biomass and solar-PV. ·
The studies are more diverse regarding the
estimations for the shares of thermal and hydro-RES: Of course, higher
shares of FOS fuels are estimated in the absence of additional policies
promoting RES-deployment. In the scenarios with more ambitious
emission-reduction policies, gas-fired power plants often have a high relevance
in serving peak-loads and load-following, due to the high shares of variable
RES sources. Nuclear power plants, without t restrictions on development, are
often considered as a vital option to help significantly reducing GHG-emissions
from power generation in a cost-effective way (e.g. ETP Blueline). ·
Innovative solutions for road transport
(electric vehicles, biofuels) and other new power and energy technologies are
identified as crucial for future energy systems throughout the studies. Most of the studies focus on electric vehicles and biofuels
besides power sector restructuring. ·
The scope for biomass technology improvements
to 2050 is not explored in most cases, nor is the prospect of productivity
increases driven by rising demand for biomass. ·
Most of the studies emphasize the importance
of policies concerning end-user efficiency (residential and industrial energy
demand) and some studies describe measures in this field as crucial factors in
the short run (2010 to 2030) to reach the emission targets set for the long
run (e.g. ETP Blueline). The proposed measures comprise the thermal integrity
of buildings, heat pumps, technological development in the processes of
energy-intensive industries and more energy-efficient vehicles. ·
Efficiency considerations on the one hand affect end-user efficiency and on the other hand
the energy transformation sector (mainly power generation). There is little
information on the latter and if, the studies estimate improvements in the
efficiency of traditional power generation technologies, but only small ones
compared to current state of the art (e.g. in the ECF Reference efficiencies of
60 % are assumed for CCGT-plants and 50 % for coal-fired plants in 2050). ·
In most scenarios except those of ECF, grid development
is not modelled or optimised for the given energy mix; it is pre-determined.
Given the expected burst in electrification, the role of "smart grid"
technology developments, increased balancing needs and distributed generation,
the assumptions about grid development equate to assumptions regarding costs
and energy mixes. Key points: In addition to the technology-related "Key points" already
presented at the end of Sections 3.1 (Policy Assumptions and Targets) and 3.2
(Economic Assumptions), the following key conclusions on technology assumptions
in the different scenarios can be made: ·
Most scenarios assume significant growth rates
in the use of RES energy sources for power generation. ·
NUC, without restrictions on development, is
often considered as a vital option to help significantly reducing GHG-emissions
from power generation in a cost-effective way. ·
Competitiveness of CCS depends strongly on the
carbon price. ·
Problems in extended use of biomass needed to
counter-balance future shares of intermittent wind and solar are nowhere
analysed in detail. ·
Estimated future investment costs are strongly
influenced by chosen assumptions on technological developments in energy technologies..
·
Innovative solutions for road transport
(electric vehicles, biofuels) are identified as crucial for future energy
systems throughout the studies. ·
Most studies emphasize the importance of
policies concerning end-user efficiency (residential and industrial energy
demand) and some studies describe measures in this field as crucial factors in
the short run to reach emission targets set for the long run. 3.5 Key Results of Scenarios From the
above modelling assumptions taken by different stakeholders, scenario models
result in often different, sometimes similar projections regarding specific
future trends: ·
Future primary energy demand has to be seen in relation with the final energy demand and the
technologies used. As shown in Figure 3, whereas the baseline
scenarios show generally slightly increasing primary energy demands, the alternative
scenarios aiming at reducing GHG-emissions show generally declining demands:
Figure 3: Development of Economy-Wide Primary Energy Demand, in PJ ·
As can be seen from Figure 4, without
new energy policies to reduce energy demand or GHG-emissions, final energy
demand will increase, similar to GDP-development. With new stringent
policy measures, final energy demand can be reduced by 20-25% until 2050. Figure 4: Development of Economy-Wide Final Energy Demand, in PJ ·
Compared to primary energy demand, long term
developments in final energy demand are also influenced by the structure of the
power generation sector (see Figure 4). ·
It has to be noted, that in some cases, differences
in efficiency targets may lead to major differences in projected energy
demand. For example, ambitious energy efficiency measures are implemented
in the Greenpeace/EREC Energy [R]evolution scenarios and in the Eurelectric
Power Choices scenario, even in the medium term up to 2020. This results in significant
declines of final energy demand and also primary energy demand, if measures aim
at reducing energy demand of end-consumers. ·
Looking at future electricity demand, a steady
increase can be seen in all scenarios. Compared to the picture of the final
energy demand, in general a substitution towards electricity can be
observed. This tendency is especially relevant for scenarios with high
GHG-reduction targets as these scenarios focus on decarbonisation of power
generation and substitution for FOS fuels in transportation (e.g. electric
vehicles) and buildings (e.g. heat pumps). Generally, this substitution process
is induced through cost-optimization, either for individuals (DG ENER,
Eurelectric), or for the whole region (e.g. ECF, FEEM), with the exception of
the Greenpeace/EREC Energy [R]evolution scenarios. Beneath this substitution
effect, electricity demand also increases due to higher income and economic
activity. Figure 5 clearly shows that reductions in
electricity demand due to energy-efficiency policies are outweighed by
additional demand caused by the mentioned factors. Figure 5: Development of Economy-Wide Electricity Demand, in TWh ·
The changes in electricity generation
(development as well as structure), which are shown in Figure 6 for
2050 depend on: ·
GHG and RES targets set in the scenarios, ·
competitiveness of power plants assumed
differently in different scenarios (capital costs, fixed and variable O&M
costs, fuel and CO2-prices), ·
pre-defined RES-targets set in
"back-casting" scenarios (Greenpeace/EREC, ECF), ·
bounds set for deployment of NUC/CCS in some
scenarios (Greenpeace/EREC, ECF). Figure 6: Electricity Generation in 2050, in TWh In the medium
term, up to 2030 and especially up to 2020, differences between the alternative
scenarios are relatively small. Of course, even in the medium term, differences
between scenarios with emission reduction targets and reference scenarios are
considerable: Ambitious scenarios generally show higher shares for RES and
NUC, with diverse views on CCS, except when NUC and CCS are excluded from
the beginning. In the long
term, even differences between alternative scenarios are considerable. In the Eurelectric Power Choices and the ETP Blueline scenarios, nuclear
power plants are estimated to obtain a high relevance in reaching the emission
reduction targets. Nuclear power plants are assumed to be the most economic
option to serve baseload in these scenarios, whereas FOS-fuelled plants are
mainly used for load following (gas-fired plants), with the exemption of
coal-fired plants with CCS. Differences between the two scenarios could be due
to slightly different geographical coverage (ETP focusing on OECD-Europe,
including Norway and Switzerland, both with high RES-shares) and differences in
the estimated competitiveness of CCS / FOS fuels vis-à-vis NUC and RES power
generation. Deployment of
CCS is of importance for all alternative scenarios
(except Energy [R]evolution where it is excluded), but significantly higher in
the Power Choices scenario and the ECF-pathways. Deployment for this form of
emission abatement starts typically in the period from 2020 to 2030, but is
assumed to gain importance only after 2030 (ETP, ECF, Eurelectric, PLANETS). The
outcomes in the basic and advanced Greenpeace/EREC Energy [R]evolution
scenarios are significantly different, due to exclusion of NUC and CCS in
these scenarios. In the low
carbon scenarios examined, the quantity of electricity from RES produced by
2050 ranges from 1862 TWh to 4110 TWh. Fossil fuel generated electricity
deploying CCS ranges from 490 TWh to 1470. Nuclear powered electricity
production ranges from 490 TWh to 2607 TWh. Key points: ·
Without new energy policies to reduce energy
demand or GHG-emissions, final energy demand will increase, similar to
GDP-development. ·
The significant differences across scenarios on
assumptions on feasibility of efficiency improvements lead to major differences
in projected energy demand. ·
Compared to primary energy demand, long term
developments in final energy demand are also influenced by the structure of the
power generation sector. Higher decreases of final energy demand in relation to
primary energy demand can be achieved by a technology-neutral approach in
developing future power generation mixes (i.e. resulting in higher shares for
CCS and NUC). ·
Electricity demand increases across all
scenarios due to higher income and economic activity. Reductions due to
energy-efficiency policies are outweighed by additional demand. ·
If a technology-neutral approach is chosen, high
prices of CO2-certificates are the main driver for deployment of both RES and
NUC, but also for development of CCS. Therefore, GHG-ambitious
technology-neutral scenarios generally show higher shares for RES and NUC,
except when NUC and CCS are excluded from the beginning. 3.6 Models Used and Interdependencies Between
Studies In all scenario
studies analysed bottom-up models are used, some of them in combination with
top-down models, as summarised (for the main models) in Table 6: Table 6:
Characteristics of Models Used Study || Models used || Type of model || Characteristic IEA - WEO || § World Energy Model || § Bottom-up-model (with additive top-down model) || § Simulation IEA - ETP || § ETP MARKAL/TIMES || § Bottom-up-model || § Optimization (lead costs) EU DG TREN || § PRIMES || § Mixed representation: Bottom-up and top-down model || § Partial market equilibrium ECF Roadmap || § a.o. McKinsey Power Generation Model || § Bottom-Up-Model (with additive top-down model) || § Simulation Greenpeace/EREC Energy [R]evolution || § MESAP/PlaNet || § Bottom-up model || § Simulation Eurelectric Power Choices || § PRIMES || § Mixed representation: Bottom-up and top-down model || § Partial market equilibrium Not least
because of the use of the same models by different scenario studies, a variety
of studies uses the input and output of other studies. Two main
studies can be indentified: IEA World Energy Outlook and DG ENER / PRIMES. ·
The IEA Energy Technology Perspectives, the ECF
Roadmap 2050, Eurelectric's Power Choices and Greenpeace/EREC's Energy
[R]evolution use the WEO baseline. ·
Input and output of the DG ENER PRIMES study are
used for the Eurelectric study. 4. Summary
of comparison From the
comparison of stakeholder scenarios presented in this report, the following
conclusions can be drawn: ·
Overall Goal: o Scenarios are marked by GHG and/or RES targets and development of
future energy mixes is primarily based on optimising this parameter. o Security of supply indicators are not created (or optimised), except
for the grid-oriented modelling of ECF. o Competitiveness indicators are limited, partial and not optimised. ·
Basic Modelling Approaches used by
Stakeholders: o Models used for scenario studies can broadly be grouped into
market-based optimisation models ("fore-casts") and models which use
exogenously defined market shares ("back-casts"). o If market-based optimisation is applied (i.e. a technology-neutral
approach chosen), deployment of the different energy technologies (FOS, NUC,
RES) mainly depends on their relative total costs. o Grid modelling (and its major implications) are modelled by ECF; in
most other scenario analyses, they are pre-determined. ·
Energy/Electricity Demand: o Without new policy measures demand will increase due to GDP growth.
Final energy consumption in 2030 in low carbon scenarios range from 41000 PJ to
61000 PJ; in 2050 from 34000 PJ to 49000 PJ. o Electrification is assumed in (almost) all scenarios. Electricity is
estimated to gain higher shares in final energy demand, especially in scenarios
confronted with ambitious GHG-targets (mainly as a substitute for fossil
fuels). ·
Development of More Sustainable Future Energy
Systems: o Most scenarios, such as those generated by the PRIMES model,
optimise to determine the final energy mix ("technology neutrality"),
based on cost input and technology learning assumptions. Greenpeace/EREC and
the ECF scenarios backcast from several targeted generation shares, the former
excluding NUC and CCS... o Estimated future investment costs are also strongly influenced by
chosen assumptions on technological developments in energy technologies whose
dependability is often difficult or impossible to verify. o Most scenarios seem to lack a clear consideration of the costs for
necessary infrastructure changes to enable further deployment of variable RES.
For example, although investments in the distribution grid seem to represent
the majority of necessary grid investments and although all studies stress the
importance of smart grids, in almost all scenarios merely transmission (if at
all) is considered. o Few studies explicitly model changes in the behaviour of economic
agents with regard to changes in consumer behaviour. o Effects on the EU labour market and the economy as a whole (e.g.
risk of deindustrialisation) are not consistently modelled in any scenario
study. o Electricity prices increase in most studies at least in the medium
term (2030). Some studies with high emission reduction targets expect a
decrease of electricity prices in the long term (up to 2050), due to lower
fossil-fuel consumption. ·
Renewables: o Absolute and relative increases of RES in the power sector across
all scenarios. o Investment costs for RES decrease across all scenarios, especially
in a long term perspective. ·
Nuclear Power: o When optimised purely on costs, nuclear power tends to expand and
gain increasing shares. ·
Fossil fuel plants: o CCS plays an increasing role in scenarios with a focus on a strong
future role of the carbon price. References [1] European Commission Reference Scenario to
2050 (2011), European Commission, Brussels, Belgium. [2] ECF (2010): Roadmap 2050 – A practical
guide to a prosperous, low-carbon Europe, European Climate Foundation, The Hague, The Netherlands. [3] Greenpeace/EREC (2010): Energy [R]evolution
– Towards a fully renewable energy supply in the EU 27, Greenpeace
International, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, and European Renewable Energy
Council (EREC), Brussels, Belgium. [4] IEA (2010): Energy Technology Perspectives
(ETP) 2010 – Scenarios & Strategies to 2050, International Energy Agency, Paris, France. [5] IEA
(2009): World Energy Outlook 2009, International Energy Agency, Paris, France. [6] Eurelectric (2009): Power Choices – Pathways
to Carbon-Neutral Electricity in Europe by 2050, Union of the Electricity
Industry (Eurelectric), Brussels, Belgium. [7] FEEM et al. (2010): PLANETS – Probabilistic
Long-term Assessment of New Energy Technology Scenarios, Fondazione Eni Enrico
Mattei (FEEM) et al., Milan, Italy, RTD Project Sponsored by the European
Commission under the Seventh EU Research Framework Programme (Project No.
211859). [8] Analysis and Comparison of Relevant Mid-
and Long-term Energy Scenarios for EU and their Key Underlying Assumptions,
Study performed by PROGNOS for EC – DG ENER, Basel, 2011. [9] Key Factors Affecting the Deployment of
Electricity Generation Technologies in Energy Technology Scenarios, Paul
Scherrer Institut, Villigen, Switzerland, 2009. [1] European Council, 29/30 October 2009. [2] See Impact assessment accompanying Communication on Low Carbon
Economy Roadmap SEC(2011)288 [3] International
Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2009, Energy Technology Perspectives 2010 [4] The decarbonisation scenarios reflect the transport policy
measures included in the White Paper "Roadmap to a Single Transport Area –
Towards a competitive and resource efficient transport system" (COM (2011)
144) with highest impact on energy demand in transport. [5] The discussion here does not deal with CCS used for
mitigation of industrial process emissions that do not stem from fossil fuel
burning. These considerations exclude also potential removal of CO2 from the
atmosphere through fitting CCS to biomass power plants, in which case the
atmospheric removal of CO2 during plant growth is not undone by later emissions
of CO2 from burning the biomass, with the CO2 from biomass burning being stored
instead. [6] In this respect, carbon intensity is a summary indicator for
the fuel mix, while energy intensity captures the efficiency of energy
consumption and the composition of economic activity (e.g. share of services versus
(heavy) industry). [7] In modelling terms this means a significant lowering of the
discount rate used in energy consumption decision making of hundreds of
millions of consumers. [8] This share is considerably lower than in decarbonisation
scenarios of DG CLIMA. There are three main explanations: 1. Decarbonisation scenarios and Current Policy
Initiatives scenario are based on revised assumptions on nuclear (abandon of
nuclear programme in Italy, no new nuclear plants in Belgium and upwards
revision of costs for nuclear power plants). 2. Electricity demand is lower than in the Low Carbon
Economy Roadmap Scenarios due to stringent energy efficiency measures. 3. Revised assumptions on the potential of electricity in
transport compared to the DG CLIMA decarbonisation scenarios, following more
closely the scenarios developed in the White Paper on Transport leading to
lower utilisation rate of nuclear power plants than in the Low Carbon Economy
Roadmap Scenarios. Electric vehicles flatten electricity demand and thus
incentivise base load power generation. [9] Average electricity prices in this table relate to a
somewhat different customer base compared with electricity prices shown in Part
A by including also energy branch customers in addition to those in final
demand sectors; this explains the slight differences in average prices (e.g.
for 2005 between 109.3 €/MWh when including the energy branch and 110.1 €/MWh
when excluding it). [10] CHP leads to emission reductions compared to conventional
systems, but is only decarbonised when fired with biomass. The use of biomass
in PRIMES is optimally allocated endogenously and might therefore not be used
for CHP. [11] The decarbonisation scenarios reflect the transport
policy measures included in the White Paper "Roadmap to a Single Transport
Area – Towards a competitive and resource efficient transport system" (COM
(2011) 144) with highest impact on energy demand in transport. [12] The PRIMES model having a micro-economic foundation,
deals with utility maximisation and can calculate such perceived utility losses
via the concept of compensating variations. However, this concept has to assume
that preferences and values remain the same, even over 40 years, and has to
compare utility with a hypothetical state of no policy or no change in
framework conditions. Examples of such decreases are lowering thermostat in
space heating, reducing cooling services in offices, switching light off,
staying home instead of travelling, using a bicycle instead of a car, etc. [13] Impact assessment report SEC(2011)288 final, section 5 [15] The energy modelling did not include possible changes in value
added of energy intensive industries as a reaction to climate policy measures.
However, the low carbon economy roadmap includes a complementary analysis of
macroeconomic and industrial competitiveness effects of a fragmented action
scenario (SEC (2011)650, section 5.1.3) which provides further insights on
these issues. [16] It should be noted that costs of engines and propulsion
cannot be separated from the rest of vehicle costs and that these numbers
include therefore the costs for owning the entire vehicle. [17] Average electricity prices in this table relate to a somewhat
different customer base compared with electricity prices shown in Part A by
including also energy branch customers in addition to those in final demand
sectors; this explains the slight differences in average prices (e.g. for 2005
between 109.3 € when including the energy branch and 110.1 € when excluding
it). [18] The average EU price of diesel is
calculated with the weighted average of country prices; differences between
scenarios are therefore also due to different amounts of diesel used in the
countries per scenario; in addition there are different blending ratios; the
different taxation regime between the Reference scenario and the other
scenarios including CPI reflecting the new proposal for the energy taxation
directive. [19] Scenarios for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap of March 2011
show the additional costs of delayed action. [20] Key references for this work are: (1) "Analysis
and Comparison of Relevant Mid- and Long-term Energy Scenarios for EU and their
Key Underlying Assumptions" (PROGNOS, 2011) [8], and (2) "Key Factors
Affecting the Deployment of Electricity Generation Technologies in Energy
Technology Scenarios" (Paul Scherrer Institut, 2009) [9]. [21] World
Energy Outlook 2011 - special
early insights: "Are We Entering A Golden Age Of
Gas?" International Energy Agency, June 2011 (complete WEO 2011
due 9 November) [22] "Making the Green Journey Work", European Gas
Advocacy Forum, February 2011 [23] Eurogas Roadmap 2050, 13 October 2011 [24] EGAF refers to European Climate Foundation's 60% RES
scenario for the power sector (Roadmap 2050, 2010) [25] "Power Perspectives 2030", European Climate
Foundation, 7 November 2011; scenarios from Roadmap 2050, ECF, 2010. [26] “Battle of the Grids”, Greenpeace supported by
Energynautics, 2011 [27] For example, members of European Environment and
Sustainable Development Advisory Councils [28] Eg. DIW work for review of German energy concept [29] "Europe" is sometimes defined as OECD-Europe,
EU-25 (for older scenario studies) or EU-27. [30] Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM). [31] ETS is explicitly modelled by the Commission services' scenarios
that derive ETS prices endogenously. [32] and 20% Demand-Side Management (DSM) by 2050 in the ECF study. [33] In scenarios mirroring cost-effective achievement of GHG reduction,
PRIMES scenarios make sure that marginal costs are equal across sectors and MS. [34] In a study published by KEMA and Imperial College London in 2010
and performed for ECF, these issues went at least partly into the modelling. [35] Only one study was identified containing specific data in this
field (ECF/KEMA). [36] WEO expects US gas prices to be partly disconnected from oil
prices, due to large indigenous gas reserves. TABLE OF CONTENTS 1........... Section 1: Procedural issues and
consultation of interested parties.................................... 3 1.1........ Organisation and timing................................................................................................... 3 1.2........ Consultation and expertise.............................................................................................. 3 1.3........ Opinion of the IAB......................................................................................................... 4 2........... Section 2: Problem definition........................................................................................... 5 2.1........ Context.......................................................................................................................... 5 2.2........ What is the problem?...................................................................................................... 6 2.3........ Underlying drivers of the problem.................................................................................... 7 2.3.1..... General barriers.............................................................................................................. 7 2.3.2..... Sector specific barriers................................................................................................... 9 2.4........ Business as usual developments..................................................................................... 13 2.4.1..... Modelling approach...................................................................................................... 13 2.4.2..... Assumptions................................................................................................................. 13 2.4.3..... Energy developments.................................................................................................... 14 2.4.4..... Sensitivity analysis......................................................................................................... 19 2.4.5..... Conclusion................................................................................................................... 20 2.5........ EU's right to act and EU
added-value............................................................................ 20 2.6........ Who is affected?........................................................................................................... 20 3........... Section 3: Objectives.................................................................................................... 21 3.1........ General objective.......................................................................................................... 21 3.2........ Specific objectives........................................................................................................ 21 3.3........ Consistency with other European
policies...................................................................... 22 4........... Section 4: Policy options............................................................................................... 22 4.1........ Methodology................................................................................................................ 22 4.2........ Policy options............................................................................................................... 24 5........... Section 5: Analysis of impacts....................................................................................... 26 5.1........ Environmental impacts.................................................................................................. 26 5.2........ Economic impacts......................................................................................................... 28 5.3........ Social impacts.............................................................................................................. 35 5.4........ Sensitivity analysis......................................................................................................... 39 6........... Section 6: Comparing the options.................................................................................. 40 7........... Monitoring and evaluation............................................................................................. 44 8........... Annexes....................................................................................................................... 45
1.
Section 1: Procedural issues and consultation of
interested parties
Identification:
Lead DG: DG ENER. Agenda planning/WP reference: 2011/ENER/002
1.1.
Organisation and timing
The IA work
started early 2009 with the Reference scenario that is being used for all
long-term initiatives of the Commission. An Interservice Steering Group was
established early 2009 together with DG CLIMA and MOVE. This Group was also
used for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap and Transport White paper. Problem
definition, objectives and design of policy options were presented to the
Impact Assessment Steering Group in May 2011 and the final draft IA in July
2011. The following
DGs participated in the Impact Assessment Steering Group: AGRI, CLIMA, COMP,
ECFIN, EMPL, ENTR, ENV, INFSO, JRC, LS, MARE, MARKT, MOVE, REGIO, RTD, SANCO,
SG, TAXUD.
1.2.
Consultation and expertise
On 20 December
2010, the Directorate General for Energy launched a public consultation on the
Energy Roadmap. The public consultation[1]
was based on an online questionnaire with seven questions, some requiring
comments and others in the form of multiple choice[2]. The public consultation was
open until 7 March 2011. Some 400 contributions, half from organisations and
half from individual citizens, were received. Several Member States sent a
formal reply to the public consultation. Given the participation from a broad
spectrum of organisations as well as citizens, this public consultation offered
insights into a large range of stakeholder opinions. All of the Commission's
minimum consultation standards were met. The full report presenting results of
the public consultation can be downloaded from Europa website[3]. Public consultation questions and summary of replies Question 1 How to ensure credibility: Many contributors emphasised the need for a stable,
clear and predictable legislative framework to encourage the necessary
investments in the energy sector which generally have a very long lead time. An
appropriate analytical framework including transparency on modelling
assumptions and results was mentioned by several respondents. Question 2 The EU's position in a global policy context: More than half of all respondents chose
"global energy efficiency and demand developments" and "global
development of renewable energy" as the most important issues. Question 3 Societal challenges and opportunities: Overall responses were fairly evenly
distributed among the different choices. Public acceptance of new
infrastructures was seen as important by many. Question 4 Policy developments at EU level: Roughly half of the respondents believe
that energy efficiency is among the three most important issues needing more
development at the EU level. Question 5 Milestones in the transition: Across all industries and NGOs,
intermediate targets, checkpoints and regular updates towards 2050 were
recommended. However, the decarbonisation roadmap should be flexible enough to
allow the route to be changed along the way. Question 6 Key drivers for the future energy mix: About half of all respondents believe that
global fossil fuel prices in relation to costs of domestic energy resources and
long term security of supply will be the most likely key drivers of the future
European energy mix. Question 7 Additional thoughts and contributions: There was considerable divergence in opinions
on the best way to decarbonise the energy sector in terms of market
intervention as well as in the selection of a preferred technology option to be
pursued. In addition to
the public consultation, representatives from the Directorate General for Energy
and Commissioner Oettinger met numerous stakeholders individually and received
many reports prepared by stakeholders on this topic. A comparison of
stakeholder reports is presented in Annex 2. An informal
Energy Council took place on 2-3 May 2011 where ministers had a full-day
discussion on the Energy Roadmap 2050. A meeting of Member State (MS) energy
experts on the Roadmap also took place on 25 May 2011. The European Commission
(EC) presented the problem definition, objectives and design of policy options
of this Impact Assessment (IA) report. An Advisory Group of 15 highly-regarded
experts mainly from academia and international institutions was established to
support the work on the preparation of the Roadmap A presentation on the
Roadmap was also given to the European sectoral social dialogue committee in
the electricity sector on 14 December 2010. The Commission
contracted the National Technical University of Athens to model scenarios
underpinning the IA analysis. Similarly to previous modelling exercises with
the PRIMES model, the Commission discloses a lot of details about the PRIMES
modelling system, modelling assumptions and modelling results which can be
found in sections 4 and 5 as well as the annex 1 including an extensive section
on macroeconomic, energy import prices, technology (capital costs of different
technologies in power generation, appliances and transport) and policy
assumptions. The PRIMES model was peer-reviewed by a group of recognised
modelling experts in September 2011 with the conclusion that the model is
suitable for the purpose of complex energy system modelling.
1.3.
Opinion of the Impact Assessment Board (IAB)
The IA report
was discussed at the IAB hearing on 14 September 2011 and the IAB issued a
positive opinion acknowledging the quality of the technical analysis and
modelling underpinning the Roadmap and the Impact Assessment. The IAB
recommended to improve the report in the following aspects: (1) to bring key
findings of the evaluation of on-going policies into the IA report; (2) to
consider an alternative policy scenario relying on a more relaxed assumption
about the global climate deal; (3) to better describe scenarios and underlying
assumptions; (4) to improve assessment of non-energy related impacts
(employment, skills and knowledge gaps) and (5) to present stakeholder views in
a more transparent way. As a response to
these suggestions, the evaluation part was reinforced; the issue of carbon
leakage and external competitiveness was added to the problem definition as well
as section 4.1. Methodology, while the part on competitiveness issues was
expanded in Annex 1; policy options were described in more detail and the
assessment of employment impacts was improved.
2.
Section 2: Problem definition
2.1.
Context
(i) In the 2nd
Strategic Energy Review (November 2008), the Commission undertook to prepare an
energy policy roadmap towards a low carbon energy system in 2050. The Europe
2020 strategy includes a general commitment to establish a vision of structural
and technological changes required to move to a low carbon, resource efficient
and climate resilient economy by 2050. (ii) The
Commission's approach to decarbonisation is firmly grounded in the EU's growth
agenda, set out in the Europe 2020 strategy, including the Resource Efficient
Europe Flagship Initiative[4].
The Communication "Energy 2020 - A strategy for competitive, sustainable
and secure energy" paves the way to 2020 stressing the three pillars of
the EU's energy policy: competitiveness, security of supply and sustainability,
building on the Climate and Energy package adopted in June 2009. (iii) The
European Council (October 2009) supports an EU objective, in the context of
necessary reductions according to the IPCC by developed countries as a group,
to reduce GHG emissions by 80-95% by 2050 compared to 1990 levels[5]. The European Parliament
similarly endorsed the need to set a long-term GHG emissions reduction target
of at least 80% by 2050 for the EU and the other developed countries[6]. (iv) The
European Council (February 2011) confirms this emissions reduction commitment and
recognises that it will require a revolution in energy systems, which must
start now. It requests that due consideration should be given to fixing
intermediary stages towards reaching the 2050 objective. (v) The Roadmap
for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050[7] makes the economic case for
decarbonisation and shows that the targeted 80-95% GHG emissions reduction by
2050 will have to be met largely domestically. Intermediate milestones for a
cost-efficient pathway, e.g. 40% domestic reduction by 2030, and sectoral
milestones expressed as ranges of GHG emissions reductions in 2030 and 2050
were put forward. (vi) The
Commission is now preparing sectoral roadmaps exploring the dynamics within the
sector and the interplay of decarbonisation[8]
and other sectoral objectives. The Roadmap to a Single European Transport Area
– Towards a competitive and resource efficient transport system[9] aims to introduce profound
changes in passenger and freight transport patterns, resulting in a competitive
transport sector which allows increased mobility, cuts CO2 emissions to 60%
below 1990 levels by 2050 and breaks the transport system's dependence on oil.
A Roadmap to a Resource Efficient Europe, also planned
for 2011, builds on and complements other initiatives, focusing on increasing
resource productivity and decoupling economic growth from resource use. This IA is a key part of initiatives to deliver on a resource
Efficient Europe, one of the 7 flagships of the Europe 2020 strategy[10]. It aims at further developing
the decarbonisation analysis of the energy sector as presented in the Low
Carbon Economy Roadmap in March 2011, with particular attention to all three EU
energy policy objectives - energy security, sustainability and
competitiveness.
2.2.
What is the problem?
The well-being
of people, industry and economy depends on safe, secure, sustainable and
affordable energy. Energy is a daily need in a modern world and is mostly taken
for granted in Europe. The energy system and its organisation evolved over
centuries if not millenaries using different fuels and distribution systems to
cover basic needs such as food preparation, protection against winter
temperatures and production of tools e.g. via metal melting. Over the last
century this has concerned delivering heat and warm water as well as industrial
and transport fuels and electricity to consumers. There has been a significant
increase in energy production and consumption over the last 100 years providing
more comfort and individual freedom but at the same time polluting the
environment and (at least partially) depleting existing reserves. Our current
energy system and ways of producing, transforming and consuming energy are
unsustainable due to: (1) High GHG
emissions of which the great majority is directly or indirectly linked to
energy[11]
which are not compatible with the EU and global objectives of limiting global
climate change to a temperature increase of 2ºC to avoid dangerous impacts[12] (even though the EU
contribution to global emissions is low and will decline in particular if other
regions make no or little efforts on decarbonisation,[13] industrialised countries
should keep their leading role in the fight against climate change); (2) Security of supply risks, notably those
related to: - high dependence on foreign sources of energy
imported from a limited number of suppliers (EU27 currently imports 83.5% of
its oil and 64.2% of its gas consumption; overall import dependency is around
54% and is projected to slightly increase by 2050), including supplies from
politically unstable regions; - gradual depletion of fossil fuel resources
and rising global competition for energy resources; - increasing electrification from more variable
sources (e.g. solar PV and wind) which poses new challenges to the grid to
ensure uninterrupted electricity deliveries; - low resilience to natural or man-made
disasters and adverse effects of climate change; (3)
Competitiveness risks related to high energy costs and underinvestment.
External competitiveness of the European industry vis-à-vis its international
competitors is another crucial aspect determining the design and timing of EU energy
and climate action. While it is important to sustain first mover advantage and
industrial leadership it should also be assessed whether "early"
action comes at a cost of comparatively high carbon, fuel and electricity
prices for industry compared to action undertaken in the rest of the world. It will take
decades to steer our energy systems onto a more secure and sustainable path. In
addition, there is no silver bullet to achieve it. There is no single energy
source that is abundant and that has no drawbacks in terms of its
sustainability, security of supply and competitiveness (price). That is why the
solution will require trade-offs and why the market alone under the current
regulatory environment might fail to deliver. The decisions to set us on the
right path are needed urgently as failing to achieve a well-functioning
European energy market will only increase the costs for consumers and put Europe’s competitiveness at risk. Significant investments will however be needed in the
near future to replace energy assets in order to guarantee a similar level of
comfort to citizens at affordable prices; assure secure and competitive
supplies of energy inputs to businesses and preserve the environment. The
energy challenge is thus one of the greatest tests which Europe has to face. Relying on more
low-carbon, domestic (i.e. intra EU) or more diversified sources of energy,
produced and consumed in an efficient way, can bring significant benefits not
only for the environment, competitiveness and security of energy supply but
also in terms of economic growth, employment, regional development and innovation.
What are the barriers? Why is the shift to an energy system using low-carbon,
more competitive and more diversified sources not, or too slowly happening?
2.3.
Underlying drivers of the problem
There are
several factors that hamper the shift:
2.3.1.
General barriers
1) Energy
market prices do not fully reflect all costs to society in terms of
pollution, GHG emissions, resource depletion, land use, air quality, waste and
geopolitical dependency. Therefore, user and producer choices are made on the
basis of inadequate energy prices that do not reflect true costs for society. 2) Inertia of
the physical system The majority of
investments in the energy system are long-term assets, sometimes requiring long
lead times, and having life times of 30-60 years, leading to significant
lock-in effects. Any change to the system materialises only gradually. Current
market structure and infrastructures can discourage new technology development,
since infrastructure, market design, grid management and development require adaptation
and modernisation which represent additional costs which face resistance from industry.
3) Public
perception and mindset of the users General public perception
of the risks related to the construction of new power plants (large-scale RES,
nuclear, low-carbon fossil) and infrastructure needed to introduce large shares
of renewables (which additionally implies new grid lines and large energy
storage technologies) or of CO2 storage can be more negative than expert
judgements. Public acceptance was also acknowledged as important by many
respondents in public consultation. It can also take a long time and require adequate
incentives or regulation to persuade people to change the way they heat their
houses, transport themselves, etc. 4) Uncertainty
concerning technological, demand, prices and market design developments The energy
system is characterised by a large proportion of long-term fixed costs that
need to be recovered over several decades. Uncertainty about future
technologies, energy demand development, market integration and rules[14], carbon and fuel prices,
availability of infrastructures can significantly increase investor risks and
costs, and make consumers and businesses reluctant to invest. Private investors
can cope well with some categories of risks but policy makers and regulators
can contribute to decreasing the uncertainties as regards political and regulatory
risks. 5) Imperfect
markets There is weak
competition in some Member States where markets are still dominated by incumbents.
In particular, the absence or lack of effective non-discriminatory third party
access to infrastructure can constitute an entry barrier for new entrants.
Another factor is market myopia, i.e. the fact that long-term investments are
not necessarily pursued by market actors who are generally drawn towards
shorter-term gains. Regarding new
infrastructure investments, it can be difficult to clearly identify the
beneficiaries, and therefore efficiently allocate the costs of new investments.
In addition, in liberalised markets with various players, interdependencies
might impose additional efforts to coordinate some investments (it is
unrealistic to expect wind power plants to be constructed in the North Sea if no adequate grid is built). In some Member
States developing markets for energy efficiency services and decentralised RES
are faced with a low number of actors on the supply side (lack of qualified
labour force) as well as on the demand side (low levels of consumer awareness
partly as a consequence of the ongoing rapid technological advances) and the
lack of enabling regulatory framework. This has a particularly negative effect
on the uptake of energy services companies (ESCOs) that can provide integrated
energy saving solutions together with financing schemes. Renewable energy can
also suffer from market designs that have been developed alongside the
development and optimisation of centralised power generation and trading.
2.3.2.
Sector specific barriers
Besides these
factors and based on an evaluation of ongoing policies[15], there are problems specific
to energy efficiency, infrastructure, security of supply and low-carbon
generation technologies which are discouraging investments. Energy
efficiency Though a number
of initiatives were undertaken at EU level since the mid-1990s, the European
Energy Efficiency Action Plan[16]
created a framework of legislation, policies and measures with a view to
realise the 20% energy efficiency and saving objective. After years of growth,
the EU primary energy consumption has stabilized in 2005 and 2006 at around 1,825
Mtoe and decreased in 2007, 2008 and 2009 to reach around 1,700 Mtoe[17]. Energy intensity kept
improving. For the first time, the latest business-as-usual scenario
projections (PRIMES 2009) show a break in the trend of ever-increasing energy
demand in the EU27[18]. However, the EU
is far from reaching its 20% objective. The projections indicate that with the
rates of implementation of the current energy efficiency policies in Member
States only half of the objective might be achieved by 2020[19]. Furthermore, while the
economic crisis contributed to this decrease in energy consumption, it has also
negatively impacted energy efficiency investment decisions at all levels -
public, commercial and private. As a response to this, the Commission has
recently adopted two new initiatives - an Energy Efficiency Plan[20] and a Directive on Energy
Efficiency - aiming at stepping up efforts towards the 20% target. In addition to
the above mentioned barriers, there are many examples of split incentives or
principal-agent market failures in the energy sector where the decision
maker may be partially detached from the price signals. For example, landlords
are often the decision-makers about renovation of buildings, but it is usually
tenants that pay the energy bills and benefit from their reduction, giving
landlords little reason to invest. Internal
market The process of
opening the EU energy markets to competition started ten years ago. It has
allowed EU citizens and industries to benefit in terms of more choice, more
competition for a better service and improved security of supply. Since July
2007, all consumers in all EU countries have been free to switch their suppliers
of gas and electricity. Independent
national regulatory authorities have been established in each EU country to
ensure that suppliers and network companies operate correctly and actually
provide the services promised to their customers. An inquiry into the
electricity and gas sectors published in January 2007[21] revealed that too many
barriers to competition and too many differences across the Member States
remain. In 2007 and 2008, a great deal of effort was put into enhancing
competition on the wholesale market; significant progress was made through the
regional initiatives. However, the Benchmarking Report adopted in 2009[22] still showed a mixed picture
of the accomplishment of the internal market and revealed in particular that
there are still high levels of concentration on the retail and wholesale markets
and a lack of liquidity. To remedy the
situation, the Commission came forward with the third internal energy market
liberalisation package. It foresees the effective separation of supply and
production activities to make the market accessible for all suppliers, the harmonization
of powers of national regulators, better cross-border regulation to promote new
investments and cross-border trade, effective transparency, as well as assuring
that EU and third country companies compete in the EU on an equal footing. For the
electricity market, a target model has been agreed in the context of the Florence regulatory forum and for gas markets a target model is under development. Infrastructure Tariff
regulation - Transmission is a mostly regulated business at national level and
cost allocation to final beneficiaries can be difficult for large
trans-European infrastructure. Tariff regulation in most Member States has been
based on the principle of cost-efficiency, allowing recovery of costs only for
projects based on real market needs or cheapest available solutions, but some
externalities, such as innovation, security of supply, solidarity aspects or
other wider European benefits may not always be fully taken into account. For
infrastructure networks that are entirely new, such as electricity highways or
CO2 transport infrastructure, it is likely to be of public interest to ensure
that the first investments are compatible with later, more efficient network
solutions. In the EU
internal energy market, a key tool to promote interconnections is the
trans-European energy networks (TEN-E) programme which has positively
contributed to the development and operation of the internal energy market and
increased security of supply[23].
Despite the progress achieved, the dramatic changes to the EU energy policy
framework in recent years call for a review of the TEN-E framework. The
programme has responded too slowly to the major energy and climate goals of
today, and is poorly equipped to deal with the growing challenges that will
arise from the 2020 and 2050 ambitions. In 2009, as the financial crisis
unfolded, EU institutions agreed on the European Energy Programme for Recovery
(EEPR)[24]
which was endowed with a €3,980 million financial envelope in support of gas
and electricity interconnection projects, offshore wind projects as well as
carbon capture and storage projects. Security of
supply EU Energy import
dependency for all fuels is 54%. More importantly, the EU is vulnerable to the
increasing supply of some commodities by global oligopolies which can create
internal and external imbalances. EU experiences of gas supply interruptions in
early 2006, 2008, 2009 and 2010, as well as the EU's strong dependence on
imports of petroleum products and the geopolitical uncertainty in many producer
regions led to the adoption of the Regulation concerning measures to safeguard
security of gas supply[25].
Since 1968, EU
legislation imposes an obligation on Member States to maintain minimum stocks
of crude oil and/or petroleum products that can be used in the event of a
supply crisis and a new directive[26]
adopted in September 2009 aligns stockholding obligations with those of the
International Energy Agency. Electricity blackouts
in the EU in November 2006 highlighted the need to define clear operational
standards for transmission networks and for correct maintenance and development
of the network. Therefore, in order to ensure the functioning of the internal
energy market, the EU established obligations for Member States to safeguard
security of electricity supply and undertake significant investment in
electricity networks[27].
Low-carbon
generation technologies All low carbon
technologies are reliant upon a strong carbon price or other regulatory
measures. As well as continuous R&D funding, long-term market or regulatory
signals to investors are needed. Renewables Some renewables
are currently at early development stage, insofar as they often have higher
costs than alternatives, though they form part of a sector with rapid
technological developments and significantly declining production costs
resulting from early economies of scale and technology learning. Renewable energy
production has grown rapidly in the last ten years. The Green electricity
Directive (2001/77) and the Biofuels Directive (2003/30) aimed to stimulate an
increase in the consumption of renewable energy. The former established an
overall EU target of 21% and national indicative targets for the RES shares in gross
electricity consumption by 2010. The latter required that all Member States
should ensure that at least 5.75% of their petrol and diesel for transport
comes from renewable fuels. Despite significant growth, the latest EUROSTAT
data indicate that 2010 targets will not be met.[28] The Renewable Energy Directive[29] sets out binding targets for
all Member State to achieve the 20% renewable energy target for the EU by 2020
as well as a 10% target for the share of renewable energy in transport. It also
addresses the problems of administrative barriers to the development of
renewables and their integration in the grids and sustainability requirements
for biofuels. According to the Communication on "Renewable Energy: Progressing
towards the 2020 target", Member States are on track to reach their
overall renewable energy target as well as the sub-target for renewable energy
in transport. Table 1: Renewable energy developments and
defined targets. Share of renewable energy in… || 2001 || Most recent data || Target 2010 (indicative) || Target 2020 (binding) electricity generation || 13.4% (36 Mtoe) || 16. 6 % (48 Mtoe - 2008 ) || 21% || no transport || 0.3% (1 Mtoe) || 3. 5 % (11 Mtoe - 2008) || 5.75%[30] || 10%[31][3] heating[32] || 9.1% (52 Mtoe) || 12 % (67 Mtoe - 2008 ) || no target || no Gross final energy consumption || 7.6% (89 Mtoe) || 10.6 % (132 Mtoe - 2009 ) || no target[33] || 20% Gross inland consumption || 5.8% (101 Mtoe) || 9.0% (153 Mtoe) || 12% || no Nuclear The EU-27 has
the largest number of commercial nuclear power stations in the world: some 150
nuclear reactors are in operation, providing around 30% of the EU's electricity
and 60% of low carbon electricity. Although nuclear is a proven technology, in
some MS it faces uncertainties regarding public acceptance due to risk
perception and often also due to lacking implementation of available technical
solutions for long term disposal of nuclear waste. The nuclear accident in Japan could further aggravate public acceptance problems in some MS while possible further
increased safety requirements might affect the competitiveness of existing
nuclear generation capacities in some MS. Nuclear safety
is and will remain one of the absolute priorities of the EU. A Directive
establishing the basic framework for nuclear safety[34] adopted in 2009 provides a
Community framework in order to maintain and promote the continuous improvement
of nuclear safety. When this Directive will be implemented the EU will be the
first major regional nuclear player with common binding nuclear safety rules.
On 3 November 2010, the European Commission also proposed a Directive which
sets safety standards for disposing spent fuel and radioactive waste. CCS As a new and
developing industry, CCS faces similar challenges to innovative renewable
energy technologies. At present, it is in the early commercial-scale
demonstration phase, and is ambitiously striving to be commercially viable soon
after 2020. But facing a number of problems, its progress is currently
challenged by issues that include financing and public perception concerns in
some Member States. The European
Council of March 2007 urged to work towards strengthening R&D and
developing the necessary technical, economic and regulatory framework to remove
existing legal barriers and to bring environmentally safe CCS to deployment. In
2008, the European Council made a commitment to supporting the design,
construction and operation of CCS in up to 12 large-scale demonstration plants
by 2015. Demonstration of the technology in commercial plants is considered to
be an essential step towards commercialisation of CCS to demonstrate the
environmental safety and economic viability of the technology, which is also
dependent on strong carbon prices. The CCS Directive[35] establishes a comprehensive
legal framework to safely manage the environmental aspects of capture,
transport and the geological storage of CO2. The revised ETS Directive ensures
that safely stored CO2 is not regarded as emitted and provides therefore a
financial incentive for CCS. In addition, 300 million allowances from the New
Entrants Reserve (NER) shall be available to support commercial-scale CCS and
innovative RES demonstration projects under the NER300 funding programme, thus
complementing and going beyond funding already provided by the EEPR. CCS is
also an important option for decarbonisation of several heavy industries[36]. Moreover, CCS has the
potential to deliver carbon-negative power, if it is combined with biomass
combustion or co-firing. As the
Energy Roadmap 2050 is a broad policy document without having the ambition of
defining individual policy measures, this IA tries to present a broad picture
of the challenges and barriers but will not propose solutions to all of them.
2.4.
Business as usual developments
2.4.1.
Modelling approach
The Commission
has carried out an analysis of possible future developments in a scenario of unchanged
policies, the so-called “Reference scenario”. The Reference scenario was
also used in the IA for the “Low-carbon economy 2050 roadmap” and IA for the
"White Paper on Transport". The Reference scenario is a projection,
not a forecast, of developments in the absence of new policies beyond those
adopted by March 2010. It therefore reflects both achievements and deficiencies
of the policies already in place. In order to take into account the most recent
developments (higher energy prices and effects of the nuclear accident in Japan) and the latest policies on energy efficiency, energy taxation and infrastructure
adopted or planned after March 2010, an additional scenario called Current
Policy Initiatives scenario (CPI) was modelled. Both scenarios build on a modelling
framework including PRIMES, PROMETHEUS, GAINS and GEM-E3 models. The PRIMES
model is a modelling system that simulates a market equilibrium solution for
energy supply and demand. The model is organized in sub-models (modules), each
one representing the behaviour of a specific (or representative) agent, a
demander and/or a supplier of energy. GAINS complements PRIMES with consistent
estimates of non-CO2 emissions and their contribution to reach the policy
targets included in the reference scenario. PROMETHEUS is a stochastic world
energy model used for determining fossil fuel import prices, while the results
of the GEM-E3 general equilibrium model are used as inputs of macro-economic
(e.g. GDP) and sectoral numbers (e.g. sectoral value added) for PRIMES. Several
EU scenarios were established at different points in time using a framework
contract with National Technical University of Athens (author and owner of the
PRIMES model).
2.4.2.
Assumptions
The Reference scenario
2050 includes current trends and recent Eurostat and EPC/ECFIN long term
projections on population and economic development. It takes into account the
upward trend of import fuel prices in a highly volatile world energy price
environment. Economic decisions are driven by market forces and technological
progress in the framework of concrete national and EU policies and measures
implemented by March 2010. The 2020 targets for RES and GHG will be achieved in
this scenario, but there is no assumption on targets for later years besides
annual reduction of the cap in the ETS directive. The CPI scenario
builds on the same macroeconomic framework and includes policy initiatives
adopted after March 2010 or policy initiatives currently being planned as well as
updated technology assumptions for nuclear and electric vehicles. The main
assumptions used for both scenarios are presented in table 2 and all
assumptions and more detailed description of results can be found in Annex 1
(part A). Table 2: Main assumptions in the Reference scenario
2050 and Current Policy Initiatives Scenario GDP growth rate: 1.7 % pa on average for 2010-2050 Oil price: 106 $/barrel in 2030 and 127 $/barrel in 2050 (in
year 2008 dollars)[37] Main policies included (Reference scenario): Eco-design and Labelling directives
adopted by March 2010; Recast of the Energy Performance of Buildings Directive,
EU ETS directive; RES directive (20% target); Effort Sharing Decision (non-ETS
part of the 20% GHG target); Regulation on CO2 from cars and vans. Main policies included (Current Policy
Initiatives scenario) in
addition to those already included in the Reference scenario 2050: Energy
efficiency Plan; facilitation policies for infrastructure and updated
investments plans based on ENTSO-e Ten Year Network Development Plan; Nuclear
Safety Directive; Waste management Directive; revised Energy Taxation Directive Consequences of the Japanese nuclear
accident leading to abandon of nuclear programme in Italy, nuclear phase-out in
Germany and in case of nuclear lifetime extension up to 20% higher generation costs
reflecting higher safety requirements as well as introduction of a risk premium
for new nuclear power plants; revisiting of progress on CCS in demonstration
projects and policies and initiatives leading to slightly higher uptake of
electric vehicles. Costs for technologies: Technology parameters are exogenous in
the PRIMES modelling and their values are based on current databases, various
studies and expert judgement and are regularly compared to other leading
institutions. Technologies are assumed to develop over time and to follow
learning curves which are exogenously adjusted to reflect the technology
assumptions of a scenario. Overall, mature fossil fuel, nuclear as well as large
hydroelectric technologies exhibit rather stable technology costs, except for
innovative concepts such as 3rd generation nuclear power plants or carbon
capture and storage (CCS), where costs decline with further RTD and more
technology experience. Similar developments are assumed for new renewable
technologies, such as off-shore wind and solar PV as has been witnessed in the
past for most energy technologies (e.g. on-shore wind or more recently solar
energy). Drivers: Within these framework conditions market forces drive
energy and emission developments. Economic actors optimise their supply and
demand behaviour while the simulation of energy markets in the model derives
energy prices, which in turn influence the behaviour of energy actors (power generators,
various industrial and service consumers, households, transport, etc). The
Reference and CPI scenarios do not assume any additional policies. The model provides
a simulation of what the interplay of market forces in the current economic,
world energy, policy and technology framework would bring about if no new
policies would be put in place. All scenarios are built on assumptions of
perfect foresight and "representative" consumer leading to a very
high certainty on regulatory framework for investors and rather optimistic
deployment of technologies by households and services that will be challenging
to ensure in practice.
2.4.3.
Energy developments
Energy
consumption Primary
energy consumption peaked in 2006, from which point
it decreases slightly up to 2050 (-4%). This is despite economic growth leading
to a doubling of GDP between 2005 and 2050. Final energy
consumption continues rising until 2020, after
which demand stabilises as more efficient technologies have by then reached
market maturity and the additional energy efficiency of the appliances is
sufficient to compensate for increased demand. The share of sectors remains
broadly stable with transport remaining the biggest single consumer accounting
for 32% in 2050; the industrial share increases slightly while that of
households declines a bit. In the CPI
scenario, further energy savings are brought about mainly by energy efficiency
measures for households and services sector and efficiency improvements in
energy transformation in the short to medium term leading to further declines
in final energy demand which remains 4-6% below the Reference scenario. There
are marked changes also at the level of primary demand in 2020 (-5.0%); 2030
(-5.8%) and 2050 (-8.4%). The energy
intensity of the economy and of different sectors decreases. Increased
energy efficiency in the residential sector is due to the use of more efficient
energy equipment (appliances, lighting, etc.) and buildings, being driven by
the Eco-Design regulations and by better thermal integrity of buildings
reflecting the Recast of the Energy Performance of Buildings Directive. Energy
consumption in transport is decoupling significantly from underlying transport
activity growth due to the use of more energy efficient vehicles; this development
is largely driven by more fuel efficient cars, in particular hybrids, following
the CO2 performance standards set by the CO2 from cars regulation[38]. There is
considerable fuel switching in final and primary energy demand in the
Reference scenario. In primary energy, the dominance of fossil fuels diminishes
with its share falling from 83% and 79% in 1990 and 2005, respectively, to only
64% in 2050. While non fossil fuels (RES and nuclear) account for 36% of
primary energy in 2050, they reach a significantly higher share in the 2050
electricity mix. Energy sources not emitting CO2 supply 66% of electricity
output in 2050, with 40% RES and 26% nuclear. Graph 1: Reference scenario- Fuel shares
in primary energy In the CPI scenario,
the share of nuclear is lower due to a change in nuclear assumptions. In this
new policy environment gas and RES replace nuclear and thereby increase their
share over Reference scenario levels. Power
generation The demand for
electricity continues rising and there is a considerable shift towards RES with
a strong increase in wind. Power generation and capacity from solids decrease
throughout the projection period due to increasing carbon prices that reduce
the competitiveness of this technology; gas power generation capacity
increases, also as peak load activated during back-up periods due to the
increased amount of RES in the system. As a result of the large increase in RES
in power generation the load factor of the system decreases given the more
widespread use of technologies that run only a limited number of hours per
year. Investment in power generation increases over the projection period,
driven by RES and gas. The carbon
intensity of power generation falls by over 75% in 2050 compared to 2010
levels, driven by the decreasing ETS cap and rising carbon prices. CO2
emissions from power generation decline by 2/3rd between 2010 and
2050, while electricity demand still increases. This strong decarbonisation is
brought about by fuel switching to RES and nuclear, an increasing share of gas
in fossil fuel generation and significant penetration of CCS after 2030. In
2050 18% of electricity is generated through power plants with CCS (solids and
gas). Electricity
demand in the CPI scenario falls well below electricity use in the Reference scenario
(by 6.5% in 2030 and 4.3% in 2050), reflecting measures in the Energy
Efficiency Plan and the revised Energy Taxation Directive. The CPI scenario
takes account of the post Fukushima policy change in Member States, notably the
abandonment of the nuclear programme in Italy, and new initiatives, such as the
nuclear stress tests that will tend to increase costs for new power plants and
retrofitting. The CPI scenario has significantly lower CCS penetration primarily
as a result of the ETS price being lower in the longer term and also as a
consequence of the relatively moderate progress that has been made since 2009
(Reference scenario) towards the EU objective of having up to 12 large-scale
CCS demonstration plants operational by 2015 in Europe. Table 3: Electricity related indicators in
CPI scenario and differences from Reference Heating A strong
increase in demand for distributed steam and heat can be observed between 2005
and 2020 following strong CHP promoting policies, as well as commercial
opportunities that arise from gas and biomass based CHP technologies. In the
longer term further demand for distributed heat in the tertiary and residential
sectors slows down as a result of the trend towards electrification (i.e. heat
pumps) and higher energy efficiency which limits the overall demand for
heating. In industry the increase in demand for distributed steam is projected
to continue in the future because the changes of industrial activity are
favourable for sectors with high demand for steam such as chemicals, food,
tobacco, and engineering. In the CPI
scenario, demand for distributed heat rises compared to current levels but is
1-2% lower than in the Reference scenario, reflecting the effects of more efficient
heating systems used in houses. Transport Transport
accounts today for over 30% of final energy consumption. In a context of
growing demand for transport, final energy demand by transport is projected to
increase by 5% by 2030 rising further marginally by 2050. Transport growth is
driven mainly by aviation and road freight transport. The EU transport system
would remain extremely dependent on the use of fossil fuels. Oil products would
still represent 88% of EU transport sector needs in 2030 and 2050 in the
Reference scenario. Energy
consumption in transport is little affected by current energy policy
initiatives (- 1.7% in 2030 and -5.7% in 2050). Changes from the Reference scenario
are brought about in particular by the proposed new energy taxation system and
through the somewhat more favourable policy environment for electric and
plug-in hybrid vehicles. Policy
relevant indicators (and targets) Emissions - It is estimated that a continuation of current trends and
policies (Reference scenario) would result in 40% reduction in energy-related
CO2 emissions between 1990 and 2050 and 26% by 2030. All GHG emissions would
fall 40% by 2050 (29% by 2030) which represents about half of the domestic
efforts needed by a developed economy in the context of limiting climate change
to 2°C[39].
Most emissions continue to be energy related emissions. Carbon intensity falls
markedly. Producing one unit of GDP in 2050 would lead to only 21% of energy
related CO2 emissions that were required in 1990. In the CPI
scenario emission reductions are broadly similar to those in the Reference
scenario. CO2 emissions in 2050 are 41% below 1990 values and below those
reached in the Reference case due to greater energy intensity improvements
brought about by vigorous energy efficiency policies which overcompensates
worsening carbon intensity due to lower availability of nuclear and CCS and
lower ETS carbon prices. Total GHG emissions in 2050 decrease by 39% below the
1990 level (1 percentage point less than in the Reference scenario) mainly a
result of changes of the carbon price over the next decades. ETS prices under developments in the Reference scenario rise from 40 €
(08)/tCO2 in 2030 to 52 € in 2040 and flattens out to 50 € in 2050. The ETS
price in the CPI scenario is lower for most of the projection period
reflecting efficiency and RES policies (by about 20% in 2025-2035) and ends at
51 € in 2050.[40]
RES target - The Reference scenario assumes that the RES target is reached in
2020; the RES share continues rising in the Reference scenario to reach 24% in
2030 and over 25% in 2050. Further penetration of RES progresses more slowly
due to the assumed phasing out of operational aid to mature RES technologies.
RES in transport contribute 10% in 2020 to comply with the RES directive; this
share increases to 13 % by 2050. However, the pace of electrification in the
transport sector is projected to remain slow in the Reference scenario:
electric propulsion in road transport does not make significant inroads by 2050[41]. The CPI scenario has higher
RES shares, e.g. 25% RES in final energy in 2030 and 29% in 2050. The
indicative 20% energy savings objective for 2020
would not be achieved under current policies - not even by 2050. The Reference
scenario would deliver 10% less energy consumed in 2020 compared to the 2007
projections. The CPI scenario delivers significantly more. Energy consumption
in 2020 is 14% below the 2007 projections further decreasing significantly up
to 2050.[42]
Import
dependency - Total energy imports increase by 6%
from 2005 to 2050. The increase is rather limited despite decreasing indigenous
production, as rising gas (+28% from 2005 to 2050) and biomass imports are
compensated by a marked decline in coal imports while oil imports remain
broadly stable. Import dependency rises above the present level (54%), reaching
58% in 2020 and flattening out to 2050 thanks to more RES and nuclear. It
remains broadly unchanged in the CPI scenario. Average
electricity prices rise up to 2030 and stabilise
thereafter. The price increase up to 2030 is due to three main elements: RES
supporting policies, ETS carbon price and high fuel prices due to the world
recovery after the economic crisis. Thereafter electricity prices remain stable
because of the techno-economic improvements of various power generation
technologies that limit the effects of higher input fuel prices and CO2 prices.
In the CPI scenario, electricity prices are slightly higher (1% in 2030 and 4%
in 2050) reflecting the lower share of nuclear as well as higher lifetime
extension costs post Fukushima and high investments for new electricity
generation capacity, especially RES. Total costs
of energy (including capital costs, energy
purchases and direct efficiency investment costs) are rising fast over the
projection period but are not equally distributed across sectors. Energy
related expenditures in households rise strongly while the growth of energy
related costs for services and industry is more moderate. Energy costs are
rising faster than GDP and represent around 15.1% of GDP in 2030 (up from 10.5%
in 2005) and 14.3% in 2050. The faster rate of growth relative to GDP reflects
significant investments needs in energy production, transmission and
distribution as well as demand based energy efficiency measures. Under the CPI scenario,
system costs are slightly higher amounting to 15.3% and 14.6% in relation to
GDP in 2030 and 2050, respectively, reflecting in particular greater investment
requirements.
2.4.4.
Sensitivity analysis
Considering the
high degree of uncertainty surrounding projections over such a long time
horizon, a sensitivity analysis has been carried out with respect to two key
parameters - energy imports prices and GDP. A high and a low case has been
analysed for both variables. GDP The two economic
growth variants explore a High GDP case where GDP per capita is 0.4 percentage
points (pp) higher than in the Reference scenario throughout the projection
period (+15% increase in GDP level in 2050) and a Low GDP case with GDP per
capita 0.4 pp lower (-14.7% in GDP level in 2050). GDP and economic activity
have a significant influence on energy consumption in particular in industry
and services. The model based
analysis shows that policy relevant indicators are rather insensitive against
variations in GDP assumption, which is a significant result given the great
uncertainty in making GDP projections for the next few years let alone the next
four decades. CO2 reduction
becomes only slightly more difficult to achieve under significantly higher
economic growth. Higher economic growth brings more opportunities for
innovation and investment leading to improvements in both energy and carbon
intensity. In a similar manner, low economic growth entails lower economic
activity but fewer investments in low carbon and energy efficient technologies.
There is thus only limited further emission reductions brought about by
considerably lower GDP levels. RES shares in gross final energy consumption are
pretty robust with respect to GDP levels with variation spanning just 1
percentage point in 2050. Import dependency is also unaffected by such
significant changes in GDP levels. Policy relevant indicators regarding competitiveness
are pretty much unaffected by economic growth; while ETS prices differ to some
extent, the effects on electricity prices are marginal. Energy prices Two energy price
sensitivities were modelled – a High energy price case with the world oil price
28% higher in 2050 and a Low energy price case with the world oil price 34%
below the Reference scenario in 2050. In the low price case, fossil fuel import
prices remain broadly at the 2010 level; coal prices are stable, oil has a
small peak around 2030, whereas gas prices remain weak over the next few years
but recover to the 2010 level in the long run.[43] High world
energy prices reduce CO2 and GHG emissions, while low prices exert the opposite
influence. However, there are several other effects via the fuel mix,
electricity generation, ETS price adaptations with a given cap and CCS
incentives that modify the overall effect. In total, differences in world
energy prices exert only a minor influence on total GHG emissions in the EU
given the existence of the EU ETS with a decreasing cap that is independent
from GDP or world energy price developments. High fossil fuel
prices limit business opportunities for energy exporters given that EU imports
would decrease, especially for natural gas. Conversely, with lower fossil fuel
prices, significantly higher gas deliveries to the EU can be assumed. Import
dependency increases with low world energy prices, whereas it stays below the Reference
scenario in the High price case. Electricity prices are significantly lower in the
Low price case, whereas they are significantly higher in the High energy price
case. High energy import prices increase the EU’s external fuel bill
substantially. On the contrary, lower fossil fuel prices give a boost to the EU
economy improving its competitiveness, also through lower costs and inflation.
2.4.5.
Conclusion
The Reference
scenario and CPI assume the overall GHG target, ETS cap and non-ETS national
targets to be achieved by 2020 but thereafter GHG reductions fall short of what
is required to mitigate climate change with a view to reaching the 2 °C objective.
Import dependency, in particular for gas, increases over the projection period
and electricity prices and energy costs are rising. So despite efforts over
recent years, the long term effects of our current and planned policies are not
sufficient to achieve the ambitious decarbonisation objective and to improve
both security of supply and competitiveness. These conclusions are broadly
consistent with other major stakeholder work such as the IEA World Energy
Outlook 2010 (Current Policies scenario), the European Climate Foundation
(baseline scenario); Power Choices (baseline scenario) and Greenpeace (baseline
scenario). A more thorough comparison of stakeholder work is provided in Annex 2.
2.5.
The EU's right to act and EU added-value
The EU's
competence in the area of energy is set out in the Treaty on the Functioning of
the European Union, in Article 194[44].
EU competences related to combating climate change, including GHG emission
reductions in energy and other sectors, are enshrined in Art. 191-193. The EU's
role needs to respect the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality. From an economic
perspective, as is the case with the European carbon market, many energy system
developments can best be achieved on an EU-wide basis, encompassing both EU and
Member State action while respecting their respective competences. An EU wide
European market can facilitate the balancing of the electricity system, reduce
the need for back-up capacities and encourage RES production where it
economically makes most sense. Large scale investments require big markets
which also justify one EU wide approach. A bigger market can also better
encourage the development of innovative products and systems mainly in the area
of energy efficiency and renewables.
2.6.
Who is affected?
Everybody is
affected. Energy consumers will be affected by higher energy costs (a combination
of energy prices and amount of energy used) as well as by extra non-energy
investment needed such as more efficient appliances, new types of vehicles,
house renovations, etc. The energy industry will be directly concerned as it
needs to heavily invest in the next two decades. Public authorities will also
need to engage in discussions about the pros, cons and trade-offs of different
options as each generation source has its drawbacks (solar and wind generation
will require significant infrastructure investments; supply of sustainable
biomass might be limited; nuclear faces public acceptance and waste problems
and CCS still requires large-scale experience to be able to reduce costs and
sufficiently decrease financial risks for private investors). Changes in the
EU energy sector will also have a strong influence on third countries, notably
fuel suppliers.
3.
Section 3: Objectives
3.1.
General objective
The general
objective is to shape a vision and strategy of how the EU energy system can be
decarbonised by 2050 while taking into account the security of supply and
competitiveness objectives.
3.2.
Specific objectives
To achieve the
general objective, more specific objectives are being proposed: –
Assist political decision making for providing
more certainty to investors as regards possible future policy orientations at
the EU level by showing different decarbonisation pathways to 2050 as well as
their main economic, social and environmental impacts; –
Show trade-offs among policy objectives as well
as among different decarbonisation pathways and identify common elements in all
decarbonisation pathways; –
Help policy makers set milestones after 2020. The Roadmap 2050
should be based on the current key objectives of EU energy policy –
sustainability, security of supply and competitiveness. Not all three
objectives can be specified and quantified in the same manner. While the decarbonisation
objective can be relatively easily defined and quantified, the other two are
more complex. The goal of sustainability is linked in particular to the achievement
of 80% domestic GHG reduction below 1990 in 2050, which implies a reduction of energy
related CO2 emissions by 85%, consistent with the required contribution of
developed countries as a group to limit global climate change to a temperature
increase of 2ºC compared to pre-industrial levels. The goal of security of
supply entails not only decreasing import dependency but also increasing supply
diversity and continued stability of electricity grid. The competitiveness
objective implies assuring a competitive energy sector, encouraging investments
and achieving affordable energy costs for consumers as well as developing new
technologies and ensuring a competitive clean technology manufacturing sector. In general the
objectives of energy policy are complementary and mutually reinforcing. For
example, increased energy efficiency reduces GHG emissions, increases energy
security and contributes towards achieving a competitive energy sector. A
significant part of low carbon energy supply can be produced in the EU, thus
also increasing energy security of supply. However, there are also some possible
trade-offs. Some of them are presented below for illustration: –
Renewables do not require fuels to be imported
and emit less or no GHG emissions, but may need public support (if necessary
and proportionate) to be competitive; this increases costs to consumers. The
merit order effect however reduces wholesale electricity prices. –
Although nuclear is a large provider of low
carbon electricity in the EU, it faces in some MS acceptance and financing
problems. –
CCS prevents CO2 emissions, but is comparatively
resource inefficient in relation to unabated fossil fuel combustion. Up to 25%
additional energy input may be needed for capture, transport and storage of
CO2. –
Gas is the fossil fuel with the lowest carbon
content but poses a challenge to security of supply especially for countries
with undiversified supplies. –
The current tariff-setting for transmission and
distribution networks is cost-based and should assure the lowest short term
prices to consumers but is not yet supportive enough to new technologies
enabling integration of RES and energy efficiency that have longer term
benefits.
3.3.
Consistency with other European policies
The Energy
Roadmap 2050 subscribes into the overall framework of decarbonisation as
designed by the flagship initiative Resource efficient Europe and the Roadmap
for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050. All objectives are
coherent with the objectives of the medium term strategy as described in the
Communication Europe 2020 and Energy 2020 as well as with energy policy objectives
as described in the Lisbon Treaty.
4.
Section 4: Policy options
4.1.
Methodology
This is not a typical
impact assessment in that it does not list policy options to meet certain
policy objectives and then assesses impacts of these policy options to determine
a preferable one. It rather examines a set of possible alternative future
developments to get more robust information on how the energy system could
achieve 85% reduction of energy related CO2 emissions compared to 1990 without
selecting one of them as the preferred option. Nor does it seek to justify the
decarbonisation target as this was the focus of the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap[45] . It is mainly concerned with analysing
possible energy related pathways to reach decarbonisation in a "global
climate action" world. Lower import fossil fuel prices are
introduced to reflect significant impacts on global fossil fuels prices in
policy scenarios while fossil fuel prices are higher in the Reference
scenario and CPI scenarios which project current trends and policies[46]. The Energy
Roadmap assumes the implementation of the European Council's decarbonisation
objective that includes similar efforts by industrialised countries as a group.
The analysis presented focuses on energy consequences. A more comprehensive
analysis of different global paths to decarbonisation was presented in the Low
Carbon Economy Roadmap 2050[47],
exploring the impacts of three global climate situations: a) business as usual;
b) global climate action and c) fragmented action. Fragmented action assumes
strong EU climate action that is however followed globally only by the low end
of the Copenhagen pledges up to 2020 and afterwards the ambition level of the
pledges is assumed to stay constant. It analyses impacts on energy intensive
industries (EII) both in a global macroeconomic modelling framework to address
carbon leakage issues and by means of energy system modelling to address the effects
of fragmented action, including electricity costs for companies. Electricity
costs are, in fact, higher in the fragmented action scenarios as compared to the
global action scenarios due to higher energy import prices. On the other hand,
carbon prices are lower under fragmented action. A
"fragmented" action scenario including measures against carbon leakage
was not analysed in this IA report as the challenges for the energy sector
arising from decarbonisation are the biggest under the "global climate
action" assumption, given that fragmented action with measures against
carbon leakage will deliver lower GHG reductions by 2050. Decarbonisation
scenarios that accommodate action against carbon leakage under fragmented
action could either go for lower ambitions in terms of GHG reduction for
sectors with relevant leakage risks or could have measures included that compensate
efforts for energy intensive industries. With action on carbon leakage the
challenge for the transition in the energy system could be smaller given lower
efforts in parts of the system. Such results are however modified through
countervailing effects from lower world fossil fuel prices under global action
that encourage somewhat higher energy consumption and emissions. In any case,
the implementation of measures will be crucial. The real difference for
industrial and thereby climate policy might come from the concrete design of
policy instruments that is not discussed in this the Energy Roadmap Impact
Assessment (e.g. special provisions on ETS for EII). Section 5
provides an assessment of the environmental, economic and social impacts that
is proportionate to the nature of the document proposed. The assessment is
supported by modelling results and/or by academic research where possible. It
is important to underline that modelling results are tentative and present
impacts as illustrations rather than as conclusive evidence. A 40-year outlook
is naturally steeped in uncertainty. Whereas some parameters such as population
growth can be projected with a reasonable degree of confidence, the projection
of other key factors such as economic growth, energy prices or technological
developments over such a long time span incorporates a great deal of
uncertainty. The modelling
framework used for decarbonisation scenarios is the same as for the Reference
scenario (see section 2.4 and annex 1). A quantitative methodology is the core
of this assessment. However, not all aspects could be modelled. For instance,
significant environmental impacts that go beyond GHG emissions, such as impacts
on biodiversity and air pollution, were not assessed quantitatively. For GDP
and employment impacts, analysis done for the Communication on moving beyond
20% GHG reductions[48]
and several recent studies were used. It was neither possible to assess impacts
on different household income levels, nor distributional impacts at Member State level. The methodology factors in uncertainties
but ensures for a coherent approach based on proven technologies, applying the
following limitations: –
Taking into account existing physical and
capital infrastructure and limitations regarding physical and capital stock
turn-over. –
Technological progress over time is assumed as
typical in long term modelling. Potential break-through technologies depending
on unforeseeable structural change have not been taken into account. Similarly,
major lifestyle changes, beyond demand side effects of carbon pricing on
behaviour, have not been taken into account in quantitative terms, as this goes
beyond the capabilities of the quantitative modelling tools. [49] –
The modelling also could not take into account
effects of the changing climate itself on the energy system. Effects can go in
different directions and will depend on how climate changes in different parts
of the EU (e.g. more demand for cooling, less demand for heating, impact on
water availability for power plant cooling or hydroelectricity production). Only by comparing results from different decarbonisation scenarios is
it possible to extract more robust conclusions, how key parameters influence
the results and how various parts interact with each other. By requiring
similar levels of cumulative GHG emissions across scenarios, this analysis
ensures comparability, as regards the objective of decarbonisation, given that
emission mitigation aims at preventing dangerous levels of atmospheric GHG
concentrations that is a matter of cumulative emissions. An identification of
common features to all scenarios will be an important part of the analysis. The
Commission's own scenario analysis will be complemented by MS and other
stakeholders' work. An in-depth impact assessment report examining impacts of
concrete policy measures will be submitted for any legislative proposal
following this roadmap.
4.2.
Policy options
Several useful
scenarios could be proposed for a decarbonisation analysis of the energy
system. The design of scenarios was extensively discussed with various
stakeholders. Stakeholders and the European Commission identified four main
decarbonisation routes for the energy sector – energy efficiency impacting
mostly on the demand side and RES, nuclear and CCS predominantly on the supply
side (lowering the carbon intensity of supply). This finding is in line with the
decarbonisation scenarios of a number of stakeholders, such as Eurelectric
Power Choices, the Energy Roadmap of the European Climate Foundation and the
work done at national level by some MS (such as the UK, DE and DK). The policy
options (scenarios) proposed explore five different combinations of the four
decarbonisation routes. Decarbonisation routes are never explored in isolation
as the interaction of different elements will necessarily be included in any
scenario that evaluates the entire energy system. All decarbonisation
scenarios achieve close to 85% energy related CO2 emissions by 2050 and it is
carefully assessed what effect each policy option has in terms of security of
supply, competitiveness of the energy sector and affordability of energy costs.
All scenarios use the same assumptions about GDP developments as the Reference
scenario. The scenarios achieving the European Council's GHG objective have
lower fossil fuel prices as a result of lower global demand for fossil fuels
reflecting worldwide carbon policies (oil price is 84 USD'08 per bbl in 2020;
79 in 2030 and 70 in 2050). In addition, most technology assumptions are the
same as in the Reference scenario, although there are additional features and
mechanisms to stimulate decarbonisation and technology penetration. For details
please see Annex 1, pages 56-60. Table 4: Policy options/Scenarios || Option/scenario || Short description 1 || Business as usual (Reference scenario[50]) || The Reference scenario includes current trends and long-term projections on economic development (GDP growth 1.7% pa). It takes into account rising fossil fuel prices and includes policies implemented by March 2010. The 2020 targets for GHG reductions and RES shares will be achieved but no further policies and targets after 2020 (besides the ETS directive) are modelled. See also section 2.4 Sensitivities: a) a case with higher GDP growth rates, b) a case with lower GDP growth rates, c) a case with higher energy import prices, d) a case with lower energy import prices. 1bis || Current Policy Initiatives – CPI scenario (updated Reference scenario) || The Reference scenario includes only adopted policies by March 2010. Since then, several new initiatives were adopted or are being proposed by the EC. The EC outlined its future work programme on energy mainly until 2020 in the Communication "Energy 2020 - A strategy for competitive, sustainable and secure energy". This policy option analyses the extent to which measures adopted and proposed will achieve the energy policy objectives.[51] It includes additional measures in the area of energy efficiency, infrastructure, internal market, nuclear, energy taxation and transport. Technology assumptions for nuclear were revised reflecting the impact of Fukushima and the latest information on the state of play of CCS projects and policies were included. See also section 2.4. || Decarbonisation scenarios || All decarbonisation scenarios build on Current Policy Initiatives (reflecting measures up to 2020) and are driven by carbon pricing to reach some 85% energy related CO2 reductions by 2050 (40% by 2030) which is consistent with the 80% reduction of GHG emissions. Transport measures (energy efficiency standards, low carbon fuels, infrastructure, pricing and transport planning) as reflected in the Transport White Paper are included in all scenarios. All scenarios will reflect significant development of electrical storage and interconnections (with the highest requirements in the High RES scenario). Different fuels can compete on a market basis besides constraints for nuclear investment in scenario 6. 2 || High Energy Efficiency || This scenario is driven by a political commitment of very high primary energy savings by 2050 and includes a very stringent implementation of the Energy Efficiency plan. It includes further and more stringent minimum requirements for appliances and new buildings; energy generation, transmission and distribution; high renovation rates for existing buildings; the establishment of energy savings obligations on energy utilities; the full roll-out of smart grids, smart metering and significant and highly decentralised RES generation to build on synergies with energy efficiency. 3 || Diversified supply technologies[52] || This scenario shows a decarbonisation pathway where all energy sources can compete on a market basis with no specific support measures for energy efficiency and renewables and assumes acceptance of nuclear and CCS as well as solution of the nuclear waste issue. It displays significant penetration of CCS and nuclear as they necessitate large scale investments and does not include additional targeted measures besides carbon prices. 4 || High RES || The High RES scenario aims at achieving a higher overall RES share and very high RES penetration in power generation, mainly relying on domestic supply[53]. 5 || Delayed CCS || This scenario follows a similar approach to the Diversified supply technologies scenario but assumes difficulties for CCS regarding storage sites and transport while having the same conditions for nuclear as scenario 3. It displays considerable penetration of nuclear. 6 || Low nuclear || This scenario follows a similar approach to the Diversified supply technologies scenario but assumes that public perception of nuclear safety remains low and that implementation of technical solutions to waste management remains unsolved leading to a lack of public acceptance. Same conditions for CCS as scenario 3. It displays considerable penetration of CCS. A more detailed presentation of assumptions
for all scenarios can be found in Annex 1.
5.
Section 5: Analysis of impacts
5.1.
Environmental impacts
Energy
consumption and use of renewable energy Primary
energy consumption is significantly lower in all
decarbonisation scenarios as compared to the Reference scenario. The biggest
decline of primary energy consumption comes in the High Energy Efficiency
scenario (-16% in 2030 and -38% in 2050) showing the effects of stringent
energy efficiency policies and smart grid deployment. The decrease in energy
consumption compared with the Reference scenario for all decarbonisation
scenarios spans a range from 11-16% in 2030 and 30-38% in 2050. Compared with
primary energy consumption in 2005 there is a very significant decrease of
32-41%. It is important to note that these levels of reduced primary energy
demand do not come from reduced GDP or sectoral production levels (which remain
the same in all scenarios). Instead they are mainly the result of technological
changes on the demand and supply side, coming from more efficient buildings,
appliances, heating systems and vehicles and from electrification in transport
and heating. All decarbonisation scenarios over-achieve the 20% energy saving
objective in the decade 2020-2030[54].
This result is consistent with other stakeholder work. Not only the
amount, but also the composition of energy mix would differ
significantly in a decarbonised energy system. Low carbon energy sources are
strongly encouraged but can follow various decarbonisation routes shown by
rather wide ranges for shares of energy sources in primary energy while all
satisfying the decarbonisation requirement by 2050. Moreover, all
decarbonisation routes achieve the same cumulative GHG emissions in 2011- 2050. Table 5: Fuel shares in primary energy
consumption Renewables increase their share in primary energy substantially in all
decarbonisation scenarios to reach at least 22% by 2030 and at least 41% by
2050. The RES share in primary energy is the highest in the High RES scenario
(60% in 2050). The RES share is higher when calculated in terms of gross final
energy consumption[55]-
it represents at least 28% (2030) and 55% (2050) in all decarbonisation
scenarios and rises up to 75% in 2050 in the High RES scenario. The share of
renewables in power generation stands at 86% in 2050 in the High RES scenario
and the share in power consumption is even higher at 97% in 2050.[56] RES share in power generation
can be further increased by allowing for imports of renewable electricity from North Africa. Nuclear developments have been affected by the policy reaction in some Member
States after the nuclear accident in Fukushima. The share of nuclear varies
depending on policy assumptions. In the Low nuclear scenario the nuclear share
declines gradually to 3% by 2050. In the most ambitious nuclear scenario
(Delayed CCS scenario), the share rises to 18%. The share of gas
is higher in the Current Policy Initiatives scenario compared to the Reference scenario,
partly replacing nuclear. It increases slightly by 2050 in the Low nuclear
scenario where the CCS share in power generation is around 32%. The oil
share declines only slightly until 2030 due to the high dependency of transport
on oil. However, the decline is significant in the last decade (2040-2050) when
oil in transport is to a large extent replaced by biofuels and electricity. The
share of solid fuels shrinks further to reach only 2-6% in all
decarbonisation scenarios except in the Low nuclear scenario (10% in 2050). Final energy
demand declines similarly to primary energy demand.
In the High Energy Efficiency scenario the reduction compared to the Reference
scenario is -14% in 2030 and -40% in 2050. The decrease in the decarbonisation
scenarios is at least -8% in 2030 and -34% in 2050. Sectors showing higher
reductions than the average are residential, tertiary and generally also transport.
There is a lot of structural change in the fuel composition of final energy
demand. Given that it is highly efficient and emission free at use, electricity
makes major inroads already under Current Policy Initiatives (increase by 9 pp
in 2005-2050). The electricity share soars further in the decarbonisation
scenarios reaching 36% - 39% in 2050 (almost doubling from current levels and
becoming the most import final energy source), reflecting also its important
role in decarbonising heating and transport. The crucial issue for any
decarbonisation strategy is therefore the full decarbonisation of power generation. Energy
intensity reduces by at least 67% in the Delayed
CCS scenario (2005-2050). It reduces by 70% in the High RES and Low nuclear
scenarios and by 71% in the Energy Efficiency scenario in 2005-2050 (against a
53% improvement in the Reference scenario). Emissions All
decarbonisation scenarios achieve 80% GHG reduction and close to 85% energy
related CO2 reductions in 2050 compared to 1990 as well as equal cumulative
emissions over the projection period. In 2030, energy-related CO2 emissions are
between 38-41% lower, and total GHG emissions reductions are lower by 40-42%. Impacts on
biodiversity, air pollution and other environmental impacts The ranking of
the different policy options as regards impacts on biodiversity, air pollution,
water use and other environmental impacts depends on the implementation of
different energy mixes. Some overall trends are presented below while some
impacts are analysed in the Resource Efficiency Roadmap 2050 but with much less
focus on energy. In most scenarios,
air pollution can be expected to decrease significantly, as this often
goes hand in hand with GHG emissions. However, in some cases (especially if the
energy mix leads to the development of small unregulated biomass plants),
particulate matter (PM) and gaseous emissions could rise, causing local air
pollution and regional acidification issues, although the overall effects can
be expected to remain positive[57].
All options will
impact land use and consequently biodiversity and other land-related
ecosystem services. Indeed, any new infrastructure, be it in terms of grid
development, power plant installations (nuclear, CCS, fossil), renewable
infrastructure (sitting of wind mills, hydropower dams) will lead to land use
changes and fragmentation, with potential negative impacts on biodiversity and
on the services we receive from ecosystems. However, if the infrastructure
development follows well established environmental rules, these potentially
negative consequences can be limited[58].
Therefore, the pathways as such do not necessarily lead to land use and
biodiversity problems, as this will depend on implementation. Consequences of
mostly domestic RES are presented in terms of needs for domestic biomass[59] giving details for each
scenario on the total use of biomass and biofuels in transport). The maximum
amount of biofuels in 2050 would reach 300 Mtoe for use within the EU and 20
Mtoe for bunkers. The other decarbonisation scenarios have around 270 Mtoe
including bunkers.[60]
Still, there are also impacts of CO2 emissions related to land use, land use
change and forestry due to increased bioenergy use.[61] As the biomass needed for
energy will not only come from forests/forest-based industries, biowaste and
residues, this will require considerable additional amounts of agricultural
land. In terms of water
use, the consequences will depend on the energy mix. New hydropower
projects (including pumped storage), the cultivation of some energy crops, and
increased demand for water for cooling in the nuclear energy sector might
exacerbate existing water shortages, increasing potential impacts on river
morphology and groundwater availability, all this in a context of increasing EU
temperatures and reduced water availability.
5.2.
Economic impacts
Economic
growth The current report
is part of a joint Commission analysis related to the transition to a
low-carbon economy by 2050. Previous assessment by the Commission shows that
the costs by 2020 of putting the EU economy on a path that meets the long-term
requirements for limiting climate change to 2°C would be limited compared to
business-as usual, at around 0.2%-0.5% of GDP[62],
with access to international carbon credits. Using the additional revenues from
auctioning CO2 emissions allowances in EU ETS sectors and tax revenues from the
non-ETS sectors to decrease labour costs would improve overall macroeconomic
results leading to 0.4%-0.6% increase in GDP by 2020. As regards the
differentiated impact of policy options on economic growth, the long-term
perspective implies that it is very difficult to go beyond a qualitative
assessment. The Reference and CPI scenarios have higher fuel costs which do not
generate much economic growth but require fewer investments in new
technologies. On the contrary, the decarbonisation scenarios entail much higher
investment in equipment and energy efficiency while lowering expenditure on
fuels. These investments can generate further GDP growth and technologies may
be exported worldwide if the EU keeps its front-runner position. Thus, policy
scenarios which drive forward energy efficiency measures and investments in
renewable energy technology have the potential to generate new industries, jobs
and substantial economic growth. Although it is difficult to assess in details,
such investments could also protect the EU economy against external energy
price shocks[63].
An assessment of
the macro-economic impact of the European decarbonisation objectives towards
2050 was performed in the European Climate Foundation's 2050 Roadmap[64]. It shows an annual GDP growth
of 0.1% below the baseline scenario until 2015 but a reversal of the trend
afterwards resulting in GDP being 2% above the baseline in 2050. Marginally
positive effects remain under different sensitivity cases. Energy system
costs The total
energy system costs are costs for the entire energy system including
capital cost, (for energy using equipment, appliances
and vehicles), fuel and electricity costs, and direct efficiency investment costs
(house insulation, control systems, energy management, etc) [65].
They exclude disutility costs[66]
and auction payments[67].
Table 6: Average
annual total energy system cost (without auctioning and disutility) Average annual total energy system costs 2011-2050 || || || Bln. EUR'08 || Ref || CPI || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Capital cost || 955 || 995 || 1115 || 1100 || 1089 || 1094 || 1104 Energy purchases || 1622 || 1611 || 1220 || 1295 || 1355 || 1297 || 1311 Direct efficiency inv. costs || 28 || 36 || 295 || 160 || 164 || 161 || 161 Total cost for final consumers excl. all auction payments and disutility || 2582 || 2619 || 2615 || 2535 || 2590 || 2525 || 2552 Absolute Difference to Reference || || || || || || Bln. EUR'08 || || || High Energy effic. || Div. supply techn. || High RES || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Δ Capital cost || || || 160 || 145 || 134 || 139 || 149 Δ Energy purchases || || || -402 || -327 || -267 || -325 || -312 Δ Direct efficiency inv. costs || || || 267 || 132 || 135 || 133 || 133 Δ Total cost for final consumers excl. all auction payments and disutility || 33 || -47 || 8 || -57 || -29 Depending on the
decarbonisation scenario, there are no or little additional average annual
energy system costs due to the pursuit of major decarbonisation as part of a
global effort compared with the Reference and CPI scenarios. Diversified supply
technologies and Delayed CCS scenarios have the lowest level of average annual
energy system costs, representing even a cost saving of around 90 bn €(08)
compared with CPI (around 50bn € compared to the Reference scenario) mainly due
to large fossil fuel import savings. Those two scenarios have the highest
nuclear share[68].
The modelling
results suggest that the highest total energy system costs will occur in the
High Energy Efficiency scenario. Unlike the majority of other scenarios, the
modelling of the High Energy Efficiency scenario does not rely entirely on
economic optimisation in determining the level of energy consumption, but
rather projects the impact of a set of energy efficiency measures (building
retrofit etc.). In addition, the scenario pushes the limits of what the chosen
measures can achieve (by assuming that the whole European building stock is
fully refurbished; by making use of distributed renewable energy solutions as
one of the more expensive renewable energy solutions; by amortising long-lived
measures over a short time). Furthermore, it has to be taken into account that
all policy scenarios already include considerable energy efficiency
improvements and the cost difference merely indicates an increasing marginal
cost for moving from a high to a very high level of energy efficiency (see
Annex 1, part B for details). Finally, the modelling reflects significant
transaction costs for energy efficiency investments in the form of relatively
high weighted average costs of capital. Cumulative
auction payments are lowest in the High Energy Efficiency scenario due to the
reduced energy consumption, decreasing emissions and therefore the necessity to
buy ETS permits. The scenario with the highest auction revenues is Delayed CCS
where the delay in the use of CCS leads to high carbon prices to ensure the
achievement of the decarbonisation target in later years, which is made more
challenging by the fact that CCS has not been able to move down the cost curve
earlier. The auction revenues represent an equivalent of around 1% of total
cumulative energy system costs. All scenarios
show higher annual costs in the last two decades 2031-2050 reflecting mainly
increased investments in transport equipment as the major transition to
electric and plug in hybrids vehicles is projected after 2030. In the High RES
scenario costs are also linked to significant expansion of RES based power
generation capacity. The ratio of energy
system costs to GDP is similar across the scenarios: ranging from around
14.1% to 14.6%, the costs of the Diversified supply technologies and delayed
CCS scenarios being at the lower end of the range. Table 7: Cumulative system costs related
to GDP 2011-2050 || Cumulative system costs related to GDP Reference || 14.37% CPI || 14.58% High Energy Efficiency || 14.56% Diversified supply technologies || 14.11% High RES || 14.42% Delayed CCS || 14.06% Low nuclear || 14.21% The external
fuel bill arising from the net imports of fossil fuels decreases below 2005
levels in all decarbonisation scenarios by 2050. This result stems from the
pursuit of major decarbonisation as part of a global climate effort with fossil
fuel import prices expected to be much lower. The actual imports of fossil fuel
due to energy efficiency and penetration of RES will be much lower too. These combined
effects reduce the expenditure for each fossil fuel and thereby the total
external fuel bill of the EU. The decrease of the fuel bill from 2005 in the
decarbonisation scenarios is smallest in the Low nuclear scenario at 31% and
highest in the High RES scenario at 43% with RES replacing most fossil fuels.
Compared with the current level, all decarbonisation scenarios increase their
fuel bill in 2030, but to much lower levels than the Reference and CPI
scenarios. Savings in the external fuel bill are most striking in 2050.
Compared with the CPI scenario, the EU economy could save in 2050 between 518
and 550 bn € (08) by taking this strong decarbonisation route under global
climate action. Impacts on
competitiveness Average prices
of electricity are rising compared to 2005 in all scenarios including Reference
and CPI scenarios (by a range of 41% in the High Energy Efficiency scenario to
54% in the Low nuclear scenario in 2030 and by 34% in the Diversified supply
technologies to 82% in the High RES scenarios in 2050). Electricity prices are
calculated in such a way that total costs of power generation, balancing,
transmission and distribution are recovered, ensuring that investments can be
financed. The residential sector has the highest user price and industry the
lowest as is currently the case. Decarbonisation scenarios have lower fuel
costs but tend to have higher capital investment costs that offer more business
opportunities for domestic investments instead of fuel imports. Due to depressed demand for electricity, the High Energy Efficiency
scenario shows the lowest prices in 2030 for all sectors – even slightly lower
than in the Reference scenario (which however exhibits a significant price
increase from today's level). In 2050, electricity prices are lowest in the
Diversified supply technologies scenario for all sectors, except industry,
which faces slightly higher prices compared with the Reference and Current
Policy Initiatives. In 2050, average electricity costs are highest in the High
RES scenario while the Low nuclear scenario has the highest prices in 2030. In this
exercise, potential macroeconomic benefits from the development of "green
technology" manufacturing and services sectors have not been quantified
for the various policy scenarios. Energy
related costs for companies Electricity
prices for industry are the lowest among all sectors. The lowest increase
occurs in the Diversified supply and Delayed CCS scenarios and the highest
increase, similarly to average prices developments, in the High RES scenario.
As the whole analysis is performed under the hypothesis of "global climate
action", the whole world would decarbonise and would have to bear carbon
prices, so the question of industrial competitiveness would not arise. More
information on electricity costs is provided in Annex 1 (part B, point 2.7).
If no global climate deal is reached and the EU is reducing emissions
significantly more than other countries, certain industries supplying low
carbon technologies will benefit from improved competitiveness due to higher
internal demand and first mover advantage. However, for energy intensive
industries it would be difficult to realise the prescribed GHG reductions
without affecting their international competitiveness through higher carbon,
fuel and electricity prices. This might be even more pronounced if reductions
need to be achieved with CCS, which is a technology that has no other benefits
than reducing GHG emissions. Energy related
costs in relation to sectoral value added rise from 5.8% in 2005 to 7.8% in
2030 in the Reference/CPI cases and to around 7.5% in the decarbonisation
scenarios. In 2050, under current policies, this indicator declines to 7.5% and
even more so in the decarbonisation scenarios falling to less than 7%. Energy intensive
industries face particularly high energy costs for their highly energy
consuming production processes. Energy related costs in relation to sectoral
value added for five industrial sectors (iron and steel, non-ferrous metals,
non metallic mineral products, chemicals, paper and pulp industries) would rise
under current trends, but would be markedly lower under global decarbonisation.
Following lower world energy prices and due to energy efficiency improvements,
the ratio of energy costs to value added would return to the 2005 level by 2050
in most decarbonisation scenarios, except for the Energy Efficiency scenario,
which exhibits an even lower ratio. ETS carbon prices The ETS allowance
price rises moderately from the current level until 2030 and significantly in
the last two decades providing support to all low carbon technologies and
energy efficiency. After 2020, the same carbon value applies also to non- ETS
sectors assuring cost-efficient emissions abatement in the whole economy post
2020. Concrete policy measures such as those pushing energy efficiency and/or
those enabling penetration of renewables depress demand for ETS allowances
which subsequently lead to lower carbon prices. Carbon prices are the lowest in
the High Energy Efficiency scenario with lowest energy demand followed by the High
RES scenario (in 2030 and 2040) and Diversified supply technologies[69] (in 2050). Delay in
penetration of technologies (CCS) or unavailability of one decarbonisation
option (nuclear) put an upwards pressure on demand for allowances and ETS
prices. Table 8: ETS prices in €'08/t CO2 || 2020 || 2030 || 2040 || 2050 Reference || 18 || 40 || 52 || 50 CPI || 15 || 32 || 49 || 51 High Energy Efficiency || 15 || 25 || 87 || 234 Diversified supply technologies || 25 || 52 || 95 || 265 High RES || 25 || 35 || 92 || 285 Delayed CCS || 25 || 55 || 190 || 270 Low nuclear || 20 || 63 || 100 || 310 Impacts on
infrastructure Infrastructure[70] requirements differ between
scenarios. Decarbonisation scenarios require increasingly more sophisticated
infrastructures (mainly electricity lines, smart grids and storage) than
Reference and CPI scenarios. The High RES scenario necessitates additional DC
lines mainly to transport wind electricity from the North Sea to the centre of Europe and more storage. Table 9: Grid investment costs
(investments in transmission grid including interconnectors and investments in
distribution grid including smart components). (Bln Euro '05) || 2011-2020 || 2021-2030 || 2031-2050 || 2011-2050 Reference || 292 || 316 || 662 || 1269 CPI || 293 || 291 || 774 || 1357 High Energy Efficiency || 305 || 352 || 861 || 1518 Diversified supply technologies || 337 || 416 || 959 || 1712 High RES || 336 || 536 || 1323 || 2195 Delayed CCS || 336 || 420 || 961 || 1717 Low nuclear || 339 || 425 || 1029 || 1793 The model
assumes that grid investments, that are prerequisites to the decarbonisation
scenarios in this analysis, are undertaken and that costs are fully recovered
in electricity prices. Reality might differ in the sense that the current
regulatory regime might be more short to medium term cost minimisation oriented
and might not provide sufficient incentives for long-term and innovative
investments. There might also be less perfect foresight and lower coordination
of investments in generation, transmission and distribution as the model
assumes. Impacts on
internal market and competition Electricity
markets might change substantially with an increasing share of generation with
close to zero marginal costs. A competitive market would in this situation lead
to almost zero prices which would be insufficient to pay for upfront capital
investments[71].
A different market design might be needed. While a specific regime for RES
(e.g. feed-in tariffs) may be justified in certain situations (e.g. for new RES
which are not yet competitive), every effort is needed to ensure that RES is
integrated into the energy market, through support, regulatory and
infrastructure policies. This is even more the case when RES becomes a
significant share of overall energy production (especially in the high RES
scenario). Innovation
and R&D A goal of the
Europe 2020 strategy[72]
(underpinned by the Communication on the Innovation Union[73]) is to increase innovation in Europe and focus R&D and innovation policies on tackling major societal challenges such
as climate change. The EU27 is already a world leader in some segments of
low-carbon and energy efficient technologies (nuclear power plants, wind
turbines, some energy efficient appliances, etc). All policy scenarios involve
significant improvement in efficiency and cost parameters of new technologies
as compared to the Reference scenario due to more economies of scale and faster
learning rates. The deployment of CCS and some RES in the decarbonisation
scenarios, for instance, implies a rate of capacity growth and innovation that
is at least as great as that seen for energy technologies in the 20th century[74]. As a consequence all policy
options are expected to further boost research and innovation, thereby also
improving competitiveness. However, the magnitude of innovation between
different policy options might differ. Moreover, impacts expected on
innovations can hardly be grasped by current models. Impacts on third
countries Impacts on third
countries, mainly oil and gas importing countries would be significant. Imports
in decarbonisation scenarios decrease sharply (besides gas imports in the Low
nuclear scenario). In addition, global decarbonisation efforts lead to lower
fossil fuel prices. So, under these particular circumstances the export
revenues from European customers are 31 to 43% lower in 2050 than in 2005. In
the mid-term, in 2030 all decarbonisation scenarios have a higher fuel bill
compared to 2005 by at least 35%, but to much lower levels than the Reference
and Current Policy Initiative scenarios[75].
(See also section on Energy system costs). There is no
major impact on electricity trade, which remains marginal with third countries.
The increased global use of biomass for energy purposes might have impacts on
food prices and input costs of other biomass-using industries. Impacts on prices for biomass and land
prices Bioenergy is
expected to be an important part of any low-carbon energy strategy. This might
have impacts on prices for biomass from agriculture and forest-based industries
either directly through increased demand for energy use, or through
increased demand for land and thus higher land prices. As most of the biomass
used for energy has competing uses (food and feed, renewable raw materials),
food prices and input costs of other biomass-using industries are likely to
increase.
5.3.
Social impacts
Impacts on
employment The social
dimension of decarbonisation is crucial as transition to a low carbon economy
will require an in depth change in several sectors, affecting companies,
employment and working conditions. Education and training need to be addressed
at an early stage in order to avoid unemployment in some sectors and labour
shortages in others. More knowledge should be gathered about the social
implications of deep and long-term decarbonisation as no studies are available
yet. Consultations, also in the context of the social dialogue, could improve
the follow-up work on the decarbonisation roadmaps[76], including decarbonisation of
the energy sector. Employment
effects of decarbonisation policies up to 2020 are generally ambiguous and
difficult to assess. A direct positive effect of relative growth in the
"green" technology sector is that some subsectors like energy
efficiency in buildings are usually assumed to have a relatively high labour
intensity. Indirect positive effects for employment may include increased
innovation resulting from stricter environmental policy, increased export
potential for green technologies, as well as less fossil fuel imports. Negative
effects may include transition costs, such as inflexibilities in the labour
market to respond to changes in skill demand. There is uncertainty as to
whether positive or negative effects would dominate. However, most
studies that evaluate the net employment effects of the EU's 20-20-20 targets record
impacts of typically ±1%[77].
A recent extensive macroeconomic study suggests that net employment effects for
meeting the EU's targets for 2020 will be small and positive, leading to an
average increase in employment demand of up to 0.3%[78]. The two scenarios with the most
ambitious targets (30% GHG emission reductions by 2020, achieving the 20%
energy efficiency target) have the highest net effects on employment.
Similarly, a 2009 study[79]
finds modestly positive net employment effects of up to 0.1% for supporting
policies to meet the 2020 RES targets. An assessment of net employment effects
of the European decarbonisation objectives towards 2050 was performed in the European
Climate Foundation's 2050 Roadmap[80].
It expects net employment to initially be marginally negative and turn positive
at a later stage: employment in the decarbonisation scenario is 0.06% below the
baseline by 2020 and 1.5% higher than the baseline in 2050. An estimate of net
employment effects until 2030 and some quantitative examples of job creation in
certain sectors are provided in the IA report on Low Carbon Economy Roadmap[81].The net impact on jobs can be
an increase by 0.7% compared to the Reference scenario, corresponding to 1.5
million jobs by 2020. The overall
effects of the increased investment in green technologies on the labour market
are thus expected to be fairly modest relative to the effects of other
developments such as globalisation, technical progress and demographic change.
On a sectoral level, a small increase in jobs in the engineering and
construction sectors and a decrease in the energy supplying sectors might
arise. The effects on the energy-intensive sectors are ambiguous. Higher energy
prices may lead to losses in competitiveness on the one hand while there would
also be increased demand for goods from the sector (such as steel and concrete)
on the other. However, by focussing on sectoral gains and losses, potentially
significant impacts at a more micro level may not be captured in these studies.
Also, regional differences may be significant. As the whole
analysis was done in a global climate effort context, there are no job losses
due to carbon leakage. However the decision by companies to relocate production
away from the EU may be related to other factors such as access to markets or
raw materials or secure access to energy sources with long-term price
guarantees. Quality of
jobs The more
investments are made in new technologies – many of which are likely to be
energy saving or related to new forms of energy generation – the more demand
there will be for people in higher skilled jobs (especially professional and
associate professional ones). In this way, the greening of the economy can
stimulate the demand for highly skilled (and high waged) workers, although the
extent to which this will occur even under the most optimistic of scenarios is
relatively modest when compared to the business as usual scenario. Affordability Affordability of energy services as regards costs for fuel
and electricity as well as for equipment, appliances, insulation and transport
services is one of the essential elements of the analysis. The sector most
concerned is households. All decarbonisation scenarios show significant fuel
savings compared to the Reference and CPI scenarios but also higher costs for
energy appliances and insulation. Energy related expenditures of households for heating,
cooling, lighting, cooking, appliances i.e. excluding transport services, almost
double from around 2000 EUR'08 today to 3800-3900 EUR'08 in 2050 in the
Reference and CPI scenarios reflecting rising fuel and electricity prices and
increasing direct household investments in energy efficiency. Expenditures per
household amount to around 4500 EUR'08 in most decarbonisation scenarios in
2050, with expenditure per household reaching some 4800 €(08) and almost 4900
€(08) in the Energy Efficiency and High RES scenarios respectively. It is
important to note that per capita income in 2050 will also almost double from
today's level, but also that households will be composed of fewer members reflecting
aging and changing lifestyles. Energy costs for stationary uses per household
exceed the Reference/CPI case level by 16-17% in 2050 in most decarbonisation
scenarios. They are 25-27% higher in the Energy Efficiency and High RES
scenarios, as these scenarios are particularly investment intensive. However, energy
expenditures including expenses for transport services as a percentage of
household expenditure show a different picture. They rise over time in all
scenarios from 10% in 2005 to around 16% in 2030, stabilising thereafter to
around 15-16% by 2050. Among the decarbonisation scenarios, the costs of the
Delayed CCS and the Diversified Supply Technology scenarios, similar to the
Reference and CPI scenarios, are at the lower end of this range, whereas the
High RES and Energy efficiency scenarios show 2050 costs at the upper end. To
the extent that vulnerable consumers would incur similar expenditure increases,
in particular the necessary upfront investment to realise later savings may
pose an affordability challenge for them. Security of
supply Import
dependency, one of the indicators of security of supply, does not change
substantially in 2030 in decarbonisation scenarios compared to the Reference
scenario and Current Policy Initiatives scenario due to declining gross inland
consumption and imports. There is however a substantial decrease in 2050,
driven by increased use of domestic resources, mainly renewables. Import
dependency is only 35% in the High RES scenario[82] (compared to 58% in the
Reference and CPI scenarios) and 39-40% in the other decarbonisation scenarios
besides the Low nuclear scenario (45% due to significant use of fossil fuels
with CCS). Decarbonisation will significantly reduce fossil fuel security
risks. Large scale
electrification combined with more decentralised power generation from variable
sources brings other challenges to high quality energy service at any time.
However, there are no standardised indicators for the time being. Moreover,
adequate stability of the grid is a precondition for modelling, which is why
differences in indicators on the stability of the grid are rather small across
scenarios[83].
Safety and
public acceptance Safety concerns might be raised against some power
generation technologies as well as against infrastructure and exploration of
energy fuels. The public in general perceives technological risks as more
important than expert judgement would suggest. Across Europe, public acceptance
of different generation technologies and infrastructures differs, but none of
them is 100% accepted by local communities where they are (going to be)
located. A better and more targeted communication with the concerned public and
stakeholders might be needed in the future to assure the EU's energy needs. Table 10: Selected results of scenario
analysis || 2005 || Current trends || Decarbonisation scenarios Reference scenario || Current Policy Initiatives || High Energy Efficiency || Diversified Supply Techno-logies || High Renewables || Delayed CCS || Low nuclear Primary energy demand reduction (in % from 2005)[84] || 2030 || || -5.3 || -10.8 || -20.5 || -16 || -17.3 || -16.1 || -18.5 2050 || || -3.5 || -11.6 || -40.6 || -33.3 || -37.9 || -32.2 || -37.7 Electrification || 2030 2050 || 20.2 - || 25.1 29.1 || 24.5 29.4 || 25.2 37.3 || 26.0 38.7 || 25.4 36.1 || 26.0 38.7 || 25.7 38.5 Fuels (in %) || || || || || || || || || Renewables in gross final energy || 2030 || 8,6 || 23.9 || 24.7 || 27.6 || 27.7 || 31.2 || 28 || 28.8 2050 || - || 25.5 || 29 || 57.3 || 54.6 || 75.2 || 55.7 || 57.5 CCS in power generation || 2030 || 0 || 2.9 || 0.8 || 0.7 || 0.8 || 0.6 || 0.7 || 2.1 2050 || - || 17.8 || 7.6 || 20.5 || 24.2 || 6.9 || 19 || 31.9 Nuclear energy in primary energy || 2030 || 14,1 || 14.3 || 12.1 || 11.1 || 13.9 || 9.7 || 13.2 || 8.4 2050 || - || 16.7 || 13.5 || 13.5 || 15.3 || 3.8 || 17.5 || 2.6 Fuels in electricity generation (in%) RES CCS NUC || 2030 2050 2030 2050 2030 2050 || 14.3 - 0.0 - 30.5 - || 40.5 40.3 2.9 17.8 24.5 26.4 || 43.7 48.8 0.8 7.6 20.7 20.6 || 52.9 64.2 0.7 20.5 18.6 14.2 || 51.2 59.1 0.8 24.2 21.2 16.1 || 59.8 86.4 0.6 6.9 15.8 3.6 || 51.7 60.7 0.7 19.0 21.5 19.2 || 54.6 64.8 2.1 31.9 13.4 2.5 Average electricity prices (in EUR'08 per MWh, after tax)[85] || 2030 || 109,3 || 154,8 || 156,0 || 154,4 || 159,6 || 164,4 || 160,4 || 168,2 2050 || - || 151,1 || 156,9 || 146,7 || 146,2 || 198,9 || 151,9 || 157,2 Annual energy system costs related to GDP (in % 2011 – 2050) || || - || 14.37 || 14.58 || 14.56 || 14.11 || 14.42 || 14.06 || 14.21 Import dependency (in %) || 2030 || 52,5 || 56.4 || 57.5 || 56.1 || 55.2 || 55.3 || 54.9 || 57.5 2050 || - || 57.6 || 58.0 || 39.7 || 39.7 || 35.1 || 38.8 || 45.1 Source: PRIMES modelling Table 11: Summary of impacts || 1 Reference scenario || 1bis Current Policy Initiatives || 2 High Energy Efficiency || 3 Diversified supply technologies || 4 High RES || 5 Delayed CCS || 6 Low nuclear Environmental impacts Energy consumption/Energy intensity || || || + + + || + || + + || + || + + RES share || || + || + + || + + || + + + || + + || + + Energy related CO2 emissions || = || + + + || + + + || + + + || + + + || + + + Economic impacts Economic growth || || = || = || = || = || = || = Competitiveness || || = || + || + || + || + || + Energy security (import dependency and imports from third countries) || || = || + + || + + || + + + || + + || + Social impacts Employment || || = || + + || + || + + || + || + Quality of jobs || || = || + + || + + || + + || + + || + + Affordability || || = || - || = || - || = || = Legend: = equivalent to
Reference scenario + to +++
improvement compared to Reference scenario - to - - -
worsening compared to Reference scenario
5.5 Sensitivity analysis
It is clear that
the robustness of modelling results is affected by the assumptions underlying
the modelling scenarios. As outlined in section 2.4, sensitivity analysis has
been carried out for the Reference scenario by varying two key parameters – GDP
and energy import prices. The conclusions on GDP analysis are quite robust
showing that key policy indicators do not vary significantly with GDP given
feedback mechanisms and the architecture of EU energy and climate policies
(ETS). Following this pattern, a similar outcome might be expected for policy
scenarios even though it has not been demonstrated by current analysis. This
holds also for variations in energy import prices, although the results are
somewhat less stable regarding certain indicators, such as import dependency.
Impacts of additional variations in import price assumptions in decarbonisation
scenarios (very high oil price and oil shock scenarios) were analysed in the
Low Carbon Economy Roadmap. Constant climate
conditions were assumed over time. This simplification may be justified given
that all decarbonisation scenarios assume that the climate targets are met.
However, even when temperature changes are limited to 2 degree Celsius, some
climate impacts will occur.[86]
In addition, changes in temperature will lead to changes in energy demand
patterns for heating and cooling. It can hence be expected that decarbonisation
leads to further positive economic impacts with regard to energy security and
competitiveness by avoiding parts of the expected damage and adaptation costs
in the energy system due to climate change impacts. Other
assumptions are embedded in the design of policy scenarios. Policy scenarios
assume different costs and timing of technology (delay of CCS, faster
penetration of RES) and can therefore be interpreted as sensitivity analysis on
R&D and learning curves for main technologies. Changes in other sectors
such as a higher uptake of electricity in transport, were implicitly studied in
this report by assuming that the main thrust of the policies included in the
2011 White Paper on Transport is also pursued in these decarbonisation
scenarios. No additional transport related policies were examined.
6.
Section 6: Comparing the options
This section
provides an assessment of how the policy options will contribute to the realisation
of the policy objectives, as set in Section 3, in light of the following
evaluation criteria: –
effectiveness –
the extent to which options achieve the objectives of EU energy policy[87]; –
efficiency – the
extent to which objectives can be achieved at least cost; –
coherence – the
extent to which policy options are likely to limit trade-offs across the
economic, social, and environmental domains. Effectiveness As regards
effectiveness, the three objectives of energy policy – sustainability, security
of supply and competitiveness - were taken into account. All policy scenarios
were designed to reach 85% reduction of energy related CO2 emissions in 2050,
so all are effective in that sense. It should be noted that some scenarios are
highly dependent on success of new technologies that are still under
demonstration or only partly proven commercially (CCS, off-shore wind, 3rd
generation nuclear etc). For the other two objectives the question of most
suitable indicators arises. As regards security of supply, all policy scenarios
improve import dependency, the best being the High RES scenario with 35% import
dependency in 2050 and the least effective the Low nuclear scenario with 45% in
2050 (as compared to 58% in the Reference scenario). However, in a more
electrified world, stability of the grid might be of much higher concern with
major challenges ahead that can be met as demonstrated by the modelling of the
scenarios. As regards competitiveness, some scenarios show a small decrease in
electricity prices as compared to the Reference and CPI scenarios (High Energy
Efficiency, Diversified supply technologies) while some others show increases
(High RES and to a lesser extent Low nuclear). ETS prices are significantly
higher than in the Reference and CPI scenarios with the highest values in Delayed
CCS scenario and lowest in High Energy Efficiency scenarios where
decarbonisation is triggered also by specialised measures. The model triggers
adequate investments which are driven by specific policies or carbon prices and
investment decisions are based on perfect foresight assumption. All
decarbonisation scenarios foster innovation and R&D. Efficiency In terms of
efficiency, the analysis demonstrates that the costs of decarbonisation of the
energy system are not substantially higher compared to the Reference scenario
and most decarbonisation scenarios even show a lower annual average cost than the
CPI scenario. The least costly scenarios are Delayed CCS and Diversified Supply
Technologies scenarios with significant penetration of nuclear. Coherence All policy
scenarios are coherent with other EU long term objectives (on climate, transport,
etc). There is no clear winner among policy options scoring the best in all
criteria and several trade-offs will need to be taken into account. The role of
this analysis is not to select one preferred pathway but rather to identify the
pros and cons of different options and identify common elements from all of
them. Table 12: Comparison of policy scenarios
to the Reference scenario || 1bis. Current Policy Initiatives || 2. High Energy Efficiency || 3. Diversified supply technologies || 4. High RES || 5. Delayed CCS || 6. Low nuclear Effectiveness Sustainability || = || + + + || + + + || + + + || + + + || + + + Security of supply || = || + + || + + || + + + || + + || + Competitiveness || = || + || + || + || + || + Efficiency Additional annual average total costs relative to Reference scenario in bn EUR'08 || 37 || 33 || -47 || 8 || -57 || -29 Additional annual average total costs as % of GDP || 0.21% || 0. 19% || -0.26% || 0.05% || -0.31% || -0.16% Coherence Trade-offs between economic, social and environmental impacts || || Scenario reducing the most energy consumption and significantly improving import dependency but rather costly for households and difficult to implement when it comes to behavioural changes || Scenario with lowest cost from the economic actors' point of view, significant energy efficiency gains and renewables shares but depending on success (technological progress of CCS and some RES as well as public acceptance of nuclear and CCS) || Scenario showing the highest penetration of RES; highest decrease in import dependency and second strongest reduction of energy consumption pushing innovation in new technologies, but rather costly and leading to highest electricity prices || Scenario with lowest costs scoring well on security of supply, RES penetration and competitiveness but the least effective in terms of energy efficiency; rather strong reliance on nuclear being contingent on absence of further public acceptance problems || Scenario scoring well on costs, RES shares and energy efficiency but still with high consumption of fossil fuels and dependency on their imports. Heavily dependent on technological progress and acceptance of CCS Legend: = equivalent to
Reference scenario + to +++
improvement compared to Reference scenario - to - - -
worsening compared to Reference scenario Conclusions The Commission
services conducted a model-based analysis of decarbonisation scenarios
exploring energy consequences of the European Council's objective to reach 80% GHG
reductions by 2050 (as compared to 1990), provided that industrialised
countries as a group undertake similar efforts. These scenarios explore also
the energy security and competitiveness dimension of such energy developments. Businesses
as usual projections show only half the GHG emission reductions needed;
increased import dependency, in particular for gas; and rising electricity
prices and energy costs. Several decarbonisation scenarios highlighting the
implications of pursuing each of the four main decarbonisation routes for the
energy sector – energy efficiency, renewables, nuclear and CCS - were examined
by modelling a high and low end for each of them. The model relies on a series
of input assumptions and internal mechanisms to provide the outputs. The
most relevant assumptions and mechanisms of the model Ø All scenarios were conducted under the
hypothesis that the whole world is acting on climate change which leads to
lower demand for fossil fuel prices and subsequently lower prices. Ø The model assumes perfect foresight
regarding policy thrust, energy prices and technology developments which
assures a very low level of uncertainty for investors, enabling them to make
particular cost-effective investment choices without stranded investments.
There is also no problem with uncertainty on whether all the infrastructure and
other interrelated investment needed to make a particular investment work will
be in place in time. Ø Regulatory framework in model allows for
investments to be built and costs fully recovered. Ø The model assumes a "representative"
or average household or consumer while in reality there is a more diversified
picture of investors and consumers. Ø The model assumes continuous improvements
of technologies. The
model-based analysis has shown that decarbonisation
of the energy sector is feasible; that it can be achieved through various
combinations of energy efficiency, renewables, nuclear and CCS contributions;
and that the costs are affordable. The aim of the analysis was not to pick
preferred options, a choice that would be surrounded with great uncertainty,
but to show some prototype of pathways to decarbonise the energy system while
improving energy security and competitiveness and identify common features from
scenario analysis. Common elements to scenario analysis Ø
There is a need for an
integrated approach, e.g. decarbonisation of heating and transport relies heavily
on the availability of decarbonised electricity supply, which in turn depends
on very low carbon investments in generation capacity as well as significant
grid expansions and smartening. Ø
Electricity (given its high efficiency and emission free nature at
use) makes major inroads in decarbonisation scenarios reaching a 36-39% share
in 2050 (almost doubling from the current level and becoming the most important
final energy source). Decarbonisation
in 2050 will require an almost carbon free electricity sector in the EU, and
around 60% CO2 reductions by 2030. Ø
Significant energy
efficiency improvements happen in all decarbonisation scenarios. One unit of
GDP in 2050 requires around 70% less energy input compared with 2005. The
average annual improvement in energy intensity amounts to around 2.5% pa. Ø
The share of renewables
rises substantially in all scenarios, achieving at least 55% in gross
final energy consumption in 2050, up 45 percentage points from the current
level (a high RES case explores the consequences of raising this share to 75%). Ø
The increased use of
renewable energy as well as energy efficiency improvements require modern,
reliable and smart infrastructure including electrical storage. Ø
Nuclear has a
significant role in decarbonisation in Member States where it is accepted in
all scenarios (besides Low nuclear and High RES), with the highest penetration
in case of CCS delay. Ø
CCS contributes
significantly towards decarbonisation in most scenarios, with the highest
penetration in case of problems with nuclear investment and deployment.
Developing CCS can be also seen as an insurance against energy efficiency, RES
and nuclear (in some Member States) delivering less or not that quickly. Ø
All scenarios show a
transition from high fuel/operational expenditures to high capital expenditure.
Ø
Substantial changes in
the period up to 2030 will be crucial for a cost-efficient long term transition
to a decarbonised world[88].
Economic costs are manageable if action starts early so that the restructuring
of the energy system goes in parallel with investment cycles thereby avoiding
stranded investment as well as costly lock-ins of medium carbon intensive
technology. Ø
The costs of such deep
decarbonisation are low in all scenarios given lower fuel procurement costs
with cost savings shown mainly in scenarios relying on all four main
decarbonisation options. Ø
Costs are unequally
distributed across sectors, with households shouldering the greatest cost
increase due to higher costs of direct energy efficiency expenditures in
appliances, vehicles and insulation. Ø
The external EU energy
bill for importing oil, gas and coal will be substantially lower under
decarbonisation due to a substantial reduction in import quantities and prices dependent
on global climate action lowering world fossil fuel demand substantially. Some policy
relevant conclusions can be drawn based both on the results of the scenario
analysis as well as on a comparison of the hypothetical situation of ideal
market and technological conditions needed for modelling purposes and what is
found in the much more complex reality. Implications for future policy making Ø
Successful
decarbonisation while preserving competitiveness of the EU economy is possible.
Without global climate action, carbon leakage might be an issue and appropriate
instruments could be needed to preserve the competitiveness of energy intensive
industries. Ø
Predictability and
stability of policy and regulatory framework creates a favourable environment
for low carbon investments. While the regulatory framework to 2020 is mainly
given, discussions about policies for 2020-2030 should start now leading to
firm decisions that provide certainty for long-term low-carbon investments.
Uncertainty can lead to a sub-optimal situation where only investment with low
initial capital costs is realised. Ø
A well functioning
internal market is necessary to encourage investment where it is most
cost-effective. However, the process of decarbonisation brings new challenges
in the context, for example, of electricity price determination in power
exchanges: deep decarbonisation increases substantially the bids based on zero
marginal costs leading in many instances to prices rather close to zero, not
allowing cost recovery in power generation. Similarly, the necessary expansion
and innovation of grids for decarbonisation may be hampered if regulated
transmission and distribution focuses on cost minimisation alone. Building of
adequate infrastructure needs to be assured and supported either by adequate
regulation and/or public funding (e.g. financed by auctioning revenues). Ø
Energy efficiency tends
to show better results in a model than in reality. Energy efficiency
improvements are often hampered by split incentives, cash problems of some
group of customers; imperfect knowledge and foresight leading to lock-in of
some outdated technologies, etc. There is thus a strong need for targeted
support policies and public funding supporting more energy efficient consumer
choices. Ø
Strong support should
be given to R&D in order to bring costs of low-carbon technologies down and
to minimize potential negative environmental and social side-effects. Ø
Due attention should be
given to public acceptance of all low carbon technologies and infrastructure as
well willingness of consumers to undertake implied changes and bear higher
costs. This will require the engagement of both the public and private sectors
early in the process. Ø
Social policies might
need to be considered early in the process given that households shoulder large
parts of the costs. While these costs might be affordable by an average
household, vulnerable consumers might need specific support to cope with
increased expenditures. In addition, transition to a decarbonised economy may
involve shifts to more highly skilled jobs, with a possibly difficult
adaptation period. Ø
Flexibility. The future
is uncertain and nobody can predict it. That is why preserving flexibility is
important for a cost efficient approach, but certain decisions are needed
already at this stage in order to start the process that needs innovation and
investment, for which investors require a reasonable degree of certainty from
reduced policy and regulatory risk. Ø
External dimension, in
particular relations with energy suppliers, should be dealt with pro-actively
and at an early stage given the implications of global decarbonisation on
fossil fuel export revenues and the necessary production and energy transport
investments during the transition phase to decarbonisation; new areas for
co-operation could include renewable energy supplies and technology
development.
7.
Monitoring and evaluation
The Roadmap is not a one-off exercise and
will be regularly updated taking into account the most recent developments. In
addition, the Commission will constantly monitor a set of core indicators which
are already available and are being currently used. Other indicators might be
added at a later stage. Table 12: Key indicators and their
relevance Key indicators || 2009 || Relevance Share of RES in gross final energy consumption || 10.3% (2008) || Increase in RES use in the economy Share of renewable energy in transport || 3.5% (2008) || Increase in RES use in the transport Energy intensity || 165.48 (toe/M€ '00) || Increase in energy efficiency Gross inland consumption (by fuel) || 1703 Mtoe http://ec.europa.eu/energy/publications/statistics/doc/2011-2009-country-factsheets.pdf || Changes in the overall demand and composition of energy mix over time; existing indicative energy saving objective for 2020 Energy per capita || 3403 kgoe/cap || Evolution of energy consumption relative to population growth Final energy consumption (by fuel and by sector) || 1114 Mtoe http://ec.europa.eu/energy/publications/statistics/doc/2011-2009-country-factsheets.pdf || Decrease in absolute energy consumption and effectiveness of energy efficiency policies as well as sectoral developments Electricity generation || 3210 TWh || Electrification of the economy Energy related CO2 emissions || 4055 MT CO2 || Trends in the emissions from the energy sector; lion's share in total GHG emissions Import dependency for all fuels || 54% || Vulnerability to imports from third countries Electricity prices || http://ec.europa.eu/energy/observatory/electricity/electricity_en.htm http://ec.europa.eu/energy/observatory/reports/EnergyDailyPricesReport-EUROPA.pdf || Competitiveness of European industry and affordability for households Diesel and petrol prices in different MS || http://ec.europa.eu/energy/observatory/oil/bulletin_en.htm || Evolution in prices of transport fuels and their convergence across the EU 27 Total GHG emissions compared to 1990 || -17.4% http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/g-gas/docs/com_2011_624_en.pdf || Meeting climate targets
8.
Annexes
Annex 1 || Scenarios - assumptions and results Annex 2 || Report on Stakeholders scenarios Annex 1 Scenarios – assumptions and results Part A: Reference scenario and its sensitivities and
Current Policy Initiatives scenario. 49 1. Assumptions. 49 1.1 Macroeconomic and demographic assumptions. 49 1.2 Energy import prices. 51 1.3 Policy assumptions. 56 1.4 Assumptions about energy infrastructure development 64 1.5 Technology assumptions. 64 1.6 Other assumptions. 73 2. Results. 75 2.1 Reference scenario. 75 2.2 Economic growth sensitivities. 84 2.3 Energy import price sensitivities. 92 2.4 Current Policy Initiatives scenario. 98 This document describes in detail the
assumptions and results of the Reference scenario 2050 and its sensitivities,
Current Policy Initiatives scenario and decarbonisation scenarios developed for
the purposes of the Energy Roadmap 2050. The Commission contracted the National Technical University of
Athens to model scenarios underpinning the Impact Assessment analysis. Similar
to previous modelling exercises with the PRIMES model, the Commission discloses
a lot of details about the PRIMES modelling system, modelling assumptions and
modelling results. In this tradition, the Commission services, based on the
modelling results and analysis on specific topics from NTUA, have drafted the
following comprehensive overview of the macroeconomic, world energy price,
policy, technology and other assumptions as well as the detailed results of the
current trend scenarios including sensitivities (Part A) and the various
decarbonisation scenarios (Part B). This is complemented with the attachments
to this document giving further details. The PRIMES model
was peer-reviewed by a group of recognised modelling experts in September 2011
with the conclusion that the model is suitable for the purpose of complex
energy system analysis. Reference
scenario is based on the scenarios up to 2030
published in the report "Energy Trends to 2030: update 2009", but
extends the projection period to 2050. It includes current trends on population
and economic development and takes into account the highly volatile energy
import price environment. Economic decisions are driven by market forces and
technology progress in the framework of concrete national and EU policies and
measures implemented until March 2010. These assumptions together with the
current statistical situation derived from the Eurostat energy balances
represent the starting point for projections which are presented from 2010
onwards in 5 year steps until 2050. The 2020 targets on RES and GHG will be
achieved, but there is no assumption on targets for later years. Sensitivities
on higher/lower economic growth and higher/lower energy import prices were
undertaken in order to assess the robustness of policy relevant indicators with
respect to these framework conditions for EU energy policy. The overall
policy context has developed since the Reference scenario was established in
2010. Therefore an additional trend scenario has been modelled including
policies that are being prepared with a view to the 2020 Energy Strategy. The Current
Policy Initiatives scenario includes the same macroeconomic and demographic
assumptions as the Reference scenario, slightly updated energy import prices
(only for 2010 with repercussions on 2015), revised cost-assumptions for
nuclear following post Fukushima reactions and policies either adopted after
March 2010 or being currently proposed by the Commission. In addition to
their role as a trend projection, the Reference and the Current Policy
Initiatives scenarios are benchmarks for energy scenarios achieving the
European Council's objective to reduce GHG by 80-95% below the 1990 level as
part of industrialised countries as a group undertaking such a reduction effort.
Comparisons of other scenarios with the Reference scenario concern questions
related to the additional policies with respect to those already implemented in
the Member States. Distinct from this, comparisons of the Current Policy
Initiatives scenario with decarbonisation scenarios address further policies
that might be envisaged in addition to those being proposed in the context of
the 2020 Energy Strategy. Such comparisons on the basis of the Current Policy
Initiatives scenario deal with new policies that might be debated under a 2030
horizon, which is an important milestone year on the decarbonisation pathways
to 2050. Decarbonisation
scenarios in the Energy Roadmap 2050 have been
designed to provide more detail on the analysis of the energy sector that was
presented in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap. Scenarios showing different energy
related decarbonisation pathways reach the 85% domestic energy related CO2
emission reductions by 2050 as compared to 1990 which is consistent with the
required contribution of developed countries as a group to limit global climate
change to a temperature increase of 2ºC compared to pre-industrial levels. All
decarbonisation scenarios developed for the Low carbon Economy Roadmap show
around 85% reductions of energy related CO2 emissions. The scenarios
modelled for the 2050 Energy Roadmap investigate in great depth the main
strategic directions (energy efficiency, RES, CCS and nuclear) towards a
decarbonised European energy system. In doing so, they reflect for each of
these directions or main ways of decarbonisation a low and a high end option.
This underlines the fact that there are many different pathways for reaching
the same level of decarbonisation in the EU. All numbers
included in this report, except otherwise stated, refer to European Union of 27
Member States.
Part
A: Reference scenario and its sensitivities and Current Policy Initiatives
scenario
1.
Assumptions
1.1 Macroeconomic and demographic assumptions
The population
projections draw on the EUROPOP2008 convergence scenario (EUROpean POPulation
Projections, base year 2008) from Eurostat, which is also the basis for the
2009 Ageing Report (European Economy, April 2009)[89]. The key drivers for
demographic change are: higher life expectancy, low fertility and inward migration. The
macro-economic projections reflect the recent economic downturn, followed by
sustained economic growth resuming after 2010. The medium and long term growth
projections follow the “baseline” scenario of the 2009 Ageing Report (European
Economy, April 2009), which derives GDP growth per country on the basis of
variables such as population, participation rates in the labour market and
labour productivity.[90]
Based on the Ageing Report the Commission services developed a common Reference
scenario, the macroeconomic part of which is referred to below. Further details
relating notably to the sectoral value added can be found in the report
"EU Energy Trends to 2030".[91]
The same macroeconomic assumptions were already used for the "Roadmap for moving to a competitive low-carbon
economy in 2050" of March 2011.[92] The
Reference scenario assumes that the recent economic crisis has long lasting
effects, leading to a permanent loss in GDP. The recovery from the crisis is
not expected to be so vigorous that the GDP losses during the crisis are fully
compensated. In this scenario, growth prospects for 2011 and 2012 are subdued.
However, economic recovery enables higher productivity gains, leading to
somewhat faster growth from 2013 to 2015. After 2015, GDP growth rates mirror
those of the 2009 Ageing Report. Hence the pattern of the Reference scenario is
consistent with the intermediate scenario 2 “sluggish recovery” presented in
the Europe 2020 strategy[93].
The
average growth rate for EU-27 is only 1.2% per year for 2000-2010, while the
projected rate for 2010-2020 is recovering to 2.2%, similar to the historical
average growth rate between 1990 and 2000. GDP increases in line with the
Ageing Report developments, depicting declining growth rates over time as well as
great variation among Member States. Recovering from the crisis (reflected by
only 0.6% pa GDP growth in 2005-2010), EU-27 GDP is expected to rise 1.7% per
annum (pa) from 2010 to 2050, and more specifically by 2.0% up to 2030 and only
1.5% pa after 2030. EU-12 growth is considerably higher in 2010-2030 (2.7% pa)
but significantly smaller post 2030 due to shrinking and ageing population
(0.9% pa). The
recent economic crisis has added sustainability problems to the public
finances. Overall, as an effect of both economic crisis and the ageing of the
population, without fiscal consolidation the gross debt-to-GDP ratio for the EU
as a whole could reach 100 percent as early as 2014 and 140 percent by 2020[94],[95].
The recent economic crisis might therefore limit the public funding available
for low carbon investments. Sensitivities – Higher and Lower GDP cases Considering the high degree of uncertainty surrounding projections
over such a long time horizon, a sensitivity analysis has been carried out with
respect to GDP developments. A high and a low case have been analysed. The
GEM-E3 model was deployed to simulate higher and lower expansion paths for GDP
growth, while all other assumptions, including world fossil fuel prices, have
remained the same. Table 1: EU-27 GDP in real terms in the high and
low economic growth variants, compared to the Reference scenario GDP Table 2: Average
annual growth rate for the EU-27 The two economic growth variants are designed to provide insights
into the energy system developments stemming from alternative outcomes on
economic drivers of energy consumption. In the high growth variant, GDP per
capita is 0.4 percentage points higher than in the Reference case throughout
the projection period, whereas it would be 0.4 pp lower in the low growth case.
These variants examine the energy consequences of alternative economic
developments broken down by economic sector in particular with regard to
activities of energy intensive sectors versus less intensive ones. Higher GDP growth would be driven mainly by enhanced activities of
the services sector, with particular high value added growth in market services
and trade, as these sectors are not very energy intensive. By comparison,
industrial value added would exhibit less additional growth with expansion
rates lower than that of GDP Both energy intensive and less energy intensive
industrial sectors would however still show healthy additional growth. In the low economic growth variant, all economic sectors would
suffer to a similar extent with value added in most cases being 14-15% lower in
2050 than in the Reference case. One exception would be agriculture where the
decrease in output with respect to the Reference case would be smaller.
1.2 Energy import prices
The energy projections are based on a relatively high oil price
environment compared with previous projections and are similar to reference
projections from other sources[96].
The baseline price assumptions for the EU27 are the result of world energy
modelling (using the PROMETHEUS stochastic world energy model) that derives
price trajectories for oil, gas and coal under a conventional wisdom view of
the development of the world energy system. International fuel prices are projected to grow over the projection
period with oil prices reaching 88$’08/bbl in 2020, 106$’08/bbl in 2030 and 127
$08/barrel in 2050 with 2% inflation (ECB target) this corresponds to some 300
$ in 2050 in nominal terms. Gas prices follow a trajectory similar to oil prices reaching
62$’08/boe in 2020, 77$’08/boe in 2030 and 98 $(08)/boe in 2050 while coal
prices increase during the economic recovery period to reach almost 26$’08/boe
in 2020 and stabilize at around 30$’08/boe.[97]
The price development to 2050 is expected to take place in a context
of economic recovery and resuming GDP growth without decisive climate action in
any world region. Prices were derived with world energy modelling that shows
largely parallel developments of oil and gas prices whereas coal prices remain
at much lower levels. Figure 1: Reference scenario fossil fuel price assumptions The evolution of
the ratio of gas and coal prices can to a great extent influence the investment
choices taken by investors in the power sector. A relatively low gas to coal
price ratio up to the year 2000, together with the emergence of the gas turbine
combined cycle technology, led to massive investments in gas fired power
plants. The investments decreased afterwards due to significant gas price
increases. The ratio between gas and oil prices remains stable over time as gas
prices continue to follow oil prices. The gas to coal price ratio is projected
to rise steadily over time as the coal prices in the world modelling results do
not follow oil prices but remain around 30$’08/boe from 2030 onwards. While
this ratio will increase over time, investment decisions will also be highly
dependent on the expectations about future carbon prices. Figure 2: Ratios of
fossil fuel prices Sensitivities:
Higher and lower energy import prices Considering the
high degree of uncertainty surrounding projections over such a long time
horizon, a sensitivity analysis has been carried out with respect to
developments in energy imports prices. A high and a low case have been
analysed. When undertaking the price sensitivities in 2011, the energy price
figures for 2010 were updated from the estimates made in early 2009 for the
Baseline/Reference scenario (in the same way as in the Reference case).[98] Global
developments as regards shale gas are taken into account in this analysis.
The world energy model PROMETHEUS was deployed to derive the
alternative prices trajectories. This stochastic model is particularly well
suited given the great uncertainty regarding future world economic developments
and the extent of recoverable resources of fossil fuels. Two different world
energy price developments have been examined. The high world fossil fuel price
development is driven by somewhat higher global GDP growth than under reference
developments, especially in China, giving rise to higher energy consumption.
Moreover, there are somewhat less optimistic assumptions on reserves regarding
unconventional oil, which has the highest marginal costs. This favours stronger
market power of key exporting countries and thereby higher prices. On the
contrary, the low world energy prices derive from markedly more subdued world
economic growth combined with higher fossil fuel reserves and consequently less
market power of key export players. The sensitivities below are more symmetrical around the Reference
case, including a High Price case with oil prices exceeding the Reference case
level by 28% in 2050 and a Low Price case, in which the oil price in 2050 is 34
% lower than in the Reference case. The price
trajectories for oil, gas and coal shown in table 3 for the high energy price
scenario stem from the following developments mirrored in the world modelling
analysis: ·
There is sustained economic growth in many Asian
economies (notably China) following their reaction to the recent crisis, which
has been to support domestic market expansion as a counterweight. The result
has been that economic growth in the large Asian economies like China and India has barely been affected by the world economic slowdown. Since these are large
consumers of coal the effect of this economic activity revision is particularly
pronounced on short to medium term coal prices. ·
There appears to be pronounced delays in oil
productive capacity expansion with many plans being constantly revised. In
addition, the recent accident in the Gulf of Mexico has resulted in a
moratorium on deep water development in that area and is likely to result in
delays in other parts of the world as well, in response to increased
environmental concerns. ·
There is increased concern that oil reserves and
prospects for undiscovered resources are overstated. This may be particularly
the case in OPEC countries where resource endowment is used as a criterion for
production quota allocations. ·
In view of the oligopolistic nature of world oil
markets the tighter supply conditions usually translate into disproportionate
increases in resource rents. Likewise such conditions imply greater
vulnerability to short term supply disruptions leading to price spikes and
resulting in higher average prices. ·
The higher oil prices result in substitution of
oil for gas in markets where the two fuels compete. The reduction in oil
discoveries also implies a reduction in future reserves of associated gas. On
the other hand gas price increases are moderated by an increasing share of
unconventional gas from shales, as technology improves and the interest in its
potential spreads beyond North America. The low energy
price scenario has been based on the following hypothetical background: ·
There is currently great uncertainty on economic
development including regarding excessive debts. It cannot be excluded that the
recovery observed in 2009 and 2010 could prove to be relatively short lived, potentially
leading to a "W shaped recession”).Whereas the reference scenario assumes
a strong recovery of the world economy in the 2011-2014 period predicated on a
rapid absorption of excess productive capacity (both capital and labour) and a
strong resumption of investment in anticipation of fast growth in demand,
developments could be less favourable. In particular, credit expansion could be
hampered by the persistence of creditor exposure to uncertainty and increasing
concern over the scope and timing of adjustments aimed at addressing imbalances
(including sovereign debt). Consequently the investment boom may fail to
materialize leading to some permanent loss of potential GDP (in the longer term
world GDP is 7% lower in the modelled environment, which explains particularly
low world fossil fuel prices). ·
There is also uncertainty about energy resources
and a more optimistic view could be adopted on this world energy price driver.
In the low price variant, undiscovered conventional oil resources are set at their
upper ten percentile value following USGS and PROMETHEUS assessments (in the
reference scenario median values were used). ·
In addition, the low price variant also assumes
an increase in exploration activity outside the Gulf region as a response to
security of supply concerns. This results in a more rapid translation of the
resource basis into larger quantities of exploitable reserves. The main impact
of this assumption is to bring forward the market easing emanating from greater
resource abundance. ·
The variant assumes rapid improvements in the
knowledge and technologies associated with unconventional (shale) gas
extraction. These in turn lead to enhanced interest in shale gas resources
beyond North America leading to their more rapid incorporation into the
exploitable resource base of some regions of the world. The assumptions
concerning shale gas are the key driver for the high oil to gas price ratio
that characterizes the low price variant. Table 3: Energy import prices in the Reference
scenario and low and high price variants Figure 3:
Sensitivity for international fuel prices Similarly, to these
sensitivities, the Current Policy Initiatives Scenario is based on slightly
higher short term energy import prices reflecting 2010 developments.
1.3 Policy assumptions
Policy measures included in the Reference
scenario are resumed in the following table: || Measure || || How the measure is reflected in PRIMES Regulatory measures || Energy efficiency 1 || Ecodesign Framework Directive || Directive 2005/32/EC || Adaptation of modelling parameters for different product groups for Ecodesign and decrease of perceived costs by consumers for labelling (which reflects transparency and the effectiveness of price signals for consumer decisions). As requirements and labelling concern only new products, the effect will be gradual (marginal in 2010; rather small in 2015 up to full effect by 2030). The potential envisaged in the Ecodesign supporting studies and the relationship between cost and efficiency improvements in the model's database were cross-checked. 2 || Stand-by regulation || Regulation No 1275/2008 3 || Simple Set-to boxes regulation || Regulation No 107/2009 4 || Office/street lighting regulation || Regulation No 245/2009 5 || Household lighting regulation || Regulation No 244/2009 6 || External power supplies regulation || Regulation No 278/2009 7 || TVs regulation (+labelling) || Regulation No 642/2009 8 || Electric motors regulation || Regulation No 640/2009 9 || Circulators[99] regulation || Regulation No 641/2009 10 || Freezers/refrigerators regulation (+labelling) || Regulation No 643/2009 11 || Labelling Directive || Directive 2003/66/EC || Enhancing the price mechanism mirrored in the model 12 || Labelling for tyres || Regulation No 1222/2009 || Decrease of perceived costs by consumers for labelling (which reflects transparency and the effectiveness of price signals for consumer decisions) 13 || Energy Star Program (voluntary labelling program) || || Enhancing the price mechanism mirrored in the model 14 || Directive on end-use energy efficiency and energy services || Directive 2006/32/EC || National implementation measures are reflected 15 || Buildings Directive || Directive 2002/91/EC || National measures e.g. on strengthening of building codes and integration of RES are reflected 16 || Recast of the EPBD || Directive 2010/31/EU || New building requirements are reflected in technical parameters of the model, in particular through better thermal integrity of buildings and requirements for new buildings after 2020 17 || Cogeneration Directive || Directive 2004/8/EC || National measures supporting cogeneration are reflected || Energy markets 18 || Completion of the internal energy market (including provisions of the 3rd package) || http://ec.europa.eu/energy/gas_electricity/third_legislative_package_en.htm || The model reflects the full implementation of the Second Internal market Package by 2010 and Third Internal Market Package by 2015. It simulates liberalised market regime for electricity and gas (decrease of mark-ups of power generation operators; third party access; regulated tariffs for infrastructure use; producers and suppliers are considered as separate companies) with optimal use of interconnectors. 19 || EU ETS directive || Directive 2003/87/EC as amended by Directive 2008/101/EC and Directive 2009/29/EC || The ETS carbon price is modelled so that cumulative cap for GHGs is respected[100]. The permissible total CDM amount over 2008-2020 is conservatively estimated at 1600 Mt. Banking of allowances is reflected The ETS cap is assumed to continue declining beyond 2020 as stipulated in legislation, however with an effective domestic emission decrease lower than the linear decrease rate of 1.74%) to result in a 50% cumulative decrease of actual emissions instead of 70% which could stem from the Directive as a maximum reduction of EU emissions if no use of international credits would be allowed beyond 2030[101]; currently no provision for the use of international credits post 2020 have been fixed and in the reference scenario world without global action, the higher ETS price might trigger greater use of such credits, which would also be in greater supply with higher ETS prices. ETS prices are derived endogenously on the basis of allowances, international credits, emissions reflecting developments of energy consumption while taking account of banking. 20 || RES directive || Directive 2009/28/EC || Legally binding national targets for RES share in gross final energy consumption are achieved in 2020; 10% target for RES in transport is achieved for EU27 as biofuels can be easily traded among Member States; sustainability criteria for biomass and biofuels are respected using the full detail of the biomass model linked to the PRIMES energy system model; cooperation mechanisms according to the RES directive are allowed and respect Member states indications on their "seller" or "buyer" positions. RES subsidies decline after 2020 starting with the phasing out of operational aid to new onshore wind by 2025; other RES aids decline to zero by 2050 at different rates according to technology. Increasing use of RES co-operation mechanisms is assumed and should help to reduce RES costs. Policies on facilitating RES penetration will continue. 21 || GHG Effort Sharing Decision || Decision 406/2009/EC || National targets for non-ETS sectors are achieved in 2020, taking full account of the flexibility provisions such as transfers between Member States. After 2020, stability of the provided policy impulse but no strengthening of targets is assumed. 22 || Energy Taxation Directive || Directive 2003/96/EC || Tax rates (EU minimal rates or higher national ones) are kept constant in real term. The modelling reflects the practice of MS to increase tax rates above the minimum rate due to i.a. inflation. 23 || Large Combustion Plant directive || Directive 2001/80/EC || Emission limit values laid down in part A of Annexes III to VII in respect of sulphur dioxide; nitrogen oxides and dust are respected. Some existing power plants had a derogation which provided them with 2 options to comply with the Directive: either to operate only a limited number of hours or to be upgraded. The model selected between the two options on a case by case basis. The upgrading is reflected through higher capital costs. 24 || IPPC Directive || Directive 2008/1/EC || Costs of filters and other devices necessary for compliance are reflected in the parameters of the model 25 || Directive on the geological storage of CO2 || Directive 2009/31/EC || Legal framework regulating the geological storage of CO2 allowing together with EEPR and NER300 CCS demonstration support (see below) economic modelling to determine CCS penetration 26 || Directive on national emissions' ceilings for certain pollutants || Directive 2001/81/EC || PRIMES model takes into account results of RAINS/GAINS modelling regarding classical pollutants (SO2, NOx). Emission limitations are taken into account bearing in mind that full compliance can also be achieved via additional technical measures in individual MS. 27 || Water Framework Directive || Directive 2000/60/EC || Hydro power plants in PRIMES respect the European framework for the protection of all water bodies as defined by the Directive, which limits the potential deployment of hydropower and might impact on generation costs. 28 || Landfill Directive || Directive 99/31/EC || Provisions on waste treatment and energy recovery are reflected || Transport 29 || Regulation on CO2 from cars || Regulation No 443/2009 || Limits on emissions from new cars: 135 gCO2/km in 2015, 115 in 2020, 95 in 2025 – in test cycle. The 2015 target should be achieved gradually with a compliance of 65% of the fleet in 2012, 75% in 2013, 80% in 2014 and finally 100% in 2015. Penalties for non-compliance are dependent on the number of grams until 2018; starting in 2019 the maximum penalty is charged from the first gram. 30 || Regulation EURO 5 and 6 || Regulation No 715/2007 || Emissions limits introduced for new cars and light commercial vehicles 31 || Fuel Quality Directive || Directive 2009/30/EC || Modelling parameters reflect the Directive, taking into account the uncertainty related to the scope of the Directive addressing also parts of the energy chain outside the area of PRIMES modelling (e.g. oil production outside EU). 32 || Biofuels directive || Directive 2003/30/EC || Support to biofuels such as tax exemptions and obligation to blend fuels is reflected in the model The requirement of 5.75% of all transportation fuels to be replaced with biofuels by 2010 has not been imposed as the target is indicative. Support to biofuels is assumed to continue. The biofuel blend is assumed to be available on the supply side. 33 || Implementation of MARPOL Convention ANNEX VI || 2008 amendments - revised Annex VI || Amendment of Annex VI of the MARPOL Convention reduce sulphur content in marine fuels which is reflected in the model by a change in refineries output 34 || Regulation Euro VI for heavy duty vehicles || Regulation (EC) No 595/2009 || Emissions limits introduced for new heavy duty vehicles. 35 || Regulation on CO2 from vans[102] || Part of the Integrated Approach to reduce CO2 emissions from cars and light commercial vehicles. || Limits on emissions from new LDV: 181 gCO2/km in 2012, 175 in 2016, 135 in 2025 – in test cycle Financial support 36 || TEN-E guidelines || Decision No 1364/2006/EC || The model takes into account all TEN-E realised infrastructure projects 37 || EEPR (European Energy Programme for Recovery) and NER 300 (New entrance reserve) funding programme || For EEPR: Regulation No 663/2009; For NER300: EU Emissions Trading Directive 2009/29/EC Article 10a(8), further developed through Commission Decision 2010/670/EU[103] || Financial support to CCS demonstration plants; off-shore wind and gas, innovative renewables and electricity interconnections is reflected in the model. For CCS, - the following envisaged demonstration plants are taken into account for commissioning in 2020: Germany 950 MW (450MW coal post-combustion, 200MW lignite post-combustion and 300MW lignite oxy-fuel), Italy 660 MW (coal post-combustion), Netherlands 1460 MW (800MW coal post-combustion, 660MW coal integrated gasification pre-combustion), Spain 500 MW (coal oxy-fuel), UK 3400 MW (1600MW coal post-combustion, 1800MW coal integrated gasification pre-combustion), Poland 896 MW (306MW coal post-combustion, 590MW lignite post-combustion); investment in further plants depends on carbon prices 38 || RTD support (7th framework programme- theme 6) || energy research under FP7 || Financial support to R&D for innovative technologies such as CCS, RES, nuclear and energy efficiency is reflected by technology learning and economies of scale leading to cost reductions of these technologies 39 || State aid Guidelines for Environmental Protection and 2008 Block Exemption Regulation || Community guidelines on state aid for environmental protection || Financial support to R&D for innovative technologies such as CCS, RES, nuclear and energy efficiency is reflected by technology learning and economies of scale leading to cost reductions of these technologies 40 || Cohesion Policy – ERDF, ESF and Cohesion Fund || || Financial support to national policies on energy efficiency and renewables is reflected by facilitating and speeding up the uptake of energy efficiency and renewables technologies. 41 || Rural development policy - EAFRD || Council Regulation (EC) No. 1698/2005 || Financial support for supply and use of renewable energy to farmers and other actors in rural areas, financial support to investments increasing energy efficiency of farms National measures 42 || Strong national RES policies || || National policies on e.g. feed-in tariffs, quota systems, green certificates, subsidies and other cost incentives are reflected 43 || Nuclear || || Nuclear, including the replacement of plants due for retirement, is modelled on its economic merit and in competition with other energy sources for power generation except for MS with legislative provisions on nuclear phase out. Several constraints are put on the model such as decisions of Member States not to use nuclear at all (Austria, Cyprus, Denmark, Estonia, Greece, Ireland, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta and Portugal) and closure of existing plants in some new Member States according to agreed schedules (Bulgaria 1760 MW, Lithuania 2600 MW and Slovakia 940 MW). The nuclear phase-out in Belgium and Germany is respected while lifetime of nuclear power plants was extended to 60 years in Sweden. Nuclear investments are possible in Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, France, Finland, Hungary, Lithuania, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain and UK For the modelling the following plans on new nuclear plants were taken into account: Bulgaria (1000 MW by 2020 and 1000 MW by 2025), Finland (1600 MW by 2015), France (1600 MW by 2015 and 1600 MW by 2020), Lithuania (800 MW by 2020 and 800 MW by 2025), Romania (706 MW by 2010, 776 MW by 2020 and 776 MW by 2025), Slovakia (880 MW by 2015). Member States experts were invited to provide information on new nuclear investments/programmes in spring 2009 and commented on the PRIMES baselines results in summer 2009, which had a significant impact on the modelling results for nuclear capacity. In addition to these measures, the
Current Policy Initiatives Scenario includes the following policies and
measures: Area || Measure || How it is reflected in the model Internal market || || 1 || Effective transposition and implementation of third package, including the development of pan-European rules for the operation of systems and management of networks in the long run || The modelling approach mirrors completion of the internal market, but has to account for existing interconnector limitations. Better market integration is reflected by having higher net transfer capacities in the near future and additional interconnectors in the longer term which lead to higher price convergence in multi-country market coupling in both electricity and gas markets (for details see below). In the gas market, more diversification (see also point 1) and higher degree of competition lead to lower oligopoly mark-ups and lower prices. 2 || Regulation on security of gas supply (N-1 rule, necessity for diversification) || Compliance with N-1 rule and the necessity for diversification induce higher costs in the model for gas companies. 3 || Regulation on Energy market integrity and transparency (REMIT) || The model simulates well functioning energy markets Infrastructure || || 4 || Facilitation policies (faster permitting; one stop shop) || All these policies induce shorter lead times and slightly lower costs allowing faster infrastructure deployment. 5 || Infrastructure instrument || More funding available from the EU budget 6 || Updated investments plans based on ENTSO-e Ten Year Network Development Plan || Interconnection capacity reflects projects in the TYNDP by 2020. 7 || Smartening of grids and metering || Smart grids and meters will lead to higher costs mainly for distribution but will allow for more energy efficiency in the system and decentralised RES Energy efficiency || measures proposed in the Energy efficiency Plan – implementation compared to scenario 3[104] less vigorously and at a more moderate rate || 8 || Obligation for public authorities to procure energy efficient goods and services || Cost perception parameters for non market service sector adapted accordingly 9 || Planned Ecodesign measures (boilers, water heaters, air-conditioning, etc) || Adaptation of modelling parameters for different product groups. As requirements concern only new products, the effect will be gradual (rather small in 2015 and up to full effect by 2030/2035 as e.g. boilers can have a very long lifetime) 10 || High renovation rates for existing buildings due to better/more financing and planned obligations for public buildings || Change of drivers (ESCOs, energy utilities obligation in point 13, energy audits point 14) influence stock – flow parameters in the model reflecting higher renovation rates, with account being taken of tougher requirements for public sector through specific treatment of the non-market services sector 11 || Passive houses standards after 2020 (already in the Reference scenario) || Higher penetration of passive houses standards compared to the Reference scenario (around 30-50 KWh/m2 depending on a country which might to a large extent be of renewable origin) 12 || Greater role of Energy Service Companies || Enabling role of ESCOs is reflected via altered economic parameters leading to more energy efficient choices (see also point 10) 13 || Obligation of utilities to achieve energy savings in their customers' energy use of 1.5% per year (until 2020) || Induce more energy efficiency mainly in residential and tertiary sectors by imposing an efficiency value for grid bound energy sources (electricity, gas, heat) 14 || Mandatory energy audits for companies || Induce more energy efficiency in industry (see also point 10) 15 || Obligation that, where there is a sufficient demand authorisation for new thermal power generation is granted on condition that the new capacity is provided with CHP; Obligation for electricity DSOs to provide priority access for electricity from CHP; Reinforcing obligations on TSOs concerning access and dispatching of electricity from CHP || To a large extent already reflected in the Reference scenario 2050 Further facilitation of CHP penetration in the model 16 || Obligation that all new energy generation capacity reflects the efficiency ratio of the best available technology (BAT), as defined in the Industrial Emissions Directive || High energy efficiency to a large extent already reflected in the Reference scenario 2050 as a response to ETS carbon prices; energy efficiency improves furthermore in power generation along with new investment from more efficient vintages 17 || Other measures (better information for consumers, public awareness, training, SMEs targeted actions) || Induce faster energy efficiency improvements Nuclear || || 19 || Nuclear Safety Directive || Harmonisation with international standards 20 || Waste Management Directive || Cost for waste management reflected in generation costs 21 || Consequences of Japan nuclear accident || Stress tests and other safety measures reflected through higher costs for retrofitting (up to 20% higher generation costs after lifetime extension compared with Reference scenario) and introduction of risk premium for new nuclear power plants. Nuclear determined on economic grounds, subject to non nuclear countries (except for Poland) remaining non-nuclear CCS || || 22 || Slower progress on demonstration plants || Downward revision of planning for some CCS demonstration plants compared to the Reference case; some plants might be commissioned later depending on carbon prices. Change regarding potential storage sites in BE and NL. Oil and gas || || 23 || Offshore oil and gas platform safety standards || Standards slightly increase production costs for oil and gas in the EU Taxation || || 24 || Energy taxation Directive (revision 2011) || Changes to minimum tax rates for heating and transport sectors reflect the switch from volume-based to energy content-based taxation and the inclusion of a CO2 tax component. Where Member States tax above the minimum level, the current rates are assumed to be kept unchanged. For motor fuels, the relationships between minimum rates are assumed to be mirrored at national level even if the existing rates are higher than the minimum rates. Tax rates are kept constant in real terms. Transport || || 25 || A revised test cycle to measure CO2 emissions under real-world driving conditions (to be proposed at the latest by 2013) [105] || Implementation of CO2 standards for passenger cars (95 g CO2/km) by 2020. Starting with 2020 assume autonomous efficiency improvements as in the Reference scenario. 26 || Update of the CO2 standards for vans according to the adopted regulation[106] || Implementation of CO2 standards for vans (175 g of CO2 per kilometre by 2017, phasing in the reduction from 2014, and to reach 147g CO2/km by 2020). Other parameters || || Energy import prices || || Short-term increase to reflect the evolution of prices up to 2010 Technology assumptions || Higher penetration of EVs reflecting developments in 2009-2010 national support measures and the intensification of previous action programmes and incentives, such as funding research and technology demonstration (RTD) projects to promote alternative fuels. || Slightly higher penetration of EVs Assumed specific battery costs per unit kWh in the long run: 390-420 €/kWh for plug-in hybrids and 315-370 €/kWh for electric vehicles, depending on range and size, and other assumptions on critical technological components[107].
1.4 Assumptions about energy infrastructure development
Regarding infrastructure
representation, the scope of the modelling was increased by undertaking the
determination of electricity interconnectors in a two stages approach. The aim
is to represent market integration cost-effectively given many different
scenarios modelled. The purpose of stage 1 is to determine electricity trade in
the internal market based on a simpler version of PRIMES determining the
equilibrium with all countries linked through endogenous trade, which due to
its great technology detail on power generation requires very long computing
times for each run. Stage 2 concerns the fully detailed modelling on the basis
of the outcome of stage 1. The very long computing
times for each model run under endogenous trade require a cost-effective
approach, given that many iterations need to be performed between demand and
supply and for meeting carbon targets. Running all countries in parallel
in stage 2, involving many iterations, ensures delivery of modelling results in
time. Data about NTCs
and interconnection capacities were taken from ENTSOe databases. Information on
new constructions was taken from the latest “Ten-year network development plan
2010-2020”, complemented, where necessary, with information from the Nordic
Pool TSOs and the Energy Community (for South East Europe). Some of the planned
new constructions would justify increase of NTCs values until 2020, as
mentioned in the ENTSOe’s TYNDP document. Other mentioned new constructions
regard directly the building of new interconnection lines which are introduced
as such in the model database. Market
integration leads to more electricity trade, which in turn needs infrastructure
that is also dealt with in the modelling. Several test modelling runs were
undertaken. It turned out that for the Reference and Current Policy
Initiatives scenarios, the 2020 interconnection capacity would allow for most
intra-EU electricity trade up to 2050 provided that a few identified
bottlenecks would be dealt with. Such areas
are the southern and eastern connections of Germany, the area linking Italy, Austria and Slovenia, the linkages of Balkans with northern neighbours and the linkages
within Balkans. Some NTC additions should be also made for the linkages
Denmark-Sweden and Latvia-Estonia. With lower electricity demand due to the
assumed strong energy efficiency policies, these results also hold for the
Current Policy Initiatives scenario. Other
infrastructure is dealt with in a less sophisticated way given that this is not
so much in the focus of the energy system model at the European level. For CCS
infrastructure (CO2 storage and transport) as well as for the sites of power
plants, e.g. nuclear or RES installations (the sites - not the generation as
such, see below) non-linear cost supply curves have been applied that take
account of increasing costs, leading to higher costs once the most suitable and
cheapest sites have been used. Details on the
modelling approach taken can be found in the Attachment 2 on interconnections.
1.5 Technology assumptions
Technology
parameters are exogenous in the PRIMES modelling and their values are based on
current databases, various studies[108]
and expert judgement and are regularly compared to other leading institutions.
Technologies are assumed to develop over time and to follow learning curves
which are exogenously adjusted to reflect the technology assumptions of a
scenario. For some technologies, in particular, for off-shore wind and
nuclear, the database of realised projects is very limited which can lead
to significant differences depending on how many projects and what projects
were included and where projects are being built. The energy
efficiency and other characteristics of the existing stock for a technology in
a given period depend on previous investments. This ensures that as in real
life changes in the characteristics of the technology stock happen only
gradually depending on the type and magnitude of new investment as well as the
rate of retirement of obsolete equipment. The market acceptance of a technology
is also modelled and depends on the maturity of a technology; the more mature a
technology the higher its market acceptance. Nuclear is however a special case
driven mainly by political considerations at government levels and acceptance
by citizens. In order to
ensuring comparability across scenarios, technology assumptions regarding
capital and operational costs as well as technology performance over time have
to remain the same across scenarios, except for cases, in which there were
specific policies on technology progress (e.g. targeted support to one specific
technology). In addition to these genuine technology parameters, the uptake of
technologies is also influenced by other modelling parameters reflecting policy
intensity, such as carbon and renewables values; these are discussed in later
chapters. Current trend and decarbonisation scenarios differ regarding enabling
policies, impacting also on technology uptake, as well as economies of scale in
technology deployment, bringing lower energy costs. Technology specific
parameters as such remain the same across scenarios. The modelling
cycle ending with the Energy Roadmap started in 2009 with the update of the
Baseline, meaning that capital costs assumptions for 2010 and their evolution
up to 2050 are based on information available in 2009/2010.. The Low Carbon
Economy Roadmap and the Transport White Paper of spring 2011 were based on the
same technology assumptions. It is clear that markets and technology costs as
well as performance parameters evolve over time. Therefore, such assumptions
need periodical update, which will be done again for the next modelling cycle
starting in 2012. Power generation Power generation
technologies are characterised by capital costs, variable and fixed operation
costs and by efficiencies. These characteristics are assumed to change over
time due to technological improvements (impacting predominantly on capital
costs). The assumptions for the Reference scenario for 2010 have been compared
to other studies (e.g. IEA[109]
and US DOE[110]),
where possible[111];
all costs have been transformed into EUR[112].
As can be seen
in Figure 4 the capital costs in PRIMES are within the range of other studies. Figure 4:
Capital costs in EUR/kWh in 2010[113] The costs of
technologies evolve over time in the Reference scenario reflecting learning
curves and economies of scale. There are ample possibilities for solar
technologies, both thermal and PV, to see costs decreasing over time, which is
also the case for CCS technologies. These are not yet mature technologies and
can therefore still follow steep learning curves. By comparison, the
possibilities of wind onshore to further decrease its costs are rather limited
with some potential still existing for small wind turbines., Figure 5 shows
cost developments for mainstream onshore wind at medium size. As can also be
seen in that figure, capital costs for off-shore wind can be expected to
decrease significantly over time. Figure 5: Development of capital costs over time in
the Reference scenario The effective cost of a technology depends also on
subsidies that may be paid by governments for environmental reasons to
encourage specific innovative technologies that may require state aids for some
time. In the case of renewables, Member States have support schemes that
encourage the uptake of renewables technologies depending often on cost
differences with conventional power generation technologies. This implies
dependence of such aids on the progress in the cost reduction for renewables
technologies, which are becoming increasingly cost competitive over time. The Roadmap modelling assumes that such
existing operational aid to RES for power generation is being phased out
according to the maturity of the individual technology subgroups. In the longer term, only innovative and still costly RES
technologies, such as solar PV, wave, tidal and off-shore wind at difficult
sites, would receive aids. While for
the more mature technologies (onshore wind) such aid is assumed to have been
phased out rather early in the modelling (by 2025), the phasing-out of
operational aid is completed by 2050 for other technologies. As RES technology
costs come down, sometimes ahead of expectations, governments curtail the aid
they grant. In any case, the operational aids
modelled only foster the uptake of RES technologies that are not yet fully
commercial. Renewables support is modelled via support to capital costs. This
support is relevant only for the investment decision but does not reduce
electricity costs, given that the full costs of RES deployment are paid for by
electricity consumers. In a large number of Member States this is currently
done via feed-in tariffs, the salient features of which (all electricity
consumers pay for the support to specific technologies) are captured by the
electricity modelling undertaken in these scenarios. It is important to note
that the current trend and decarbonisation scenarios have the same levels of
operational aids that decrease over time.[114] Distributed
Heat and Steam Distributed heat
in PRIMES can come either from CHP or district heating boilers. There are
several technologies to produce steam, but distribution technologies are rather
standard. For CHP there are ten different technologies that are applicable to
different power generation technologies; the CHP technologies relate to the
different technical options to extract the steam e.g. extraction, back-pressure
or condensing technologies. The CHP technologies are considered mature,
therefore no new learning effects are assumed. The higher penetration of CHP
technologies in the different scenarios is based on policy drivers. Demand side
technologies Demand side
technologies are mainly related to buildings, appliances, industrial equipment
and transport vehicles. The penetration of new technologies can have important
effects on energy efficiency improvement as well as on fuel switching.
Technology parameters are exogenous with assumptions being based on results of
various studies. The PRIMES data is compared regularly to other sources. For
electric appliances PRIMES technologies were compared to the EuP Preparatory
studies set out in directive 2005/32/EC and to the IEA Energy Technology
Perspectives 2008, as well as the “Study on the Energy Savings Potentials in EU
Member States, Candidate Countries and EEA Countries Final Report”[115]. The comparison proved that
the assumptions taken in the PRIMES model are comparable to the developments of
BAT and BNAT available from the EuP preparatory studies. There is a very
large number of different energy uses and technologies to provide the energy
services (heating and cooling, light, motion, communication, etc) that
consumers want when purchasing equipment and energy carriers. In the PRIMES modelling,
consumers always have the possibility of choosing between several vintages of
the same technology, which are characterised by different prices and
efficiencies. Throughout the projection period technologies become more mature
and their market acceptance may grow, due to increased market maturity and
policies. Figure 6: Examples of developments of electric
appliances in PRIMES compared to other literature sources[116] The technologies
in the above table only show a small variety of the technologies available in
the model; further technologies and fuels for the technologies are available
both for the services and residential demand as well as for industry and
agriculture. The data has been compiled and updated over the years based on
numerous sources including data from NEMS, the MURE database, industrial
surveys, EU project reports and IEA studies. For households
PRIMES includes five different dwelling types, differentiated according to the
main energy pattern[117]
which each have energy services provided to them such as: space heating, water
heating, cooking, cooling, lighting and other needs. Because of the very large
variety of housing types both within and between countries, PRIMES uses curves
for the possibilities of changes in thermal integrity of buildings relating
marginal costs with energy efficiency improvements. Specific numbers for a
typical household/dwelling type can therefore not be provided explicitly. Transport For transport
vehicles the same mechanisms apply as for appliances; a consumer can choose
different vintages of the same kind of vehicle at different costs and
efficiency. Also for transport, a comparison with a variety of literature
sources was carried out, which proves that the estimates of PRIMES are in line
with other estimates. Table 4:
Comparison of costs and efficiencies from different literature sources with
PRIMES[118] The amounts of
biofuels in the fuel mix of the Reference scenario are determined by the
relative costs of the fuels taking account of tax differentials and biofuel
quotas. The PRIMES model currently does not distinguish between dedicated
biofuel vehicles and vehicles that allow only for blending; the fuel and
vehicle stock mix simulate the inclusion of dedicated vehicles implicitly. The Current
Policy Initiatives Scenario relies on the same technology assumptions besides
nuclear in power generation which has been revised upwards reflecting the
follow-up to the Japanese nuclear accident.
1.6 Other assumptions
Discount
Rates The PRIMES model
is based on individual decision making of agents demanding or supplying energy
and on price-driven interactions in markets. The modelling approach is not
taking the perspective of a social planner and does not follow an overall least
cost optimization of the energy system. Therefore, social discount rates play
no role in determining model solutions. However, social discount rates can be
used for ex post cost evaluations. Discount rates
pertaining to individual agents play an important role in their decision
behaviour. Agents’ decisions about capital budgeting involve the concept of
cost of capital, which is depending on the sector - weighted average cost of
capital (for firms) or subjective discount rate (for individuals). In both
cases, the rate used to discount future costs and revenues involves a risk
premium which reflects business practices, various risk factors or even the
perceived cost of lending. The discount rate for individuals also reflects an
element of risk averseness. Table 5:
Discount rates for the different actors[119] Discount rates Industry || 12% Private individuals || 17.5% Tertiary || 12% Public transport || 8% Power generation sector || 9% Degree days against the background of climate change The heating
degree days, reflecting climate conditions, are kept constant at the 2000
level, which is higher than the long term average without assuming any trend
towards further warming. The degree days in 2000 were fairly similar to the
ones in 2005. This simplification allows comparison of recent statistics with
the projection figures, without the need for climate correction. There are also other energy related impacts from climate. However,
future climate change depends on future emissions worldwide, atmospheric
concentration and the sensitivity of the climate system to such concentration
increases. Future developments in these areas are surrounded by substantial
uncertainty. Given this uncertainty and the focus of this impact assessment on
the various energy system impacts this quantitative analysis has assumed
constant climate conditions over time. This simplification should be borne in
mind when considering the following detailed results under constant climate,
which is likely to change more, the more pronounced the global emission
increase. All the decarbonisation scenarios in Part B assume meeting the
climate targets, which are expected to prevent dangerous climate change.
However, even when temperature changes are limited to 2 degrees Celsius, some
climate impacts will occur. A literature review on climate change impacts in
the European energy supply sector[120] has
identified the following main impacts: ·
Cooling water constraints for thermal power
generation (especially during heat waves), with nuclear appearing to be
particularly strongly affected[121] ·
Damage to offshore or coastal production
facilities due to sea level rise and storm surges ·
Damage to transmission and distribution lines
due to storm events, flooding ·
Lower predictability of hydropower availability ·
Affected yield in renewable energy sector
(hydropower in Southern Europe, possibly biofuels due to diseases and forest
fires, possibly faster biomass plant growth in certain areas) ·
Melting permafrost affecting energy production
and distribution in cold climates ·
Damages and output constraints in wind energy
due to storms and increased average wind speed In addition,
changes in temperature might lead to changes in energy demand patterns for
heating and cooling. It can hence be
expected that decarbonisation has also positive economic impacts with regard to
energy security and competitiveness by avoiding parts of the damage and
adaptation costs in the energy system due to climate change.
In any case, given our lack of knowledge – perhaps
for a considerable time to come - about how the EU 2050 GHG emission objective
will be met and how global GHG emission will develop over time and therefore
lacking information on future atmospheric concentrations and their impacts on
temperatures in the Member States, the simplifying assumption has been made in
this analysis that heating degree days remain constant.
Exchange
rates
All monetary
values are expressed in constant, 2005, terms (without inflation). The economic
modelling in PRIMES is based on euros. The dollar exchange rate for current
money changes over time; it starts at the value of 1.45$/€ in 2009 and is
assumed to decrease to 1.25 $/€ by 2020 and to remain at that level for the
remaining period.
2.
Results
2.1 Reference scenario
Energy
consumption and supply Primary energy consumption peaked in
2006 at a level only marginally different from the year before. Given that 2005
numbers in the PRIMES output have been fully calibrated to 2005 Eurostat energy
statistics, the following comparisons start from 2005, being virtually the peak
year of energy consumption so far[122].
With ongoing energy efficiency policies – even in the absence of any further
policy intensification as depicted in the Reference case- total energy demand
decreases slightly up to 2050 (-4% from 2005). This is despite post-crisis economic
growth leading to a doubling of GDP between 2005 and 2050 (on an EU-27 average
of 1.6 % per year). Therefore, energy intensity drops considerably with one
unit of GDP in 2050 requiring only less than half the energy needed in 2005. Final energy consumption continues
rising until 2030, after which demand stabilises as more efficient technologies
have by then reached market maturity and the additional energy efficiency of
the appliances is sufficient to compensate for increased demand for energy
services (heat, light, motion, etc). The share of sectors remains broadly
stable with transport staying the biggest single consumer accounting for 32% in
2050; the industrial share increases slightly while that of households declines
a bit. Figure 7: Final energy demand indicators The energy intensity of different sectors decreases, as does the
overall energy intensity of the economy. Increased energy efficiency in the
residential sector is due to the use of more efficient energy equipment
(appliances, lighting, etc.) and buildings as well as behavioural changes. The
strong improvement in the energy efficiency of energy equipment is driven by
the Eco-Design regulations and by better thermal integrity of buildings
reflecting the Recast of the Energy Performance of Buildings Directive. While
these improvements are sufficient to ensure a decrease in final energy demand
over the projection period in the residential sector, the increased efficiency
is not sufficient to compensate for higher needs in the tertiary sector. In the transport
sector, the correlation between GDP growth and transport activity is found to
decouple somewhat when using satellite transport modelling tools. Energy
consumption is decoupling much more significantly due to the use of more energy
efficient vehicles, in particular hybrids. The CO2 from cars regulation is
instrumental for this development. This scenario takes a conservative view
regarding the development of alternative energy carriers such as electric and
fuel cell cars; it does not assume strong policies leading to a shift towards
electric mobility or plug-in hybrid vehicles in addition to the existing CO2
from cars regulation. The CO2 emissions per kilometre driven
decrease rapidly up to 2020 but as the regulation is not strengthened after
2020 in this scenario, improvements thereafter are due to stock renewal and
some autonomous efficiency improvements brought about by markets as has been
the case in the past. The penetration of biofuels in the Reference scenario is
limited to road transportation; overall biofuels in liquid fuels achieve a
share of 10% by 2050. The amount of RES in transport meets the 10% target in
2020 to comply with the RES directive and increases to 13.3% by 2050. Figure 8: Energy and Activity in
transport; composition of private vehicle stock[123] There is
considerable fuel switching in final energy demand, especially in the
residential and tertiary sectors where the use of fossil fuels (solids,
petroleum products and gas) decreases while there is a strong tendency towards
electrification. The share of RES in final energy consumption increases
markedly, reflecting the RES Directive. RES penetration continues with ongoing
enabling policies (priority access, streamlined authorisation) whereas
operation aid to mature RES technology is progressively reduced in this Reference
case. Also on the
primary energy level, there is significant restructuring. This can be seen from
the pronounced shifts in the shares of individual fuels up to 2050 (in terms of
primary energy):
Figure 9: Fuel mix development ·
RES gain 13 percentage points (pp) from 2005 (15
pp from 1990); making it the third most important primary energy source (after
oil and gas) in 2050 (when it reaches 20% of primary energy consumption);
·
Nuclear increases 2 pp from 2005 (4 pp from
1990), becoming more important than solid fuels (16% share in 2050); ·
Oil loses 5 pp (6 pp on 1990); oil share in 2050
amounts to only 32%; ·
Solids lose 7 pp from 2005 (16 pp from 1990)
reaching just 11% by 2050; ·
Gas declines least of all fossil fuels (-3 pp
from 2005 to 2050); the gas share in 2050 is still higher than in 1990 (3 pp)
because of the significant inroads made up to now; gas will represent more than
a fifth of the primary EU energy mix in 2050 (21%); ·
The dominance of fossil fuels diminishes with
their share falling from 83% and 79% in 1990 and 2005, respectively to only 64%
in 2050. While non fossil
fuels (RES and nuclear) account for 36% of primary energy in 2050, they reach a
significantly higher share in the 2050 electricity mix. Energy sources not
emitting CO2 supply 66% of electricity output, with 40% RES and 26% nuclear. In
addition, 18% of electricity would come from CCS plants, which do however still
emit some CO2.
Power generation
changes substantially in the projection period; the demand for electricity
continues rising and there is a considerable shift towards RES. As can be seen
in Figure 10 installation of capacity and generation from wind increase
steadily throughout the period. The incentives due to the RES target until 2020
are sufficient to make wind power generation competitive with other
technologies. Power generation and capacity from solids decrease throughout the
scenario due to the carbon prices that reduce the competitiveness of this
technology; gas power generation capacity increases, also as peak load
activated during back-up periods due to the increased amount of RES in the
system. As a result of the large increase in RES in power generation the load
factor of the system decreases due to the more widespread use of technologies
that run only a limited number of hours per year, such as wind.
Investment in power generation increases
over the projection period, driven by new investments in RES and gas.
Figure 10:
Electricity generation and net generation capacity The carbon
intensity of power generation reduces by over 75% in 2050 compared to 2010
levels, driven by the decreasing ETS cap and the rising carbon prices (see
Figure 11). In 2050 17.8% of electricity is generated through power plants
equipped with CCS. This corresponds to a CCS share in fossil fuel power
generation of over 50%. More than 50% of the potential emissions from the power
generation sector are captured. The efficiency of thermal electricity
production rises throughout the projection period due to the renewal of the
power plants, in particular investment in gas and in spite of CCS being widely
used in power generation. CHP plants are assumed to be integrated into the
competitive electricity markets, facilitated by the CHP Directive and their
share in electricity generation will rise. Incentives for CHP focus on
electricity, which implies that an increase in electricity production from CHP
power plants does not necessarily imply an increase in CHP capacity, given that
there is some flexibility in the power to heat ratio. Figure 11: Power generation indicators [124] The price of
electricity peaks in 2030 and decreases slightly thereafter. The price increase
up to 2030 is due to three main elements: the policies inducing investment in
RES, the ETS carbon price and the high fuel prices due to the world recovery
after the economic crisis. Thereafter electricity prices do not increase
further, indeed decline slightly, because of the technical improvements of
technologies that limit the effects of higher input fuel prices. Moreover,
taxes on fuels and ETS auction payments sink beyond 2030. This is due to the
declining cap and the introduction of CCS in particular, which limits emission
quantities and therefore auction revenues from the ETS despite rising ETS
prices. Whereas the CO2 price increases, the average levy on electricity
production, including the carbon free and decarbonised parts, declines in the
long term. Moreover, there is a continued decrease in the use of diesel oil in
power generation, which Member States may tax for environmental reasons. Figure 12: Cost components of average electricity price Distributed Heat Demand for
distributed heat demand rises in the Reference scenario throughout the
projection period; a strong increase can be observed between 2005 and 2020
reflecting the strong CHP promoting policies in all Member States, as well as
commercial opportunities that arise from gas based and biomass based CHP
technologies. It is assumed that the same policies continue at least until 2020
as part of the implementation of the 20-20-20 policy package. Among the CHP
promoting drivers worth mentioning are: the CHP directive (facilitating
absorption of CHP-electricity by wholesale markets), national policies
including feed-in tariffs and the ETS-carbon prices. CHP growth is limited by
the geographic possibilities of the distribution system. District heating
powered by boilers is a less attractive option, except in cases exploiting
local resources e.g. biomass, and existing distribution networks. In the longer term further
demand for distributed heat in the tertiary and residential sectors seem to
slow down as a result of the trend towards electrification (i.e. heat pumps)
and higher energy efficiency which limits the overall demand for heating. In
industry the increase in demand for distributed steam is projected to continue
in the future because the changes of industrial activity are favourable for
sectors with high demand for steam such as chemicals, food, drink, tobacco,
engineering and other industries. Furthermore the development of the market for
distributed steam and the possibilities of selling electricity to the wholesale
market favours the construction of CHP units of different sizes and
technologies in these industrial sectors Figure 13:
Heat demand by sector Transport Transport
accounts today for over 30% of final energy consumption. In a context of
growing demand for transport, final energy demand by transport is projected to
increase by 5% by 2030 to represent 32% of total final energy consumption. This
development is driven mainly by aviation and road freight transport. At the
same time, however, the energy use of passenger cars would drop by 11% between
2005 and 2030 due to the implementation of the Regulation setting CO2 emission
performance standards for new passenger cars[125].
After 2030 transport energy demand would increase only marginally up to 2050. The EU transport system
would remain extremely dependent on the use of fossil fuels. Oil products would
still represent 88% of the EU transport sector needs in 2030 and in 2050 in the
Reference scenario. Energy Imports/ Security of Supply Total energy
imports increase 6% from 2005 to 2050. The increase is rather limited despite
decreasing indigenous production, as rising gas and biomass imports are
compensated by a marked decline in coal imports while oil imports remain
broadly stable. Gas imports continue to
rise (28% from 2005 to 2050) due to declining production and despite decreasing
consumption. Import dependency rises only slightly above the present level (54%),
reaching 58% in 2020 and flattening out to 2050 thanks to more RES and nuclear. Emissions Energy related CO2 emissions decline much
faster than energy consumption, giving rise to some decarbonisation of the
energy system because of fuel switching to RES and nuclear at the expense of
solid fuels and oil: ·
Carbon intensity falls markedly. Producing one
unit of GDP in 2050 would lead to only 30% of energy related CO2 emissions that
were required per unit of GDP in 2005 and to just one fifth of what the CO2/GDP
indicator was in 1990. ·
Energy related CO2 emissions sink 40% below the
1990 level in 2050; thus the reference scenario represents about half of the
efforts needed by a developed economy if a global deal to limit climate warming
to 2°C will be achieved. ·
CO2 emissions from electricity and heat
generation fall almost 70% between 1990 and 2050 when they will make up 14 % of
all GHG emissions (down from 27 % in both 1990 and 2005); ·
Total GHG emissions decrease slightly less (39%)
by 2050 from 1990. Whereas non-CO2 emissions fall somewhat more, the total
emission decline is hampered by the very moderate decrease of CO2 from
industrial processes (CO2 not related to fuel combustion). Figure 14: CO2 emissions [126] The contribution to the emission reductions is driven by the ETS
sectors which decrease emissions by 48% between 2005 and 2050; on the contrary
the non-ETS sectors reduce by 21% compared to 2005. The share therefore shifts
from 56% of emissions in ETS sectors in 2005 to 46% in 2050. Most emissions
continue to be energy related emissions; energy related CO2 emissions decrease
by 39% in the time period from 2005 to 2050 whereas non-energy related CO2
emissions increase by 3%. Policy relevant indicators (and targets) The indicative
20% energy savings objective for 2020 would not be achieved under current
policies - not even by 2050. The reference case would deliver 10% less
energy consumed in 2020 compared to the 2007 projections. The reference case assumes
that the RES target is reached in 2020; the RES share (as defined in the RES
directive: as a percentage of gross final energy consumption) continues rising
to reach 24% in 2030 and 25% in 2050; further penetration of RES is
limited due to the assumed phasing out of operational aid to mature RES
technologies (see below). On the basis of final energy, the RES share gains
nevertheless 17 pp between 2005 and 2050 (13 pp on the basis of primary
energy). The ETS carbon price rises from 40 € (08)/tCO2 in 2030 to 52 € in
2040 and flattens out to 50 € in 2050 (after having triggered some
emission reducing restructuring in ETS sectors to comply with the dynamic
requirements of the Directive). These CO2 prices
seem high enough to trigger significant CCS investment from 2040 onwards;
whereas the CCS share in gross power generation reaches only 2% in 2030, it
rises to 12% in 2040 and 18% in 2050 (this percentage is 15% in net power
terms). CCS is mainly applied on solid fuel power generation, but also to gas
power plants towards the end of the projection period; by 2050 half of solid
fuel power capacities are equipped with CCS and 17% of gas power plants.
Generation by solid fuel CCS plants represents 10% of net total power
generation in 2050; the share of gas based CCS is 5% in 2050. The reference case assumes the overall GHG target, ETS cap and
non-ETS national targets to be achieved by 2020 but thereafter GHG reductions
fall short of what is required to mitigate climate change with a view to
reaching the 2 °C aim. While the reference case development lead to only 40%
less GHG emissions from 1990, more than twice as much might be needed, i.e.
minus 80-95% by developed economies.
2.2 Economic growth sensitivities
Economic
activity is a key driver of energy consumption and therefore emissions. It can
be expected that higher GDP growth rates will lead to higher energy consumption
and CO2 emissions and vice versa in the case of lower economic growth. Final
energy demand In fact, final
energy consumption in the high economic growth case is 7.3% higher in 2050 than
in the Reference case. This increase is however much lower than the increase in
GDP (+15.0%) due to important energy intensity improvements. These improvements
are linked in particular to the structure of the additional economic activity,
which takes place mainly in less energy intensive sectors, such as market
services and trade. Moreover, higher economic growth allows faster capital
turnover so that more energy efficient equipment enters the capital stock
sooner. Better capacity utilisation in case of high economic growth can also
add to this improvement in energy intensity. Higher household income also allows
for faster replacement with new, more energy efficient, appliances and cars,
although the overall demand of energy services would increase via more purchase
of higher performing items. CO2 emissions from final energy demand rise slightly less than
energy consumption thanks to some fuel switching to zero carbon (electricity
and heat) or low carbon fuels (gas). In 2050, CO2 emissions in final demand are
6.9% higher than in the Reference case (while energy demand and GDP are 7.3%
and 15% higher, respectively).
Figure 15: Final energy consumption broken down by sector in different economic
growth cases (in Mtoe)
Additional energy consumption is most pronounced in the services/agriculture
sector where demand in 2050 is 14.9% higher than in the Reference case. Again,
CO2 emissions rise less than energy consumption thanks to fuel switching
connected especially with more use of electricity[127]. In 2050, CO2
emissions from this sector exceed the Reference level by 12.6%, falling
nevertheless well below current levels (see table 6). With less pronounced expansion of economic activities in industry
there is lower, but still considerable, growth in final energy demand.
Increased industrial activities require more energy inputs so that industrial
energy demand exceeds Reference case levels in 2050 by 9.9%. Energy consumption
growth in industry is fossil fuel intensive with higher demand for carbon rich
coal in certain branches, which – under constant CO2 policies via the EU ETS -
leads to higher CO2 emissions, which exceed the Reference case level in 2050 by
12.0%. It is however worth noting that even with such high economic growth,
industrial CO2 emissions in 2050 remain below today's level. Table 6: CO2 emissions from final energy
demand sectors in different economic growth cases (in Million tonne CO2) || 1990 || 2005 || 2050 low growth || 2050 Reference || 2050 high growth Industry || 781 || 582 || 361 || 425 || 476 Services/agriculture || 301 || 262 || 136 || 158 || 178 Households || 499 || 487 || 292 || 297 || 303 Transport || 813 || 1053 || 951 || 1007 || 1061 Total final demand || 2394 || 2384 || 1740 || 1888 || 2018 Energy consumption of households rises much less in comparison to the
Reference case (by 1.9% in 2050) because many energy services, such as heating
and cooking are very income inelastic once certain comfort levels have been
reached. Moreover, increased purchases of appliances in the context of higher
incomes concern items with lower specific energy consumption compared with the
existing stock, a process that is being made more pronounced with eco-design
Regulations. Household CO2 emissions in 2050 are just 2% higher than in the Reference
case, but still a third lower than today. Transport energy demand exceeds Reference case levels by only 5.5%
in 2050. The reason is similar to that for households. Except for holiday
trips, passenger transport activity tends to grow slower than private incomes.
On the contrary, freight transport activity is much more influenced by the
level of economic activity. In the absence of major possibilities for fuel
switching under current trends and policies, higher transport energy demand
translates directly into higher CO2 emission (5.3% higher than Reference in
2050), keeping emissions at current levels in 2050. The improvement of carbon intensity in final energy demand under
high economic growth (lower CO2 growth than growth of final energy demand) is mainly
due to fuel switching towards electricity, which has been an ongoing trend with
higher incomes and structural change in the economy (e.g. more ICT based
services). Higher economic growth would lead to 8.8% higher electricity
consumption (compared with Reference) in 2050 with CO2 consequences for power
generation. Higher GDP growth leads to higher demand for heat (+ 7% in 2050) in
line with overall increase of final energy demand but significantly lower than
increase in GDP (+15%). The growth comes mainly from industry and tertiary sectors
reflecting higher economic activity in these two sectors. Residential demand is
rather stable (+1%) as heat is an essential need and not very elastic to
changes in household income. Supply increases from both CHP and district
heating units. Lower economic growth entails lower
energy consumption and emissions in all sectors. With GDP in 2050 remaining
14.7% below the Reference case level, there would be a reduction of final
energy demand by only 8.4%. Consequently, energy intensity (of final demand)
would deteriorate compared with the Reference case (and even more so in the
high growth case). Slower capital turnover in case of sluggish economic growth
is one reason for this as well as a lot of energy uses being rather income
inelastic, such as home heating and cooking. CO2 emission would decline to a
somewhat smaller extent than energy consumption (only by 7.8% in 2050 compared
with Reference). Low carbon content fuels reduce somewhat more than the more
carbon intensive ones, leading also to a slight worsening of carbon intensity
of final energy demand. Energy demand in services/agriculture would fall almost as much as
GDP in 2050 compared with the Reference case (-14.3%). The decline in CO2
emissions would be similar (-13.8%). Industrial energy consumption and emission
decrease also markedly with lower economic growth; they are down on the Reference
case in 2050 by 13.6% and 15.1%, respectively. CO2 emissions reduce somewhat
more than energy consumption, as fossil fuel demand drops slightly more than
demand for electricity and steam that are carbon free at use. By comparison, households and transport reaction to
lower GDP is much less pronounced. Household energy consumption and CO2
emissions are both down 2% on the Reference case 2050 level (i.e. substantially
less than the decline in GDP: almost -15%). Given that freight transport reacts
rather strongly to lower economic activity while passenger transport decreases
comparatively little with lower income, transport energy consumption falls 5.7%
below the 2050 reference case. CO2 emissions sink by almost the same percentage
(-5.5%), as possibilities for fuel switching are limited in a Reference case
environment without intensified climate or renewables policies. Lower economic growth leads to a rather strong reduction of
electricity demand, which remains 9.7% below the Reference case level in 2050,
still exhibiting healthy growth from current levels. Demand for distributed heat decreases by 10% in 2050 compared to the
Reference scenario mainly due to sharp decreases in tertiary (-14%) and
industry (-12%) sectors reflecting lower economic activity. Residential demand
reacts much less (-3%) as heat is an essential need and not very elastic to
changes in household income. There is a shift from CHP production (-11% in 2050
following lower electricity demand) to higher district heating units production
(+10%). Electricity
generation Electricity demand is particularly sensitive to variations in
economic activity. With limited possibilities for electricity imports this
translates into a similar requirement on the generation of electricity in the
EU. In the high economic growth case with 15% higher GDP in 2050, gross
electricity generation exceeds the 2050 reference case level by 9.2%.
Similarly, 14.7% lower economic activity in 2050 entails 10.2% less electricity
generation in 2050. Whereas the level of electricity generation strongly depends on the
magnitude of economic growth, its structure changes much less with lower or
higher GDP in 2030 and 2050. In 2030, the RES share in electricity varies
within a margin of 1 percentage point around 40.5% in the Reference case (see
table 7 on fuel shares in generation). This range becomes somewhat larger in
2050 (around 2 percentage points). With unchanged support for RES, higher
economic growth encourages in particular nuclear and fossil fuel generation,
leading to a somewhat lower RES share in power generation; it should be noted
that the absolute level of RES based electricity generation is significantly
higher with high economic growth (+5.3% in 2050 compared with Reference).
Table 7: Electricity related indicators under different economic growth
assumptions High economic growth brings about higher ETS prices (see table 7),
which in turn encourage CCS deployment. Combined with a higher share of fossil
fuel based power generation, this leads to CCS shares in power generation that
are higher than Reference in 2030. The increase is particularly pronounced in
2050, when 20% of total power generation would be equipped with CCS. On the
contrary, with low economic growth leading to low ETS prices as well as lower
fossil shares in power generation, CCS amounts to only 12% in 2050. Electricity prices are rather insensitive with respect to variations
in economic growth. Higher economic growth increases the 2030 average
electricity price slightly by 1.2%, while lower economic growth would lead to
an electricity price that is 0.4% below the Reference case price. These
electricity price modifications relate to the significant changes in ETS prices
brought about by variations in allowances demand due to growth of energy demand
and changing fossil fuel inputs to power. In 2050, when the variation in ETS
prices from the Reference case is pretty small, the variations in electricity
prices become marginal or even undetectable (electricity prices: minus 0.2%
with low GDP growth and 0.0% with high growth). Consequently, different
economic growth patterns do not alter the Reference case result that shows strongly
rising electricity prices up to 2030 in the context of higher fixed costs
following the restructuring of the power generation system for reaching the RES
and GHG targets, with a stabilisation of prices in the following two decades. Primary
energy consumption and energy intensity As was
discussed in the part on final energy demand, certain parts of energy
consumption react only to a limited extent to variations in economic growth;
this concerns in particular the household sector and also passenger transport.
Combined with more favourable conditions for improving energy efficiency under high
economic growth (bringing about, together with structural change in
economic activity, 5.8% better energy intensity), this leads to primary energy
demand rising much less than GDP. Compared with the Reference case, primary
energy demand increases 3.4% in 2030 while GDP is 6.3% higher, in 2050 primary
energy exceeds the Reference case by 8.4% with the economy being 15.0% larger
in terms of GDP. Also in the case of lower
economic growth, the effects on primary energy consumption are moderated by
the less income elastic consumption sectors (households, where heating needs
remain largely the same, as well as passenger transport having rather unchanged
needs for commuting, shopping and similar travelling). Moreover, lower capital
turnover with lower economic growth limits the opportunities for investing in
energy efficient items. As a result, energy intensity worsens by 6.4% in 2050.
Consequently, energy consumption sinks significantly less than GDP. With 7.7%
lower GDP in 2030 compared with the Reference case, primary energy is down
5.0%; in 2050 with 14.7% lower GDP compared with Reference there is a decline
of primary energy by just 9.3%. These energy
intensity effects (the improvement of 5.8% compared with Reference in 2050
under high economic growth and the 6.4% deterioration under sluggish GDP growth)
limit the impacts of alternative developments of GDP on CO2 emissions. Another
countervailing (or reinforcing) factor could come from changes in the fuel mix.
Different economic growth patterns exert somewhat different influences on
individual fuels. Fuel
mix and carbon intensity Under high economic
growth, oil and gas consumption grow less than overall energy consumption.
Nuclear reacts in a more pronounced way (above average) given its exclusive use
in power generation, which in turn is more sensitive to variations of GDP. Also
the reaction, to higher economic growth, of solids being mostly used in power
generation is fairly marked in 2050, given the absence of strong CO2 limitation
policies. On the assumption of unchanged RES support schemes, RES are not
particularly encouraged by higher economic growth. On the other hand, RES
are not particularly discouraged by lower economic growth. The negative
effects of such GDP losses on nuclear and solids are much stronger, exceeding
the percentage changes of total energy consumption. Oil and gas sink largely in
line with the reduction in total energy demand. This leads to the following
fuel shares in 2050: ·
Oil reaches shares between 31% and 32.5% under
high and low economic growth, respectively; ·
The gas share amounts to 20% in both growth
cases; ·
Solids account for 12% under high and 10.5%
under low economic growth; ·
The nuclear share reaches 17.5% under high and
16% under low economic growth ·
RES increase their share to 19.5% with high GDP
and even 21% with lower economic expansion; When evaluated in terms
of gross final energy consumption (definition in the RES Directive), the RES
shares amount to 25% under high and to 26% under low economic growth, which
represents increases from the 2005 level of between 16 and 18 pp in the high
and low GDP case, respectively. The RES share in transport is also pretty
robust across economic growth cases amounting to 13% in 2050 under the
different GDP assumptions, up half a percentage point from its level in 2030. While there are only
limited changes of fuel shares across economic growth cases, the evolution of
fuel shares over time, especially regarding RES, is pretty dynamic. Fossil
fuels in total lose around 16 percentage points between 2005 and 2050, with
somewhat higher losses for solids and oil. RES gain between 12.5 and 14
percentage points under high and low growth, respectively, while nuclear
accounts for the remaining gain.
Figure 16: Development of the fuel mix under high and low economic growth The overall result of these changes in the
fuel mix is that the carbon intensity improves with higher economic
growth, i.e. one unit of energy consumed results in slightly less CO2 emissions
under high growth (1.32 t CO2/toe in 2050) than in the Reference case (1.36 t
CO2/toe for the same year). The opposite effect on carbon intensity comes about
under lower economic growth, in which case one tonne of oil equivalent energy
consumption is associated with CO2 emissions of 1.45 tonnes, which equates to a
6.4% worsening. Total CO2 emissions These effects on energy
and carbon intensity and the existence of the ETS with a given emission cap
mean that GDP-induced changes in CO2 emissions are much less significant than
underlying changes in GDP. With 15% higher GDP in 2050, CO2 emissions are only
5.3% higher (both on Reference in 2050). Similarly, a GDP drop of 14.7% leads
to CO2 emissions that are only 3.3% lower in 2050. For 2030, a GDP rise on
Reference by 6.3% is associated with a 1.2% increase of CO2 emissions, while a
GDP loss of 7.7% entails 2.3% lower CO2 emissions (compared with Reference
case). It can be concluded
that emission results are pretty robust with respect to variations of GDP. This
reduces greatly one possible uncertainty regarding policy objectives on
emissions, as there are mechanisms (ETS, effects on energy intensity) that
limit the effects of variations in GDP levels on energy consumption and on CO2
emissions. This is important given the great uncertainty in projecting economic
activity for the coming years, let alone over the next four decades. While there are such
energy and carbon intensity effects, limiting the impact of economic activity
on CO2 emissions, alternative economic developments would still alter the
expected decline in CO2 emissions up to 2050. Such a decline of emissions
materialises under Reference case policies and is also brought about by Current
Policy Initiatives and even more so in decarbonisation scenarios. Emissions reduce
somewhat more over time with lower economic growth and somewhat less with
higher economic growth. Variations in CO2 reductions from 1990 levels are
however marginal in 2030 (around 1 percentage point more or less CO2 reduction
from Reference case level in 2030 with higher or lower growth), while GDP
varies 6-8 percentage points. In 2050 variations in the policy relevant
indicator: CO2 reductions from 1990 around what would materialise in the
reference case are still rather small (plus/minus 2-3 percentage points) - with
GDP varying 15 percentage points around the reference case level. Table 8: CO2 reduction below 1990 (index 1990 =100) and major drivers 1990 = 100 || 2030 || 2050 || High growth || Reference || Low growth || High growth || Reference || Low growth GDP || 220 || 207 || 191 || 319 || 277 || 236 Energy consumption || 108 || 104 || 99 || 115 || 106 || 96 CO2 emissions || 75 || 74 || 72 || 63 || 60 || 58 Again, the
possibilities for technically achieving GHG gas targets are not overly
dependent on the level of economic growth. In any case, it needs to be borne in
mind that GHG reduction requires innovation and investment, which is harder to
finance in a low economic growth environment. Overall, emission reduction may
be rather facilitated with sustained economic growth. Finally, regarding the
GHG emission reductions in ETS and non-ETS sectors, there is as to be
expected with a given emission cap particularly little variation across
economic growth cases for ETS sectors, whereas the GDP growth cases are somewhat
more contrasted regarding non-ETS emissions. Non-ETS GHG emissions
reduce comparatively little up to 2030 under high economic growth and stay
almost flat thereafter, whereas there is still a slight decrease in the
reference case. Nevertheless, these changes are much lower than the underlying
changes in GDP. In case of sluggish economic development, non-ETS emissions
would continue declining through 2050. However, the reduction from Reference in
2050 is much lower than the decline of GDP.
Energy imports and external dependency Total net energy
imports increase 16% from 2005 to 2050 under high economic growth, whereas they
decline 4% with low GDP (Reference case: 7% increase). Increasing imports of
both gas and biomass contribute to the import rise in both economic growth
cases, whereas imports of solid fuels decline both under high and low GDP
assumptions; oil imports increase with higher economic growth and decline under
low economic growth. Despite different
developments of energy imports in quantitative terms, import dependency as a
percentage of total supply stays constant at 58% in 2050 in the different
economic growth cases, marginally up from 57% in all cases in 2030 and an
estimated 54% in 2010.
Conclusions on economic growth variants The model based
analysis shows that policy relevant indicators are pretty robust against
variations in economic growth assumption, which is a significant result, given
the great uncertainty in making GDP projections for the next few years let
alone the next four decades. ·
CO2 reduction becomes only slightly more
difficult in technical terms under significantly higher economic growth.
Moreover, it is important to note in this context that higher economic growth
brings also more opportunities for innovation and investment in low carbon
technologies, thus facilitating climate change mitigation and dealing with the
competitiveness and energy security aspects. This result stems from
improvements in both energy and carbon intensity facilitated by the ETS
emission cap in place. ·
In a similar manner, the countervailing effects
through energy and carbon intensity are also present in the case of low
economic growth so that there is only limited further emission reduction
brought about by considerably lower GDP levels. ·
RES shares are pretty robust with respect to GDP
levels with variation spanning just 1 percentage point in 2050 for the RES
share in gross final energy demand (overall indicator of the RES Directive).
Similar results hold for the RES share transport and to a slightly lesser
extent for the RES-E share. ·
High economic growth gives rise to more energy
intensity improvements, but would render absolute energy saving objectives with
respect to e.g. a statistical year more difficult to achieve (with opposite
conclusions under low economic growth). Energy saving objectives, such as the
current one for 2020, are measured in absolute terms (without reference to
GDP). However, energy consumption reacts to economic growth; it rises with
higher GDP and declines in the opposite case. ·
Policy relevant indicators regarding
competitiveness are pretty much unaffected by economic growth; while ETS prices
differ to some extent the effects on electricity prices are marginal. ·
Exposure to external dependency measured as
share of energy imports in energy supplies is also unaffected by such
significant changes in GDP levels.
2.3 Energy import price sensitivities
Two such
sensitivities were modelled spanning a fairly wide range around the Reference
case price trajectories (see assumptions part above for details). The world oil
price in 2050 is assumed to be 28% higher than the Reference scenario in the
high price case, whereas it stays 34% below Reference in the low price case. In
the low price case, fossil fuel import prices remain broadly at the 2010 level;
coal prices are stable, oil has a small peak around 2030, whereas gas prices
remain weak over the next few years but recover to the 2010 level in the long
run. Higher import prices
bring about higher end-user prices discouraging energy use in the various
sectors and vice versa. Moreover, such developments change the competitive
position of individual fuels and technologies given all the other cost elements
in addition to fuel input costs in the formation of end-user prices (e.g.
capital costs and taxes). Effects are therefore differentiated according to
fuel and sector. For example, electricity prices are less affected than end
user prices of e.g. gas. Similarly, the percentage increase of end user prices
following higher import prices is much more pronounced in e.g. industry
compared with transport where existing high excise taxes moderate the increase
in percentage terms.
Energy consumption Under higher energy
import prices (oil price up 28% on Reference in 2050), final energy
consumption decreases by just 2.3% in 2050 from the Reference case. The
decline spans from 1.1% in transport to 4.7% in services/agriculture where more
electricity use, encouraged by higher prices of competing fuels, improves the
energy intensity of the sector (electricity at use having a very high
efficiency). Total electricity use in final energy consumption rises 1.0%
compared with Reference in 2050. Primary energy
demand decreases 2.0% in 2050 compared with
Reference, mirroring also the price induced effects in the energy
transformation sectors notably in power generation as well as price inelastic
parts, such as energy use as feedstock in the petrochemical industry. Whereas higher energy
prices exert only a limited effect on the level of energy consumption, the influence
on the fuel mix is important. Gas demand reacts most strongly to rising prices
given its use as a major input fuel for power generation where it competes with
coal, RES and nuclear, which are either not affected (RES, nuclear) or less
affected by rising fossil fuel import prices (see assumption part above). Gas
demand in 2050 would fall by 14.7% in 2050 compared with Reference. Oil demand
would also decline by 3.3% in 2050. The limited reaction is due to the
concentration of oil use on petrochemicals and transport, where price reactions
are small due to lack of substitutes and high existing tax levels in transport. The use of solid fuels
is encouraged despite higher import prices as gas competitiveness suffers in
particular as a result of the more pronounced price increases (this is also
linked to the cost structure in power generation where fuel costs are
relatively more important for gas given its lower capital costs than for coal
plants). Solid fuel use would increase 2.2% over Reference in 2050. Nuclear
benefits also from higher fossil fuel import prices gaining 4.4% on Reference
in 2050. Renewables win most, reaching 5.4% higher use compared with Reference
in 2050. In the case of low
energy import prices (-34% in 2050 from Reference), final energy demand
would increase by only 4.2% above Reference in 2050. The increase would be
particularly high in services/agriculture where higher gas and oil use would be
encouraged to the detriment of electricity. As electricity loses
competitiveness, it contributes less to overall energy intensity improvements.
Similar effects occur in households, while demand rises in the other sectors
stay well below average. Electricity demand under low prices sinks 2.2% in 2050
compared with Reference. Lower fossil fuel energy import prices entail 5%
decrease in heat and steam demand, mainly due to decrease in industry (-9%).
There is also a shift from CHP generation that looses 5% in 2050 to district
heating units (+14%). Primary energy
consumption increases 2.8% in 2050 compared with
Reference. The lower increase than for final energy is linked to lower
electricity demand, which entail somewhat lower electricity generation and
therefore transformation losses. Again, with limited
effects on overall energy consumption there are considerable changes in the
fuels mix. Gas consumption increases 23.0% over Reference in 2050, while oil
demand rises 4.8%. Solids, RES and nuclear, having all power generation as
major areas of use, are discouraged, also because their prices do not fall
(RES, nuclear) or to a lesser extent (solids). Solids use drops 7.3% below
Reference, nuclear declines by 7.6%, while RES reduce least below Reference in
2050 (-6.6%).
Fuel mix Consequently, the fuel
mix would be somewhat altered both in the high and in the low energy import
price cases. Table 9: Shares of energy sources in
primary energy consumption (in %) || 2005 || 2030 || 2050 || || High price || Ref. || Low price || High price || Ref. || Low price Oil || 37.1 || 32.0 || 32.8 || 32.4 || 31.3 || 31.8 || 32.4 Gas || 24.4 || 20.3 || 22.2 || 25.4 || 17.7 || 20.4 || 24.4 Solids || 17.5 || 13.0 || 12.4 || 11.7 || 11.8 || 11.4 || 10.2 Nuclear || 14.1 || 15.4 || 14.3 || 13.2 || 17.8 || 16.7 || 15.0 RES || 6.8 || 19.5 || 18.4 || 17.5 || 21.4 || 19.9 || 18.1 The marked variations
in the import prices give rise to rather limited changes in the fuel share
trends. Fossil fuels, especially solids, lose importance under both high and
low prices, while RES make substantial inroads und nuclear progresses in the
long term under high prices. Variations across
scenarios regarding the fuel shares are most important for gas, for which high
import prices could lead to a considerable decline in its contribution (falling
to only 17.7% in 2050 whereas low import prices could help maintain its current
share in 2050 and even increase it somewhat in 2030 to over a quarter). Power generation Fossil fuel import
prices render direct use of fuels more expensive. They result in lower
percentage price increases for electricity given the rather small part of fuel
input costs in total electricity costs. Under high fossil fuel prices,
electricity production is encouraged, whereas it falls below Reference case
under low import prices. RES and nuclear benefit
from high fossil fuel import prices. Low fossil fuel prices affect in
particular nuclear penetration. The RES share remains stable due to rather
unchanged production still benefiting from RES support and sinking overall
electricity generation (compared with Reference). The fossil fuel share in
power generation would go down to only 30% in 2050 under high energy import
prices, down from 55% in 2005. CCS penetration would
be somewhat encouraged by lower fossil fuel prices and corresponding higher ETS
carbon prices to ensure meeting the emission cap, leading to almost 4
percentage points more deployment in 2050. On the contrary high fossil fuel
prices would delay its introduction so that the CCS share would be about 3.5
percentage points lower in 2050 compared with Reference. Table 10: Electricity related indicators in different energy import
price cases Electricity prices are
lower than Reference with low import and therefore power generation input
prices, while the opposite is the case with high import prices. The time
profile of prices remains the same as under Reference case developments (see
above). CO2 emissions The changes in the fuel
mix and CCS penetration have important effects on CO2 emissions and ETS prices.
With significantly more zero carbon power generation under high fossil fuel
prices, ETS prices in the high import price case are somewhat below
Reference, despite lower CCS penetration and somewhat higher electricity
generation, given that with a constant ETS cap there is less demand for
allowances. Under low import prices the opposite trends materialise and ETS
prices are higher. In total, significant changes in the level of world energy
prices exert only a small influence on ETS prices, as long as the coal to gas
price ratio does not change significantly. In the high fossil
fuel price case, larger use of zero carbon fuels, moderated by effects on
coal and lignite consumption as well as lower CCS deployment and slightly lower
ETS prices bring about a marginal improvement in carbon intensity of primary
energy consumption (1.35 t CO2/toe instead of 1.36 t CO2/toe in 2050 in
Reference). Combined with the 2.0% improvement of energy intensity under high import
prices, this leads to a 2.7% reduction of CO2 emissions below Reference in
2050. In the low fossil
fuel price case, in which oil and gas prices remain virtually flat at 2010
level through 2050 rather than increasing as in the Reference case, there is a
more marked increase of CO2 emissions from Reference in 2050 (6.6%), in
particular due to increases of non-ETS emissions with lower fuel prices. This
is due to energy intensity deteriorating 2.8% compared with Reference in 2050
combined with a worsening of carbon intensity by 3.7%. Carbon intensity rises
to 1.45 t CO2/toe in 2050 as a result of delayed CCS and higher shares of gas
and of oil in the long run. It can therefore be
concluded that important further rises in oil and gas import prices, under a
given emission cap for power and energy intensive industries, lead to only
minor changes in CO2 emissions via limited effects on energy intensity and
marginal effects through changes in fuel mix and technology deployment. The CO2
effects of lower fossil fuel prices (virtual stabilisation of fossil fuel
import prices) appear to be proportionately more pronounced in the long term
than those from further price increases above Reference case levels. Table 11: CO2 reduction below 1990 (index 1990 =100) and major drivers 1990 = 100 || 2030 || 2050 || High prices || Reference || Low prices || High prices || Reference || Low prices Oil ($(08) / barrel) || 149 || 106 || 91 || 162 || 127 || 84 Energy consumption || 102 || 104 || 105 || 104 || 106 || 109 CO2 emissions || 71.7 || 74.0 || 76.1 || 57.9 || 59.6 || 63.5 || || || || || || Higher world energy
prices bring lower CO2 emissions including in the
sectors subject to ETS, which in turn reduces both demand for allowances and
their price, given the fixed cap. Conversely, lower fossil fuel prices increase
emissions and therefore demand for allowances, leading to higher ETS prices. In total, differences
in world energy prices exert only a minor influence on total CO2 emissions in
the EU. There are feedback mechanisms via ETS carbon prices. High fossil fuel
prices reduce demand and CO2 emissions and thereby carbon prices. With low
fossil fuel prices there is upward pressure on CO2 emissions and carbon prices
increase under ETS. Energy imports Net energy imports fall
6.9% below Reference in 2050 under high import prices. Gas imports are
particularly sensitive to variations in price levels (-15.7% on Reference in
2050) given the competitive environment in power generation and most final
demand sectors, where ample substitution possibilities exist. Oil use is less
flexible (transport, petrochemicals) so that oil imports decline by only 3.4%
in 2050. Solid fuel imports are even less affected (-2.0%), while imports of
biomass increase (4.9%) given higher demand. Low energy prices encourage significantly higher net energy imports, which in 2050
exceed the Reference level by 11.0%. Gas is the main driver for this increase,
with imports being 25.2% higher than Reference in 2050. Again, oil and coal
imports react more moderately, rising 5.0% and 6.5%, respectively. With lower
RES consumption, biomass imports would fall 11.5% below Reference in 2050. Import dependency in the high price case would stay at the current level throughout
the projection period reaching 54% in 2030 and 55%. Under low energy prices
import dependency would increase slightly reaching 58% in 2030 and 62% in 2050
(up over 4 percentage points from Reference). Energy costs Higher and lower fossil
fuel import prices impact strongly on the EU's external energy bill. With
fossil fuel prices exceeding significantly the Reference level (e.g. oil by 41%
and 28% in 2030 and 2050, respectively), the EU has additional costs over
Reference for fossil fuel imports of 158 bn € (08) in 2030 and of 148 bn € (08)
in 2050. The average annual extra fuel bill over the next 40 years amounts to
131 bn (08); it is worth noting that this is per year and in real terms. In the low fossil fuel
import price sensitivity, i.e. in case energy import prices remain essentially
at the 2010 level, there are considerable external fuel bill savings. The costs
for importing oil, gas and coal would decrease by 88 bn € (08) in 2030 and by
230 bn € (08) in 2050 with respect to Reference developments, in which fossil
fuel prices rise considerably. The average annual import cost saving in
2011-2050 would amount to 108 bn € (08). Total energy system
costs, i.e. the amount that the rest of the economy has to pay to the energy
system for the provision of energy, including capital, fuel and other costs,
amounts to 2582 bn € (08) on average in each year from 2011 to 2050. This
amount does not include auctioning payments, as these expenditures for
individual sectors are not costs for the economy as a whole, since the
auctioning revenues are recycled back to the economy. Moreover, this cost
concept excludes so called disutility costs.[128] With higher energy
import prices, total energy system costs are 187 bn € (08) per year larger throughout
the period 2011 to 2050. Under the hypothesis of low world fossil fuel prices,
average annual energy system costs would decrease by 155 bn € (08) per year
over the same period. Conclusions on import price
sensitivities High world
energy prices reduce CO2 and GHG emissions, while low prices exert the opposite
influence. However, there are several other effects via fuel mix, electricity
generation, ETS prices (given the same ETS cap across scenarios) and CCS
incentives that modify the overall effect while working in different
directions. High fossil fuel
prices lead to slightly higher electricity demand given the small reaction of
electricity prices to increasing fuel input prices in the presence of large
unrelated cost blocks such as capital costs, levies and taxes. Combined with a
significant increase in the share of zero carbon (non-fossil) fuels there is
lower demand for ETS allowances and therefore the ETS price decreases somewhat.
Lower fossil
fuel prices give rise to the opposite effects. Energy consumption and CO2
emissions rise, however moderated by lower competitiveness of non-fossil,
carbon free fuels. As an overall result, the effect of this fuel shift
outweighs the effects through lower electricity production and lower CCS share,
bringing about higher demand for allowances and slightly higher ETS prices. The sensitivity cases
show that significant changes in world energy prices exert only a small
influence on ETS prices as long as the gas to coal price ratio does not change
significantly. This conclusion on
rather limited effects of significant changes in world energy prices on EU GHG
emission can also be derived by considering the above results on energy and
carbon intensities. Important further rises in oil and gas import prices lead
to only minor changes in CO2 emissions via limited effects on energy intensity
and marginal effects through changes in fuel mix and technology deployment
(carbon intensity). The CO2 effects of lower fossil fuel prices (virtual
stabilisation of fossil fuel import prices) appear to be proportionately more
pronounced in the long term than those from further price increases above
Reference case levels. Regarding total GHG emission, the CO2 effects from
changes in fossil fuel prices would be limited through countervailing effects
of high fossil fuels prices through reduced carbon prices. High fossil fuel prices
limit business opportunities for energy exporters given that EU imports would
decrease, most so for natural gas. Conversely, with lower fossil fuel prices,
significantly higher gas deliveries to the EU can be assured. Import dependency
increases with low world energy prices, whereas it stays below Reference at the
current level throughout the projection period. Electricity prices are
significantly lower than Reference under low fossil fuel import prices, whereas
they are significantly higher in the case that high energy import prices
prevail. Moreover, high energy
import prices increase the EU’s external fuel bill substantially, thereby
weakening the competitiveness of the EU economy. Income that would have been
used to buy domestically produced goods and services would be diverted to
energy exporters with only a small part being recycled into higher EU exports
into these countries. On the contrary, lower fossil fuel prices give a boost to
the EU economy improving its competitiveness, also through lower costs and
inflation. The external energy
bill of the EU becomes significantly larger with high world energy prices (+132
bn € (08) per year over the next 40 years), whereas this bill was reduced by
109 bn € (08) annually in the case that fossil fuel prices remained broadly at
the level seen in 2010. Similarly, total energy system costs would be
significantly larger with high fossil fuel prices, whereas the rest of the
economy would need to pay to the energy system a significantly lower amount in
case of low world energy prices.
2.4 Current Policy Initiatives scenario
This scenario reflects
the Current Policy Initiatives (CPI) that are being discussed or undertaken in
the EU context with a view to the 2020 Energy Strategy. This scenario does not
attempt to give a full appreciation of all the results that might be expected
from the Energy Strategy, nor does it mirror in detail the – future – policy
adoption and implementation; it reflects the measures being proposed and
discussed (for details see above under assumptions). While the measures focus
on the medium term, the CPI scenario modelling evaluates also the long term
consequences up to 2050 and provides thereby another benchmark for comparison
with decarbonisation scenarios. Energy demand Primary energy
consumption under CPI declines pretty strongly
between 2005 and 2020 (-6.9%) and continues to do so through 2030 when it will
have fallen well below the 1990 level. There is a further decline up to 2050
(-11.6% from 2005), in which year energy consumption would be 8.4% lower than
in the Reference case. There are also marked changes from Reference in 2020
(-5.0%) and 2030 (-5.8%). These energy savings
from 2005 levels are brought about by a decline in final energy demand,
especially in the households and services/agriculture sectors, and by
efficiency improvements in energy transformation resulting from the
implementation of measures in the Energy Efficiency Plan. Bottom up energy
efficiency measures reverse the trend of ever increasing final consumer demand
witnessed so far in statistics and many trend scenarios, including the
Reference scenario in the period up to 2020. Total final
energy demand reduces 1.3% from 2005 by 2020. Reductions by 2030 amount
to 3.2%; thereafter final demand starts growing again slightly through 2050.
Nevertheless, in 2050, CPI final demand stays 5.3% below Reference (even 5.6%
for 2020 as CPI includes many energy efficiency policies to be implemented over
the next few years). Households show the greatest decrease below 2005 levels: by 6.1% up to 2020 as
well as by 8.5% and 10.0% until 2030 and 2050, respectively. In 2020 household
energy consumption is 8.9% below the Reference case, while this decline in 2050
amounts to 3.8%. This decline compared with Reference in 2050 is smaller given
that large parts of the energy efficiency potential captured in CPI in the
earlier years is taken up the Reference case in later years. Energy efficiency
measures linked especially to Eco-design regulations and savings obligations on
energy providers with respect to their customers are instrumental for this
pronounced decline in CPI. Moreover, the effects on final consumer prices
stemming from the proposed Energy taxation directive contribute towards
reducing energy consumption. Energy demand in services
and agriculture also decreases significantly by 5.5% and 6.7% in 2005-2020
and 2005-2030, respectively. After 2030, final energy demand in this sector
would resume its rising trend reflecting growing economic activity. In any
case, demand in services/agriculture falls well below Reference case levels
through 2050, with demand being 7.0% lower in 2050 and even 7.8 % lower in
2020. Eco-design measures, faster renovation rates for existing - especially
public - buildings, promotion of energy service companies as well as energy
savings obligations are key policy measures to bring about such savings. The
new energy taxation directive also contributes to this decline. Energy consumption in industry also
declines from 2005 levels: by 2.3% up to 2020 and by 3.7% up to 2030.
Thereafter, industrial energy demand starts growing slightly without reaching
again the current level. Industrial energy demand stays below Reference
scenario levels: by 5.5% in 2030 and 5.1% in 2050. Energy service companies,
eco-design and energy savings obligations are among the drivers for bringing
about such savings, which are somewhat moderated by healthy production growth
and by the feedbacks through lower ETS prices regarding certain industrial
branches. Such feedbacks stem from energy/electricity savings that reduce the
demand for ETS allowances and therefore ETS prices (see below). Figure 17: Final Energy Consumption by sector in
Current Policy Initiatives and Reference Scenarios (in Mtoe) Transport
energy consumption is comparatively little affected by current energy policy
initiatives. Energy consumption continues to increase, exceeding the 2005 level
by 5.6% in 2020. After 2025, transport energy consumption starts declining
slowly, returning the 2005 level by 2050. Compared with Reference, consumption
remains below the levels reached throughout the projection period (by 1.7% in
2030 and 5.7% in 2050). Changes from Reference are brought about in particular
by the proposed new energy taxation system and through the somewhat more
favourable policy environment for electric and plug-in hybrid vehicles, while
CO2 standards exert only a limited influence given that the CO2 from cars
regulation is already included in the Reference case. While final energy
demand for oil, gas and coal would continuously decline up to 2050, demand for
electricity, heat and RES would increase. Most important in absolute terms is
the increase in electricity demand, which rises 43% between 2005 and
2050. Nevertheless, electricity demand in CPI falls well below electricity use
in Reference, reflecting measures in the Energy Efficiency Plan and revised
Energy taxation Directive. CPI electricity consumption is down on Reference by
6.5% in 2030 and 4.3% in 2050. Demand for distributed
heat is rising compared to current level but is 1-2% lower than in the
Reference scenario reflecting effects of measures in the Energy Efficiency
Plan, in particular more efficient heating systems in houses. Heat demand in
residential sector is 7% lower in 2020 compared to the Reference scenario. The
difference is much lower towards the end of the projection period (1-2%) as the
measures included in the Energy Efficiency Plan target short to medium term. Power generation Rising electricity
demand over time will require a similar increase in power generation and a lot
of new investment in power generation and grids. Even though energy efficiency
measures bring about lower electricity demand and production compared with
Reference (see table 12) gross electricity production is expected to
increase 41% by 2050 under CPI. Electricity based on RES is expected to
make major inroads reaching a share in power generation of close to 50% in
2050. Table 12: Electricity related indicators in CPI scenario and
differences from Reference The CPI scenario takes
account of the post Fukushima policy change in Member States, notably the
abandoning of the nuclear programme in Italy and the new nuclear
approach in Germany modifying somewhat the previously decided nuclear phase-out
Moreover, it includes other changes and new initiatives, such as the nuclear
stress tests that tend to increase costs for new power plants and retrofitting.[129] The slightly higher
nuclear share in 2020 reflects lower total electricity production and the
modification in the nuclear phase-out provisions between the German nuclear law
before the extension of nuclear plant lifetimes in autumn 2010 (mirrored in the
Reference case) and the new schedule. The new phase-out schedule includes
faster closure of nuclear plants in the next few years, compensated by slightly
higher capacity around 2020, keeping cumulative allowed nuclear generation (in
TWh) at the same level. Fossil fuel based power
generation falls significantly throughout the projection period; its share
diminishes from 55% to just over 30% in 2050. Solid fuels lose most, with
losses for gas based power generation remaining rather limited. The
CPI scenario has significantly lower CCS penetration in 2020 compared to
the quite optimistic national plans as envisaged in 2009 (Reference scenario)
and rather moderate recent progress in demonstration plants. This concerns also
potential storage sites. In medium term, lower ETS price in the CPI scenario,
reflecting lower energy demand due to additional energy efficiency measures,
affects commercial viability of CCS. In the long term, lower numbers compared
with Reference are also a result of the strong decline in solid fuels and gas
based power generation. ETS prices are lower in
CPI compared with Reference in the medium to long term. The CCS incentive
through carbon prices is reduced by 20% from 40 €/tCO2 to 32€/t CO2 in 2030.
Consequently, the CCS share in CPI in 2030 amounts to 1% and rises thereafter
significantly with high ETS prices to reach 8% in 2050. The energy efficiency
measures in CPI cut electricity and fuel demand and the need for allowances,
which in a context of an unchanged ETS cap leads to lower ETS prices. This
limits - as a side effect - also the incentives for CCS. Average electricity
prices are slightly higher than Reference over the
projection period (0.8% in 2030 and 4.0% in 2050) reflecting the lower share of
nuclear post Fukushima and high investments for new electricity generation
capacity, especially RES.
Fuel mix These changes in the
demand side and in power generation have significant impacts on primary energy
consumption and the fuel mix. Primary energy demand declines 200 Mtoe up to
2050, when it remains 150 Mtoe below the Reference case level. In the long term to
2050, both fossil fuels and, to a limited extent, nuclear reduce their
importance in the fuel mix, with solids undergoing the greatest decline (minus
8 percentage points in 2005-2050). The share of nuclear is lower also in
comparison to the Reference scenario due to changes in nuclear assumptions.
RES are the clear winner of this structural change, making them in 2050 the
second most important fuel after oil. RES gain 16 percentage points from
today's level in terms of primary energy and about 20 percentage points when
accounted for in terms of gross final energy demand. Oil remains the most
important fuel throughout the projection period as the fuel mix in transport
remains largely unchanged. Nevertheless oil loses 5 percentage points by
2050.With primary energy demand declining, the fuels used most in sectors that
are least affected by current energy policies, such as oil in transport, are
able to score a slightly higher share in the fuel mix compared with Reference. Post Fukushima changes
in nuclear (discussed above) reduce the role on nuclear compared with
Reference. In this new policy environment gas and RES replace nuclear and
thereby increase their share over Reference scenario levels. These changes towards a
significantly greater RES contribution bring about an important decline in
carbon intensity over time (by a third between 2005 and 2050). However, with
respect to Reference, there is a certain increase in carbon intensity, given
that CPI relies less on nuclear and that CCS penetrates more slowly. Carbon
intensity in 2050 exceeds the Reference case level by 7.7%. Table 13: Fuel mix of primary energy consumption in CPI and Reference
CO2 and GHG emissions In spite of this
deterioration of carbon intensity there is a somewhat greater CO2 reduction in
CPI than in Reference; CO2 emissions in 2050 are slightly lower than in the
Reference scenario. This development is due to greater energy intensity
improvements brought about by vigorous energy efficiency policies, which
overcompensates the worsening of carbon intensity due especially to lower use
of nuclear and CCS. This energy intensity
effect on CO2 emissions is somewhat moderated by the effect of energy
efficiency on carbon intensity via ETS prices. Declining ETS prices, triggered
to some extent by lower energy demand, give rise to lower incentives for
investing in e.g. CCS and nuclear, thereby giving rise to somewhat higher
carbon intensity. Table 14: CO2 emissions and drivers in CPI and Reference scenarios Energy intensity
improvements are particularly pronounced in the earlier years of the projection
period thanks to vigorous new energy saving measures targeting in particular
the short and medium term. In total CO2 emissions reduce 40% between 2005 and
2050, up one percentage point from what would be achieved under reference case
developments. With respect to 1990 CO2 emissions in CPI decline by 41.3% up to
2050. The Reference scenario has a decrease of 40.4%. Total GHG emissions in
2050 decrease 38.6% below the 1990 level, which is slightly less than in the
Reference case (-39.7%), given the significantly lower carbon price until just
before 2050, reflecting especially successful energy efficiency policies. This
means, on the other hand, that total GHG emissions reduce faster in CPI than in
Reference in the time horizon to 2020 and also to 2030. Energy imports /
security of supply Lower energy demand and
the changes in the political environment after the Japanese nuclear accident of
March 2011 give rise to significant changes in EU energy production,
which is down on Reference by 9.0% in 2050. Nuclear production sinks 25.8%
compared with Reference in 2050, while RES production is 7.8% higher. Also gas
production is seen in a more favourable light (+4.0%). Despite lower
indigenous production, energy imports are 7.5% lower in 2050 than in the
Reference scenario due to the policy measures, notably on energy efficiency,
included in CPI. Nevertheless, net energy imports are expected to broadly
stabilise throughout the projection period (peaking in 2015, when they exceed
the 2005 level by 6.4%, before declining 7.5% up to 2050). Biomass and natural gas
imports increase significantly, whereas oil imports decline moderately and
solids see their imports sink considerably. Gas imports in 2050 are expected to
be 26% higher than they were in 2005. Oil imports decrease 6% over this period,
while solid fuel imports plummet 56%. Import dependency remains broadly unchanged from Reference case and also current
levels. Up to 2020, this indicator rises from 54% at present to reach 56%. This
is one percentage point less than in Reference, reflecting the impact of efficiency
measures mainly on imported fuels. In 2030, import dependency reaches 57.5%, up
one percentage point on Reference, which is largely a result of lower nuclear
availability. In 2050, this indicator amounts to 58% in both CPI and Reference. Conclusions on Current Policy
Initiatives scenario As a result of current
policy initiatives, energy consumption is expected to be reduced significantly.
The decline in both final and primary energy consumption is most pronounced in
the medium term, for which most of the measures have been designed. The
implementation of the Energy Efficiency Plan brings important reductions in
final energy demand, especially in the household and services/agriculture
sectors. In terms of primary
energy, consumption sinks throughout the projection period, falling below
the 1990 level by 2030 with a continuing decline thereafter. In 2050, energy
demand decreases 12% below the 2005 level. As a result, energy intensity
improves 1.8% pa, which is 0.2 percentage points up from the number in the
Reference case. This decline in energy
consumption is connected with significant changes in the fuel mix, which
are also linked, among other things, to post Fukushima changes in the policy
environment for nuclear energy in several Member States. Compared with
Reference, the contribution of nuclear and solid fuels declines, while oil, gas
and in particular RES account for higher shares in primary energy consumption
in 2050. In a comparison over
time, fossil fuels lose as much as 16 percentage points from 2005 to 2050, of
which solid fuels account for 8 percentage points, oil for 5 and gas for 3
percentage points. Renewables are the clear winner, benefiting from several
policies not even directly targeting RES and of course those measures included
in the 2008 Energy and climate package. The RES share in primary energy rises
16 percentage points, while the nuclear share remains almost constant (only a
slight decrease post Fukushima). The RES share in
gross final energy consumption increases 20 percentage points from 2005 by 2050
when it reaches 29%. Also the RES shares in transport and power generation rise
considerably reaching 49% and 20% in 2050, respectively. Taking a 2030
perspective, the overall RES share in final demand grows 16 percentage points to
reach 25% in 2030 under current policy initiatives. RES in transport account
for 13%. RES contribute 44% to power generation. Electricity
generation also falls compared with Reference,
given successfully implemented energy efficiency policies, but would exceed the
2005 level by 41% in 2050. Again, there are significant changes in the
generation mix, which also explain to a large extent the fuel mix changes at
the primary energy level. Almost half of power generation in 2050 would be
based on RES, up from just 14% in 2005. Nuclear loses around 10 percentage
points share in power generation in 2005-2050 given strongly rising electricity
production and the recent changes in the policy environment for nuclear. The
share of fossil fuel based electricity generation diminishes from 55% in 2050
to just over 30% in 2050 mainly due to reductions in solid fired power
generation. These changes in power
generation towards lower solid fuel contribution compared with Reference entail
lower demand for ETS allowances giving rise to lower ETS prices thus also
providing fewer incentives for CCS. As an overall result of these simultaneous
changes, the ETS price falls 20% below the Reference level in 2030. In 2030
almost 1% of gross power generation undergoes CCS, while this share rises to 8%
in 2050. Developments of the
fuel mix and the CCS penetration bring about a 0.9% pa decline in carbon
intensity from 2005 to 2050. This decline in carbon intensity is marginally
smaller than the one under Reference developments, reflecting in particular
post Fukushima changes for nuclear and lower medium term ETS prices following
strong energy efficiency measures, which, as an indirect effect, limit CCS
penetration. Nevertheless, energy
related CO2 emissions reduce slightly more than under Reference
developments. CO2 emissions in CPI sink 41.3% while the decline amounts to
40.4%. Total GHG emissions in CPI reduce 38.6% below 1990 by 2050. Total energy imports
broadly stabilise throughout the projection period, despite significant
increases in biomass and natural gas imports. Oil and notably solid fuels
import decline. Import dependency remains broadly unchanged from
Reference case and also current levels. The CPI scenario
involves higher system costs stemming notably from the additional investment
triggered through additional energy efficiency requirements and the
restructuring of the energy and transport systems including the lower nuclear
contribution due to upward revised costs and more Member States renouncing the
nuclear option. Moreover the inclusion of the Energy taxation directive adds to
these additional costs. Taking into account the fuel savings from energy
efficiency measures as well as the taxation induced savings, energy system
costs in the period 2011 to 2050 increase by an annual amount of bn 37 €(08).
These cost estimates do not consider possible changes in the utility levels of
consumers regarding the behavioural changes induced that are, in any case, not
directly measurable and can only be captured in the modelling indirectly via
the concept of compensating variations. Average electricity
prices rise at only a slightly faster pace compared with Reference
developments. In 2030, the average electricity price exceeds Reference by only
1%; this price increase becomes 4% in 2050. [1] http://ec.europa.eu/energy/strategies/consultations/20110307_roadmap_2050_en.htm [2] Questions 1, 5 and 7 were open questions and 2, 3, 4 and 6 were
multiple choice. [3] http://ec.europa.eu/energy/strategies/consultations/20110307_roadmap_2050_en.htm [4] COM(2011) 21, 26 January [5] European Council, Brussels, 29/30 October 2009, Presidency
conclusions. 15265/1/09 [6] European Parliament resolution of 4 February 2009 on "2050: The
future begins today – Recommendations for the EU's future integrated policy on
climate change; resolution of 11 March 2009 on an EU strategy for a
comprehensive climate change agreement in Copenhagen and the adequate provision
of financing for climate change policy; resolution of 25 November 2009 on the
EU strategy for the Copenhagen Conference on Climate Change (COP 15) [7] COM(2011)112, 8 March [8] Both roadmaps provide analysis under global climate action
assumption. [9] COM(2011)144, 28 March [10] COM(2010) 2020, EUROPE 2020 - A strategy for smart, sustainable and
inclusive growth [11] Energy related emissions account for almost 80% of the EU’s total
greenhouse gas emissions with the energy sector representing 31%; transport
19%; industry 13%; households 9% and others 7 %. [12] Other important issues related to the environmental impacts of our
energy system include air pollution, water pollution, wastes and impacts to
ecosystems and their services. Indeed, negative trends in land, water (fresh
and marine) and air quality depend on how energy is generated and used:
combustion processes, especially in the case of small unregulated biomass
plants, give rise to gaseous emissions and cause local air quality and regional
acidification; fossil and nuclear fuel cycles (as well as geothermal
production) emit some radiation and generate waste of different levels of
toxicity; intensification of biomass use (and of biomass imports) may lead to
forest degradation; bioliquids may lead to GHG emissions and direct and
indirect land use driving prices for food up globally; last but not least,
large hydropower dams flood land and may cause silting of rivers. [13] International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2010.
The EU contribution would decline from 13% of global CO2 at present to 8% in
2035 if all world regions are only pursuing current policies. [14] As regards market developments, questions about adequacy and
intensification of incentives for investments; future of support schemes for
RES and other technologies; support mechanisms/regulations for energy
efficiency; etc might arise. [15] SEC(2010) 1346 final, COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT State of play in the EU energy policy [16] COM(2006) 545. [17] 2009 Eurostat data are the latest official data. [18] The scenarios of the "Energy trends 2030" (update 2009)
are accessible at the following address:
http://ec.europa.eu/energy/observatory/trends_2030/doc/trends_to_2030_update_2009.pdf [19] COM (2011) 109 [20] Communication Energy Efficiency Plan 2011, SEC(2011) 280 final,
SEC(2011) 277 final, SEC(2011) 275 final, SEC(2011) 276 final, SEC(2011) 278
final, SEC(2011) 279 final [21] COM(2006) 851. [22] COM(2010) 84. [23] SEC(2010) 505. [24] Regulation (EC) No 663/2009 of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 13 July 2009 establishing a programme to aid economic recovery by
granting Community financial assistance to projects in the field of energy. [25] Regulation 994/2010 [26] Council Directive 2009/119/EC of 14 September 2009 imposing an
obligation on Member States to maintain minimum stocks of crude oil and / or
petroleum products. [27] Directive 2005/89/EC of the EP and of the Council of 18 January 2006
concerning measures to safeguard security of electricity supply and
infrastructure investment. [28] COM(2009) 192, The renewable energy progress report. [29] 2009/28. [30] Relates to share of biofuels and other renewable fuels in petrol and
diesel for transport [31] The 2020 target can be fulfilled through the use of renewable energy
in all types of transport. Energy use in maritime and air transport counts only
for the numerator, not the denominator. [32] "Heating" is a catch-all term for energy consumption that
is neither for transport nor in the form of electricity. [33] A 1997 White Paper established an indicative target of 12% of
primary energy consumption in 2010, which was used to derive the 21% target for
RES in power generation in 2010 [34] Council Directive 2009/71/Euratom of 25 June 2009 establishing
a Community framework for the nuclear safety of nuclear installations. [35] Directive 2009/31/EC on the geological storage of carbon dioxide
adopted as part of the Climate and Energy Package in 2009 [36] According to recent Technology Roadmap from IEA/ UNIDO,
CCS could reduce CO2 emissions by up to 4.0 gigatonnes annually by 2050 in
industrial applications, accounting for 9% of the reductions needed to halve
energy-related CO2 emissions by 2050. [37] Short-term projections for oil, gas and coal prices were slightly
revised according to the latest developments in the Reference scenario as
compared to the version used in the low carbon economy roadmap. [38] Regulation on CO2 from cars 2009/443/EC [39] This includes also some energy-related non-CO2 emissions, e.g.
methane emissions from coal mining and losses in gas distribution networks and
F-Gas emissions related to air conditioning and refrigeration. While the former
are estimated to decrease under current trends, the latter are projected to
increase considerably. For a more detailed analysis of the overall GHG
reduction efforts needed and of trends in non-CO2 emissions see the Impact
Assessment of the Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in
2050 (SEC(2011)288). [40] Correspondingly, a higher amount of banking of ETS allowances beyond
2020 takes place in the CPI scenario compared to the Reference scenario, rising
from around 2000 Mt to 2700 Mt in 2020 and reducing more slowly in the
post-2020 period. For a detailed interplay of ETS, other policies, carbon
prices and ETS allowance banking see SEC(2010)650 part 2. [41] The Reference scenario does not cover the European Commission CARS
21 (Competitive Automotive Regulatory System for the 21st century) initiative
and the recent initiatives of car manufacturers as regards electric vehicles. [42] The results diverge slightly from the assessment done for the Energy
Efficiency Directive. In fact, measures of the Energy Efficiency Directive were
taken but they are expected to produce effects over a longer period of time.
Also the stringency of energy efficiency measures is assumed to be slightly
lower. However, a more vigorous implementation of the Energy Efficiency
Directive is assumed in decarbonisation scenarios which all surpass the
indicative 20% target in the decade 2020-2030.
[43] Global developments as regards shale gas are taken into account when
projecting global gas prices. [44] Article 194: 1. In the
context of the establishment and functioning of the internal market and with
regard for the need to preserve and improve the environment, Union policy on
energy shall aim, in a spirit of solidarity between Member States, to: (a) ensure
the functioning of the energy market; (b) ensure
security of energy supply in the Union; (c) promote
energy efficiency and energy saving and the development of new and renewable
forms of energy; (d) promote
the interconnection of energy networks. [45] COM (2011)112 [46] Please see IA on Low carbon economy Roadmap for the analysis of
impacts of decarbonisation on energy import prices SEC(2011)288. [47] Impact assessment report SEC(2011)288 final, section 5) [48] European Commission: Communication 'Analysis of options to move
beyond 20% greenhouse gas emission reductions and assessing the risk of carbon
leakage' (COM(2010) 265 final). Background information and analysis, Part II
(SEC(2010) 650).;
http://ec.europa.eu/clima/documentation/international/docs/26-05-2010working_doc2_en.pdf [49] For details and the implications on the cost and benefit
quantifications please refer to Annex 1, part A, point 1.4 and part B, points
1.4 and 2.7. [50] Used also in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap and Transport White
Paper. [51] This analysis does not prejudge the final outcome of the legislation
process on these policies and will not be able to deliver a quantitative
assessment of the consequences of the Energy 2020 strategy. [52] Scenario 3 reproduces "Effective and Widely Accepted
Technologies" scenario used in Low Carbon Economy roadmap and Transport
White Paper on the basis of scenario 1bis. [53] Global climate action requires that each region uses
its RES potential. Moreover, geopolitical and security of supply risks can
justify the reliance on domestic energy sources. [54] The scenarios are based on model assumptions, which are
consistent with the input for the 2050 Low Carbon Economy Roadmap. Recognising
the magnitude of the decarbonisation challenge, which implies a reversal of a
secular trend towards ever increasing energy consumption, this Energy Roadmap
has adopted a rather conservative approach as regards the effectiveness of
policy instruments in terms of behavioural change. However, the Roadmap results
should not be read as implying that the 20% energy efficiency target for 2020
cannot be reached effectively. Greater effects of the Energy Efficiency Plan
are possible if the Energy Efficiency Directive is adopted swiftly and
completely, followed up by vigorous implementation and marked change in the
energy consumption decision making of individuals and companies. In modelling
terms this means a significant lowering of the discount rate used in energy
consumption decision making of hundreds of millions of consumers. [55] As specified in the RES directive for the calculation of the 20%
target by 2020. [56] With much more variable supply and demand some electricity produced
needs to be stored. Losses, linked to storage, lead to lower consumption than
production of electricity. When calculating the RES-E share in line with the
RES directive (focussing on gross final energy consumption i.e. excluding
energy losses to pumped storage and hydrogen storage), the RES share in
electricity consumption amounts to 97%. [57] For a detailed analysis see SEC(2011)288, section
5.2.14. [58] For example by making sure that rich habitats are not fragmented,
ensuring the integrity of Natura 2000 sites and the coherence and connectivity
of its network. Green Infrastructure developments can lead to win-win
situations, where negative environmental impacts of energy-related
infrastructure can be mitigated while adaptation to climate change is enhanced,
as well as public acceptance of alternative energy projects. [59] Annex 1, table 37, pages 83 [60] The European Environment Agency assessed the amount of
biomass that could be used in an environmental sustainable way in EU-25 by 2030
at 295 Mtoe. [61] .For a detailed
analysis of these interactions see SEC(2011)288, sections 5.1.4, 5.2.7 and
5.2.10. [62] SEC(2010) 650, Commission Staff Working Document accompanying the
Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the
European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions -
Analysis of options to move beyond 20% greenhouse gas emission reductions and
assessing the risk of carbon leakage: Background information and analysis. [63] For
further analysis of the role of energy price shocks see SEC(2011)288. [64] "Roadmap 2050: a practical guide to a prosperous, low-carbon Europe; Volume 1 – Technical and Economic Analysis" (European Climate Foundation,
2009) [65] As
discussed in Annex 1, this represents a cautious approach. Whereas investment
costs are displayed at their actual maximum levels, future benefits are priced
in at a lower level. [66] Disutility costs are a concept that captures losses in utility from
adaptations of individuals to policy impulses or other influences through
changing behaviour and energy consumption patterns that might bring them on a
lower level in their utility function. The PRIMES model has a micro-economic
foundation which allows it to deal with utility maximisation and to calculate
such perceived utility losses via the concept of compensating variations. While
these costs capture relevant short term transition costs, their relevance and
appropriate calculation over a long time horizon is challenging. This concept
has to assume that preferences and values remain the same, even over 40 years,
and it compares utility with a hypothetical state of no policy or no change in
framework conditions. Examples of such decreases in utility are lowering
thermostat in space heating, reducing cooling services in offices, switching
lights off, staying at home instead of travelling, using a bicycle instead of a
car, etc. [67] Auction payments are expenditures for individual sectors, and are
not considered as costs for the economy as a whole, since the auctioning
revenues are assumed to be recycled back into the economy in a neutral way.
However, one could also have taken account of the shadow costs in making public
transfers and it is not guaranteed that this transfer would be purely neutral
for the economy, as shown by the discussions on the optimal reallocation of
auction revenues (see above). [68] When taking a macroeconomic view, i.e. by excluding auctioning
revenue that are recycled to the economy, and excluding disutility costs, the
Delayed CCS scenario has lower costs than the Diversified supply technologies
scenario. However, when the economic actors' perspective is taken, i.e.
auctioning and disutility costs are included, the lowest system costs
materialise in the Diversified supply technology scenario (for details see
Annex 1, part B, point 2.7). [69] The difference in ETS prices compared to Effective and Widely
accepted technologies presented in the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap is due to
additional energy efficiency measures, the revised Energy Taxation Directive
and changed assumptions for nuclear after Fukushima. The share of nuclear is
considerably lower than in decarbonisation scenarios presented in the Low
Carbon Economy Roadmap. Current Policy Initiatives and all policy scenarios in
this exercise are based on revised assumptions on nuclear (abandonment of the
nuclear programme in Italy, change of nuclear policy in Germany, no new nuclear
plants in Belgium and upwards revision of costs for nuclear power plants).
Moreover, electricity demand is lower due to stringent energy efficiency
measures. In addition, assumptions on the potential of electricity in transport
were revised, following more closely the scenarios developed in the White Paper
on Transport leading to lower utilisation rate of nuclear power plants than in
the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap Scenarios. Electric vehicles flatten electricity
demand and thus incentivise baseload power generation. [70] A dedicated infrastructure modelling was performed with the PRIMES
model and the main results are presented in Annex 1. [71] The modelling does not show this situation arising because the model
assumes full cost recovery of capital investments in all scenarios [72] Europe 2020 COM(2010) 2020 [73] EU 2020 Flagship Initiative Innovation Union SEC(2010) 1161 [74] The fastest previous scale-up was for electricity generation from
nuclear power, which expanded at a rate of approximately 25-30% per year
between 1960 and 1980 globally. The decarbonisation scenarios almost all
envisage a major roll-out of CCS starting after 2030 and reaching average rates
of up to 36% per year in 2030-2040 (20% pa in 2030-2050); similarly but closer
to now, certain RES technologies could be soaring, especially from 2010 to 2030
at average annual rates of up to 20% and 15% per year for off-shore wind and
solar electricity, respectively. [75] No further analysis has been done as regards the impact of increased
revenues of oil and gas exporting countries on imports from the EU. [76] The social dimension might be better tackled in a
decarbonisation roadmap treating all the interdependencies among sectors such
as energy, transport, industry and agriculture than in a sectoral roadmap
dealing with energy only. [77] See literature review section in the report "Studies on
Sustainability Issues- Green Jobs; Trade and Labour" (2011) commissioned
by the European Commission, DG Employment. [78] "Studies on Sustainability Issues- Green Jobs; Trade and
Labour" (2011) commissioned by the European Commission. The leading
objective has been to analyse the employment consequences of the implementation
of policies to achieve the key EU environmental targets of a 20% cut in
emissions of GHG by 2020 compared to 1990 levels (increasing to 30% if other
countries make similar commitments), a 20% increase in the share of renewable
energy, and the objective of a 20% cut in energy consumption (the 20-20-20
targets). [79] "EmployRES: The impact of renewable energy policy on economic
growth and employment in the European Union" (2009), commissioned by the
European Commission, DG Transport and Energy [80] "Roadmap 2050: a practical guide to a prosperous, low-carbon
Europe; Volume 1 – Technical and Economic Analysis" (European Climate
Foundation, 2009) [81] SEC(2011) 288 final page 44 and 90-91 [82] High RES scenario relies mainly on domestic sources of renewable
energy. [83] Please see more specialised indicators in Annex 1, part B, section
2.5. [84] Results for primary energy consumption should not be
confused with the energy saving targets for 2020 which is calculated against
the projected consumption for 2020. Relating this savings objective to energy consumption in 2005, similar to the calculations in the
scenarios, would be equivalent to a saving target of 14% in 2020. [85] The price projections ensure full recovery of costs
associated with electricity supply in order to depict scenarios in which the
investment in production, storage, grids, taxes, etc are fully covered by
revenues from selling electricity. In that sense they are not forecasts of
future electricity prices, as systems may evolve, in which, contrary to the
overall practice today, such investments are partly remunerated by other
schemes. [86] A literature review on climate change impacts in the
European energy supply sector as part of the European Commission contract
"Climate proofing EU policies" has identified the following main
impacts: • Cooling water
constraints for thermal power generation (especially during heat waves), with
nuclear appearing to be the most vulnerable technology • Damage to offshore or
coastal production facilities due to sea level rise and storm surges • Damage to
transmission and distribution lines due to storm events, flooding • Unpredictable
hydropower potential • Affected yield in renewable
energy sector (hydropower in Southern Europe, possibly biofuels due to vector
diseases and forest fires) • Melting permafrost
affecting energy production and distribution in cold climates • Damages and output
constraints in wind energy due to storms and increased average wind speed [87] It has been considered more useful to check scenarios against
objectives of the EU energy policy than against those of the Roadmap that focus
on instruments and processes to deliver more certainty to investors. [88] Scenarios for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap of March
2011 show the additional costs of delayed action. [89] European Commission, DG Economic and Financial Affairs:
2009 Ageing Report: Economic and budgetary projections for the EU-27 Member
States (2008-2060). EUROPEAN ECONOMY 2|2009,
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication14992_en.pdf. The
“baseline” scenario of this report has been established by the DG Economic and
Financial Affairs, the Economic Policy Committee, with the support of Member
States experts, and has been endorsed by the ECOFIN Council. [90] European Commission, DG Economic and Financial Affairs:
2009 Ageing Report: Economic and budgetary projections for the EU-27 Member
States (2008-2060). EUROPEAN ECONOMY 2|2009, http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication14992_en.pdf [91] EU energy trends to 2030, Directorate General for Energy in
collaboration with Climate Action DG and Transport DG, 2010 [92] COM(2011)112, 8 March 2011 [93] Communication from the Commission: Europe 2020. A
strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive growth. COM(2010)2020, Brussels, 3.3.2010. [94] European Commission, DG Economic and Financial Affairs:
Sustainability Report 2009. EUROPEAN ECONOMY 9|2009,
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication15998_en.pdf. [95] European Commission, DG Economic and Financial Affairs:
Public Finances in EMU 2010. EUROPEAN ECONOMY 4|2010,
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2010/pdf/ee-2010-4_en.pdf. [96] This refers to energy projections from the US Energy Information
Administration (EIA) and the International Energy Agency (IEA). The EIA
International Energy Outlook 2009 assumed 130 $/barrel in 2007 prices for 2030,
equivalent to 134 $/barrel in 2008 prices. The IEA World Energy Outlook 2009
assumed 115 $/barrel in 2008 prices for 2030. [97] As the model operates in constant euros, for which the exchange
rate is assumed to depreciate from the currently high levels of around 1.4 $/€,
there will be a somewhat faster increase in energy prices in euros than in
dollar. [98] The price
sensitivities presented in this IA complement those made in the Impact
Assessment for the Low Carbon Economy Roadmap, which included an oil shock case
in 2030 with oil prices suddenly rising to 212 $(08)/barrel, representing a
doubling from Reference case in that year. In the following years, the genuine
oil shock case depicts some oil demand reaction and a subsequent gradual
decline of oil prices towards Reference case levels without reaching those, not
even in 2050 (still being 18% higher). On the contrary, an alternative
development was also examined, in which the oil prices would stay at the high
212 $/barrel level throughout the rest of the projection period. In the latter
case, the 2050 oil price exceeds the Reference case level still by two thirds.
(Results can be found in the above mentioned Impact Assessment and are not
repeated here). [99] Circulator is an impeller pump designed for use in heating and
cooling systems. Glandless standalone circulators and glandless circulators
integrated in products are covered by this regulation. [100] For the allocation
regime for allowances in 2010, the current system based on National Allocation
Plans and essentially cost-free allowances is assumed, with price effects
stemming from different investment and dispatch patterns triggered by need to
submit allowances. For the further time periods, in the power sector there will
be a gradual introduction of full auctioning, which will be fully applicable
from 2020 onwards, in line with the specifications of the amended ETS
directive. For the other sectors (aviation and industry), the
baseline follows a conservative approach which reflects the specifications in
the directive on the evolution of auctioning shares and the provisions for free
allocation for energy intensive sectors based on benchmarking. [101] Compared with the Reference scenario to 2030, in the Reference
scenario to 2050, the expectation of high ETS allowance prices in future and
the possibility to bank allowances leads to higher prices in 2025 and 2030 than
in the Reference scenario up to 2030. [102] On 28 October 2009 the European Commission adopted a new
legislative proposal to reduce CO2 emissions from light commercial vehicles
(vans). The draft legislation is closely modelled on the legislation on the CO2
emissions from passenger cars (Regulation 443/2009) and it is part of the
Integrated Approach taken by the Commission in its revised strategy to reduce
CO2 emissions from cars and light commercial vehicles (COM(2007) 19 final). Not
including this proposal in the 2050 Reference scenario could lead to an
increased bias towards vans, which is not justified given the likelihood of its
adoption towards the end of 2010/beginning of 2011. [103] NER covers 300 million allowances set aside in the new
entrants reserve of the EU ETS for the co-financing of commercial demonstration
projects of environmentally safe CCS as well as innovative RES technologies [104] All measures included in the scenario underpinning the
IA for the Energy efficiency Directive are included. Energy (saving) results
can differ given different framework conditions flowing from all the additional
assumptions above. Moreover, it should be considered that scenario 3 Energy
Efficiency should show contrasted results in terms of energy consumption so
that a significant individual contribution of energy efficiency towards decarbonisation
can be identified. Scenario 1bis includes some adjustments to reflect somewhat
less optimistic expectations for penetration of energy efficiency
products/renovation of buildings. [105] In Europe, the New European Driving Cycle is the official driving
cycle used for vehicle type approval. According to a study carried out for the
Commission in 2009, there is some discrepancy (typically 10-20%) between the
fuel consumption as measured on the NEDC and that in real world driving.
Source: Sharpe, R.B.A. (2009) Technical options for fossil fuel based road
transport, Paper produced as part of contract ENV.C.3/SER/2008/0053 between
European Commission Directorate-General Environment and AEA Technology plc;
http://eutransportghg2050.eu/cms/assets/EU-Transport-GHG-2050-Paper-1-Technical-options-for-f-fuel-road-transport-11-02-10.pdf,
p.9 [106] Regulation (EU) No 510/2011 of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 11 May 2011, setting emission performance standards for new light
commercial vehicles as part of the Union's integrated approach to reduce CO2
emissions from light-duty vehicles [107] International Energy Agency (2009), Transport, Energy and CO2: Moving
Towards Sustainability. [108] NEMS database and reports, IEA studies, industry
surveys, EU project reports, etc. [109] IEA (2010), Projected Costs of Generating
Electricity, 2010 Edition. IEA, NEA, OECD, Paris [110] Energy Information
Administration, Annual Energy Outlook 2010, December 2009, DOE/EIA-0383 (2009) [111] Definitions in the studies may not totally overlap, in
particular for fixed and variable costs. [112] The exchange rates used are:
1.34USD/EUR (USD2010 to EUR2010). [113] Abbreviations in the figure: ST Coal: Steam Turbine
Coal; CCS: Carbone Capture and Storage; PC with CCS: pulverised coal with CCS;
IGCC: Integrated Gasification Combine Cycle; GTCC: Gas Turbine Combined Cycle;
PV: photovoltaic. [114] Greater deployment of RES or other low carbon technologies
in decarbonisation scenarios is due to carbon prices/values as well as other
specific changes (including higher RES values) depending on the scenario, but
does not involve greater operational aid. [115] Eichhammer et al. (2009), Study on the Energy Savings
Potentials in EU Member States, Candidate Countries and EEA Countries Final
Report, Fraunhofer ISI and ENERDATA and ISIS and Technical University Vienna and WI, March 2009. [116] Due to the variety of appliances available (in
particular for boilers) the values here are chosen as examples and due to lack
of data it is possible that the typical appliances of the different sources do
not correspond entirely to the PRIMES technology. [117] Please refer to the PRIMES model description available
at : http://www.e3mlab.ntua.gr/e3mlab/PRIMES%20Manual/The_PRIMES_MODEL_2010.pdf [118] Note: for EV 1l/100km is
approximately 8.5kWh/100km; an exchange rate USD to EUR of 1.2USD/EUR has been
used. [119] The discount rate for private
individuals includes risk aversion; risk premiums are added for other actors
and are technology specific. [120] As part of the European Commission contract "Climate
proofing EU policies". [121] Interim results of the FP7 project "European
RESPONSES to climate change" [122] … and perhaps ever – except for much higher economic
growth materialising (see below under sensitivities) [123] Freight transport does not include international
maritime. [124] The percentage of emissions
captured is calculated as the ratio between the total emissions captured and
the potential emissions of thermal power plants, which are the remaining
emissions plus the emissions captured. [125] Regulation (EC) No 443/2009 of the European Parliament
and of the Council of 23 April 2009 setting emission performance standards for
new passenger cars as part of the Community’s integrated approach to reduce CO2
emissions from light-duty vehicles, OJ L 140, 5.6.2009, p. 1–15. [126] The split between ETS and non-ETS emissions reflects
over the whole period the ETS scope as valid from 2013 onwards. [127] However, it should be noted that such higher electricity
demand could lead to higher CO2 emissions, depending on the fuel input
structure, which are accounted for under power generation (see below) [128] Disutility costs are a concept that tries to capture losses in
utility from adaptations of individuals to policy impulses or other influences
through changing behaviour and energy consumption patterns that might bring
them on a lower level in their utility function. The PRIMES model, having a
micro-economic foundation, deals with utility maximisation and can calculate
such perceived utility losses via the concept of compensating variations
(amount of additional income that would bring the individual on the same level
of utility as experienced before the change). However, this concept has to
assume that preferences and values remain the same, even over 40 years, and has
to compare utility with a hypothetical state of no policy or no change in the
framework conditions. Numbers in particular in the longer term are uncertain.
The numbers shown above relate to costs that reflect actual payments. [129] There are
slightly higher risk premiums for new nuclear investment in this scenario,
considering that investors might factor into their decisions the possibility
that the policy reaction to any hypothetical further nuclear accident may
affect the nuclear plants under investment consideration, even though such an
accident could happen rather far away geographically. Requiring thereby a
slightly higher return on investment to cover this political risk has also
certain effects on new nuclear investment. As a result of these changes in the
policy environment, the nuclear share is somewhat lower than Reference in the
long term, for which the Italian withdrawal from nuclear is particularly
important. Moreover, lower ETS prices in CPI reduce the economic advantages
connected to nuclear investments.