This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 02004R0138-20220502
Regulation (EC) No 138/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 5 December 2003 on the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community (Text with EEA relevance)Text with EEA relevance
Consolidated text: Regulation (EC) No 138/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 5 December 2003 on the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community (Text with EEA relevance)Text with EEA relevance
Regulation (EC) No 138/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 5 December 2003 on the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community (Text with EEA relevance)Text with EEA relevance
02004R0138 — EN — 02.05.2022 — 007.001
This text is meant purely as a documentation tool and has no legal effect. The Union's institutions do not assume any liability for its contents. The authentic versions of the relevant acts, including their preambles, are those published in the Official Journal of the European Union and available in EUR-Lex. Those official texts are directly accessible through the links embedded in this document
REGULATION (EC) No 138/2004 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 5 December 2003 on the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community (OJ L 033 5.2.2004, p. 1) |
Amended by:
|
|
Official Journal |
||
No |
page |
date |
||
L 52 |
9 |
25.2.2005 |
||
L 168 |
14 |
21.6.2006 |
||
L 65 |
5 |
8.3.2008 |
||
REGULATION (EC) No 1137/2008 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 22 October 2008 |
L 311 |
1 |
21.11.2008 |
|
REGULATION (EU) No 1350/2013 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 11 December 2013 |
L 351 |
1 |
21.12.2013 |
|
COMMISSION DELEGATED REGULATION (EU) 2019/280 of 3 December 2018 |
L 47 |
7 |
19.2.2019 |
|
REGULATION (EU) 2022/590 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 6 April 2022 |
L 114 |
1 |
12.4.2022 |
REGULATION (EC) No 138/2004 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL
of 5 December 2003
on the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community
(Text with EEA relevance)
Article 1
Subject matter
This Regulation sets up the economic accounts for agriculture in the Community (hereinafter referred to as ‘EAA’), by providing for:
an EAA methodology (common standards, definitions, classifications and accounting rules), intended to be used for compiling accounts on comparable bases for the purposes of the Community, and for the transmission of data in accordance with Article 3;
time limits for the transmission of the agricultural accounts compiled in accordance with the EAA methodology.
Article 2
Methodology
Those delegated acts shall be adopted only where they do not change the underlying concepts in Annex I, they do not require additional resources for producers within the European Statistical System for their implementation and they do not impose a significant additional burden on Member States or on the respondents.
The Commission shall duly justify the statistical actions provided for in those delegated acts, using, where appropriate, input from relevant experts based on a cost-effectiveness analysis, including an assessment of the burden on the respondents and of the production costs, as referred to in point (c) of Article 14(3) of Regulation (EC) No 223/2009 of the European Parliament and of the Council ( 1 ).
Article 3
Transmission to the Commission
However, the first transmission of data for the regional economic accounts for agriculture (‘REAA’) at NUTS 2 level within the meaning of Regulation (EC) No 1059/2003 of the European Parliament and of the Council ( 2 ) shall take place by 30 September 2023.
Those delegated acts shall not impose a significant additional burden on the Member States or on the respondents.
The Commission shall duly justify the statistical actions provided for in those delegated acts, using, where appropriate, input from relevant experts based on a cost-effectiveness analysis, including an assessment of the burden on the respondents and of the production costs, as referred to in point (c) of Article 14(3) of Regulation (EC) No 223/2009.
Article 3a
Dissemination of statistics
Without prejudice to Regulation (EC) No 1367/2006 of the European Parliament and of the Council ( 3 ) and Regulation (EC) No 223/2009, the Commission (Eurostat) shall disseminate the data transmitted to it in accordance with Article 3 of this Regulation online, free of charge.
Article 3b
Quality assessment
Article 4
Exercise of the delegation
Article 4a
Committee procedure
Article 4b
Derogations
Article 5
Final provision
This Regulation shall enter into force on the 20th day following that of its publication in the Official Journal of the European Union.
This Regulation shall be binding in its entirety and directly applicable in all Member States.
ANNEX I
ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS FOR AGRICULTURE
(EAA)
CONTENTS |
|
Foreword |
|
I. |
General features of the accounts |
A. |
Introduction |
B. |
The basic unit and the agricultural industry |
1. |
Basic unit |
2. |
Agricultural industry |
3. |
Inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities |
C. |
Measurement of output |
D. |
Sequence of accounts |
1. |
Sequence of accounts as provided for in the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ |
2. |
Sequence of accounts of the EAA |
E. |
Sources of data and methods of calculation for compiling the EAA |
F. |
The classification |
1. |
General |
3. |
Definition of the characteristic units of agriculture |
4. |
Observations concerning various items |
5. |
Discrepancy between the EAA agricultural industry and the agricultural branch of the centralframework of the national accounts |
II. |
Transactions in products |
A. |
General rules |
1. |
Reference period |
2. |
Units |
3. |
Time of recording |
B. |
Output |
1. |
General comments on the concepts of output in the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ and EAA |
2. |
Output of agricultural activity: quantities |
3. |
Output of inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities |
4. |
Output of the agricultural industry |
5. |
Valuation of output |
C. |
Intermediate consumption |
1. |
Definition |
2. |
Elements of intermediate consumption |
3. |
Valuation of intermediate consumption |
D. |
Gross capital formation |
1. |
Gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) |
2. |
Change in stocks |
3. |
Recording of livestock as ‘GFCF’ or ‘changes in stocks’ |
III. |
Distributive transactions and other flows |
A. |
Definition |
B. |
General rules |
1. |
Reference period |
2. |
Units |
3. |
Time of recording distributive transactions |
4. |
General remarks concerning value added |
C. |
Compensation of employees |
D. |
Taxes on production and imports |
1. |
Taxes on products |
2. |
Treatment of value added tax VAT |
3. |
Other taxes on production |
E. |
Subsidies |
1. |
Subsidies on products |
2. |
Other subsidies on production |
F. |
Property income |
1. |
Definition |
2. |
Interest |
3. |
►M6 Rents (on land and subsoil assets) ◄ |
4. |
►M6 Investment income attributable to insurance policy holders (not covered by the EAA) ◄ |
G. |
Capital transfers |
1. |
Investment grants |
2. |
Other capital transfers |
H. |
Consumption of fixed capital |
IV. |
Agricultural labour input |
V. |
Agricultural income indicators |
A. |
Definition of income and balancing items |
B. |
Treatment of the income of units organised on a corporate basis |
C. |
Definition of the agricultural income indicators |
D. |
Aggregation of income indicators for the European Union |
E. |
Deflation of income indicators |
VI. |
Valuation of EAA at constant prices |
A. |
Price and volume measures |
B. |
Principles and method for compiling EAA at constant prices |
1. |
Choice of index formula |
2. |
Base year |
3. |
Presenting series in relation to a reference year |
4. |
►M6 Calculation of value added at fixed year prices ◄ |
5. |
Breakdown of taxes and subsidies on products into volume and price components |
VII. |
Regional economic accounts for agriculture (‘REAA’) |
A. |
General principles |
1. |
Introduction |
2. |
Regional economy, regional territory |
3. |
Basic unit in the compilation of the REAA |
4. |
Methods of compiling the REAA |
5. |
Concepts of residence and territory |
6. |
Agricultural industry and characteristic units |
B. |
Transactions in products |
1. |
Output |
2. |
Intermediate consumption |
3. |
Gross capital formation |
C. |
Distributive transactions and other flows |
1. |
General rules |
2. |
Value added |
3. |
Consumption of fixed capital |
4. |
Subsidies |
5. |
Taxes |
6. |
Compensation of employees |
7. |
Net operating surplus |
8. |
Interest, rents |
9. |
Agricultural entrepreneurial income: general calculation rules |
D. |
A brief look at implementation |
1. |
Introduction |
2. |
Defining regional agriculture |
3. |
Measuring agricultural output |
4. |
Inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities |
5. |
Intermediate consumption |
FOREWORD
The revision of the European system of accounts (ESA 2010) ( 4 ) has led to some revisions of the basic methodology used for the EAA, to guarantee consistency with the ESA to allow harmonisation of the EAA both between Member States and with the central framework of the national accounts and to ensure that the changes to be made were feasible. This manual has been drawn up with these considerations in mind as, in addition to the concepts, principles and basic rules for compiling the EAA, it also refers to any adaptations to specific characteristics in the field of agriculture.
I. GENERAL FEATURES OF THE ACCOUNTS
A. INTRODUCTION
1.01. |
A system of integrated economic accounts should provide an overview of economic activities which is systematic, comparable and as complete as possible, to serve as a basis for analyses, forecasts and political measures. The vast number and variety of economic transactions and units covered by the system therefore have to be classified according to general criteria and set out clearly and simply in a coherent system of accounts and tables. |
1.02. |
The European system of integrated economic accounts, which is derived from the United Nations revised system of national accounts ( ►M6 2008 SNA ◄ ) ►M6 ( 5 ) ◄ , was created in response to the specific needs of the European Union. It lays down concepts, definitions, accounting rules and uniform classifications to be used by the EU Member States. |
1.03. |
The economy of a country is the sum of the activities of a very large number of units engaged in many different types of transaction with a view to producing, financing, insuring, distributing and consuming. Units and groups of units considered in the context of a system of national accounts have to be defined in terms of the economic models under examination. ►M6 The ESA 2010 is characterised by the use of two types of unit and two corresponding ways of subdividing the national economy. ◄ |
1.04. |
In order to analyse flows involving income, capital, financial transactions and assets, it is essential to select units which depict the interaction between economic operators (institutional units). In order to analyse the production process, it is crucial to select units which illustrate technico-economic relationships (i.e. kind-of-activity units at local level and units of homogeneous production). |
1.05. |
Thus, the economy may be broken down in two different ways:
(i)
into institutional sectors or subsectors, which represent groups of institutional units;
(ii)
into industries, which comprise groups of kind-of-activity units at local level (industry) or units of homogeneous production (homogeneous branch). |
1.06. |
The main purpose of the EAA is to analyse the production process and primary income generated by it. The accounts are therefore based on the industry concept. |
1.07. |
The EAA are a satellite account providing complementary information and concepts adapted to the particular nature of the agricultural industry. Although their structure very closely matches that of the national accounts, their compilation requires the formulation of appropriate rules and methods. |
1.08. |
A distinction needs to be made between the income generated by agricultural production and the income of agricultural households, the latter including, apart from income from agricultural activity, income from other sources (from property, social transfers, etc.) that agricultural households may have. ►M6 These two types of income (income generated by agricultural production and the income of agricultural households) are measured for two distinct purposes, which require two distinct methods of breaking down the economy: the first, for the EAA, is based on production units, which are defined by reference to an economic activity; the second is based on households (i.e. institutional units) whose main source of income is independent agricultural activity. ◄ |
B. THE BASIC UNIT AND THE AGRICULTURAL INDUSTRY
1. Basic unit
1.09. |
In order to analyse flows occurring in the process of production and in the use of goods and services, it is necessary to choose units which emphasise relationships of a technico-economic kind. This requirement means that as a rule institutional units must be partitioned into smaller and more homogeneous units with regard to the kind of production. Local kind-of-activity units (local KAUs) are intended to meet this requirement as an operational approach (ESA 2010, 2.147) ( 6 ). |
1.10. |
The local kind-of-activity unit (local KAU) is the part of a KAU which corresponds to a local unit. The local KAU is called an establishment in the 2008 SNA and ISIC Rev.4. A KAU groups all the parts of an institutional unit in its capacity as a producer contributing to the performance of an activity at class level (four digits) of the NACE Rev. 2 (the reference classification for economic activities, cf. 1.55) and corresponds to one or more operational subdivisions of the institutional unit. The institutional unit's information system must be capable of indicating or calculating for each local KAU at least the value of production, intermediate consumption, compensation of employees, the operating surplus and employment and gross fixed capital formation (ESA 2010, 2.148). The local unit is an institutional unit, or part of an institutional unit, producing goods or services situated in a geographically identified place. |
1.11. |
Although a local KAU may correspond to an institutional unit or part of an institutional unit in its capacity as a producer, it can never belong to two distinct institutional units. Since, in practice, most institutional units producing goods and services are involved in a number of different activities at once (a principal activity and one or more secondary activities), they can be broken down into the same number of local KAUs, if necessary information is available. Ancillary activities (purchases, sales, marketing, accounting, transport, warehousing, maintenance, etc.; cf. 1.27), however, cannot lead to the creation of a local KAU, unless they are carried out in a separate location, located in a region other than the local KAU they serve (ESA 2010, 3.13). |
1.12. |
Basically, as many local KAUs should be recorded as there are secondary activities, but it can happen that statistical (accounting) information does not make it possible to separate a local KAU's secondary activities or parts of those activities from its principal activities. If an institutional unit producing goods or services contains a principal activity and also one or several secondary activities, it is subdivided into the same number of KAUs, and the secondary activities are classified under different headings from the principal activity. The ancillary activities are not separated from the principal or secondary activities. But KAUs falling within a particular heading of the classification system can produce products outside the homogeneous group on account of secondary activities connected with them which cannot be separately identified from available accounting documents. Thus a KAU may carry out one or several secondary activities. (ESA 2010, 2.149). |
1.13. |
An activity can be said to take place when resources such as equipment, labour, manufacturing techniques, information networks or products are combined, leading to the creation of specific goods or services. An activity is characterised by an input of products (goods and services), a production process and an output of products. The principal activity of a local KAU is the activity where the value added of such activity exceeds that of any other activity carried out within the same unit. The classification of the principal activity is determined by reference to NACE rev. 2, first at the highest level of the classification and then at more detailed levels (ESA 2010, 3.10). |
2. Agricultural industry
1.14. |
By grouping all local KAUs engaged in the same type of activity, it is possible to establish an industry. This makes it possible to break down the economy by industry. The classification of these industries depends on the principal activity of the units thus grouped together. ►M6 At the most detailed level of classification, as defined by ESA 2010, 2.150, an industry includes all local KAUs in the same class (four digit level) of NACE Rev. 2 and therefore engaged in the same principal activity as that defined in NACE Rev. 2. ◄ |
1.15. |
Although the agricultural industry was formerly defined as a grouping of units of homogeneous agricultural production, the local KAU was chosen as the basic unit of description for the EAA so as (i) to approach the EAA from the economic situation of agriculture, i.e. to take the existence of certain inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities into full account when measuring the total productive activity of agricultural units and (ii) to remain consistent with the rest of the national accounts. This represents a shift from an analytical approach based on the concept of the unit of homogeneous production and homogeneous branch to a statistical approach based on the concept of the KAU at local level and industry. |
1.16. |
Inseparable, non-agricultural secondary activities are activities whose costs cannot be observed separately from those of the agricultural activity. Examples are the processing of farm products on the farm, forestry, logging, tourism. The output of the agricultural industry thus results from two kinds of activity:
(i)
agricultural activities (main or secondary) performed by agricultural units;
(ii)
non-agricultural inseparable secondary activities of agricultural units. |
1.17. |
The agricultural holding, which is the unit currently used for statistical studies of agriculture (censuses, surveys of the structure of agricultural holdings), is the local KAU most appropriate to the agricultural industry (even though certain other units, such as wine or olive oil cooperatives, or units performing contract work, etc., have to be included in it). Nevertheless, it should be pointed out that the variety of agricultural activities that can be performed on agricultural holdings makes them a special type of local KAU. ►M6 The strict application of the ESA rule to units and their group should in fact result in a division of the agricultural holding into several separate local KAUs in cases where several activities of the NACE Rev. 2 four-digit class are performed on the same holding and the information required according to paragraph 1.10 is available. The adoption of the agricultural holding as the local KAU of the agricultural industry in the national accounts and EAA is based on a statistical approach. ◄ |
1.18. |
Thus, the accounts for the agricultural industry are essentially similar to the accounts of agricultural holdings (production and generation of income accounts). In order to avoid any ambiguity, however, it should be pointed out that the agricultural accounts are not accounts of enterprises whose principal activity is agricultural: firstly, they do not include all of these holdings' non-agricultural activities (those which can be separated from agricultural activities are excluded). Moreover, they include the agricultural activities of enterprises whose principal activity is not agricultural. Consequently, the adoption of the agricultural holding as the base unit for the EAA does not alter the fact that the agricultural accounts are agricultural industry accounts. |
1.19. |
►M6 Since, according to ESA 2010, an industry comprises a group of units which carry out as their principal activity the same or similar types of activity, the definition of the agricultural industry in the EAA depends on the identification of the characteristic activities and units in that industry. ◄ The resultant selection of characteristic agricultural activities and units may lead to some differences between the EAA agricultural industry accounts and the national accounts (cf. 1.93). |
1.20. |
►M6 The agricultural industry is treated as a grouping of all KAUs at local level which perform the following economic activities, as principal or secondary activity (cf. 1.60 to 1.66 for the precise definition of the agricultural industry): ◄
—
crop growing; market gardening; horticulture (including the production of wine and olive oil from grapes and olives grown by the same unit),
—
farming of animals,
—
crop production associated with animal husbandry,
—
agricultural contract work,
—
hunting, trapping and game propagation, including related service activities.
|
1.21. |
In addition to agricultural holdings, the agricultural industry comprises units made up of groups of producers (e.g. cooperatives) which produce wine and olive oil and specialised units which provide machines, material and labour for the performance of contract work. |
1.22. |
Specialised units which provide machines, equipment and personnel for the performance of contract work at the agricultural production stage (commercial enterprises engaged in contract work or agricultural holders providing services as contractors) are treated as part of the agricultural industry. Under a stricter interpretation, these units, which must be included in the agricultural industry, must perform work which (a) is part of the agricultural production process, (b) is linked to the production of agricultural products, (c) is customarily performed by the agricultural holdings and (d) is actually performed entirely by specialist units providing machines, material and labour. |
1.23. |
If, however, the contract work is not performed entirely by specialised units (e.g. if holders hire machines but employ their own workers), this activity must be recorded in Division 77 of NACE Rev. 2 (Rental and leasing activities); in this case, amounts paid by the holders to enterprises working under contract must be recorded as ‘other goods and services’ under ‘intermediate consumption’ (cf. 2.108). |
1.24. |
Since the purpose of the EAA is to measure, describe and analyse the formation of income from agricultural economic activity (which, in the EU Member States, is almost exclusively a commercial activity), it was decided to exclude units for which the agricultural activity represents solely a leisure ( 7 ) activity. In contrast, units engaged in subsistence farming are included in the EAA. It should be pointed out that agricultural output for own final consumption by agricultural holdings must be recorded in the EAA. |
3. Inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities
1.25. |
The use of the local KAU as the basic unit for the agricultural industry entails recording non-agricultural secondary activities where they cannot be isolated from the main agricultural activity. |
1.26. |
Inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities of local agricultural KAUs are defined in the EAA as activities closely linked to agricultural production for which information on any of output, intermediate consumption, compensation of employees, labour input or GFCF cannot be separated from information on the main agricultural activity during the period of statistical observation. |
1.27. |
The main characteristics of these inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities are as follows:
—
they must be intended for sale or barter (during the accounting period or later, after storage), own final use by the producer or as payment in kind (including compensation in kind paid to employees),
—
they must not be ancillary activities. Ancillary activities are not isolated to form distinct entities or separated from the principal or secondary activities or entities they serve. Accordingly, ancillary activities must be integrated with the local KAU they serve, unless they are organised in separate units and located in another region. Ancillary activities remain in the same industry as the local KAU they serve. Ancillary activities are supplementary activities (e.g. sales, marketing, warehousing, transport for own account; see ESA 2010, 3.12 and 3.13, and 2008 SNA, 5.35 to 5.44) carried out by an enterprise in order to create the conditions for conducting the main or secondary activities. Typically, the output of ancillary activities appears as input in the different types of productive activity,
—
by convention, they may not include production of GFCF of non-agricultural products (such as buildings or machines) for own account. That production of GFCF of non-agricultural products for own final use is presumed to be a separable activity and is recorded as the production of an identifiable local KAU. Accommodation services made available to employees as remuneration in kind must be treated in a similar manner (they are recorded as remuneration in kind in the generation of income account),
—
they must be characteristic of agricultural holdings, i.e. they must be of significant economic importance for a significant number of holdings,
—
agricultural ‘contract work’ is not a non-agricultural activity since it is a characteristic activity (agricultural services) of the agricultural industry.
|
1.28. |
Only that part of a specific non-agricultural secondary activity which is inseparable must be included. As a consequence, a given non-agricultural activity will be included in the agricultural industry if it is impossible to separate it from the main agricultural activity of a local KAU, but will be excluded if it can be separated from the main agricultural activity, in which case the secondary activity gives rise to a non-agricultural local KAU. The selection criterion for inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities is not so much the nature of the product as the type of activity ( 8 ). For example, agro-tourism services provided by a farm must only be included if they cannot be separated from its agricultural activities. This would probably not be the case when these activities become important. Thus, non-agricultural products accounted for in the production of the agricultural industry may vary geographically and over time. |
1.29. |
Two main types of inseparable non-agricultural secondary activity may be distinguished:
1.
Activities which represent a continuation of agricultural activity and which use agricultural products. This type of activity can be found in most of the EU Member States. The processing of agricultural products is the typical activity of this group: Processing of agricultural products
—
milk into butter, cream, cheeses, yoghurts and other dairy products,
—
fruit and vegetables into fruit juices, tinned foods, alcoholic beverages and other products,
—
grapes, must and wine into alcoholic products (e.g. sparkling wine, such as Champagne, and spirits, such as Cognac),
—
plaiting of vegetable material/textiles/wool,
—
production of pâtés, foie gras and other processed meat products,
—
processing of other agricultural products,
Grading and packaging of agricultural products, e.g. eggs and potatoes
2.
Activities involving the agricultural holding and its means of agricultural production (equipment, installations, buildings, workforce). These activities are basically the following:
—
agro-tourism — camping, catering, hotels, various kinds of accommodation, etc.,
—
farm shops — retail trade activities concerning products other than those from the holding. Direct sales of agricultural products, raw or processed, are recorded in the output of the products concerned,
—
sports and rural recreation — the use of land for activities such as golf, horse-riding, hunting, fishing, etc.,
—
services for third parties — e.g. the renting and repair of agricultural machinery, irrigation projects, agricultural advisory services, product storage, maintenance of farm buildings, commercial services relating to agricultural products, transport of agricultural products, etc. These services are recorded as secondary activities, only if they are performed for a third party. When performed for own account, they are ancillary activities, which are not recorded in the accounts (cf. 1.27),
—
landscaping services — grass-mowing, hedge-trimming, snow-clearing, laying out, planting and maintenance of green areas and the like,
—
fish-farming,
—
other activities involving the use of the land and the means of agricultural production. These other activities will include R & D, if not performed by separate local KAUs and if possible to be estimated.
|
1.30. |
The list of non-agricultural secondary activities (cf. 1.29) is however given by way of illustration and does not apply in every country. On the contrary, each country has to compile its own list of inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities, depending on the characteristics of its agriculture. The list must be drawn up in collaboration with the national accounts departments so as to ensure that the EAA is compatible with the agricultural branch accounts and the accounts for these non-agricultural activities as compiled for national accounts purposes (i.e. to ensure that no activity is omitted or double-counted). |
1.31. |
The agricultural secondary activities of non-agricultural units are negligible and are recorded as zero by convention. Agricultural production carried out by a non-agricultural unit is in fact considered to be always separable, in terms of accounting data, because of the specific features of the products and the means of agricultural production as well as the data sources and methods used for drawing up the resulting EAA (cf. section E of chapter I and sections B and C of chapter II). In order to base the EAA on the industry concept, the output of all agricultural products, excluding those products arising from the secondary activities of non-agricultural local KAUs, has to be measured. As these by convention are deemed to be zero, all agricultural output is recorded (with the exception of the output of units for which the agricultural activity represents solely a leisure activity; cf. 1.24). |
1.32. |
Non-agricultural goods and services produced by agricultural holdings are not included in the EAA unless they are the result of inseparable secondary activities. For example, if units include several vertically integrated production processes (e.g. enterprises engaged in slaughtering, packing and vacuum-packing fowl, grading, washing and pre-packaging potatoes or other vegetables, sorting, preparing and selling seeds; cooperatives providing storage space and selling the products, etc.), the agricultural industry includes only the part of their activity which is related to agricultural production as defined in 1.62 and 1.63, and to the inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities. |
C. MEASUREMENT OF OUTPUT
1.33. |
According to the ESA 2010, the output of the industry represents all of the products produced over the accounting period in question by all the units of the industry except for goods and services produced and consumed over the same accounting period by the same unit. The measurement of agricultural output is based on an adaptation of this ESA rule, with the inclusion in agricultural output of part of the output consumed by the agricultural units themselves (cf. 2.032 to 2.036). Thus in the EAA, agricultural output represents the sum of output by all units in the industry (excluding output for intermediate consumption by the same unit), plus output used as intermediate consumption by the same unit, provided this output concerns two different basic activities (such as crop products intended for use as animal feedingstuffs) and it meets certain criteria (set out in 2.055). |
1.34. |
The ESA rule has been adapted because of the special nature of the agricultural industry:
—
the amount of agricultural output used in the same unit as intermediate consumption is greater in agriculture than in other economic sectors,
—
the agricultural holding includes a great variety of agricultural activities which are closely linked to one another (one activity being a basis for or continuation of another activity, such as cereal and fodder production for animal feedingstuffs; close links in the use of production factors such as equipment and machinery). The varied content of the agricultural holding, without putting into question its characterisation as a local KAU, makes it a very special case as compared to local KAUs in other parts of the economy (cf. 1.17). The aim of the accounts in subdividing the economy into industries is, in part, to reflect the flows within the production process: creation, transformation, trade and transfer of economic value. The different activities carried out on an agricultural holding would not be fully taken into account by solely measuring the output leaving the holding.
|
1.35. |
This adaptation of the ESA rule calls for special treatment for certain products such as agricultural products intended for use as feedingstuffs on the holding, grapes used for wine production and olives used for olive oil production, and agricultural products intended for use as intermediate consumption for inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities. |
1.36. |
Trade in live animals between agricultural holdings and imports of live animals are the subject of special treatment as they are considered work-in-progress (cf. chapter II). |
D. SEQUENCE OF ACCOUNTS
1. Sequence of accounts as provided for in the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄
1.37. |
The EAA are based on a sequence of interconnected accounts. In the ESA 2010, the full sequence of accounts includes current accounts, accumulation accounts and balance sheets (ESA 2010, 1.113 to 1.115). These different accounts make it possible to record transactions and other flows linked to specific aspects of the economic cycle (for example, production) in an ordered framework. These transactions range from the generation of income through income accumulation in the form of assets, to its distribution and redistribution. The balancing items which are deducted from them are then used as aggregates for measuring economic performance. |
1.38. |
The current accounts deal with the production and related generation, distribution and redistribution of income and its use in the form of final consumption; they make it possible to calculate ‘savings’, which is the essential component of accumulation. Accumulation accounts analyse the various components of changes in the assets and liabilities of units and make it possible to record changes in net worth (the difference between assets and liabilities). The balance sheets show the total assets and liabilities of the various units at the beginning and end of the accounting period, together with their net worth. The flows for each asset and liability item recorded in the accumulation accounts are seen again in the ‘changes in balance sheets’ account (ESA 2010, 8.02 to 8.09 and Table 8.1). |
1.39. |
The sequence of accounts referred to above applies to institutional units, sectors and subsectors, and the total economy. The ESA 2010 assumes that there is no point in compiling a full sequence of accounts for a local KAU and an industry because such units rarely have the capacity to retain goods or assets in their own name or to receive and distribute income. |
2. Sequence of accounts of the EAA
1.40. |
As the EAA are based on the industry concept, the sequence of accounts in accordance with the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ has to be limited to the first accounts of the current accounts:
—
the production account and
—
the generation-of-income account
whose balancing items are value added and operating surplus respectively (cf. tables 1 and 2 below). |
1.41. |
Nevertheless, it is thought that, given the specific features of agriculture, it should be possible to compile other accounts, at least in part, in so far as the relevant flows can be clearly attributed to them. The accounts in question (cf. tables 3 and 4 below) are the following:
—
the entrepreneurial income account (one of the current accounts) and
—
the capital account (one of the accumulation accounts).
|
1.42. |
Consideration is being given to extending this sequence of accounts to include certain items (flows) in the account ‘other changes in assets’ in the accumulation accounts (i.e. certain headings under ‘other changes in the volume of assets’ and the revaluation account) and the balance sheet. |
1.43. |
On the basis of the tables and accounting structure in the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ , the sequence of accounts of the EAA can be depicted as shown in tables 1 to 4.
|
1.44. |
It should be borne in mind that transactions and stocks set out in italics in Tables 3 and 4 are items which:
—
are not relevant for the EAA because the industry concept is used and the sequence of accounts is incomplete. The headings concerned are headings D.42 Distributed income of corporations, D.43 Reinvested earnings on direct foreign investment, D.44 Other investment income and D.45 Rent under Resources of Table 3 and headings B.8n Saving, net, B.101 Changes in net worth due to saving and capital transfers and B.9 Net lending(+)/Net borrowing(-) in Table 4 or
—
are not recorded, either for lack of reliable information or because they are currently of limited interest for EAA purposes. The headings in question are D.9p Capital transfers, payable, D.91p Capital taxes, payable and D.99p Other capital transfers, payable P.53 Acquisitions less disposals of valuables, NP Acquisitions less disposals of non-produced assets (land and other non-produced assets), K.1 Economic appearance of assets, K.2 Economic disappearance of non-produced assets, in Table 4. Some of these (e.g. D.91, K.1, K.2) may be recorded in the EAA at some later date.
|
1.45. |
The production account records transactions relating to the production process. It includes output under ‘Resources’ and intermediate consumption under ‘Uses’. Value added, i.e. the balancing item, may be calculated either before or after consumption of fixed capital (gross or net value added). As output is valued at the basic price and intermediate consumption at purchaser price, the value added includes subsidies less taxes on products. |
1.46. |
The generation of income account is concerned with the formation of income resulting from the production process and its attribution to the ‘labour’ production factor and general government (in the form of taxes and subsidies). The operating surplus, i.e. the balancing item, corresponds to the income which the units generate by using their production assets. ►M6 In the case of unincorporated enterprises in the households sector, the balancing item of this account implicitly contains an element corresponding to remuneration for work carried out by the owner or members of the family. This income from self-employment has characteristics of wages and salaries, and characteristics of profit due to work carried out as an entrepreneur. This income, neither strictly wages nor profits alone, is referred to as ‘mixed income’ (ESA 2010, 8.19). ◄ |
1.47. |
The entrepreneurial income account makes it possible to measure income which is similar to the concept of current profit before distribution and taxes on income, as customarily used in business accounting. |
1.48. |
The capital account makes it possible to determine the extent to which acquisitions less disposals of non-financial assets have been financed from saving and capital transfers. It shows lending or borrowing. It is not possible to compile a complete capital account for agriculture because, although certain flows may be clearly attributable to this industry, other items (e.g. net saving, the balance of the sequence of the current accounts) cannot be calculated on an industry basis. Nevertheless, by recording as much as possible of the changes in the value of non-financial assets in the industry (due to acquisitions, disposals and the consumption of fixed capital) and capital transfers received by the industry, valuable information is obtained on its economic and balance-sheet situation (plus information on the income generated by the production process). |
E. SOURCES OF DATA AND METHODS OF CALCULATION FOR COMPILING THE EAA
1.49. |
One of the main characteristics of the EAA is the adoption of the ‘quantity x price’ formula when measuring the output of the large majority of products. This approach was prompted mainly by the difficulty of compiling agricultural accounts based on representative samples of business accounts. |
1.50. |
The evaluation of crop output can normally be based on resources, i.e. the estimate of quantities produced (harvested) based on estimates of areas under crops and yields, or on uses, i.e. on estimates of purchases by the user branches of agricultural products, exports net of imports, to which should be added certain quantities used for intermediate consumption by the agricultural industry, changes in producer stocks and use for own account (much of which is own final consumption). The latter approach can prove highly appropriate in cases where the buyers of these agricultural products are readily identifiable and the four other components of uses are limited (for example, products requiring preliminary processing before they can be used, such as sugar beet, tobacco, etc.). Nevertheless, a physical balance sheet is necessary in order to verify the consistency and reliability of the data. |
1.51. |
Statistics on slaughterings, exports/imports of live animals and the size of herds are the main sources of data for measuring the output of animals. The output of animal products (mainly milk) is generally estimated using sales to user branches (dairies, packers) because of the specific uses to which they are put. |
1.52. |
A more detailed description of the methods of calculation is given in chapter II. |
1.53. |
Most intermediate goods can basically only be used in agriculture (seeds and planting stock, fertilisers, pesticides, etc.). In this case purchases by agriculture are based on the data relating to sales by branches which supply these intermediate goods (after inclusion of external trade). |
1.54. |
Applying this rule is not without certain risks, however. In actual fact, sales by producers of intermediate consumption goods, which are mainly used in agriculture, do not necessarily correspond to the purchases of those goods by the agricultural sector, because fertilisers, pesticides, etc. may also be bought for other purposes (stocks of commercial units, consumption of other units such as public parks and households etc.). |
F. THE CLASSIFICATION
1. General
1.55. |
The EAA are an integral part of the European system of accounts and therefore for their compilation use is made of Eurostat’s general classification of economic activities, NACE Rev. 2. NACE Rev. 2 is a four-level nomenclature of activities which was compiled in 2006. It is in fact a revision of the general industrial classification of economic activities within the European Communities, or NACE, which was first published by Eurostat in 1970. |
1.56. |
►M3 NACE Rev. 2 ◄ is a more detailed version of ►M3 ISIC Rev. 4 ◄ ( 9 ), adapted to specifically European circumstances. ►M3 NACE Rev. 2 ◄ is also directly linked to the statistical classification of products by activity (CPA) within the European Economic Community, which in turn is based on the United Nations' central product classification (CPC). |
1.57. |
NACE Rev. 2 is a classification of activities which is used for defining industries in the national accounts. It is based on the four-level coding system described below:
—
a first level consisting of headings identified by an alphabetical code (sections);
—
a second level consisting of headings identified by a two-digit numerical code (divisions);
—
a third level consisting of headings identified by a three-digit numerical code (groups); and
—
a fourth level consisting of headings identified by a four-digit numerical code (classes).
|
1.58. |
Each level in a classification of economic activities can usually be defined by its characteristic goods or services. Thus, the CPA is used to describe in detail the various economic activities in the agricultural industry with an additional two-digit differentiation providing a more detailed definition of the headings. |
1.59. |
According to ESA 2010, the industry corresponds to the group of local KAUs engaged in the same or similar principal activity. At the most detailed level of classification, an industry includes all local KAUs in the same class (four digits) of NACE Rev. 2 and which are therefore engaged in the same activity as defined in this nomenclature (ESA 2010, 2.150). A definition of the field of the agricultural industry therefore requires a precise statement of:
—
its characteristic activities,
—
the characteristic units of the EAA.
|
2. Definition of the characteristic activities of agriculture
1.60. |
The agricultural industry, as described in the EAA, corresponds, in principle, to Division 01 in NACE Rev. 2 with differences shown in following paragraphs 1.62 to 1.66. |
1.61. |
The EAA are a satellite account in the framework of the national accounts, whose basic concepts, principles and rules are based on the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ . However, the latter only provides a general framework for the economy as a whole, and has to be adapted to the specific requirements of agriculture. These particular requirements derive mainly from the specific purposes of the EAA, the availability of data sources and the special character of agricultural units and their economic activities. The specific nature of the satellite accounts necessitates the compilation of a list of characteristic agricultural activities of the EAA, which obviously has to be based on ►M3 NACE Rev. 2 ◄ . |
1.62. |
For national accounts purposes the agricultural industry is defined as all units performing, either solely or together with other secondary economic activities, activities which come under Division 01 of NACE Rev. 2 ‘Crop and animal production, hunting and related service activities’. Division 01 comprises ( 10 ):
—
Group 01,1: Growing of non-perennial crops;
—
Group 01,2: Growing of perennial crops;
—
Group 01,3: Plant propagation;
—
Group 01,4: Animal production;
—
Group 01,5: Mixed farming;
—
Group 01,6: Support activities to agriculture and post-harvest crop activities;
—
Group 01,7: Hunting, trapping and related service activities.
|
1.63. |
The list of characteristic agricultural activities of the EAA corresponds to these seven groups of activities (01,1 to 01,7), but with the following differences:
—
inclusion of the production of wine and olive oil (exclusively using grapes and olives grown by the same holding),
—
exclusion of certain activities which, in NACE Rev. 2, are considered as agricultural services (e. g. the operation of irrigation systems — only agricultural contract work is taken into account here).
|
3. Definition of the characteristic units of agriculture
1.64. |
All units which perform characteristic activities of the agricultural industry of the EAA must be included. The units in question perform the activities included in the following groups in NACE Rev. 2:
—
groups 01,1 and 01,2: Growing of non-perennial and perennial crops,
—
production of seeds: only the units engaged in seed multiplication,
—
group 01,3: Plant propagation
—
group 01,4: Animal production,
—
group 01,5: Mixed farming,
—
group 01,6: Support activities to agriculture and post-harvest crop activities
—
excluding units which perform agricultural service activities other than contract work (i.e. units which operate irrigation systems or seed processing for propagation),
—
group 01,7: Hunting, trapping and related service activities.
|
▼M3 —————
1.66. |
It can be seen from the list that, apart from agricultural holdings, the other characteristic units of agriculture are: groupings of producers producing wine and olive oil and specialist units performing agricultural contract work (cf. 1.20 and 1.21). It should be remembered that units for which the agricultural activity represents solely a leisure activity are not included among the characteristic units of agriculture (cf. 1.24). |
4. Observations concerning various items
(a) Groups from 01,1 to 01,3: Growing of non-perennial and perennial crops, plant propagation
1.67. |
Groups from 01,1 to 01,3 include a systematic breakdown making it possible to classify all crop production activities in the EU Member States. |
1.68. |
In order to be recorded, the production of fodder crops must be part of an economic activity. |
▼M3 —————
1.70. |
In the nomenclature of the EAA, agricultural seeds are grouped under the heading ‘Seeds’, the exceptions being seed for cereals (including rice), oilseeds, protein crops and potatoes, which are entered respectively under the individual cereal and oilseeds varieties, protein crops and potatoes ( 11 ). The production of seeds in fact covers several types of production activity: research (i.e. production of first-generation seed prototypes), multiplication (done by agricultural holdings under contract) and certification (i.e. grading and packing by specialist production units). Only the multiplication of seeds is a characteristic agricultural activity since research and certification activities are done by research and production institutes and are not part of traditional agricultural activity (i.e. the exploitation of natural resources with a view to producing plants and animals). As a result, the production of seeds in the EAA only concerns the production of multiplied seeds. The intermediate consumption of seeds corresponds to (i) first-generation seeds purchased with a view to multiplication and (ii) certified seeds purchased by agricultural producers with a view to crop production. |
1.71. |
Following the convention adopted by NACE Rev. 2 ( 12 ), when own produced agricultural products are processed by the same unit of production, the processed products are also attributed to agriculture. As an example, grape must, wine and olive oil are treated as food products in the CPA. NACE Rev. 2 classifies the production of wine and olive oil under section C ‘manufacturing’ (Classes 11,02 ‘Manufacture of wine from grape’ and 10,41 ‘Manufacture of oils and fats’). Only the production of wine grapes and olives comes under agriculture (Classes 01,21 ‘Growing of grapes’ and 01,26 ‘Growing of oleaginous fruits’). However, following the above convention, wine and olive oil produced from grapes and olives grown by the same unit of production are attributed to agriculture. |
1.72. |
The production of wine by units closely linked to agricultural holdings is also treated as a characteristic agricultural activity in the EAA. Units with strong links to agricultural holdings include groups of producers (e.g. vine-growers' cooperatives). Their inclusion in the agricultural industry is dictated by the nature of these organisations, which have historically represented an ‘extension’ of agricultural holdings (on mutual grounds relating to production and marketing) and which are usually owned by them. By contrast, the production of wine (olive oil) by agri-food businesses is excluded from the EAA (since it is clearly industrial by nature). |
1.73. |
The production of grape must features together with the production of wine in the list of characteristic activities since grape must can be sold or exported in its raw state or added to stocks prior to being sold or exported, either for consumption or to be made into wine, in a subsequent reference period. |
1.74. |
Since wine, olive oil and grape must (the latter only in so far as it is not vinified during the reference period) result from agricultural production in the form of the processing of grapes and olives grown by the same unit, neither grapes intended for the manufacture of grape must and wine nor olives intended for the manufacture of olive oil (i.e. the basic products) should be included under output. They are treated as intra-unit consumption which is not measured as industry output (cf. 2.052). Grape must which is not vinified during the reference period should be included in the period's output. During the vinification period, it should be recorded as intermediate consumption (intra-industry consumption) balancing a corresponding stock decline. The wine resulting from the processing of the must should be recorded as a component of output. |
1.75. |
Plantations (e.g. vineyards and orchards) are fixed capital goods, and their establishment has to be recorded under output. The establishment of plantations for own account constitutes ‘Own-account produced fixed capital goods’. When the establishment of plantations is carried out by specialised units on contract basis, the corresponding value is considered as ‘Sales’. |
(b) Group 01,4: Animal production
1.76. |
As with crop-growing activities (cf. 1.67), this group comprises a systematic breakdown of all the livestock and animal products produced in the EU Member States. |
▼M3 —————
1.78. |
Horse breeding is a characteristic activity of the EAA whatever the final destination of the animal may be (breeding, meat production or services). ►M3 It should be noted, however, that the management of racehorse stables and riding schools is not a characteristic agricultural activity (it is a part of ‘Sports activities and amusement and recreation activities’: Division 93) (cf. 2.210). ◄ ►M6 Therefore, flows accruing to farmers from such activities must be excluded from the EAA. ◄ In addition, the keeping of racehorses or saddle horses which are not part of the agricultural production process is excluded from the EAA. A similar treatment is applied to bulls bred for bullfights. |
1.79. |
In the economic accounts, by-products ( 13 ) which automatically result from the production of certain agricultural products are not recorded under the same headings as the product itself. They appear separately at the end of each group of production activities, broken down by species. In crop production, for example, examples include straw, beet leaves and cabbage leaves, pea and bean pods, etc.; in vinification, lees and argols; in the manufacture of olive oil, waste, such as oilseed cakes; and, in the case of animal production, hides, hair and the fur of dead game, and wax, manure and slurry. Generally speaking, none of these products is the prime objective of production, which explains why it is so rare for statistical data on them to be reliable. In agriculture itself, these products are used mainly as animal feedingstuffs or soil improvers. Occasionally, however, these by-products are sold to economic sectors other than agriculture, in which case the value of output should be shown in the EAA. |
(c) Group 01,6: Support activities to agriculture and post-harvest crop activities
1.80. |
The activities in group 01,6 can be divided into two categories:
—
agricultural services in the form of contract work at the production stage (i.e. agricultural contract work),
—
‘other’ agricultural services (the operation of irrigation systems, seed processing for propagation, etc.).
|
1.81. |
Agricultural service activities in the second category are not treated as characteristic EAA activities (even though they are recorded in the agricultural accounts of the national accounts), since they are not traditional or typical agricultural activities. |
Agricultural contract work
1.82. |
As part of the process of economic specialisation, agricultural holdings and households have long since ceased to perform certain functions, which have been taken up by a growing number of specialist professions with their own production units. This division of functions mainly concerns the processing of agricultural products (slaughtering and meat processing, the milling of cereals, the manufacture of bread, butter and cheese and the processing of seeds by new sectors), and, at a later stage, certain marketing transactions. This is especially the case in the context of the major structural changes affecting agriculture, the growing use of large machines and agricultural activities which make a direct contribution to the production of crop products and animal husbandry and which have increasingly been outsourced to specialised units. |
1.83. |
Notable among these activities are manuring, liming, ploughing, sowing, weeding, pest control, plant protection, hay harvesting, threshing and the shearing of sheep. |
1.84. |
A characteristic feature of all these activities is that they are generally necessary as part of the production process for agricultural products and are linked to the production of these products. |
1.85. |
Activities which are not directly related to the production of agricultural products, i.e. which do not take place at the agricultural production stage (transport for account of third parties and deliveries of milk to dairies are examples of a non-agricultural activity constituting part of a different industry) should not feature in the EAA (unless they are activities which are inseparable from the principal agricultural activity; cf. 1.12). |
1.86. |
It should be borne in mind that this classification applies only on so far as the activities in question are exclusively for account of the specialised units. ►M3 If, on the other hand, the farmer hires machines without operators or with only some of the operators required, with the result that he/she continues to carry out the activity as such, with the help of the machines, this activity comes under Division 77 of NACE Rev. 2. ◄ This situation mainly occurs with simple machines requiring relatively few repairs, and mainly during peak periods, when the machines are in greatest demand (cf. 1.23). |
1.87. |
Contract work performed during the agricultural production stage mainly involves the use of expensive machines and equipment. Such work may be performed by:
(a)
specialist contractors for whom these are the principal activities (contractors in the true sense);
(b)
agricultural holdings Contract work by holders usually takes the following forms:
—
as far as farmers' supplementary income is concerned, the most flexible form is occasional aid given to neighbours. This category also includes the provision of accommodation for livestock and, mainly for pigs and poultry, animal husbandry on a fee basis (especially fattening). Accommodation may be provided for livestock owned by another farmer or the livestock may be the property of an industrial enterprise, usually a supplier (e.g. a manufacturer of/trader in fodder crops) or a purchaser (e.g. an abattoir),
—
in the form of a more or less autonomous machine pool which represents a systematised form of mutual aid between neighbours. The high cost of machinery and its low rate of utilisation by an individual holding lead holdings which possess such machines to form machine pools which are placed at the disposal of other holdings, complete with the necessary personnel. Increasingly, farmers are deriving their main agricultural income from contract work on account of persons for whom agriculture is no more than a secondary activity and who in some cases are merely the owners of the land,
—
agricultural machine cooperatives (
14
). These are large cooperatives with paid employees; they resemble specialist contractors;
(c)
enterprises involved in a subsequent production stage which harvest fruit or vegetables and then process themselves (e.g. tinning factories tinning peas under contract);
(d)
enterprises involved in a previous production stage. These include traders in agricultural machinery who perform contract work. Although other cases may, from the point of view of the EAA, seem highly unlikely, it is theoretically possible for a manufacturer of pesticides to apply the product himself. If this is done using the most modern techniques, however, it is not necessarily contract work at the agricultural production stage, and certainly not if the work is not regularly carried out by the farmer (e.g. aerial spraying of parasites). |
1.88. |
In cases where it has to be decided if an activity should be treated as contract work (i.e. work which, in the context of the agricultural production process, would normally be performed by agricultural holdings themselves), it should be borne in mind that not only the nature of the activity, but also the specific context in which it is performed, i.e. the ‘agricultural production process’ is important. |
1.89. |
Animal husbandry performed on farms for remuneration (the provision of land for livestock) is agricultural contract work since it is part of the agricultural production process. This heading does not, however, include the private rearing and care of saddle horses, since these activities do not constitute the production of goods but a genuine service within the meaning of the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ (section R of NACE Rev. 2). |
1.90. |
The type of compensation paid to the persons performing contract work is unimportant. It does not in any way have to be fixed remuneration (i.e. a wage in the strict sense); the compensation can perfectly well take the form of profit-sharing or a mixed formula (for example, a farmer who fattens calves in return for compensation generally receives a fixed amount for each animal plus a share in net profit). Compensation can also take the form of a specified share of the output. |
1.91. |
Nevertheless, the work must always be performed by independent enterprises: work performed by the holding's paid employees does not fall into this category. From the point of view of the holding, remuneration for such work (for example, work done by a paid herdsman) is a wage cost and appears under the heading ‘compensation of employees’. By contrast, work performed by an enterprise which carried out milking on a contract basis for other agricultural holdings is recorded in the EAA both as output (sales of services), from the point of view of the contractor, and as intermediate consumption (purchase of services), from the point of view of the agricultural holding. |
(d) Group 01,7: Hunting, trapping and related service activities
1.92. |
This group of activities comprises the following activities: (i) hunting and trapping on a commercial basis; (ii) taking of animals (dead or alive) for food, fur or skin, or for use in research, in zoos or as pets; (iii) production of fur skins or reptile or bird skins from hunting or trapping activities. It should be noted that the production of hide and leather from slaughterhouses and hunting performed as a sports or recreation activity are not included as characteristic activities of the agricultural industry. Additionally, the ‘hunting’ group does not comprise the breeding of game on holdings, which should be recorded under class 01,49 ‘Raising of other animals’. |
5. Discrepancy between the EAA agricultural industry and the agricultural branch of the central framework of the national accounts
1.93. |
The EAA agricultural industry, as defined in Sections 1.62 to 1.66, differs in some respects from the branch as defined for national accounts purposes. The differences relate to the definition of both characteristic activities and units. They can be summarised as follows: EAA agricultural industry = NA agricultural branch (Nace Rev.2 Division 01)
—
Production of units providing associated agricultural services other than agricultural contract work (e.g. the operation of irrigation systems)
—
Units for which the agricultural activity represents solely a leisure activity and which are included in national accounts, cf. ESA 2010, 3.08
+
Production of units producing wine and olive oil (exclusively using grapes and olives grown by the same unit (grouping of producers, cooperatives, etc.))
+
Separable secondary agricultural activities of units whose principal activity is not agricultural (cf. 1.18). |
II. TRANSACTIONS IN PRODUCTS
2.001. |
Transactions in products provide an account of the origin and use of products. Products are goods and services created within the production boundary. The main categories of transactions in products defined by the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ are: output, intermediate consumption, final consumption expenditure, actual final consumption, gross capital formation, exports of goods and services and imports of goods and services. |
2.002. |
As mentioned in 1.40 and 1.41, only output, intermediate consumption and gross capital formation are taken into account in the EAA. Output is recorded as a resource and intermediate consumption as a use in the production account. Gross capital formation is recorded as a use (a change in assets) in the capital account. |
A. |
GENERAL RULES 1. Reference period
2. Units (a) Quantities
(b) Prices
(c) Values
3. Time of recording
|
B. |
OUTPUT 1. General comments on the concepts of output in the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ and EAA
2. Output of agricultural activity: quantities
3. Output of inseperable non-agricultural secondary activities
4. Output of the agricultural industry
5. Valuation of output
|
C. |
INTERMEDIATE CONSUMPTION 1. Definition
▼M2 ————— 2. Elements of intermediate consumption (a) Seeds and planting stock
(b) Energy; lubricants
(c) Fertilisers and soil improvers
(d) Plant protection products and pesticides
(e) Veterinary expenses
(f) Animal feedingstuffs
(g) Maintenance of materials
(h) Maintenance of buildings
(i) Agricultural services
(j) Financial intermediation services indirectly measured (FISIM) 2.107.1. In accordance with the convention of ESA 2010, the value of financial intermediation services indirectly measured (FISIM) used by the agricultural industry should be recorded as intermediate consumption of the agricultural industry (cf. ESA 2010, Chapter 14). (k) Other goods and services
(k) Items not included in intermediate consumption
3. Valuation of intermediate consumption
|
D. |
GROSS CAPITAL FORMATION
|
III. DISTRIBUTIVE TRANSACTIONS AND OTHER FLOWS
A. DEFINITION
3.001. |
Distributive transactions are transactions:
—
which distribute value added generated by production among the workforce, capital and general government,
—
which involve the redistribution of income and wealth.
|
3.002. |
The ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ distinguishes between current transfers and capital transfers, the latter representing a redistribution of saving or wealth rather than of income. |
3.003. |
Given that the EAA are the accounts for an industry, only certain distributive transactions will be described in this chapter. The most important ones are those recorded in the primary income distribution accounts, particularly the generation of income account and entrepreneurial income account (cf. EAA sequence of accounts, 1.38 to 1.48). In the case of the generation of income account, these distributive transactions relate to other taxes on production, other subsidies on production and the compensation of employees. For the entrepreneurial income account, they correspond to certain types of property income (mainly land rents, interest and property income attributed to insurance policy holders). The account also records distributive transactions corresponding to aid for investment and other capital transfers in the capital account. |
3.004. |
They do not include some distributive transactions relating to certain property income (mainly dividends and other income distributed by corporations), current taxes on income and wealth, etc. Recording these transactions is only statistically feasible and meaningful if groupings of institutional units, i.e. sectors and subsectors, are taken into account (cf. 1.06). |
B. GENERAL RULES
1. Reference period
3.005. |
The reference period for the EAA is the calendar year. |
2. Units
3.006. |
The values should be expressed in millions of units of the national currency. |
3. Time of recording distributive transactions
3.007. |
As was explained in 2.008, the ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ records distributive transactions on an accrual basis, i.e. at the time an economic value, amount due or claim is created, transformed or cancelled or ceases to exist, and not at the moment when payment is actually made. This recording principle (based on rights and obligations) is applied to all flows, irrespective of whether they are monetary flows, or whether they occur between units or within a single unit. However, certain exceptions might be justified for practical reasons. |
3.008. |
The times of recording the various types of distributive transaction are as follows: |
(a) |
Compensation of employees
|
(b) |
Taxes and subsidies on production
|
(c) |
Property income
|
(d) |
Capital transfers
|
4. General remarks concerning value added
3.013. |
Value added is the balancing item of the production account. It is the difference between the value of output and the value of intermediate consumption (irrespective of the output concept used, since intermediate consumption changes accordingly). It is a key item in measuring the productivity of an economy or industry. It can be accounted for on a gross basis (gross value added) or on a net basis (net value added), i.e. before or after the deduction of the consumption of fixed capital. Net value added is the only resource in the generation of income account. In line with the method for valuing output (basic price) and intermediate consumption (purchaser prices) net value added is measured at basic prices. |
3.014. |
By deducting other taxes on production from the value added at basic prices, and adding other subsidies on production, the value added at factor cost is obtained. Net value added at factor cost constitutes the income of the factors of production. |
C. COMPENSATION OF EMPLOYEES
(cf. ESA 2010, 4.02 to 4.13)
3.015. |
►M6 The compensation of employees is defined as total remuneration, in cash or in kind, payable by an employer to an employee in return for work done by the latter during the accounting period (cf. ESA 2010, 4.02). ◄ It includes:
—
gross wages and salaries (cash/kind),
—
employers' social contributions (actual and imputed).
|
3.016. |
Gross wages and salaries in cash comprise the following components:
(a)
direct basic wages and salaries (payable at regular intervals);
(b)
enhanced rates for overtime, night or weekend work, work of a particularly arduous nature, etc.;
(c)
cost of living and accommodation allowances;
(d)
wage benefits such as Christmas, end-of-year, holiday or productivity bonuses and allowances for higher grades;
(e)
allowances for transport to and from work ( 35 );
(f)
compensation for days not actually worked, paid holidays;
(g)
commissions, tips, attendance fees;
(h)
other allowances or occasional payments linked to overall company results as part of profit-sharing schemes;
(i)
payments made by employers contributing to asset formation by employees;
(j)
one-off payments to employees when they leave the enterprise, in so far as the payments are not made under a collective agreement;
(k)
housing allowances payable in cash by employers to their employees. |
3.017. |
It should be stressed that the data to be entered are gross wages and salaries, including wage and salary taxes and any higher rates of these taxes and employees' social security contributions. In cases where net wages and salaries are paid by employers to their employees, therefore, they should be increased by the value of these items. |
3.018. |
Gross wages and salaries in kind comprise goods and services made available by employers to their employees free of charge or at reduced prices for use by the employees and their families, as and when they wish, to satisfy their needs. They do not necessarily figure in the production process. Their value is the value of the benefit which they represent: the value of the goods if they are provided free of charge, or the difference between the latter value and the payments to the employees if they are provided at reduced prices These items, which are of considerable significance in the EAA, include the following components:
(a)
agricultural products made available to employees free of charge or at reduced prices, by way of remuneration ( 36 );
(b)
accommodation services produced for own account and provided to employees free of charge or at reduced prices ( 37 );
(c)
goods and services purchased by employers, provided that these purchases fulfil the definition of wages in kind (i.e. when they do not constitute intermediate consumption). In particular, the transport of employees between their place of work and home is part of their wages in kind, unless the journeys take place during the employer's time. This category includes purchased accommodation services and children's crèches, etc. (cf. ESA 2010, 4.05). |
3.019. |
Wages and salaries in kind should be valued at their basic price or at the purchaser price (depending on whether the items are produced by the unit or purchased from outside). |
3.020. |
Gross wages and salaries, by contrast, do not include expenditure by employers which is to their own benefit and incurred in the interest of the enterprise. The items in question are, inter alia: allowances towards/reimbursements of expenditure on travel, separation or removal incurred by employees in the course of their duties, entertainment expenses incurred by employees on behalf of the enterprise and expenditure on providing amenities at the place of work (e.g. sports and recreational facilities). Similarly, cash payments by employers to their employees for the purchase of tools or special clothing (including amounts which employees are contractually obliged to devote to such purposes) are not part of gross wages and salaries included under this heading. ►M6 All these items are recorded in the intermediate consumption of employers (cf. ESA 2010, 4.07). ◄ |
3.021. |
Employers' social contributions include the value of social contributions paid by employers to ensure that their employees are covered by social welfare provisions (except employees' social contributions deducted at source from gross wages or salaries (cf. 3.017). These contributions may be actual or imputed. |
3.022. |
Actual social contributions represent the payments made by employers, including statutory, contractual and voluntary contributions by way of insurance against risks and social hardship. These social contributions are paid to insurers (social security administrations or private insurers). Although paid directly to insurers, they are treated as a component of compensation of employees since the latter are deemed to receive the contributions and then pay them to insurance enterprises. |
3.023. |
Employers' imputed social contributions represent the counterpart to other social insurance benefits, paid directly by employers to their employees or former employees and other eligible persons without involving an insurance enterprise or autonomous pension fund ( 38 ) (cf. ESA 2010, 4.10). These contributions are recorded during the period in which the work is performed (if they are the counterpart of compulsory social benefits) or when the benefits are provided (if they are the counterpart of voluntary social benefits). Employers' imputed social contributions is split into two categories: (a) Employers' imputed pension contributions and (b) Employers' imputed non-pension contributions (ESA 2010, 4.10 and 4.97). |
3.024. |
It must be stressed that, in the EAA, if the production units are individual enterprises, the compensation of employees does not include the remuneration for work carried out on the holding by the holder or non-salaried members of his family; these persons share in the mixed income, which is the balance of the generation of income account for individual enterprises. If, however, the production units are part of a corporation (cf. 5.09 and 5.10), all remuneration has to be recorded as compensation of employees. |
D. TAXES ON PRODUCTION AND IMPORTS
(cf. ESA 2010, 4.14 to 4.29)
3.025. |
Taxes on production and imports are compulsory, unrequited payments, in cash or in kind which are levied by general government, or by the institutions of the European Union, in respect of the production and importation of goods and services, the employment of labour, the ownership or use of land, buildings or other assets used in production. ►M6 These taxes are payable whether or not profits are made (cf. ESA 2010, 4.14). ◄ |
3.026. |
Taxes on production and imports are divided into:
—
taxes on products (D.21):
—
VAT-type taxes (D.211),
—
taxes and duties on imports excluding VAT (D.212), and
—
taxes on products, except VAT and import taxes (D.214)
—
other taxes on production (D.29)
|
1. |
Taxes on products
|
2. |
Treatment of VAT
|
3. |
Other taxes on production
|
E. SUBSIDIES
(cf. ESA 2010, 4.30 to 4.40)
3.051. |
Subsidies are current unrequited payments which general government or the institutions of the European Union make to resident producers, with the objective of influencing their levels of production, their prices or the remuneration of the factors of production. Other non-market producers can receive other subsidies on production only if those payments depend on general regulations applicable to market and non-market producers as well. ►M6 By convention, subsidies on products are not recorded in non-market output (P.13) (cf. ESA 2010, 4.30). ◄ |
3.052. |
Subsidies are classified into:
—
subsidies on products (D.31):
—
import subsidies (D.311),
—
other subsidies on products (D.319), and
—
other subsidies on production (D.39).
|
1. |
Subsidies on products
|
2. |
Other subsidies on production
|
F. PROPERTY INCOME
(cf. ESA 2010, 4.41 to 4.76)
1. Definition
3.070. |
Property income is the income receivable by the owner of a financial asset or tangible non-produced asset in return for providing funds to, or putting the tangible non-produced asset at the disposal of, another institutional unit (ESA 2010, 4.41). |
3.071. |
The ESA 2010 classifies property incomes in the following way:
—
interest (D.41),
—
distributed incomes of corporations (dividends and withdrawals from income of quasi-corporations) (D.42),
—
reinvested earnings on foreign direct investment (D.43),
—
other investment income (D.44): investment income attributable to insurance policy holders (D.441), investment income payable on pension entitlements (D.442); investment income attributable to collective investment funds shareholders (D.443),
—
rents (D.45).
|
3.072. |
The EAA are concerned only with property income accounted for in the entrepreneurial income account (cf. sequence of accounts, 1.38 to 1.48). This account records on the resources side income received by units as a result of their direct participation in the production process (operating surplus/mixed income) and receivable property income received. It records on the uses side payable property income linked to agricultural activities (and inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities). Generally speaking, the entrepreneurial income account can only be calculated for the institutional sectors, although it may be calculated for an industry if certain property income can be attributed to local KAUs. |
3.073. |
Only three types of property income can be of relevance to the EAA:
—
interest (D.41), rents (D.45) and investment income attributable to insurance policy holders (D.441).
|
2. Interest
(ESA 2010, 4.42- 4.52)
3.074. |
Interest is the charges payable on a capital loan. It includes payments to be made at intervals, fixed in advance, of a percentage (fixed or otherwise) of the value of the loan. In the EAA, interest is the counterpart of loans granted to meet the needs of agricultural holdings (for example, with a view to acquiring land, buildings, machines, vehicles or other equipment, even if these are used in the context of inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities). |
3.075. |
Interest also includes payments relating to leasing of fixed capital goods for their use in agriculture (possibly including land). Only the rent part (treated as an imputed loan granted by the lessor to the lessee) paid by the lessee is included under payment of interest (the capital part is recorded in the financial account). |
3.076. |
It should be noted that notional interest on fixed equity capital in agricultural holdings is not recorded under this heading; it appears as a component of the income of the agricultural enterprise (cf. 5.06). Similarly, the amount to be recorded as interest payable includes interest-rate subsidies to agriculture. |
3.077. |
Interest receivable in connection with agricultural activities by units belonging to corporate agricultural enterprises should also be recorded. Interest receivable by individual enterprises is excluded from the measure of entrepreneurial income of the agricultural industry, since it was felt that the majority of interest-bearing assets are not linked to the agricultural activity of the units and because it is very difficult to distinguish family assets from assets used in production ( 45 ). |
3.078. |
Interest is recorded in line with the accrual principle, i.e. as accrued interest (not as interest paid). |
3.079. |
The value of the services provided by financial intermediaries being allocated among different customers, the actual payments or receipts of interest to or from financial intermediaries need to be adjusted to eliminate the margins that represent the implicit charges made by financial intermediaries. The estimated value of these costs should be subtracted from the interest paid by borrowers to financial intermediaries and added to the interest received by depositors. ►M6 The costs are regarded as remuneration for services rendered by financial intermediaries to their clients and not as an interest payment (see 2.107.1 and 2.108(i); ESA 2010, 4.51). ◄ |
3. Rents (on land and subsoil assets)
(ESA 2010, 4.72 – 4.76)
3.080. |
►M6 Rents correspond to payments made to the owner of non-produced tangible assets (land and subsoil assets) in return for making assets available to another unit. ◄ In the EAA, this item corresponds mainly to rents paid on land by holders to the landowners ( 46 ). |
3.081. |
Where the owner pays certain charges directly linked to agricultural activity (property tax, the cost of maintaining land, etc.), the rents to be recorded should be reduced accordingly. These charges are accounted for as other taxes on production (in the case of property tax) or intermediate consumption (in the case of land maintenance). |
3.082. |
Rents on land do not include the rentals of buildings or dwellings situated on it; those rentals are treated as the payment for a market service provided by the owner to the tenant of the building or dwelling, and are to be recorded in the accounts as the intermediate consumption of services or as final consumption expenditure (household accounts), depending on the type of tenant unit. If there is no objective basis on which to split the payment between rent on land and rental on the buildings situated on it, the whole amount is to be recorded as rent on land. ►M6 This rule is an adapted version of the ESA recommendation (cf. ESA 2010, 4.73) ( 47 ). ◄ |
3.083. |
All rent on land should be recorded under this heading whether the land is rented for less or more than one year. |
3.084. |
Rents do not include:
—
the rental value of dwellings contained in these buildings; this is remuneration for a market service which is a component of private consumption (i.e. the occupant pays the rent from his net residual income),
—
rents paid for the professional use of non-residential buildings (cf. 2.108(a)),
—
depreciation of buildings,
—
current maintenance expenditure on buildings (cf. 2.106),
—
property tax (cf. 3.048(a)),
—
expenses relating to buildings insurance (cf. 2.108(g)).
|
3.085. |
In the case of land and buildings used by the owner, there is no need to account for notional rents. The rents corresponding to non-produced intangible assets such as patented assets and production rights (milk quotas), should be recorded as intermediate consumption (cf. 2.108(n)). |
4. Investment income attributable to insurance policy holders (not covered by the EAA)
3.086. |
►M6 Investment income attributable to insurance policy holders corresponds to total primary incomes received from the investment of insurance technical reserves and pension funds (cf. ESA 2010, 4.68). ◄ These technical reserves are treated as assets belonging to the insured. The ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ provides for the calculation of entrepreneurial income to include, as resources, incomes received from the investment of insurance technical reserves. This income is attributed to the insured as property income attributed to insurance policy holders. The latter is treated as being paid back to the insurance enterprises in the form of additional premiums, since, in practice, the income is retained by them (cf. ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ , 4.69). |
3.087. |
►M6 Investment income attributable to insurance policy holders is not covered by the EAA. ◄ In fact, in order to be meaningful, a measure for the income of agricultural activity should:
—
include all flows related to non-life insurance (value of the service, income attributed to insurance policy holders, net premiums and claims): in this case, the income measured appears after description of all transactions of redistribution (between insurance policy holders and insurance enterprises and between periods) linked to non-life insurance, or
—
only take into account the value of the service (which is definitely acquired from the insurance enterprise) (cf. 2.108. (g)): in this case, the income measured appears before description of all these transactions of redistribution.
The EAA have opted for the second solution. |
G. CAPITAL TRANSFERS
(cf. ESA 2010, 4.145 to 4.167)
3.088. |
The only capital transfers recorded in the EAA are receivable capital transfers, i.e. investment grants and other capital transfers. These distributive transactions are recorded in the capital account (cf. 1.41 and 1.48). |
1. |
Investment grants
|
2. |
Other capital transfers
|
H. CONSUMPTION OF FIXED CAPITAL
(cf ESA 2010, 3.139- 3.145)
3.098. |
The foreseeable wear and tear and obsolescence of fixed capital goods over the accounting period represent a charge which is implicit so long as the item is not replaced by a new acquisition. This wear and tear and obsolescence are measured by fixed capital consumption. Its inclusion under ‘uses’ in the production account allows expenditure on fixed capital formation to be distributed over the entire period of use. |
3.099. |
If the economic life of the means of production is more than one year, the consumption of fixed capital represents the amount of fixed capital used up in the production process during the accounting period as a result of normal wear and tear and foreseeable obsolescence ( 48 ). If, on the other hand, the means of production used have an economic life of less than one year, the wear and tear is recorded as intermediate consumption. |
3.100. |
All fixed capital goods (i.e. products) are the subject of consumption of fixed capital (although some flexibility is required in specific cases; cf. 3.105). This includes tangible and intangible fixed assets, major improvements to non-produced assets and the costs associated with the transfer of ownership. The consumption of fixed capital is not calculated for either stocks or work in progress, or for non-produced assets such as land, underground deposits and patented assets. |
3.101. |
The consumption of fixed capital is only one component of the change in the value of assets (together with GFCF, other changes in volume and nominal holding gains (net of losses); cf. 2.134). In particular, the consumption of fixed capital does not include other changes in the volume of assets (other than those due to GFCF):
—
exceptional losses due to disasters (earthquakes, war, drought, epidemics, etc.),
—
unforeseeable obsolescence, which is the difference between provisions made in the consumption of fixed capital for normal wear and tear and actual losses, accidental events causing depreciation greater than that accounted for on the basis of the anticipated consumption of fixed capital,
—
changes in the classification of fixed assets, i.e. changes in their economic use, as in the case of farming land or buildings converted for private use or a different economic use.
|
3.102. |
The consumption of fixed capital, which has to be distinguished from depreciation calculated for fiscal purposes and that appearing in the company accounts, should be evaluated on the basis of stocks of fixed capital goods and the (average) probable economic life of the various categories of goods in question. If no information on the stock of fixed capital goods is available, it is recommended that it be calculated using the perpetual inventory method and that its acquisition price in the reference period be evaluated (i.e. the replacement value of the assets during the reference year, not on the basis of historic values). The replacement value is ascertained from the prices which holders have to pay, during any given reference period, to replace a fixed capital good by a new one which resembles it as closely as possible. It is necessary to proceed in this manner in order to calculate net domestic product correctly. |
3.103. |
The consumption of fixed capital is calculated using the linear depreciation method, i.e. by attributing the value of the fixed capital good in question evenly throughout the period in which it is used. The rate of depreciation is defined by the formula 100/n, where ‘n’ represents the probable economic life of this category in years (‘n’ may vary from one country to another and over time). The rate of depreciation can, in certain cases, be geometric. In view of the use of the current replacement price and the fixed rate of consumption of fixed capital, the consumption of fixed capital varies from year to year unless the purchaser prices remain unchanged throughout the entire normal economic life of the asset. |
3.104. |
The consumption of fixed capital in the form of the costs associated with the transfer of the ownership of produced tangible and intangible assets should be calculated on the basis of an average economic life, conventionally put at one year. |
3.105. |
The consumption of fixed capital in animals corresponds to the anticipated decline in the productivity of animals if they are used for production purposes (milk, wool, etc.), which is reflected in the current value of future income obtainable form these animals. As the value of future income from productive animals declines over time, the animals will have to become the object of consumption of fixed capital. Given the practical difficulties of calculating the consumption of fixed capital for this type of asset, however, it was felt that the consumption of fixed capital should not be calculated for productive animals. The decision to exclude animals from this calculation was based on the following considerations:
—
depreciation in terms of productivity and economic value is linked to age but is not a direct, regular and continuous function of it, as is otherwise implicitly the case for depreciation,
—
the withdrawal of animals from the productive herd may be a function of the economic environment (changes in the prices obtainable for slaughtered animals and the prices of animal feedingstuffs, etc.).
|
3.106. |
Although these considerations are not a hindrance to calculating the consumption of fixed capital for livestock, they do make such calculations very complicated in terms of adequate definitions of average life and rates of consumption of fixed capital. Otherwise, it would be difficult to ensure consistency between forecast and actual average depreciation of animals. ►M6 This treatment also ensures compatibility between the EAA and the ESA 2010 (cf. ESA 2010, 3.140) and microeconomic accounts of the farm accountancy data network and obviates the need to distinguish between livestock having the character of fixed capital goods and livestock having the character of stock. ◄ |
IV. AGRICULTURAL LABOUR INPUT
4.01. |
Agricultural employment covers all persons — both employees and self-employed — providing salaried and non-salaried labour input to the resident units performing characteristic activities (agricultural and inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities) of the agricultural industry of the EAA. All persons of retiring age who continue to work on the holding are included in agricultural employment. Persons having not reached school-leaving age are not included. |
4.02. |
Employees are defined as all persons who, by agreement, work for another resident institutional unit (which is an agricultural unit) and receive a remuneration (recorded as compensation of employees, cf. Section C of Chapter III). The labour input provided by employees is referred to as salaried labour input. By convention, labour of non-family workers is classified as salaried labour input. When an agricultural unit is organised as a conventional company (cf. 5.09), all the labour input performed is classified as salaried labour input. |
4.03. |
Self-employed persons are defined as persons who are the sole owners, or joint owners, of the unincorporated enterprises in which they work. The labour input provided by self-employed persons is referred to as non-salaried labour input. Members of the holder's family who do not receive a compensation which is predefined and calculated according to their actual work are classified as self-employed. |
4.04. |
In the case of specific companies (cf. Section B of Chapter V), the labour input of workers is treated in the same manner as in unincorporated enterprises (sole proprietorships). The directors/shareholders share in the mixed income of the unit (non-salaried labour input), whilst their employees receive a remuneration (salaried labour input). |
4.05. |
Total hours worked represent the aggregate number of hours actually worked as an employee or self-employed for resident agricultural units, during the accounting period. |
4.06. |
►M6 A description of what total hours worked include and exclude can be found in ESA 2010 (11.27 and 11.28). ◄ Total hours worked do not cover work for the private household of the holder or manager. |
4.07. |
Annual work units (AWUs) are defined as full-time equivalent employment (corresponding to the number of full-time equivalent jobs), i.e. as total hours worked divided by the average annual number of hours worked in full-time jobs within the economic territory. |
4.08. |
One person cannot represent more than one AWU. This constraint holds even if someone is working in the agricultural industry for more than the number of hours defining full time. |
4.09. |
The agricultural labour input of persons who work less than full time on agricultural holdings is calculated as the quotient of the number of hours actually worked (per week or per year) and the number of hours actually worked (per week or per year) in a full-time job. |
4.10. |
The number of hours actually worked in a full-time job is not necessarily the same for all categories of labour. It is possible that the number of hours comprising a full-time job used for self-employed persons is greater than that used for employees. For in the latter case, the maximum number of hours to be worked are laid down in a contract. |
4.11. |
The number of hours worked by a person is not to be adjusted by some coefficient because of age (i.e. under 16 or over 65) or gender. Equality must be applied. ‘Full-time’ is determined by the number of hours worked and not as an evaluation of an amount and/or a quality produced. |
4.12. |
Unless there are reasons for preferring alternative sources, the AWU representing full-time work in agriculture should be based on the current definition in the Community surveys on the structure of agricultural holdings, as the minimum hours required by the national provisions governing contracts of employment. If these do not indicate the number of annual hours then 1 800 hours is to be taken as the minimum figure (225 working days of eight hours per day). |
V. AGRICULTURAL INCOME INDICATORS
5.01. |
One of the principal objectives of the EAA is to measure agricultural income and changes therein. |
A. |
DEFINITION OF INCOME AND BALANCING ITEMS
|
B. |
TREATMENT OF THE INCOME OF UNITS ORGANISED ON A CORPORATE BASIS
|
C. |
DEFINITION OF THE AGRICULTURAL INCOME INDICATORS
|
D. |
AGGREGATION OF INCOME INDICATORS FOR THE EUROPEAN UNION
|
E. |
DEFLATION OF INCOME INDICATORS
|
VI. VALUATION OF EAA AT CONSTANT PRICES
A. PRICE AND VOLUME MEASURES
(cf. ESA 2010, Chapter 10)
6.01. |
For the purposes of economic analysis, when looking at how values change, it is useful to distinguish between those value changes due to changes in volume and those due to changes in price. ►M6 The ESA 2010 (10.13 to 10.23) clearly states that the price component should only include changes relating to prices and that all other changes should be included in the volume component. ◄ Thus, differences in quality between products (physical characteristics, types of retail outlet, etc.) are to be taken into account as volume and not price changes. |
6.02. |
For many goods and services there exist several variations which differ in quality. The ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ defines several factors which give rise to differences in quality, but the most important for the EAA is that linked to physical characteristics. This recognises that within the definition of a given product, there may be physical differences which imply that the physical units (e.g. one tonne) are not identical in an economic sense. An example of this is with two tonnes of grain sold in two consecutive years. In year one all the grain is of milling quality, in year two, less than half is of milling quality, the rest is sold for feed. This means that the average quality of the grain has fallen. ►M6 The other difference in quality, important for the EAA, is that of a shift in sales of a product between two differently priced markets, e.g. domestic and external, industrial use and sales to consumers (cf. ESA 2010, 10.13 to 10.18). ◄ |
6.03. |
The indicators of volume and price used to compile data at constant prices have to take account of changes in quality. It is therefore recommended that work is conducted at the greatest level of detail in order to get as close as possible to entirely homogeneous elementary products. If the elementary products are entirely homogeneous, changes in volume can be estimated on the basis of changes in quantity. |
6.04. |
However, statistical information is often only available at a more aggregated level and therefore no longer concerns strictly homogeneous products. ►M6 In this case, the ESA 2010 (10.32) states that it is preferable to deflate the value for the current year by a suitable price index to estimate changes in volume (ESA 2010, 10.01). ◄ |
6.05. |
The level of detail for which the index used is assumed to be an elementary index (the product under investigation is thus considered as homogeneous) is called the elementary level of aggregation. In the EAA, the elementary level of aggregation corresponds at least to the most disaggregated level of the nomenclature within the data transmission table. A greater level of detail is, however, desirable for compiling price indices. |
6.06. |
For each aggregate of goods and services shown in the accounts, price and quantity measures have to be constructed so that value index = price index × volume index
This means that each and every change in the value of a given flow must be attributed to either a price change or a change in volume or a combination of the two (cf. ESA 2010, 10.12). |
6.07. |
The systematic breakdown of the changes in current value into the components ‘changes in price’ and ‘changes in volume’ is restricted to flows representing transactions of goods and services and to elements concerned in the valuation of these transactions (output, intermediate consumption, consumption of fixed capital, gross value added, net value added, GFCF, change in stocks, taxes and subsidies on products). |
B. PRINCIPLES AND METHOD FOR COMPILING EAA AT CONSTANT PRICES
1. Choice of index formula
▼M6 —————
6.09. |
►M6 In accordance with ESA 2010 (10.20), in the EAA, changes in volume are measured using Laspeyres-type indices and changes in price are measured using Paasche-type indices. ◄ Laspeyres volume index:
Paasche price index:
For each elementary product:
|
2. Base year
6.10. |
Changes in volume are measured using Laspeyres-type indices: changes in the quantities of elementary series are therefore weighted by the value in the base year. Changes in price are measured using Paasche-type indices: changes in the prices of elementary series are therefore weighted by the value in the current year at the prices for the base year. |
6.11. |
The base year is the year from which the prices are used to compile the weighting scheme. |
6.12. |
The most accurate way to measure changes in volume from one year to another is to use the most recent base year available. This approach guarantees that weightings are relatively up-to-date and avoids problems linked to weighting products that are no longer produced and new products that have emerged. It is for this reason that the EAA measures changes in volume using the weightings for the preceding year. |
3. Presenting series in relation to a reference year
6.13. |
The year used for submitting and presenting data at constant prices can be different from the base year; it is called the reference year. In a series of indices, the reference year is the one that takes the value 100. |
6.14. |
Series of volume indices in the prices of a reference year are obtained by chaining indices calculated in the prices of the preceding year (cf. ESA 2010, 10.20). |
6.15. |
It is important that a change of reference year has no effect on the changes in volume with respect to the preceding year. It is for this reason that EAA data are presented in relation to a fixed reference year by re-referencing each variable separately, regardless of whether these are aggregates or elementary indices. |
6.16. |
Example: Let us consider two homogeneous elementary products, A and B. The following series are based on the price structure for the preceding year:
The volume and price indices for the whole (A + B) depend on the weighting given to each product, A and B.
If these series are expressed in relation to a fixed reference year (e.g. n), the only way to retain the same n/n-1 volume indices is to chain the indices separately. This gives the following series (base equal to 100 in n):
(101,4 = 108,8 * 93,2/100)
The values at constant prices expressed in relation to the reference year n are:
(405,6 = 400 * 101,4/100)
As a result, the account is no longer additive. Adding the values at constant prices for A and B gives the following series:
Other than in the year following the reference year, the re-referenced series are not additive.
|
6.17. |
►M6 According to ESA 2010 (10.23), the non-additive constant price data are published without any adjustment ( 51 ). ◄ This is also the approach taken by the EAA. It is to be explained to users, however, that the tables are not additive. |
4. Calculation of value added at fixed year prices
6.18. |
Value added constitutes the balancing item of the production account. As such, it is not possible to split value added directly into a price component and a volume component. ►M6 The theoretically correct method for calculating value added at fixed year prices is to carry out ‘double deflation’ (cf. ESA 2010, 10.31-10.32). ◄ |
6.19. |
Gross value added expressed in the prices of the preceding year is therefore defined as the difference between output measured in the prices of the preceding year and intermediate consumption measured in the prices of the preceding year. Net value added in the prices of the preceding year is defined as the difference between gross value added in the prices of the preceding year and consumption of fixed capital in the prices of the preceding year. The value added in prices of a fixed reference year is obtained by re-referencing. |
6.20. |
Example: A series of current values and values in the prices of the preceding year (volumes) concerning output and intermediate consumption is set out below:
The value added in volume terms is obtained by deducting the volume of intermediate consumption from the volume of output. The following series is derived:
In this way, the following volume indices in the prices of the preceding year are obtained:
(118,2 = 130/110 * 100) (103,7 = 140/135 * 100)
The gross value added of a particular year in prices of year n (fixed year prices) is derived by multiplying the current value for n by the volume chain index.
VA n + 1 (in n prices) = 110 * 1,182 = 130
VA n + 2 (in n prices) = 110 * 1,182 * 1,037 = 135.
|
5. Breakdown of taxes and subsidies on products into volume and price components
6.21. |
The breakdown of valuations at basic price into respective volume and price components presupposes that this breakdown also applies to the taxes and subsidies on products. The choice made in the EAA is the following one: |
6.22. |
The volume index of the subsidy (or the tax) on product is identical to the volume index of the output at the producer price. In this case, the volume index of the output is the same whether expressed in the producer price or in the basic price. |
6.23. |
This solution has another advantage: the volume index is independent of the method of valuation. Consequently, the interpretation of the price and volume indices at the basic price, is straightforward: for a perfectly homogeneous basic product, the volume index is identical to the quantity index; the price index reflects the change in the average basic price. |
6.24. |
Example: For a given product, the value of output at the producer price in year n is 1 000 ; the value of output in year n+1 is 900. The volume index of output is 102. This product is subsidised. The value of the subsidy for year n is 100; the value of the subsidy for year n+1 is 150. The volume/price breakdown of the subsidy is carried out in the following way:
The volume index of the subsidy is the same as that of the output at the producer price. |
VII. REGIONAL ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS FOR AGRICULTURE (‘REAA’)
A. GENERAL PRINCIPLES
1. Introduction
7.01. Regional accounts play an important role in the formulation, implementation and evaluation of regional policies. Objective, reliable, consistent, coherent, comparable, relevant and harmonised regional statistical indicators provide a firm foundation for policies aimed at reducing economic and social disparities between the regions of the Union.
7.02. The REAA are a regional-level adaptation of the EAA.
7.03. The REAA comprise the same set of accounts as the EAA, but conceptual and measurement problems result in a set of accounts for regions which are more limited in scope and detail than EAA at national level.
7.04. As regional accounts, the REAA shall be compiled on the basis of regional data collected directly, and of national data that have regional breakdowns based on assumptions. The lack of sufficiently complete, timely and reliable regional information requires assumptions in compiling regional accounts. That implies that some differences between regions are not necessarily reflected in regional accounts (ESA 2010, 13.08).
2. Regional economy, regional territory
7.05. Any compilation of regional accounts, whether they refer to industries or institutional sectors, needs a strict definition of the regional economy and regional territory. In theory, the agricultural industry in a region covers the units (agricultural holdings) engaged in agricultural activities (cf. 1.60 to 1.66) on the regional territory.
7.06. A regional economy of a country is part of the total economy of that country. The total economy is defined in terms of institutional units and sectors. It consists of all the institutional units that have a centre of predominant economic interest in the economic territory of a country. The economic territory does not coincide exactly with the geographic territory (cf. 7.08). The economic territory of a country is divided into regional territories and the extra-regio territory (ESA 2010, 13.09).
7.07. The regional territory, as defined in the ESA 2010, consists of that part of the economic territory of a country that is directly assigned to a region. Free zones, bonded warehouses and factories under customs control, are attached to the regions where they are located.
7.08. However, that division of territory is not totally consistent with the concept of national economic territory as used by the national accounts. The extra-regio territory is made up of parts of the economic territory of a country which cannot be attached directly to a single region, and which are excluded from the REAA, i.e.:
the national air-space, territorial waters and the continental shelf lying in international waters over which the country enjoys exclusive rights;
territorial enclaves, i.e. geographic territories situated in the rest of the world and used, under international treaties or agreements between States, by general government agencies of the country (embassies, consulates, military bases, scientific bases, etc.);
deposits of oil, natural gas etc. in international waters, outside the continental shelf of the country, worked by resident units.
7.09. The Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics (NUTS) classification established by Regulation (EC) No 1059/2003 of the European Parliament and of the Council ( 52 ) provides a single, uniform breakdown of the economic territory of the Union. The REAA require statistics at NUTS 2 level as commonly established under the current arrangements under that Regulation. For national purposes, regional accounts may also be compiled at a more detailed regional level, namely at NUTS 3 level, where applicable (ESA 2010, 13.12).
3. Basic unit in the compilation of the REAA
7.10. The units used for the regional accounts by industry are local KAUs. The local KAU is the observable form of the production unit.
7.11. The statistical approach (industry) ‘makes do’ with an observable unit even if that means deviating from the single activity. As with the 2008 SNA, the ESA 2010 prefers the statistical approach and advocates the local KAU for the compilation of national accounts by industry. They thus define the same unit for the industries whether those are covered at regional or national level.
7.12. Like the EAA, the REAA use the agricultural holding – ‘adapted’ in line with certain conventions to comply with the objectives in question – as the basic unit for the agricultural industry. There are two crucial reasons for that choice. On the one hand, the agricultural holding unit is the local KAU for agriculture (cf. 1.09 to 1.17), defined as that part of a KAU which refers to the local level. The local KAU is also the most appropriate unit for the agricultural industry, even if it includes non-agricultural secondary activities, which cannot be shown separately from the agricultural activities (cf. 1.15 and 1.16, 1.25 to 1.32).
7.13. Using the agricultural holding as the basic unit means including the non-agricultural secondary activities of those agricultural holdings in the REAA (cf. 7.12). Since the purpose of the EAA is to measure, describe and analyse the formation of income from agricultural economic activity, it excludes units that produce solely a leisure activity (e.g. kitchen gardens and private livestock rearing). In contrast, units engaged in subsistence farming are included in the EAA (cf. 1.24).
7.14. The agricultural holding is the reference unit for statistical surveys relating to agriculture, whether those are national or regional. That has the advantage that evaluations of output in quantity terms may be based directly on the statistical systems for measuring areas, yields, herd sizes, etc. The choice of the agricultural holding also makes for better accounting consistency.
4. Methods of compiling the REAA
7.15. The ESA (ESA 2010, 13.24 to 13.32) proposes two methods, applying to either industries or institutional sectors: the bottom-up and the top-down methods. The bottom-up method consists of collecting the data at the level of the units (local KAUs, institutional units) and then summing them to obtain the regional value for the different aggregates. The top-down method reconstructs the regional values by breaking down the national figure, using an indicator that reflects as closely as possible the regional distribution of the variable in question. Those two methods may also be combined in various ways, combinations which the ESA refers to as a mixture of bottom-up and top-down methods. However, collecting the same information more than once, thus creating redundancy in the data reporting, shall be avoided. Yet priority is given to the bottom-up method, although it is realised that in many cases a mixture of bottom-up and top-down methods is actually used. Details of the specific method and sources shall be set out in full transparency in the quality reports, indicating which regional data have been collected directly and which data are based on national data with regional breakdowns based on assumptions.
5. Concepts of residence and territory
7.16. Economic transactions of both enterprises and households may cross regional boundaries. Enterprises may also operate in more than one region, either at permanent sites or on a temporary basis, e.g. big farms may undertake work in different regions. Therefore, a clear principle is needed to help Member States to consistently allocate that interregional activity to a region.
7.17. The regional accounts of the industries are based on the criterion of residence of the production unit. Each industry at a regional level refers to the group of local KAUs of the same or similar principal economic activity, which have their centre of economic interest in that regional territory. More often than not, that centre of interest is associated with a specific long-term location in the region, like the institutional units to which the local KAUs belong.
7.18. However, the regional accounts have a number of distinct features. For certain activities, it is not always easy to define the region as a specific area. The relationship between the location of the head office and the physical location of the agricultural holding can create a problem, as factors of agricultural production may be managed by a head office in another region. For the REAA, it is important to split the two entities, and for that reason an agricultural holding must be assigned to the region where its factors of production are situated and not to the region where its headquarters are located. One head office may therefore give rise to several units within the meaning of the REAA, i.e. to as many units as there are regions of residence for local KAUs that are away from the region of the head office.
7.19. An alternative concept, which is generally not applied in the national and regional accounts, would be strictly territorial. That concept implies that activities are allocated to the territory where they actually take place, regardless of the residence of the units involved in the activity.
7.20. Though the residential approach takes precedence for the regional allocation of transactions of resident units, ESA 2010 provides for some limited scope for the application of the territorial approach (ESA 2010, 13.21). That occurs where notional units are created for land and buildings in the region or country in which the land or buildings are located.
7.21. In the hypothetical case, where units resident in a region only have activities within their regional territory, the residence concept coincides with the territory concept. That is also the case for the regional allocation based on notional units created for land and buildings and for unincorporated enterprises in other countries or in regions that are different from the region of residence of the owner.
6. Agricultural industry and characteristic units
7.22. The industry consists of all the local KAUs, which carry out an identical or similar economic activity (cf. 1.59). The agricultural industry, as described in the EAA, corresponds, in principle, to Division 01 in NACE Revision 2, with differences shown in 1.62 to 1.66. The scope of the REAA is defined on the basis of the list of characteristic activities drawn up for the EAA. There are some differences between the agricultural industry in the EAA, and thus in the REAA, and the industry established for the central framework of the national accounts (cf. 1.93).
B. TRANSACTIONS IN PRODUCTS
7.23. Valuing agricultural output poses a number of specific problems. The most important relate to seasonal products, livestock production and the timing of the entries in the accounts. The EAA methodology puts forward precise rules governing how the effects of the storage of seasonal products shall be taken into account, how the output of livestock shall be measured and how products on which work is in progress must be recorded. Those principles shall be complied with when the REAA are compiled. However, that does not rule out certain adaptations at regional level, for example for livestock production. It should be stressed that the total of the regional valuation must be identical with the EAA valuations.
1. Output
(a) Measurement of output
7.24. In the REAA, output of a region represents all products within the scope of EAA produced over the accounting period in that region by all the units of the agricultural industry, whether they are intended for marketing outside the industry, for sale to other agricultural holdings or, in certain cases, for use by the same agricultural holding. Consequently:
any agricultural product leaving an agricultural holding in the region shall be recorded as part of the output of the region, irrespective of its destination or the unit buying it;
certain agricultural products used as intermediate consumption by the same agricultural holding shall be included in the output of the region (cf. 2.056).
7.25. The production process of livestock generally takes several years. When livestock is valued, a distinction must be made between animals classified as fixed assets (breeding and draught animals, dairy cows, etc.) and those classified as stocks (animals intended mainly for meat). Thus, in order to avoid double counting, transactions involving the movement of animals between agricultural holdings (which are taken to be positive sales for the agricultural holdings selling the livestock and negative sales for the purchasing agricultural holdings), are dealt with as set out below:
transactions between agricultural holdings in the same region involving animals classified as fixed assets cancel each other out, apart from the transfer of ownership costs ( 53 ); they are not entered as the agricultural holdings’ sales and are therefore not included in the output of the region in question;
animals classified as stock and which are the subject of a transaction between regions are treated as positive sales (along with exports) for the region of origin and animals bought from other regions as negative sales (along with imports) ( 54 );
when ownership transfer costs (transport, trade margins, etc.) relate to trade in animals classified as stock, they are deducted from output; that happens automatically when purchases from agricultural holdings in other regions are involved, since the costs are part of negative sales, whereas an adjustment must be made in sales, and thus in output, for trade in animals between agricultural holdings in the same region.
(b) Valuation of output
7.26. Output shall be valued at basic prices (cf. 2.082), i.e. including subsidies on products, less taxes on products. That method of calculation means that taxes and subsidies on products need to be broken down by region.
2. Intermediate consumption
(a) Definition
7.27. Intermediate consumption consists of the goods (other than fixed assets) and market services consumed during the production process to produce other goods (cf. 2.097 to 2.109).
7.28. When the REAA are compiled, intermediate consumption includes:
agricultural products purchased for consumption during the production process from other agricultural holdings (whether in the same region or in another region);
certain products used as intra-unit consumption and entered as output (cf. 2.054 to 2.058 and 7.24).
7.29. The particular case of FISIM is treated in regional accounts in the same way as in national accounts. If the estimation of stocks of loans and deposits is available by region, the bottom-up method can be used. However, usually estimates of stocks of loans and deposits are not available by region. Where that is the case, the allocation of FISIM to the user industry is made with a second-best method: regional gross output or gross value added by industry are used as distribution indicators (ESA 2010, 13.40).
(b) Valuation of intermediate consumption
7.30. All products and services used for intermediate consumption shall be valued at the purchaser price (excluding deductible VAT) (cf. 2.110 to 2.114).
3. Gross capital formation
7.31. Gross capital formation for agriculture is subdivided into:
GFCF;
changes in inventories.
(a) GFCF
7.32. There is fixed capital formation in agriculture whenever a holder acquires or produces fixed assets which are intended to be used for a period of more than 1 year as a means of production in the agricultural production process. The allocation criterion for the recording of GFCF refers to the user industries and not to the industry to which the legal owner belongs.
7.33. Fixed assets owned by a multiregional unit are allocated to the local KAUs where they are used. Fixed assets used under an operating lease are recorded in the region of the owner of the assets, and those used under a financial lease are recorded in the region of the user (ESA 2010, 13.33).
7.34. New assets being included in fixed capital are entered gross, i.e. without deducting the consumption of fixed capital. In addition, the consumption of fixed capital is generally calculated on those assets. Net capital formation is obtained by deducting the consumption of fixed assets from gross capital formation.
7.35. Production units can sell existing assets to each other, e.g. second-hand machinery. When assets move between industries and regions, the total price paid shall be included in the GFCF in one industry or region and the price received shall be deducted from GFCF in the other industry or region. Transaction costs of ownership of assets, such as legal fees on sales of land and existing buildings, are counted as additional GFCF by the acquirer, even if some of the costs are paid by the seller.
7.36. The GFCF for livestock of a region must be compiled in accordance with ESA 2010 (3.124 to 3.138) and 2.149 to 2.161 of this Annex. The GFCF for livestock is equivalent to the difference between livestock acquisitions over the year (natural growth and purchases outside the region including imports), including those resulting from own-account production, and livestock disposals (for slaughter, sales to other regions, including exports, or any other final use). When all the regions are aggregated, it is important to make sure that interregional flows cancel each other out (excluding ownership transfer costs) so that the sum of all the regional GFCFs is the same as the GFCF of the national agricultural accounts. When the bottom-up method is used, the following applies: sales of animals to agricultural holdings in other regions constitute negative GFCF whereas purchases from other regions are positive GFCF. For the calculation of GFCF for livestock of a region, the recommended indirect method may be used (cf. 2.156).
(b) Changes in inventories
7.37. Inventories comprise all the assets which are not part of fixed capital and which, at a given moment, are held temporarily by production units. A distinction is made between two types of inventories: input inventories and output inventories (cf. 2.171).
7.38. For animals classified as inventories, the trade to be taken into account in the calculation of changes in inventories includes sales to, and purchases from, other regions as well as imports and exports.
C. DISTRIBUTIVE TRANSACTIONS AND OTHER FLOWS
7.39. The practical difficulties of obtaining reliable regional information on distributive transactions in certain cases, in particular when units carry out activities in more than one region, or when the region is not always a clearly defined area in which certain activities are carried out, explain why the ESA covers the regional accounts of the agricultural industry only with respect to a few aggregates: value added, subsidies, taxes, compensation of employees, rents and other income, interest and GFCF.
1. General rules
7.40. The distributive transactions are recorded on an accrual basis, i.e. at the time an economic value, amount due or claim is created, transformed or cancelled or ceases to exist, and not when payment is actually made. That recording principle (based on rights and obligations) is applied to all flows, irrespective of whether they are monetary flows, or whether they occur between units or within a single unit.
7.41. However, when the date on which the claim (debt) is acquired cannot be determined precisely, the payment date or another acceptable approximation of the accrual basis may be used (cf. 3.007).
2. Value added
(a) General rules
7.42. Value added is the result of the production activity of an economy or of one of its industries during a given period, and it is the balancing item of the production account. It is the difference between the value of output and the value of intermediate consumption. It is a key item in measuring the productivity of an economy or industry (cf. 3.013) or a region or industry within a region.
(b) Valuation of value added
7.43. Value added may be entered gross (gross value added at basic prices) or net (net value added at basic prices), i.e. before or after the deduction of the consumption of fixed capital. In line with the method for valuing output (basic price) and intermediate consumption (purchaser prices), value added is measured at basic prices (cf. 3.013).
7.44. The use of basic prices means that the taxes on products and subsidies on products must be assigned to specific goods and services, which then have to be allocated among the regions.
7.45. By deducting other taxes on production from the value added at basic prices, and adding other subsidies on production, the value added at factor cost is obtained. Net value added at factor cost constitutes the income of the factors of production (cf. 3.014).
3. Consumption of fixed capital
7.46. In the REAA, goods and services which make up the agricultural holding’s fixed capital (such as plantations yielding repeat products, machinery and buildings, major improvements to land, software, costs of ownership transfer of non-produced assets) suffer wear and tear and obsolescence as means of production in the production process. Such wear and tear and obsolescence are measured as the consumption of fixed capital. Similar to the EAA, the consumption of fixed capital shall not be calculated for productive animals.
4. Subsidies
7.47. The REAA apply the same rules as the EAA: flows that are classified as operating subsidies in the EAA are classified in the same way in the REAA, a similar treatment applying for flows in the form of capital transfers.
5. Taxes
7.48. The REAA apply the same rules as the EAA: the different kind of taxes are classified in the same way in REAA as they are classified in EAA.
6. Compensation of employees
7.49. For producers, compensation of employees is allocated to the local KAUs where the people are employed. Where those data are not available, compensation of employees is allocated as a second best method, based on the hours worked. If neither compensation of employees nor hours worked are available, the number of employees by local KAU is used (cf. ESA 2010, 13.42).
7. Net operating surplus
7.50. Net operating surplus is obtained from net value added at basic prices by deducting the compensation of employees and other taxes on production and by adding other subsidies on production.
8. Interest, rents
7.51. The REAA apply the same rules as the EAA: flows that are classified as interest, rents in the EAA are classified in the same way in the REAA.
9. Agricultural entrepreneurial income: general calculation rules
7.52. Directly payable property income arising from agricultural activities and non-agricultural secondary activities, i.e. interest paid on loans taken out in connection with those activities, including for the purchase of agricultural land, and rents paid to landowners, is deducted from operating surplus (cf. 3.070 to 3.087).
D. A BRIEF LOOK AT IMPLEMENTATION
1. Introduction
7.53. This section aims to highlight some aspects of the methodology, in particular the choice of agricultural holding and the measure of output.
7.54. The agricultural holding is the reference unit for statistical surveys on agriculture, at both national and sub-national level. That is a major advantage for the REAA because it means that the valuation of output quantities can be based directly on statistical systems for measuring land areas, yields, herd sizes etc. Choosing the agricultural holding also has the advantage of enabling accounts to be more consistent. Output and costs relate, in fact, to identical sets of units, even if the extrapolation methods vary from one source to another. Lastly, choosing the agricultural holding, together with the concepts of characteristic activities and units, avoids having to make adjustments that might be contentious, as could be the case for kitchen gardens and private non-holder livestock rearing. That convention makes it easier to make comparisons between countries. Indeed, the link with statistical data in physical quantities, which are crucial for agriculture and guarantee that measurements of accounting entries will be consistent because adjustments or ‘extra-statistical’ corrections are thus restricted, obviously simplifies and improves the calculations. Those aspects are also consistent with the aim of giving priority to the bottom-up approach in the REAA.
2. Defining regional agriculture
7.55. For each region, the agricultural industry consists of all the agricultural holdings whose factors of production are located in the region. That principle, which is consistent with the concept of the residence of production units, may pose a few problems: agricultural statistics usually define the location of agricultural holdings according to their headquarters and not directly according to the location of the factors of production. Those two locations are not always the same and that phenomenon is likely to be more frequent as agricultural holdings get larger. When the REAA are compiled, therefore, some agricultural holdings shall be reclassified between regions and even, in some cases, split up. That is likely to be difficult in practice, in which case it may be preferable to keep the same location for the agricultural holdings as in the statistical surveys. That proposal, however, depends on two conditions: firstly, the method of defining the location must be identical for all the regions in the country and secondly, the accounting entries must all be valued from sources that use the same rules for defining the location of the agricultural holdings.
3. Measuring agricultural output
7.56. Agricultural output includes certain crop products that are used again by the same agricultural holding in the form of intermediate consumption; that concerns mainly products for animal feedingstuffs. For arable crops in particular, regional output may often be determined on the basis of the quantities harvested in each region, those then being given a value via prices. In that case, all output is valued, whether it is intended for marketing outside the industry, sale to other agricultural holdings or use by the same agricultural holding. The output of each region is thus obtained directly, in line with the concept adopted in the EAA and the REAA. The prices by which output forming intra-unit consumption is valued may also be based on regional data, corresponding to the prices at which output is marketed. However, the lack of regional price data poses a general problem when it comes to valuing output, both (regional) output which is marketed and output which forms intra-unit consumption. Thus the REAA valuation of products forming intra-unit consumption raises the same difficulties as the valuation of products that are marketed. Obviously, it is a different matter when the quantities cannot be valued at regional level. In that case, a top-down method based on national-level valuations is generally the only one that can be used ( 55 ).
7.57. As regards animals, whether they are classified as inventories or fixed capital, the following elements shall be taken into account:
7.58. In certain cases, the indirect method of calculating animal output can be too difficult at regional level. In such cases, it is better to calculate output on the basis of a model using physical data and then adjust the values to those in the EAA.
4. Inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities
7.59. There are various ways of incorporating inseparable non-agricultural secondary activities into the REAA, depending on the type of activity. Some of those secondary activities are highly concentrated at regional level, for example agricultural product processing. In that case, output valuations of both quantities and prices can rely on local statistical data. For that output, the values in the EAA are de facto the same as those in the REAA. Other cases, however, may be more difficult. For example, there may be no regional source for some activities, especially if they are not concentrated in particular regions from the outset. For other activities, regional data are provided by statistical surveys or micro-economic accounts information (for example the farm accountancy data network (‘FADN’)) but there is no guarantee that those are regionally representative. Furthermore, data may be old with no sources available for reliable updating. Lastly, sometimes qualitative indicators are not available at regional level. In all those cases, the values of the EAA are the starting point for the REAA and the top-down method must often be used.
5. Intermediate consumption
7.60. Intermediate consumption in the REAA includes agricultural products used by agricultural holdings, whether those are directly traded between holders in the same region or different regions or change hands via intermediaries who may or may not become the owners of the products before they are resold. Moreover, some agricultural products of intra-unit consumption are also entered as intermediate consumption, essentially certain crops used as animal feed. Purchases of animals, even of animals that are imported, shall not be entered as intermediate consumption.
7.61. The first method of calculating the intermediate consumption of agricultural products at the regional level is to calculate the difference between the output of the REAA and that part of the output which is intended to leave the industry, on a product-by-product basis ( 56 ). However, it is not a totally accurate representation of the intermediate consumption of agricultural products in each region, because while agricultural products intended for intermediate consumption by agricultural holdings in other regions are included, agricultural products which come from agricultural holdings in other regions are not included. Intermediate consumption must, therefore, be adjusted in line with the values in the EAA.
7.62. Another calculation method is also possible, using the FADN as a source of information. That source enables the intermediate consumption of agricultural products to be valued, irrespective of whether they come from sales by other agricultural holdings or from other sources such as imports. However, the FADN does not cover in exactly the same way the products that are used as intermediate consumption by the same agricultural holding, and thus corrections are necessary. Similarly, therefore, intermediate consumption must be adjusted in line with the values in the EAA.
ANNEX II
TRANSMISSION PROGRAMME OF DATA
For each of the output items (items 01 to 18, including sub-items), the value at basic prices as well as its components (value at producer prices, subsidies on products and taxes on products) shall be transmitted.
The data for production account and for gross fixed capital formation (‘GFCF’) shall be transmitted at both current prices and the prices of the previous year.
All values shall be expressed in millions of units of the national currency. Labour input shall be expressed in 1 000 annual work units.
The data for regional economic accounts for agriculture (‘REAA’) shall be provided at NUTS 2 level and transmitted at current prices only.
1. Production account
|
|
Transmission concerning reference year n |
|||
a |
b |
c |
d |
||
Item |
List of variables |
November year n (EAA estimates) |
March year n+1 (EAA estimates) |
September year n+1 (EAA data) |
September year n+2 (REAA data) |
01 |
CEREALS (including seeds) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.1 |
Wheat and spelt |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.1/1 |
Soft wheat and spelt |
— |
— |
X |
X |
01.1/2 |
Durum wheat |
— |
— |
X |
X |
01.2 |
Rye and meslin |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.3 |
Barley |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.4 |
Oats and summer cereal mixtures |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.5 |
Grain maize |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.6 |
Rice |
X |
X |
X |
X |
01.7 |
Other cereals |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02 |
INDUSTRIAL CROPS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.1 |
Oil seeds and oleaginous fruits (including seeds) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.1/1 |
Rape and turnip rape seed |
— |
— |
X |
X |
02.1/2 |
Sunflower |
— |
— |
X |
X |
02.1/3 |
Soya |
— |
— |
X |
X |
02.1/4 |
Other oleaginous products |
— |
— |
X |
X |
02.2 |
Protein crops (including seeds) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.3 |
Raw tobacco |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.4 |
Sugar beet |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.5 |
Other industrial crops |
X |
X |
X |
X |
02.5/1 |
Fibre plants |
— |
— |
X |
— |
02.5/2 |
Hops |
— |
— |
X |
— |
02.5/3 |
Other industrial crops: others |
— |
— |
X |
— |
03 |
FORAGE PLANTS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
03.1 |
Fodder maize |
— |
— |
X |
X |
03.2 |
Fodder root crops (including forage beet) |
— |
— |
X |
X |
03.3 |
Other forage plants |
— |
— |
X |
X |
04 |
VEGETABLES AND HORTICULTURAL PRODUCTS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
04.1 |
Fresh vegetables |
X |
X |
X |
X |
04.1/1 |
Cauliflower |
— |
— |
X |
— |
04.1/2 |
Tomatoes |
— |
— |
X |
— |
04.1/3 |
Other fresh vegetables |
— |
— |
X |
— |
04.2 |
Plants and flowers |
X |
X |
X |
X |
04.2/1 |
Nursery plants |
— |
— |
X |
— |
04.2/2 |
Ornamental plants and flowers (including Christmas trees) |
— |
— |
X |
— |
04.2/3 |
Plantations |
— |
— |
X |
— |
05 |
POTATOES (including seeds) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06 |
FRUITS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.1 |
Fresh fruit |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.1/1 |
Dessert apples |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.1/2 |
Dessert pears |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.1/3 |
Peaches |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.1/4 |
Other fresh fruit |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.2 |
Citrus fruits |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.2/1 |
Sweet oranges |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.2/2 |
Mandarins |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.2/3 |
Lemons |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.2/4 |
Other citrus fruits |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.3 |
Tropical fruit |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.4 |
Grapes |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.4/1 |
Dessert grapes |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.4/2 |
Other grapes |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.5 |
Olives |
X |
X |
X |
X |
06.5/1 |
Table olives |
— |
— |
X |
— |
06.5/2 |
Other olives |
— |
— |
X |
— |
07 |
WINE |
X |
X |
X |
X |
07.1 |
Table wine |
— |
— |
X |
— |
07.2 |
Quality wine |
— |
— |
X |
— |
08 |
OLIVE OIL |
X |
X |
X |
X |
09 |
OTHER CROP PRODUCTS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
09.1 |
Vegetable materials used primarily for plaiting |
— |
— |
X |
— |
09.2 |
Seeds |
— |
— |
X |
— |
09.3 |
Other crop products: others |
— |
— |
X |
— |
10 |
CROP OUTPUT (01 TO 09) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11 |
ANIMALS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.1 |
Cattle |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.2 |
Pigs |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.3 |
Equines |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.4 |
Sheep and goats |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.5 |
Poultry |
X |
X |
X |
X |
11.6 |
Other animals |
X |
X |
X |
X |
12 |
ANIMAL PRODUCTS |
X |
X |
X |
X |
12.1 |
Milk |
X |
X |
X |
X |
12.2 |
Eggs |
X |
X |
X |
X |
12.3 |
Other animal products |
X |
X |
X |
X |
12.3/1 |
Raw wool |
— |
— |
X |
— |
12.3/2 |
Silkworm cocoons |
— |
— |
X |
— |
12.3/3 |
Other animal products: others |
— |
— |
X |
— |
13 |
ANIMAL OUTPUT (11+12) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
14 |
AGRICULTURAL GOODS OUTPUT (10+13) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
15 |
AGRICULTURAL SERVICES OUTPUT |
X |
X |
X |
X |
15.1 |
Agricultural services |
— |
— |
X |
— |
15.2 |
Renting of milk quota |
— |
— |
X |
— |
16 |
AGRICULTURAL OUTPUT (14+15) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
17 |
NON-AGRICULTURAL SECONDARY ACTIVITIES (INSEPARABLE) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
17.1 |
Processing of agricultural products |
X |
X |
X |
X |
17.2 |
Other inseparable secondary activities (goods and services) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
18 |
OUTPUT OF THE AGRICULTURAL INDUSTRY (16+17) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19 |
TOTAL INTERMEDIATE CONSUMPTION |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.01 |
Seeds and planting inventory |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.02 |
Energy; lubricants |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.02/1 |
— electricity |
— |
— |
X |
— |
19.02/2 |
— gas |
— |
— |
X |
— |
19.02/3 |
— other fuels and propellants |
— |
— |
X |
— |
19.02/4 |
— other |
— |
— |
X |
— |
19.03 |
Fertilisers and soil improvers |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.04 |
Plant protection products and pesticides |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.05 |
Veterinary expenses |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.06 |
Animal feedingstuffs |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.06/1 |
— feedingstuffs supplied by other agricultural holdings |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.06/2 |
— feedingstuffs purchased from outside the agricultural industry |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.06/3 |
— feedingstuffs produced and consumed by the same agricultural holding |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.07 |
Maintenance of materials |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.08 |
Maintenance of buildings |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.09 |
Agricultural services |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.10 |
Financial intermediation services indirectly measured (FISIM) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
19.11 |
Other goods and services |
X |
X |
X |
X |
20 |
GROSS VALUE ADDED AT BASIC PRICES (18-19) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
21 |
FIXED CAPITAL CONSUMPTION |
X |
X |
X |
X |
21.1 |
Equipment |
— |
— |
X |
— |
21.2 |
Buildings |
— |
— |
X |
— |
21.3 |
Plantations |
— |
— |
X |
— |
21.4 |
Others |
— |
— |
X |
— |
22 |
NET VALUE ADDED AT BASIC PRICES (20-21) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
2. Generation of income account
|
|
Transmission concerning reference year n |
|||
a |
b |
c |
d |
||
Item |
List of variables |
November year n (EAA estimates) |
March year n+1 (EAA estimates) |
September year n+1 (EAA data) |
September year n+2 (REAA data) |
23 |
COMPENSATION OF EMPLOYEES |
X |
X |
X |
X |
24 |
OTHER TAXES ON PRODUCTION |
X |
X |
X |
X |
25 |
OTHER SUBSIDIES ON PRODUCTION |
X |
X |
X |
X |
26 |
FACTOR INCOME (22-24+25) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
27 |
OPERATING SURPLUS / MIXED INCOME (22-23-24+25) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
3. Entrepreneurial income account
|
|
Transmission concerning reference year n |
|||
a |
b |
c |
d |
||
Item |
List of variables |
November year n (EAA estimates) |
March year n+1 (EAA estimates) |
September year n+1 (EAA data) |
September year n+2 (REAA data) |
28 |
RENTS AND OTHER REAL ESTATE RENTAL CHARGES TO BE PAID |
X |
X |
X |
X |
29 |
INTEREST PAYABLE |
X |
X |
X |
X |
30 |
INTEREST RECEIVABLE |
X |
X |
X |
X |
31 |
ENTREPRENEURIAL INCOME (27-28-29+30) |
X |
X |
X |
X |
4. Elements of the capital account
|
|
Transmission concerning reference year n |
|||
a |
b |
c |
d |
||
Item |
List of variables |
November year n (EAA estimates) |
March year n+1 (EAA estimates) |
September year n+1 (EAA data) |
September year n+2 (REAA data) |
32 |
GFCF IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS |
— |
— |
X |
X |
32.1 |
GFCF in plantations |
— |
— |
X |
— |
32.2 |
GFCF in animals |
— |
— |
X |
— |
33 |
GFCF IN NON-AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS |
— |
— |
X |
X |
33.1 |
GFCF in materials |
— |
— |
X |
— |
33.2 |
GFCF in buildings |
— |
— |
X |
— |
33.3 |
Other GFCF |
— |
— |
X |
— |
34 |
GFCF (EXCLUDING DEDUCTIBLE VAT) (32+33) |
— |
— |
X |
X |
35 |
NET FIXED CAPITAL FORMATION (EXCLUDING DEDUCTIBLE VAT) (34-21) |
— |
— |
X |
X |
36 |
CHANGES IN INVENTORIES |
— |
— |
X |
X |
37 |
CAPITAL TRANSFERS |
— |
— |
X |
X |
37.1 |
Investment grants |
— |
— |
X |
— |
37.2 |
Other capital transfers |
— |
— |
X |
— |
5. Agricultural labour input
|
|
Transmission concerning reference year n |
||
a |
b |
c |
||
Item |
List of variables |
November year n (EAA estimates) |
March year n+1 (EAA estimates) |
September year n+1 (EAA data) |
38 |
TOTAL AGRICULTURAL LABOUR INPUT |
X |
X |
X |
38.1 |
Non-salaried agricultural labour input |
X |
X |
X |
38.2 |
Salaried agricultural labour input |
X |
X |
X |
( 1 ) Regulation (EC) No 223/2009 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 March 2009 on European statistics and repealing Regulation (EC, Euratom) No 1101/2008 of the European Parliament and of the Council on the transmission of data subject to statistical confidentiality to the Statistical Office of the European Communities, Council Regulation (EC) No 322/97 on Community Statistics, and Council Decision 89/382/EEC, Euratom establishing a Committee on the Statistical Programmes of the European Communities (OJ L 87, 31.3.2009, p. 164).
( 2 ) Regulation (EC) No 1059/2003 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 May 2003 on the establishment of a common classification of territorial units for statistics (NUTS) (OJ L 154, 21.6.2003, p. 1).
( 3 ) Regulation (EC) No 1367/2006 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 6 September 2006 on the application of the provisions of the Aarhus Convention on Access to Information, Public Participation in Decision-making and Access to Justice in Environmental Matters to Union institutions and bodies (OJ L 264, 25.9.2006, p. 13).
( 4 ) European System of National and Regional Accounts — ESA 2010, Luxembourg 2013.
►M6 ( 5 ) System of National Accounts, 2008. Joint publication by the United Nations, European Commission, International Monetary Fund, OECD and World Bank. ◄
( 6 ) It should be pointed out that, although the ESA gives preeminence to local KAUs, the unit best suited to analyses of the production process is the unit of homogeneous production (UHP). This unit is used to analyse inputs and outputs, since it corresponds exactly to a type of activity. Institutional units are thus divided into as many UHPs as there are activities (other than ancillary). By grouping these UHPs it is possible to break down the economy into ‘pure’ (homogeneous) branches. A UHP cannot, as a rule, be directly observed. Therefore, the accounts of homogeneous branches cannot be compiled on the basis of groups of UHPs. The ESA describes a method for compiling these accounts. It involves attributing secondary production and the corresponding costs of activity branches to the appropriate homogeneous branches (ESA 2010, 2.153-2.156, 9.52 to 9.63).
( 7 ) These are small units producing for own consumption, not for selling, carrying out agricultural activities without depending economically on these activities.
( 8 ) Note however that some secondary activities are always considered separable from agricultural activity e.g. renting out of buildings or dwellings.
( 9 ) ►M3 ISIC Rev. 4 ◄ : United Nations international standard industrial classification of all economic activities.
( 10 ) See also the ‘Explanatory notes’: Eurostat: NACE Rev. 2, Statistical classification of economic activities in the European Community, Theme 2, Series E, Luxembourg, 2007.
( 11 ) The reason for this deviation from the general rule is that in these special cases a considerable part of the seed is obtained from the normal output of the corresponding cereal, oilseed, protein crop or potato harvest, whereas in other cases it is produced in specialised holdings.
( 12 ) See the ‘Introductory guidelines’ to NACE Rev. 2: Statistical classification of economic activities in the European Community, Theme 2, Series E, Luxembourg, 2007.
( 13 ) A secondary product is a product which is technically linked to the production of other products. It may be exclusive when linked to other products of the same group but whose production is exclusive to this group, or ordinary when linked to other products, but whose production is not peculiar to one group.
( 14 ) The equipment and machines belong to the cooperative, unlike with pools of machines, where they are generally the property of individual holdings.
( 15 ) Cf. 2.029 to 2.031 for the time at which stocks are recorded.
►M6 ( 16 ) FAO (1996) System of economic accounts for food and agriculture, United Nations, Rome. ◄
( 17 ) Output for these animals is calculated by adding own-account produced fixed capital goods (= entries less disposals of assets) and sales (= disposals).
( 18 ) When valuing trade, the costs involved in the transfer of ownership (trade margins and transport costs) are included in the value of the acquisition. In the case of trading between resident holdings, sales and purchases offset each other except for the transfer costs which are treated, in the calculation of output, as a ‘negative sale’.
( 19 ) An identical treatment applies to other agricultural products having the character of stocks.
( 20 ) This is generally the case if production is promoted, and in some cases only made possible, by this expenditure by the employer.
( 21 ) Leasing differs from simple hiring in that the risks and advantages of ownership in leasing are transferred de facto, but not de jure, from the lessor to the lessee (the user of the asset). The ESA takes account of the economic situation of leasing by considering, for its recording, that the lessor provides a credit to the lessee which allows the latter to purchase a durable good and to become its de facto owner. Leasing is thus regarded as a special form of investment financing.
( 22 ) As a direct consequence of this method, the costs associated with trade in ‘fixed assets’ livestock between units should be recorded under the GFCF of the acquirer.
( 23 ) In this case, the activity of felling the plantation and selling the timber come under forestry activity.
( 24 ) It should be noted that the cost of the grubbing service which may be invoiced by a grubbing company constitutes intermediate consumption of a service.
( 25 ) The treatment of sales of livestock for slaughter (i.e. by abattoirs or the farmer, including all sales to non-agricultural units for economic uses other than slaughter) as disposals of fixed assets constitutes a simplification of the accounting procedure for recording the disposal of fixed assets whose economic use has changed. ‘Fixed asset’ livestock are in fact converted into stocks by recording a flow entitled ‘other change in volume’ (cf. 2.136) entered in the ‘other changes in volume of assets’ account. They are only sold in the form of stocks, the sale then constituting a withdrawal from stocks and not a disposal of assets.
( 26 ) In as much as the sale and purchase occurred during the same accounting period. Otherwise, a disposal (for the period in which the sale occurred) and an acquisition (for the period in which the purchase occurred) are recorded.
( 27 ) Including slaughterings for own final consumption or payment in kind.
( 28 ) Trade in breeding livestock between farmers is not recorded in the accounts. This is also the case if the trading is carried out via agents (if the purchase and sale occurred in the same period). However, the cost of transfer of ownership (agents' services, trade margins, transport costs, etc) must be included in the value of the GFCF for livestock.
( 29 ) The 2008 SNA (10.94), unlike the ESA 2010 (3.140), considers that consumption of fixed capital should be calculated for livestock.
( 30 ) Any other method leading to equivalent results may be used.
( 31 ) This deduction corresponds to the theoretical case where the imports of productive animals are recorded as GFCF. In practice all animals imported by the agricultural industry are treated as changes in stocks (cf. 2.205).
( 32 ) Other changes in volume are generally understood to be stocks of goods destroyed in the wake of exceptional events (such as natural disasters). Current losses are included in withdrawals from stocks.
( 33 ) Use is made of the breakdown of output into sales (and other uses) and stock changes.
( 34 ) A similar result may be obtained by recording sales on a half-yearly basis and calculating the output of reference year n by adding together the sales of the second half of year n and those of the first half of year n + 1.
( 35 ) This category must not include payments made primarily in the employer's interest. Such payments are part of intermediate consumption (cf. 2.108 (e)).
( 36 ) Agricultural products provided to employees are output of the agricultural branch.
( 37 ) Accommodation services are treated as a separable non-agricultural activity, with the result that they only appear as compensation of employees and in the form of a deduction from the operating surplus of the agricultural industry. If they were an inseparable non-agricultural activity, they would be recorded as a component of production and a form of compensation of employees.
( 38 ) They correspond in particular to wages and salaries which employers continue to pay on a provisional basis to their employees in the event of illness, maternity, accidents at the workplace, invalidity or redundancy, in so far as the amounts concerned can be separately identified.
( 39 ) Turnover is the most important taxable item. All EU Member States raise turnover tax in the form of VAT. The rates of this tax vary from one Member State to another and indeed within individual Member States. Generally speaking, agricultural products are subject to a lower rate of tax than the standard rate.
( 40 ) The percentage rate may vary according to the type of product and channel of distribution.
( 41 ) The variations between Member States in the VAT systems which they operate sometimes produce situations in which VAT paid by farmers on their purchases cannot be recovered or compensated for. Such VAT payments represent (i) non-deductible VAT, i.e. VAT paid on purchases which farmers, irrespective of the system to which they are subject, may not deduct from the VAT invoiced on sales and for which there is thus no compensation; (ii) and/or VAT other than that mentioned under (i), paid on purchases for which farmers subject to the flat-rate system are not fully compensated via the selling price or via reimbursement.
( 42 ) Subsidies on agricultural products paid to agricultural producers include any subsidy in the form of a deficiency payment to holders (i.e. in cases where general government pays the producers of agricultural products the difference between the average market prices and the guarantee prices of agricultural products).
( 43 ) An important example are subsidies paid to non-life insurance companies which enable these companies to charge lower (gross) premiums from the insurance policy holders (e.g. agricultural enterprises taking out insurance to cover risks such as damage by hail, frost etc.). As these subsidies are subsidies on products, the product being the insurance service, they are not recorded in the generation of income account of the policy holder (and thus not, in the above example, in the EAA). However, in as much as these subsidies reduce the costs of the insurance services (to the insurance policy holder), their effect is reflected in the production account (by a lower value of intermediate consumption, cf. 2.108(g)) of the insurance policy holder.
►M6 ( 44 ) However, when a grant serves the dual purpose of financing both the amortisation of the debt and the payment of interest on it, and when it is not possible to apportion it between the two elements, the whole of the grant is treated as an investment grant. ◄
( 45 ) Interest receivable corresponds to ‘Other accounts receivable’ (F.8) in the financial account.
( 46 ) Note that rents received are not relevant to the EAA due to the use of the agricultural industry concept (cf. 1.44).
►M6 ( 47 ) The ►M6 ESA 2010 ◄ proposes that the full amount be recorded as rent on land if the value of the land is thought to be higher than that of the building, and as rent on buildings if the opposite is the case. ◄
( 48 ) Including a provision for losses of fixed capital goods as a result of accidental damage which can be insured against. The value of these provisions to be recorded is the value of the net premiums paid in respect of insured fixed capital goods.
( 49 ) In order to take into account part-time and seasonal work, agricultural employment or changes therein are measured in AWUs (see Chapter IV for more details). A distinction is drawn between non-salaried and salaried AWUs, which together make up total AWUs.
( 50 ) This measure of income corresponds to the former measure ‘net income from family agricultural activity’ for sole proprietorships.
►M6 ( 51 ) This does not preclude the possibility that there may be circumstances in which compilers may judge it preferable to eliminate the discrepancies in order to improve the overall consistency of the data. ◄
( 52 ) Regulation (EC) No 1059/2003 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 May 2003 on the establishment of a common classification of territorial units for statistics (NUTS) (OJ L 154, 21.6.2003, p. 1).
( 53 ) As long as the corresponding sales and purchases fall in the same accounting period.
( 54 ) The purchase of an animal is never to be recorded as intermediate consumption (basically, it is an acquisition of work in progress, cf. 2.067) and the calculation of animal output can only be calculated indirectly, on the basis of the sales, the GFCF and the stock changes.
( 55 ) According to the method used, the intra-unit consumption shall be adjusted to the EAA values.
( 56 ) Imported agricultural products (except animals) are excluded.