This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52011SC0537
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT
/* SEC/2011/0537 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT /* SEC/2011/0537 final */
1. Problem Definition 1.1 Introduction The Generalised System of Preferences ("the
scheme") helps developing countries, and particularly Least Developed
Countries (LDCs), to reduce poverty by offering them import preferences in
order to generate or boost revenue from international trade. In addition, the
scheme provides incentives in the form of additional tariff preferences, to
countries that commit themselves to sustainable development and good
government. The scheme currently aims to achieve the objectives set out in the Communication
from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament and the Economic
and Social Committee on the function of the Community’s Generalised System of
Preferences (GSP) for the ten-year period from 2006 to 2015. The scheme
grants preferential access to EU markets on a generalised and
non-discriminatory basis to 176 eligible countries and territories. It has
three arrangements: · the general arrangement (often described simply as "GSP"); · the special incentive arrangement for sustainable development and
good governance (described as "GSP+") which offers additional
preferences as incentives to support vulnerable developing countries in
ratifying and implementing 27 international conventions on human and labour rights,
environment and good governance; · the Everything But Arms arrangement (EBA), which provides duty-free,
quota-free access to LDCs. The present GSP scheme is implemented
through successive regulations, each applying for three years. The current GSP
regulation will expire on 31 December 2011. On 26 May 2010 the Commission
adopted a proposal to extend the validity of the current regulation until 31
December 2013, in order to allow time to prepare the revision of the GSP scheme
in view of the longer legislative procedures introduced by the Lisbon Treaty. A
recently completed mid-term review provides the background for the planned
Commission proposal for a revised regulation to replace the existing scheme
upon expiry in 2013. Both the EBA arrangement and the rules of origin
provisions fall outside the scope of this revision: the former, because it is
not subject to periodic reviews; and the latter, because new legislation on
rules of origin has entered into force in 2011. 1.2 Consultation and expertise This impact assessment has been prepared
following extensive consultations with Member States and other stakeholders
(including civil society, industry, beneficiary countries, the European
Parliament, and WTO members). The views of stakeholders were taken into
account, as is highlighted in several instances in the main report. The
Commission's minimum standards for consultations were met. To assess the extent
to which the EU's scheme meets the needs of developing countries, a mid-term
evaluation was conducted by an external consultant, the Centre for Analysis of
Regional Integration at Sussex (CARIS). The final report was published on 26
May 2010 on DG Trade's website[1]. The results of this
study are reflected in the main impact assessment report where relevant. 1.3 Strengths and weaknesses of the existing GSP scheme The CARIS evaluation of the existing GSP
scheme (2010) concluded that: · there is clear evidence that the EU's GSP preferences can be
effective in increasing developing countries' exports and welfare; · utilisation rates for the GSP scheme(s) are high, and positively
correlated to the extent of the tariff and preference margin; · the exporting countries capture about half of the rents derived from
the preference margins; · the GSP+ regime has had a positive impact on the ratification of the
27 international conventions required for eligibility, but progress on
effective implementation of these is much less clear. Nevertheless, the scheme is subject to a
number of structural and other constraints (detailed both in the CARIS study
and in the main report). There are also a number of specific issues that need
to be addressed in the review process; these are summarised in the problem tree
on the following page. Sub-optimal targeting of beneficiaries A large degree of competitive pressure on
LDCs is exerted by other GSP beneficiaries. Several high-income countries
(HICs) continue to be beneficiaries, on the grounds that they are not
sufficiently diversified. Such countries have the resources to attain higher
levels of diversification without the help of EU preferences. Much the same is
true for so-called Upper Middle Income countries (UMIs). And countries that
benefit from preferences derived from another bilateral preferential
arrangement with the EU also continue to benefit from the GSP scheme. The use
of GSP preferences by HICs, UMIs and countries that already benefit from other
bilateral preference arrangements increases the competitive pressure on exports
from poorer, more vulnerable countries, whose needs are far greater and thus
deserve increased attention. Sub-optimal graduation mechanism Emerging developing economies have
generated very successful export-oriented manufacturing sectors that are highly
competitive at world level. These sectors receive benefits under the scheme, although
arguably they no longer require preferences to achieve a substantial presence
in the EU. They exert competitive pressure on EU industry; and raise the
barriers to entry for poorer countries which consequently need even greater
efforts to diversify their export base. The GSP scheme has a mechanism to weed
out competitive sectors from specific countries and withdraw preferences – the graduation
mechanism. Yet under the current scheme, it has been barely used. Out of a
total of over 2400 country-sectors, only 20 have been graduated – 13 of which
are Chinese sectors. This indicates that the current graduation mechanism is
insufficiently responsive to ensure the effectiveness and efficiency of the
scheme. Another important weakness of the graduation mechanism is that
graduation is based on sections of the EU Customs Tariff which are so large and
heterogeneous, that products which are not necessarily competitive are excluded
just because they fall within a category where products from a totally
different, highly competitive industry predominate. Insufficient product coverage The GSP scheme has broad product coverage
but it is not complete. Currently, 9% of all tariff lines are outside the
scheme and are subject to positive tariffs. Countries most in need sometimes fail
to gain access to the EU market because they would want to export some of these
products. Another de facto limitation on product coverage results from
the division of product lines into sensitive and non-sensitive ones:
non-sensitive products enjoy duty-free access, but sensitive products obtain
only a tariff reduction of 3.5 percentage points on ad valorem duties. Insufficient support to diversification
of exports The original goal of generalised
preferences schemes lent support to diversification by industrialisation. Yet
the 2010 evaluation found that when all beneficiaries and products are taken
together, the evidence for diversification is largely limited to products with
low preference margins exported by emerging economies. The inclusion in the
current scheme of GSP countries that scarcely qualify as countries most in need
(HICs and UMIs) and which exert significant pressure on competing EBA and GSP+
products in the scheme – as well as the relatively weak graduation mechanism –
makes diversification by poorer and vulnerable countries more difficult,
because the GSP countries capture much of the preferences. Inconsistency with overall trade
objectives The existence of GSP benefits might weaken
the incentives for beneficiary countries to negotiate bilateral or
multilateral trade agreements. By contrast, the objective of focusing GSP benefits
on countries most in need might have the unintended consequence of providing
more advanced developing countries with a greater incentive to enter into and
conclude reciprocal trade negotiations with the EU. Low utilization of preferences by some
countries The competitive pressure exerted by GSP
beneficiaries can reduce GSP+ countries and LDCs to the status of residual and
irregular suppliers to the EU market. Given the low value of transactions
concluded under such conditions, importers have less incentive to bear the
costs entailed in claiming preferences (e.g., to obtain or administer origin
certificates). As a result, many preferences are simply not utilised. Insufficient support for sustainability and good governance The current vulnerability criteria that
determine eligibility for GSP+ are excessively restrictive. This limits the
extent to which GSP+ can promote sustainable development and good governance,
in the sense that a less restrictive eligibility requirement can be an
incentive for a greater number of countries to ratify and implement
international rules and standards and engage in internal reforms. The condition
for access to GSP+ (that the country has not only ratified, but also
'effectively implemented' the conventions) is unnecessarily limiting; it does
not support the incentive based nature of the scheme. The existence of entry
windows for GSP+ (open only once every 18 months) prevents potential
beneficiaries from entering the scheme as soon as they have fulfilled all entry
requirements. Under the current scheme the Commission must monitor the status
of ratification and effective implementation of the 27 specified conventions by
examining available information from the relevant monitoring bodies. Yet the
monitoring mechanism for implementing the conventions presents a number of
significant weaknesses. Inadequate safeguard mechanism Several weaknesses have been identified in
the current GSP safeguard mechanism, notably the lack of definition of key
legal concepts; the lack of definition of the rights and obligations of parties
to an investigation; and the ill-defined procedural framework. 2. Analysis of Subsidiarity The legal basis for Community action in
this matter is Article 207 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European
Union (hereinafter TFEU). The principle of subsidiarity does not apply in this
case. The principle of proportionality is satisfied inasmuch as the regulation
is the only appropriate type of action that the European Union can take to
establish unilateral, non-reciprocal, preferential market access for developing
countries. 3. Objectives 3.1 General objectives The scheme has three general objectives: 1. Contribute to poverty
eradication by expanding exports from countries most in need (G-1); 2. Promote sustainable
development and good governance (G-2); 3. Ensure a better safeguard
for the EU's financial and economic interests (G-3). 3.2 Specific and operational objectives For the period from 2006 to 2015 the Commission GSP Communication
established the following objectives for the scheme: 1. To maintain generous
tariff preferences that continue to provide real incentives for developing
countries to expand their exports in a sustainable manner; 2. To target the preference
on the countries that most need it, in particular by terminating preferential
access for countries that no longer need it, and by ensuring that GSP
preferential rates are withdrawn from competitive products; 3. To offer a simple, predictable and easily accessible preference scheme; 4. ³To further encourage
sustainable development and good governance; 5. To provide withdrawal
mechanisms and safeguard instruments in order to ensure that the sustainable development
and good governance aspects of the GSP as well as the EU's financial and
economic interests are protected. In order to ensure that policy options considered are the most
appropriate for reaching the scheme’s general objectives in a changing global
economic environment, these objectives have been translated into specific and
operational objectives: The specific objectives are as follows: 1. To better focus the
preferences on the countries most in need (S-1); 2. To remove disincentives
for diversification for countries most in need (S-2); 3. To enhance consistency
with overall trade objectives (bilateral and multilateral, S-3); 4. To strengthen support for
sustainable development and good governance (S-4); 5. To improve the efficiency
of safeguard mechanisms ensuring that the EU's financial and economic interests
are protected (S-5); 6. To enhance legal
certainty, stability and predictability of the scheme (S-6). The operational objectives are as follows: 1. To revise the beneficiary
country list by deferring benefits to those countries, which based on their
development, financial and trade needs, no longer need the preferences; 2. To target graduation on
the prime beneficiaries ensuring that GSP preferential rates are withdrawn from
competitive products; 3. To redefine product
sections to reflect more homogeneous product categories; 4. To simplify GSP+ entry
mechanism; 5. To develop a more
effective and transparent mechanism for monitoring and evaluating the GSP+
countries' commitment and progress in the implementation of GSP+ conventions; 6. To develop credible and
efficient procedures for temporary withdrawal of the preferences and procedures
for renewal of the preferences; 7. To improve the
administrative procedures of safeguard mechanisms. 4.Policy options The following summary table presents a set of core policy options
that have been identified as being representative of the main avenues that can
be selected. Option || Main features Option A: Discon-tinuation || Preferences are abandoned for GSP and GSP+ beneficiaries. EBA arrangement would remain. Option B: No policy change BASE-LINE || The current policy continues without change. This option has two baseline scenarios: B1 (short run) – the continuation of the scheme taking into account the current status of multilateral and bilateral agreements. B2 (long run) – the continuation of the scheme based on the assumption that all on-going but unfinished multilateral and bilateral negotiations have been concluded successfully Option C: Partial redesign || This comprises two sub-options. They have certain common elements, and certain differences—C1's changes being less extensive than C2's. Elements common to the 2 sub-options: 1. Preferences are deferred for certain eligible countries: overseas countries and territories; high and upper middle income countries; countries with a preferential trade agreement covering substantially all preferences. 2. Graduation principles are revised: product sections are redefined; graduation does not apply to GSP+ countries. 3. GSP+ entry mechanism is simplified and made more flexible: countries must ratify, not fully implement, conventions, while providing binding commitments to guarantee their implementation; countries can apply for GSP+ at any time. 4. GSP+ monitoring mechanism is redesigned to enhance implementation of the conventions. 5. More transparent and efficient procedures for temporary withdrawal of preferences are introduced. 6. The administrative procedures of safeguard mechanisms are improved. Elements that differ between the 2 sub-options: 1. Graduation threshold Option C1 Graduation threshold remains unchanged. Option C2 Graduation threshold is reduced to 7.5% and 50% safety net is eliminated. 2. GSP+ vulnerability criteria Option C1 The import-share threshold is relaxed (increased from 1% to 2%). Option C2 Vulnerability criteria are eliminated. 3. List of GSP+ conventions Option C1 The list of GSP+ conventions remains unchanged. Option C2 The list of GSP+ conventions is expanded. Option D: Full redesign || This option includes and builds upon the features of option C. In particular, the product coverage of the scheme is redesigned, with 3 sub-options: Option D1 All beneficiary countries receive full product coverage and all products are deemed non-sensitive No graduation takes place. Option D2 A number of industrial and agricultural products move from the sensitive to the non-sensitive list. Option D3 The list of products covered by the scheme is expanded to include a number of industrial and agricultural products. 5. Analysis of impacts 5.1 General Imports benefiting from preferences account for less than 5% of
total EU imports. This implies that, while impacts on beneficiaries may be
large, the general impacts on the EU are likely to be of a limited nature. Impacts
have been assessed using the analysis performed by CARIS, additional analysis
via a SMART model[2], and the examination of
official EU imports, production, consumption and employment statistics. The
main variable used to analyse social impacts has been employment. Environmental
impacts are invariably low, and have been analysed separately. 5.2 Comments on the baselines (B1 and B2) There is a natural reduction in the level of import duties (and,
therefore, preferences) due to preference erosion under the impact of further
bilateral and multilateral trade deals. Preference erosion reduces imports from
GSP beneficiaries; this is the reality against which this assessment takes
place. In the long run, when all multilateral and bilateral agreements are fully
implemented, duties are likely to be so low that the idea of preferences
becomes largely irrelevant – and so would a generalised system of preferences.
Other totally different tools may have to be designed. Until then, the question
is what can be done for the countries most in need of preferences. 5.3.Option A: discontinuation Option A ends the GSP scheme while retaining the EBA scheme which
benefits LDCs. Total EU imports fall, but by an insignificant amount (about €6
billion, or less than 1%). General assessment of economic, social and environmental effects Relative to B1, the general effects are as follows. The economic and
social effects for countries most in need are expected to be negative. LDCs would
benefit, but the many other developing countries and economic sectors which are
also most in need would suffer as preferential access disappears. Within the
EU, three elements will impact upon general economic and social effects:
producer surplus, consumer surplus, and tariff income. Negative impacts for
consumers are likely to be compensated by higher tariff revenues, which are of
the same order of magnitude. The net impact would thus be generated by benefits
to producers. As explained above, these benefits would on the whole not be
significant, but would nonetheless have significant positive effects on
important sectors (sugar, fruits and vegetables, textiles and apparel) – and on
the EU Member States where those sectors are important. Therefore, these
impacts would be positive as a whole. Environmental impacts in the EU would be
(at best) marginally positive, given that the drop of imports would be
marginal. As for the countries most in need, it is possible those countries
losing GSP+ would deviate from environmentally sustainable practices. Thus, on
the whole, a marginally negative impact may be felt. A vs. B1. Effects on: || economic || social || environmental Countries most in need || -- || -- || 0/- EU || + || + || 0/+ Relative to baseline B2, the changes would be expected to go in the
same direction, but they would be significantly smaller – to the point of not
being noticeable. 5.4 Option C: partial redesign Option C has many building blocks. To explore the different angles
of these building blocks, two sub-options were explored. The main differences
between them concern the graduation of competitive sectors and the
vulnerability criteria under GSP+. With regard to graduation, the sectors which
will actually be graduated are not known at this stage – they will depend on
the calculations of imports on the basis of the latest available figures prior entry
into force of the new regulation. Current figures have been used as a proxy.
With regard to vulnerability, C1 relaxes the 'economic' criterion from 1% to
2%. The actual list of countries which will meet the relaxed criterion is not
known at this stage – again, these calculations will be made on the basis of
the latest available figures prior to entry into force of the new regulation.
The additional countries that would currently meet the test (Pakistan,
Philippines and Ukraine) have been considered as a proxy. C2 eliminates the vulnerability criteria while it adds additional
requirements regarding conventions. Again, the actual list of countries meeting
the relevant conventions criterion will be determined as close as possible to
the time of entry into force of the new regulation. Currently, we would expect
these to be the three C1 countries plus Namibia and Nigeria (all of them having
already ratified the relevant conventions), and these have been used as a proxy
for the purpose of this exercise. The assessment starts with an analysis of
option C1 and then describes the main differences that arise under option C2. 5.4.1 Option C1 General assessment of economic, social and environmental effects When compared with baseline B1, the general effects of option C1 are
as follows. Total EU imports fall by about €4 billion (a €1 billion increase in
imports from countries that have never belonged to the scheme, offset by a €5
billion fall in imports from countries that cease to be members of the scheme. The
economic and social effects on countries most in need are expected to be
positive, as exports increase and welfare gains accrue. As under option A, negative impacts on EU consumers are likely to be
compensated by higher tariff revenues, which are of the same order of
magnitude. The net impact would thus be generated by impacts on producers. As
explained above, these benefits would on the whole not be significant, but
would have significant negative effects on important sectors (rice, arable
crops, oils and fats, sugar, fruit and vegetables, textiles and apparel, and
leather) – and on the EU Member States where those sectors are important.
Therefore, these impacts would be negative as a whole. Environmental impacts in
the EU would be (at best) marginally positive, given that the drop of imports
would be marginal. As to the countries most in need, the impact of expanded
GSP+ membership would lead overall to a marginally positive impact. C1 vs. B1. Effects on: || economic || social || environmental Countries most in need || ++ || ++ || 0/+ EU || - || - || 0/+ When comparing the effects of options C1 with baseline B2, the
changes would be expected to go in the same direction, but they would become
significantly smaller – once again, to the point of not being noticeable. 5.4.2 Option C2 There is one important difference between C2 and C1. Lower
graduation thresholds increase the level of graduation significantly for
certain countries and sectors, particularly for India. This leads to a number
of effects. The first one is a larger decrease in exports by GSP participants
as a whole. The second is an increase in EBA exports, as the negative impacts
on Bangladesh (foreseen under C1) diminish. The result is that, while the
positive effects on EBA and GSP+ beneficiaries can not be underestimated, GSP
exports by many beneficiaries will suffer. Dynamic effects are expected to more
than compensate for this static loss, so the impact as a whole is considered to
be positive, but certainly less so than C1. Given that the remaining impacts
are largely similar to C1, the general assessment table for C2 would therefore
read as follows: C2 vs. B1. Effects on: || economic || social || environmental Countries most in need || + || + || 0/+ EU || - || - || 0/+ 5.5 Option D: full redesign Most of the building blocks of the scheme have been re-defined under
option C. However, a number of respondents to the consultation suggested a
broad expansion of the two other key building blocks of the scheme: the range
of products covered and the preference margins. We have therefore also examined
a comprehensive re-design that includes the proposed changes under option C,
and in addition changes to these two building blocks. In order to
simplify the analysis, D sub-options are calculated as increments to C2 only.
Three sub-options are assessed. D1 is a far reaching option. It provides full
product coverage expansion and elimination of all sensitive products (eg,
extending the duty-free, quota-free treatment of EBA countries) to all
countries most in need (whether GSP or GSP+). This implies that the remaining
beneficiaries are no longer subject to graduation. D2 and D3 are less
far-reaching. They take all the parameters of C2 (graduation included) and add
partial de-sensitisation (D2) and partial expansion in product coverage (D3). 5.5.1 Option D1: full product coverage, full de-sensitisation General assessment of economic, social and environmental effects When compared to baseline B1, the general effects of option D1 are
as follows. Although the economic and social effects on countries most in need
are expected to be positive as a whole, these gains accrue mainly to sectors
which are already competitive, at the expense of those which are less advanced.
There would be large distributional effects, with the additional share of EU
imports captured by China, India and other countries that were previously
subject to graduation having a negative impact on many other countries most in
need. EBA beneficiaries in particular would suffer (Bangladesh being the prime
example), as would GSP+ countries such as Pakistan. The overall positive assessment
("+") must therefore be nuanced. The positive impact for EU consumers
is likely to be compensated by lower tariff revenues, which are of the same
order of magnitude. The net impact would thus be generated by impacts on
producers. As explained above, these impacts on the whole would not be
significant, but would have significant negative effects for important sectors
– and for the EU Member States where they are important. As a result, these
impacts would be negative overall. Although larger than under option C, they
would probably be of a similar order of magnitude. Environmental impacts in the
EU would be marginally negative, given the overall increase in imports. The
large increase in imports particularly from China or India can lead to negative
impacts in those countries also. The impact on GSP+ countries would be positive
overall because, although their exports would increase, the environmental
protection framework under which (all) businesses operate would be improved by
adherence to the relevant environmental conventions. The overall balance of
these effects would be marginally negative. D1 vs. B1. Effects on: || economic || social || environmental Countries most in need* || + || + || 0/- EU || - || - || 0/- *Positive economic and social impacts for
countries most in need as a whole hide significant negative impacts on
EBA and GSP+ beneficiaries. When comparing the effects of option D1 to baseline B2, the changes
would be expected to go in the same direction, only that they would become
smaller – but still noticeable. 5.5.2 Options D2 and D3 These options build on option C. In order to simplify the analysis,
only one of the options, in this case C2, has been used as a basis for
D2 and D3. There is no reason to believe that significant differences would
exist if C1 were taken as a basis instead. Given that D2 and D3 change only one
building block at a time with respect to C, only the salient novelties are
mentioned here. D2 and D3 generate preference erosion to the disadvantage of LDCs D2 explores de-sensitisation. As expected, the immediate impact is
preference erosion for EBAs, particularly vis-à-vis GSP competitors, which are
the net winners. Given that the CARIS evaluation made clear that significant
competitive pressure is exerted by GSP countries on their EBA counterparts,
this was to be expected. India, Indonesia, Vietnam and Thailand absorb almost
all the gains, while EBA countries capture almost none. D3 explores product
expansion. A similar impact as that described for D2 is foreseen: benefits to
GSP beneficiaries at the cost of preference erosion and export losses for EBA
countries. Both D2 and D3 thus confirm that product expansion and
desensitisation have a price, a price which is paid by the poorest and which
compounds the preference erosion they suffer. D2 and D3 may place obstacles to negotiation of bilateral and
multilateral agreements Compared to option C, these options would arguably send a false
signal to our trade partners, by creating the expectation that concessions
regarding products which have been introduced into the GSP scheme or which have
been desensitised can be obtained from the EU automatically in bilateral or
multilateral negotiations. The size of the changes introduced by D2 and D3 are
not sufficiently large as to vary the order of magnitude of the rest of the
results of option C. However, EU producers of new products that are introduced
into the GSP scheme, and of those goods which receive higher preference margins
via desensitisation, would suffer additional pressure. 6. Comparing the options 6.1 Review of different options by objectives and impacts The following table compares how well the different options examined
above meet the objectives sought by a review of the scheme. This comparison is
based on three criteria: effectiveness (number of objectives met, to what
degree); efficiency (use of resources necessary to meet the objectives,
unintended spill-over effects); and consistency with overarching EU objectives. Options || A || C1 || C2 || D1 || D2 || D3 Effectiveness || - || ++++ || +++ || -- || ++ || ++ Efficiency || -- || +++ || ++ || -- || + || + Consistency || ++++ || ++ || ++ || --- || + || + A detailed analysis follows, based on the relative efficiency and
effectiveness of each of the options in achieving the general policy objectives. 6.2 Effectiveness of the policy options in achieving the general and
specific objectives Option A Option A meets general objective G-1 (contributing to poverty
eradication by expanding exports of countries most in need) only partly. By
focusing preferences on LDCs, it leaves many other countries with similar
trade, development and financial needs without preferences (specific objective
S-1) – with adverse economic and social impacts as a consequence. Moreover,
removing preferences from some countries that are most in need will expose
export sectors in those countries to competition from developed countries.
Option A runs directly contrary to specific objective S-4 and general objective
G-2 (promoting sustainable development and good governance). And it does
nothing to ensure better safeguards for the EU's financial and economic
interests (general objective G-3 and specific objective S-5). By contrast,
option A can strengthen the EU's hand in bilateral and multilateral
negotiations (specific objective S-3). It would have positive economic and
social impacts for certain sectors in certain Member States at a time when so
much emphasis is on boosting competitiveness, growth and job creation. And
last, at a time of extreme pressure on public finances, it boosts tariff
revenues. Option C1 Option C1 contributes well to general objective G-1 (contributing to
poverty eradication by expanding exports of countries most in need). In
particular, it ensures that preferences are properly targeted on countries most
in need (S-1) and it reduces the disincentive to diversification (S-2) that
arises from the competitive pressure exerted by more developed beneficiaries of
the current system. Option C1's combination of a more flexible entry mechanism
for GSP+, more flexible trade criteria for eligibility, and no graduation,
would boost the scheme's contribution to promoting sustainable development and
good governance (G-2 and S-4). It improves the efficiency of the safeguard
instrument (S-5) and the withdrawal mechanism, which both would contribute to
G-3. It also boosts tariff revenue. It would have the unintended effects of
strengthening the EU's hand in bilateral and multilateral trade negotiations
(but in respect of fewer countries than under option A). There would, however,
be negative economic and social impacts for certain sectors in certain Member
States. Option C2 The main difference between C2 and C1 is that the lower graduation
thresholds of C2 reduce total exports by countries most in need. In addition,
the more GSP+ beneficiary countries enter the scheme, the greater the
competitive pressure on LDCs – the neediest of all developing countries. These
effects make C2 a less effective way to achieve general objective G-1
(contribute to poverty eradication). However, it ranks superior to C1 in terms
of its likely effectiveness for achieving G-2 (promoting sustainable
development) because it provides for a revision of the required conventions. Option D (only D1 is discussed in the executive summary) Option D1 targets those most in need by deferring preferences for
sufficiently rich beneficiaries and for those that enjoy preferential access
via a bilateral agreement. Yet it eliminates graduation entirely, and extends
EBA-equivalent treatment to all beneficiaries (which would accelerate
preference erosion for the poorest). Overall therefore, it cannot be said to be
meeting objective G-1. Equally the G-2 objective (promoting sustainable
development via the incentives of GSP+) is totally undermined by granting EBA-
equivalent treatment to all beneficiaries. Option D1 improves the efficiency of
the safeguard mechanism (S-5) and of the withdrawal mechanism (S-6), and thus
contributes positively to safeguarding the EU's financial and economic
interests (general objective G-3). However, D1 is expected to decrease tariff
revenues at a time of extreme pressure on public finances. Also, it gives rise
to negative economic and social impacts in certain industrial sectors and
Member States. And it would significantly weaken the EU's negotiating position
in the bilateral and multilateral context (specific objective S-3). 6.3 Preferred option The option which meets the objectives of the scheme in the most
effective, efficient and coherent manner is C, and in particular C1. This does
not negate that C2 contain positive aspects (review of the list of conventions)
which can also be considered. 7. Monitoring and Evaluation The table below includes suggestions for indicators that can be used
to assess the progress and effectiveness of the preferred option in achieving
general policy objectives. General Objectives || Indicators || Sources of information To contribute to poverty eradication by expanding exports from countries most in need || - expansion of developing countries exports to EU - increased share of imports from countries most in need - increased utilization of the preferences - effective graduation of the competitive sectors -increasing diversification || - Eurostat data To promote sustainable development and good governance || - increased number of countries committing to sustainable development and good governance principles within GSP+ arrangement - overall improvement of implementation of GSP+ conventions by GSP+ beneficiaries -number of withdrawals || - reports of relevant international monitoring bodies -DG TRADE To ensure a better safeguard for the EU's financial and economic interests. || -number of safeguard requests -number of safeguard measures -revenue foregone due to the scheme -number of preferential trade agreements signed with beneficiaries - number of preferential trade agreements signed with non-beneficiaries || -Safeguard requests -Eurostat data -DG TRADE The effectiveness of the GSP scheme should be subject to formal and
independent evaluation prior to any subsequent revision. To be effective, such
evaluation is likely to require a minimum of 3 years' post-implementation data,
which implies that the evaluation cannot take place before the end of 2017 at
the earliest. [1] http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/may/tradoc_146196.pdf [2] A model developed by the World Bank in collaboration
with various international organisations.