This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document 52013SC0076
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY
/* SWD/2013/076 final */
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY /* SWD/2013/076 final */
TABLE OF CONTENTS 1........... Introduction. 3 2........... Characteristics of
financing long term investments. 4 3........... Demand for long-term
investments. 4 4........... Investment and savings
in the EU.. 7 5........... Financing chain: from
providers to the end-users of funds. 9 6........... Reduced incentives for
households’ long term savings. 10 7........... Recent dynamics in
financial intermediation. 11 7.1........ Inefficiencies
in the intermediation chain. 12 7.2........ Bank lending
gap. 14 7.3........ Opportunities
for long-term investors. 18 8........... Capital markets and
other sources of finance. 19 9........... Public policy
instruments. 23 10......... Conclusion. 24 11......... References. 25 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European
Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE
EUROPEAN ECONOMY COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Long-Term Financing of the European
Economy Accompanying the document GREEN PAPER LONG-TERM FINANCING OF THE
EUROPEAN ECONOMY 1. Introduction Productive investments are important
drivers to boost productivity, improve competitiveness and ensure sustainable
growth. They require generally financing over an extended time horizon. In the
EU, there is a need for long-term investments not only to finance
infrastructure, innovation, education and environmental projects, but also to
increase competitiveness and ensure public debt sustainability.[1] This working paper accompanies the Green
Paper “Long Term Financing of the European Economy” (see document [...]2013)
XXX) and aims to give more insight, from an economic perspective, on
investments and saving in the EU; the need and incentives to increase long-term
savings; as well as the role that financial intermediation plays in channelling
funds from savers to productive investments that generate capital formation and
sustainable growth. The paper analyses the main problems in the current capital
allocation and financial intermediation process across bank finance, which is
the major financing channel in the EU (accounting for 85% of total financing in
the euro area and the UK), corporate debt markets, and equity markets,
including an assessment of whether these problems are of a structural nature or
temporary as a consequence of the crisis. Taking into account this analysis,
the Green Paper puts forward for public discussion a number of policy options,
for example, related to how misalignments in financial intermediation could be
reduced and how incentives for more effective and efficient allocation of funds
to productive long term investments cold be strengthened. The paper is
organised as follows: Section 2 presents the main characteristics of long term
investment, while Section 3 is dedicated to the demand for long-term
investments. Section 4 examines the past trends in investment and savings in
the EU and compares these developments with the US and Japan. Section 5 discusses the reasons for restrained long-term saving, while Section 6 outlines
the major intermediation channels for allocating funds from savers to the
end-users of capital. Section 7 discusses inefficiencies and misalignments in
the intermediation chain and developments in bank lending for non-financial
corporates. It also assesses the opportunities for institutional long-term
investors, such as insurers and pension funds. Corporate bond markets and other
sources of finance, such as equity markets and IPOs are discussed in Section 8.
The last section concludes. It is important to note that this paper focuses mainly
on the two major private sources of finance: bank borrowing and corporate bond
issuance. However, there are several other sources to finance long-term
investments, including private equity, venture capital, leasing, hire-purchase,
supply chain finance, financing through internal generated funds as well as
public sector initiatives. Section 9 presents some
public policy instrument to enhance financing of long-term investments. The
last section concludes. 2. characteristics
of financing long term investments There is no simple or single definition of
long-term financing. In broad terms, financing long term
investments or long term financing[2] can be
considered as the process by which the financial system provides the funding to
pay for investments that stretch over an extended time
period. Investors engaged in long-term financing are generally expected to
hold onto the assets for a long time and are less concerned about interim
changes in asset prices, focused instead on long-term income growth and/or
capital appreciation. Descriptions tend to cover a range of
features, including: ·
The nature of the asset classes appropriate
for long-term investment. These assets are likely
to be less liquid, have long maturities that extend over the business cycle,
yield first returns only after some years and carry significant risk. However, even very liquid assets can be appropriate for long-term
financing, and, conversely, long-term asset classes can also be the subject of
short-term trades; ·
The nature of the financial intermediation
involved. Long-term financing may require
significant maturity transformation, as the majority of currently-available
funds tend to be short-term, whereas the subsequent investments are made over
an extended time horizon. It also involves sophisticated risk assessment,
management and sometimes risk sharing, and the pooling of different sources of
funds given the large size of investments; and The nature of
valuation and pricing of the assets involved. The
illiquid and long-term nature of the assets complicates the risk assessment
process. The economic and social value of the assets may differ from their
financial value, and may not be taken into account by all investors, and
accounting principles, benchmarks and credit ratings may measure only part of
the value of assets. The pricing of risk by financial markets may lead to an
increase in the risk-pricing of otherwise lower risk investments funded by
public resources. Alternatively, on-going international
work under the auspices of the G20 on long-term investment defines long-term
finance more narrowly, focusing on maturities of
financing in excess of five years, including sources of financing that have no
specific maturity (e.g. equities). 3. demand
for long-term investments Long-term financing plays a key role in supporting productive investment, such as: ·
R&D and innovation, education and
professional training; ·
Infrastructures, including transport, energy and
communication networks; ·
Industrial technology transformation and
long-term capital-intensive projects; ·
Health care and other welfare related assets; ·
Environmental and climate change-related
technologies and ·
Enterprises, including in particular SMEs,
throughout all stages of their development. Investments in these areas contribute to
higher productivity, innovation and competitiveness and involve positive
externalities. Whether publicly or privately delivered, they require periodical
renewal and upgrading. This type of investments must support the Europe 2020 objectives and longer-term priorities,
including sustainable economic, social, environmental and demographic
developments. Box 1 illustrates the case for financing the low
carbon economy. In broad terms, the provision of long-term financing is key for any strategy aimed at enhancing
competitiveness in the EU through addressing investment needs for industry,
enterprises and public goods. The demand for long-term
investments applies across the whole economic cycle (such as the industrial
innovation cycle), affecting the source and nature of financing at any one
time. The Commission has underlined the need for
significantly higher long-term investment levels in the future, taking into
account the lack of investment in the past across a whole range of sectors. Estimates of needs for financing long-term investments are very
significant. For example, overall investment needs for transport, energy and
telecom infrastructures networks of EU importance amount to EUR 1 trillion for
the period up to 2020.[3] Significant investment will also be needed in R&D, new
technologies and innovation. Total estimated investment in the EU over the same
period is around EUR 24 trillion.[4] The overall
growth of investments in Europe, including long-term investments, is mainly
driven by developments in the non-financial corporate sector and, to a lesser
extent, by governments and households (Chart 1). Data show that private
investments in 2011 were well below their 2007 level and the decrease in
private investment was four times more than the drop of real GDP over the same
period.[5] This is both demand and supply side driven, as the following
sections demonstrate. The overall demand for investment in new projects is
constrained by macroeconomic and financial uncertainty. For instance in terms
of net demand for long-term credit from non-financial companies, recent ECB
data reports a decline. The slowdown in economic activity and uncertain market
outlook has lowered profitability expectations and the quality of loan
applications has deteriorated following the worsening of macroeconomic
conditions. The bank lending survey of October 2012 suggests that subdued
lending in 2012 was caused due to a decrease in net loan demand rather than a
constrained loan supply. Box 1: The case for financing the low-carbon
economy Green
Growth In the
Commission's Low-Carbon Roadmap[6], the EU investment needs in low-carbon energy, energy efficiency
and infrastructure, consistent with the political objective of limiting climate
change below two degrees, were estimated at €270 billion per year. These
investments would result in fuel savings of €170 – 320 billion per year and
monetized health benefits of up to €88 billion a year by 2050. In order to
generate these benefits for human health, the environment and the economy, it
is therefore essential to mobilise more long-term investment. Investors
and stakeholders have identified[7] various policies that would help generate investment for green
growth, including long-term regulatory certainty, a phasing out of fossil fuel
subsidies and a strong carbon price signal, and the use of public funds to
leverage private investment. It has also been suggested[8] that reforming
the financial sector would in itself have benefits for green investments, by
dis-incentivising short-termism. In
response, the Commission has started work on a 2030 Framework for Climate and
Energy Policy, one of the goals of which is to increase long-term certainty for
investors. A Green Paper on this topic will be released by March 2013 to invite
stakeholder contributions. On a stronger carbon price signal, the Commission
has invited stakeholders to comment on options for the structural reform of the
European Emissions Trading System[9], and
proposed a restructuring of the Energy Taxation Directive[10]. The
European Council has also confirmed the Commission's proposal that
climate-relevant expenditure will represent at least 20% of the EU spending in
the Multiannual Financial Framework 2014 – 2020. In order to utilize their
resources cost-effectively, in a context of budgetary constraints, public
authorities at all levels will need to develop and deploy both proven and
innovative financial instruments, in order to leverage private investment. Stakeholders
are invited to explicitly take the investment requirements for green growth
into account in their general comments on long-term financing of the EU
economy. Low-carbon
and climate-resilient Infrastructure investments Global
emissions of greenhouse gases are to a large extent dependent on the choice and
design of infrastructure systems[11]. In
2009, power generation, building energy use, transportation systems and waste
management infrastructure accounted for 74% of net Greenhouse Gas emissions for
developed countries.[12] Moreover, these infrastructure systems are generally composed of
long-term capital assets, which without re-investment provide lock-in to future
emissions paths." The
transformation in the design of infrastructure is necessary to address climate
change goals. Given the long life span of infrastructure assets and their
interconnectivity (e.g. infrastructure networks is necessary. Both low carbon
and climate resilience have to be considered when infrastructure is planned,
designed and constructed. Chart 1: Contributions of sectors to the growth of nominal gross
capital formation in the euro area (annual percentage change and percentage
point contributions) Source: Eurostat 4. Investment
and savings in the EU Economic
recovery and sustainable growth need to be investment-driven. Investment (gross
capital formation) leads to innovations that improve the competitiveness of
businesses and markets and thus also to income and jobs being secured or
created. Over the last decade, aggregate investment performance in the EU has
been slightly better than in the USA, but worse than in Japan and the world average. Before the crisis, the ratio of the total investment to GDP
(i.e. investment rate) in the EU increased, but then it dropped significantly
during the crisis (approximately by 4%-points), mirroring similar developments
in other economies in the downturn. The current investment rate in the EU and
other major economies is close to 20%, its lowest level since the 1980s (Chart 2).
However, there are significant differences between Member States. In countries
that experienced a significant increase in investment in the pre-crisis period,
the trend in investment has reversed sharply and declined to relative low
shares of GDP (e.g. Ireland and Spain, both of which have experienced boom-bust
cycles in real estate investments). Chart 2: Investment rate in
different Chart 3: Saving rate in different economies in % of GDP economies
in % of GDP Source: IMF database. Note:
Total investment is the gross capital formation that includes mainly
investments made in fixed assets. Aggregate
volumes of investment may also hide significant differences in terms of sector
composition and maturity profile of the investments. For example, EU annual
growth rates of investment in equipment have trailed those in the USA in the decade before crisis. As regards R&D investments, especially those in the
high R&D-intensive sectors that require long-term investment, the top 400
R&D-investing companies in the EU invested €132 bn in R&D in 2011
compared to the €160 bn invested by 487 US counterparts.[13] The capacity of
the economy to finance long-term productive investment depends on its capacity
to generate and mobilise internal savings and to attract and retain foreign
direct investment (FDI) for the long-term, as well as on its ability to
effectively channel the funds efficiently to the right users and uses. As regards FDI,
the development of FDI inflows in the EU has been quite volatile: after falling
to nearly half of the volume of the previous year, they picked up in 2009, but
then shrank considerably again in 2010. In 2011, FDI increased considerably,
reaching €224 bn compared to €156 bn in the previous year. In terms of sources
of FDI, inward direct investments from EU Member States represented 60% of
total FDI in the EU.[14]
In Member States that have suffered most from the sovereign debt crisis there
has been a clear outflow of direct investments to other European countries. In
contrast, the inflow of FDI from outside the EU has considerably increased on
average compared to the pre-crisis period. As regards savings, the ratio of the
aggregate savings to GDP (i.e. saving ratio) in the EU has stabilised at 20%
over the past decade and, after a drop during the crisis in 2008/2009, it
picked up again. The ratio is still higher than in USA (by 5 to 8 percentage points),
and the gap compared to Japan has fallen in the last two years. The majority of
savings (about 80%) results from households, the rest are corporate savings
(e.g. cash and cash equivalent on the balance sheets) and government savings
(such as external reserves of central banks and sovereign wealth funds). It is
important to note that while household saving rates in Europe have declined due
to a reduction in disposable income, the savings of large corporates’ in many
Member States have increased[15]
due to delays in investment and leading to an enlargement of cash holdings
during the crisis – for example, cash and equivalent positions of large firms
are estimated to have increased by around four percentage points from 2009 to
2011.[16]
Conversely, many SMEs suffer from a continual lack of liquidity. A comparison
between Chart 2 and Chart 3 shows that in the US the gap between saving and
investment demand remains significant. In Japan there is excess saving over the
desired level of investment, while in Europe both investment and saving rates
are at similar aggregate levels, suggesting that in principle there are
sufficient funds to meet investors' needs. It is important to mention that the
aggregate numbers do not reflect variations in sector composition and maturity
profile (e.g. the stronger preference of savers for short- rather than
long-term savings). Strong
increases in public debt and deficit levels imply that today in Europe there is less scope for government spending to provide the desired level of investment.
Therefore, Member States need to attract an increasing amount of private
capital to offset the decline in public capital. Moreover, levels of savings
per se are not sufficient in and of themselves. What also matters is that they
are channelled to appropriate investments. The analysis below sets out some of
the reasons why this is not always the case. The sources and
mechanisms to collect and invest savings have a significant influence on the
ability to finance long-term investments. The flow-of-funds in Chart 4 illustrates
the allocation of funds from savers to the end-users and uses. 5. Financing chain: from providers to the end-users of
funds Broadly
speaking, and assuming a closed economy without foreign investment inflows,
savings from households, corporates and governments (on the bottom right in
Chart 4) flow into the system through financial intermediaries to reach the
end-users of funds (bottom left in Chart 4) which are: households that borrow
for housing investment (mortgage lending) and financing of consumer goods;
governments that collect funds through debt issuance; and, corporates.
Corporates can either issue equity or debt in the capital markets to accumulate
funds, or they can take loans from banks, which in turn could be securitized
through collateral loan obligations and also end up in capital markets. The pool of
users and sources of funds are primarily linked through financial
intermediation, which, when it functions properly, has the advantage of
providing clients with maturity transformation, better information and lower
transaction costs through economies of scale by pooling funds and operating
large and well-diversified portfolios. The leading
intermediaries in most European countries are banks: retail banks that are
typically very close to their clients, both on the deposit and on the lending
side. In Europe, 85% of financing is provided through banks. Financial
intermediaries and banks in particular, help in general to reduce the problem
of asymmetric information (adverse selection and moral hazard).[17] The large European banks,
typically "universal banks" that offer a much broader range of
services, have established themselves as the key distribution channel for a
number of non-banking products. The other way
to channel funds from savers to end-users is through capital markets. Savings
are used to buy/sell securities, as indicated in Chart 3 by
"distribution". In addition, savings can also be pooled in collective
investment vehicles and can flow to fiduciaries or asset managers, who in turn
will manage these assets on behalf of the ultimate owners. The major functions
of capital markets can be grouped in three categories. ·
First, origination/ underwriting that brings
securities to the markets. Loans, which are originated by banks, may also end
up in capital markets though securitization, e.g. asset- backed securities for
credit-cards loans or collaterized loan obligations (CLO) for corporate loans; ·
Secondly, brokerage and trading, which might be
client-driven, either for investors or for borrower-issuer clients, or
proprietary trading for the firm's own book; and ·
Third, the direct distribution of securities
either to institutional investors or to retail end-user. Banks are the
leading intermediaries for new product distribution, accounting for more than
50% in countries such as Belgium, Spain, France, Sweden, Italy and Portugal. Brokers are the most common intermediaries in countries such as Netherlands, Slovakia, Ireland and the UK, while agents predominate in Germany, Poland and Slovenia.[18] In addition, direct selling
has increased substantially in some countries, e.g. the Netherlands, and is becoming a serious competitor to the traditional channels. Chart 4:
Flow of funds from providers to the end-users of funds 6. Reduced incentives for households’ long term savings Households tend to be reluctant to commit to long-term savings for
both cyclical and structural reasons. They also want to be able to manage
individual liquidity shocks. It is important to note that the factors outlined
below are considered from the perspective of households. From a bank
perspective, even the volume of deposits could – at least partially – be
considered long term. MGI (2010) shows that the increased availability of credit during
the economic boom, the “wealth effect” of asset appreciation during the stock
market boom in the 90s and the real estate bubble in some Member States after
2000 have lowered the level of households savings. In an economic downturn,
increased uncertainty, high unemployment and the lack of perspectives have
increased the preference of savers for liquidity. The crisis experience has
also increased savers’ distrust in financial institutions and markets. In
addition, the current low interest rate environment makes saving less attractive.
As regards structural factors, studies suggest that most European
households are very risk-averse when it comes to long-term decisions.[19] Most consumers prioritise
returns and safety (predictability), and therefore they regard capital
guarantees as a factor of great importance. Other reasons for not saving
long-term are the often poor performance of financial intermediaries to deliver
reasonable return, and costs of intermediation. Market intermediaries have
prospered and grown – both in scale and profit – often benefiting themselves
more than the end-users. Taxation also plays an important role on the amount of savings in
the economy and their allocation to different assets and investments. It
influences the tax burden on lifetime income for tax payers with similar
incomes but different income patterns and it affects the welfare of households
by directly affecting consumption behaviour.[20]
Tax regimes sometimes penalise saving by double-taxing interest, income,
capital gains and inheritance. Structural tax privileges for investing in
property have contributed to housing bubbles pre-crisis and draw private
savers’ funds away from other potentially more productive uses. The housing market problems in some European countries, with a large
build-up in household debt, have not only reduced income for non-housing
consumption, but also for savings. Long-term saving may also be discouraged by lack of knowledge of
most of the savers in financial products. Customers often do not understand
them, are not willing to devote much time to financial matters, and are
unlikely to closely monitor their investment decisions over time. Due to population ageing and the reduced possibilities of public
(pay-as-you-go) pension systems to pay, there is a need for funded complementary
pensions and supplementary individual savings for retirement. This should, in
principle, increase the pool of savings and investable capital in the long
term. The traditional way of encouraging voluntary savings for retirement has
been through tax incentives. Member States have already put in place a number
of policies, notably with respect to pension related savings. However, there is no clear evidence for the efficiency of using tax
relief to improve overall retirement savings outcomes.[21] For
instance, it is not clear that tax reliefs actually create additional saving
rather than simply divert existing saving. Providing tax relief can be very
expensive, costing between over 1.7 % GDP in IE and UK to less than 0.2 % GDP
in SK. OECD suggests that the costs of tax relief will continue to outweigh
revenues collected. As voluntary private pension coverage has been generally low[22], mandatory pension savings might
collect funds in a more regular way. They have already been implemented in
a number of EU Member States, for example in Sweden and some countries in the
CEE. The latest example is the UK, which has been operating a mandatory scheme
with automatic enrolment since October 2012. However, it is not clear whether
such solution may be generalised for all EU Member States or could easily be
accepted by all stakeholders. Once the economy has picked up and confidence is restored, the
recovery is likely to positively influence saving behaviours. Nevertheless,
structural problems may remain unless different actions are considered to
reduce barriers to long-term savings. Policy actions in this respect are
discussed in the Green Paper. 7. Recent dynamics in financial intermediation In this section, inefficiencies in the intermediation chain, the
bank lending gap due to the current situation in the banking sector, as well as
opportunities for other intermediaries to fill this gap are discussed. 7.1. Inefficiencies in the intermediation chain As set out in
detail in Kay (2012), intermediation has to serve the end-users, i.e. corporate
and other borrowers, who seek to raise funds, and savers wishing to generate
returns on their savings. Kay (2012) also argues that the success of
intermediation should be measured by how well it serves these two groups and
less by how markets contribute to intermediate objectives per se, such as
liquidity and price discovery. Transformation
of the financial system during the last decades, be it through globalisation,
deregulation or other factors, has changed the culture of financial institutions
and the behaviour of market participants. According to Kay (2012), a culture
based on trust and relationship is replaced by one that gives trading priority
and price discovery, resulting in: ·
Increased fragmentation in shareholder
structure, reducing incentives for engagement and the level of control by
shareholders and leading to an explosion in financial intermediation; ·
Complex and long investment chains, raising
costs for end users and risking misalignment of incentives; and ·
An undue focus of some key intermediaries, such
as asset managers, on their short-term relative performance to their
competitors, which is required from the environment in which they act. Their
decisions are based on relative performance, rather than on the long-term
prospects and underlying business of the companies or products in which they
invest. On the other hand, the interests of savers and companies are in
absolute performance. This misalignment of incentives between asset managers
and market users is the product of the short-term performance horizon. The
principal agent problem in asset management, outlined in Box 2, is one of the
market failures that hamper long-term investment. Inefficiencies arise
also from the fact that banks are inherently vulnerable to confidence crises
and deposit runs that are economically costly, in the sense that a
fundamentally solvent and healthy bank can be forced into insolvency through
depositors’ self-fulfilling expectations (which may or may not be driven by
fundamentals), causing severe economic pain (recall of loans and termination of
productive investments). If only a limited number of depositors claim their
money back, then no early liquidation of long-term projects is required.
However, if many depositors run relative to what had been expected, this will
force the bank to liquidate the illiquid assets (also loans) at a loss
("fire sales"). To avoid this well-known scenario, institutions have
been put in place, such as deposit insurance, lender of last resort facilities
(LoLR or emergency lending assistance ELA), creditor protection, and suspension
of deposit convertibility. However, safety nets
also give rise to excessive risk taking behaviour on behalf of the beneficiary
banks (and they create competitive distortions through an artificially lowered
funding cost for beneficiary banks). Given the relatively high leverage and
creditor dispersion (which leads to imperfect market monitoring), the usual
problem of moral hazard stemming from limited liability takes a particularly
important role in banking. In the run-up to the crisis, higher return for
higher risk was achieved not by socially-valuable product innovation, but by
leveraging and taking excessive risks, leaving the problem to governments if
and when the bad tail risks materialised. This moral hazard risk needs to be
curtailed through bank regulation and supervision. Structural
reform may significantly reduce investors' concerns that many large banks are a
complex portfolio of franchises. It is very difficult to value any individual
component of that portfolio, as investments are too-complex-to-price. This
undermines confidence in banks and thus negatively affects their ability to
channel long term investments to high-yield investment opportunities in the
real economy. The Green Paper discusses policy actions to
reach simpler, more efficient and less costly financial intermediation, where
incentives should align with long-term decisions. Box 2:
Market failures and regulatory side-effects Markets may allocate a sub-optimal amount or composition of
long-term investment (LTI) for several reasons, reflecting both the market
failures and regulatory side-effects. Market failures include mainly
externalities[23]
(where the marginal benefit to the investor does not include the marginal social
benefit given that not all costs/benefits fall to the investor); market power
(which could result in the overpricing of LTI finance) and asymmetries of
information which leads to indirect finance, but the issue of information
problems is still present. . Example: Asset management – principal agent problem Long-term investors ('principals') often invest via 'agents' such as
fund managers. Agents usually have better information and different objectives
than their principals. It has been argued that the net result may be that
agents, in pursuing their own interest, misprice securities (by mimicking their
counterparts in other firms to exacerbate bubbles and crashes) and extract
rents. In principle, large investors and the authorities could address these problems
by changing the way investors deal with agents – e.g. by requiring agents to
adopt a long-term investment approach based on long-term dividend flows rather
than on short-term price movements. Regulatory side-effects may arise from national and EU regulation. Examples of these
alleged side-effects of legal frameworks can be found for example in
accounting, liquidity regulation, Basel III and taxation. Example: Accounting rules Some commentators have alleged that fair value
accounting has incentivised them to operate in a manner which might discourage
long-term investment. In principle, fair value shows
the market value of assets and liabilities; this information can be relevant to
all types of investors as part of an overall appraisal, providing a sense of
the relative financial condition of different institutions. But some argue that through the use of fair value, the volatility in
the market value of their securities introduces volatility into their P&L.
This is thought to be to the detriment of a long-term financing horizon,
especially for institutional investors with long-term liabilities,
who for internal valuation of some of their assets may use other valuation
techniques (such as historic or book values). Therefore,
there is a need for further analysis on the scope and relevance of fair value
accounting in relation to long-term financing. Example: Adequate taxation Taxation influences considerably investment decisions. As outlined
in Section 4, the current tax systems give a preference to debts compared to
equity which influences the channels by which companies get funded. Adequate
tax policy is necessary in order to avoid distortion in the allocation of
savings for investment. Other factors: the general evolution of
economic conditions seems to be biased against "patient" activities.
The development of information and communication technologies has facilitated
the development of short-term and speculative transactions. In addition, a number of other factors may create a short-term bias. These factors include: - A lack of engagement by long-term investors, which can reduce the
focus of companies on longer-term strategies; - Shareholder value which currently prioritises the maximisation of
share value against the longer-term fundamental value of the firm; and - The nature of the relationship between investors and asset
managers and the way asset managers' incentives are
structured, which is argued by some[24] to contribute to increasing
short-termism and mispricing. Corporate governance policies may target this suboptimal market
behaviour. Companies investing over the long term have
a clear interest in having shareholders who take a long-term view of the
company and, as stewards of its long-term interests, engage in important
strategy and investment discussions. However, some shareholders may pay too
little heed to this crucial role. As a consequence, company directors may focus
overly on its short, not long-term health. There are different reasons for
this, including remuneration policies and an excess focus on the short-term
share price. Improvements in this general area require more realignment of
incentives between shareholders and company management. Some of the actions in
the corporate governance to encourage long term engagement and long term perspective
on the company are discussed in the Green Paper. 7.2. Bank lending gap Non-financial
corporates in Europe depend on banks for most of their debt finance. The share
of the banking sector in Member States is large by international comparison,
reflecting the European economy's greater dependency on bank intermediation.
For example, bank loans and other advances accounted for 85% of total
non-financial corporate debt outstanding in the euro area and in the UK in 2011, while non-financial corporate bonds accounted for only 15%.[25] In the USA, by contrast, the proportion between bank loans and cooperate bonds was 53% to 47%.
While in Europe non-financial corporates – especially mid-caps and SMEs – are
highly dependent on banking sector, loans to non-financial corporates and
households represent about 1/3 of banks' total assets, reflecting the
asymmetric dependency between non-financial corporates and the financial
sector.[26]
European
banks rely heavily on maturity transformation In the years
leading up to the crisis, European banks had relatively high loan-to-deposit
ratios in international comparison (Chart 5) and they relied heavily on (often
short-term) wholesale creditors and excessive maturity transformation (i.e.
borrowing short and lending long) to fund their long-term lending. Although the
crisis changed this, even after 2008 the ratio of (typically illiquid) loans to
(stable) retail funding (the loan-to-deposit ratio) in Europe remained
relatively high at 130% on average in 2011, while in the USA it has fallen from
around 95% to 75% since the onset of the crisis.[27] Moreover, European banks have
stable funding ratios[28]
that are lower than in the USA, Japan and emerging markets, suggesting also
that maturity transformation was, and remains, substantial for European banks'
balance sheets (Chart 6). Chart 5: Loan to deposit ratios, 1997-2011 Chart
6: Stable funding ratios, 1997-2011 Source: BIS, Annual Report
2012. As confidence vanished during the crisis,
the interbank market – as immediate source of banking liquidity and funding –
dried up, highlighting the risks associated with excessive maturity
transformation. Many banks have started to de-risk their business in order to
adjust to pressures in their funding through deleveraging their balance sheets
(by increasing equity capital and/or disposing of assets) as well as changes in
funding structures. While de-leveraging after the crisis is necessary, this
process may last for several years, with the consequence that credit might
become less available and more costly, changing the attractiveness of different
types of investments and altering the feasibility of some banks’ business
models.[29]
Seen historically, private investment was often quite low for the duration of
deleveraging. One of the reasons why deleveraging has been relatively slow is
due to the interventions of governments and the ECB to provide swift and
abundant liquidity. As these interventions are for a limited period of time,
the impact of deleveraging on private investments might be more noticeable
afterwards. The ECB bank
lending survey October 2012 reports that net tightening of credit standards by
euro area banks for loans or credit lines to enterprises increased (15% in net
terms, compared to 10% in the second quarter of 2012). The responding banks
expected a further tightening of standards for the near future. The main
reasons were negative economic outlook, as well as the actual bank capital
positions and the related on-going need for balance sheet adjustments. In terms
of company type, the tightening of credit standards has applied more for loans
to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) than to large ones; while in terms
of maturity, the tightening of credit standards increased for both short- and
long-term loans. The bank lending survey demonstrates that unless corporates –
and especially SMEs – have access to alternative sources of finance, any
decline in bank lending is likely to have an adverse impact on corporates'
ability to finance investment. Negative feedback loop between banks and
sovereigns harm investments Particularly challenging is the simultaneity of the
deleveraging pressures on banks and sovereigns. Sovereign indebtedness has
risen to peacetime highs across several Member States, feeding into the balance
sheets of banks. Direct exposure of banks to sovereign debt weakens their
balance sheets, increases their riskiness as counterparties and makes funding
more costly and more difficult to obtain. In addition, higher sovereign debt
risk reduces the value of sovereign collateral that banks can use to raise
wholesale funding. Other factors, such as the reduced value of government
guarantees due to weaker government finances or financial contagion (sovereign
to sovereign or sovereign to banks) further affect bank funding conditions.
Banks participating in the ECB bank lending survey reported increased funding
pressure because of the sovereign debt crisis in the second quarter of 2012.
The resulting additional funding pressures might in turn affect lending to
non-financial corporates across all maturities, including the long-term ones. Different elements in the regulatory framework favour investments in
sovereign debt. While sovereign debt itself in part funds long-term
investments, private sector long-term investment may be at a relative
disadvantage. This situation may merit consideration in the future, once market
conditions allow for a comprehensive discussion. Long-term lending and the
"home-bias" Several periods of liquidity squeeze have taken their
toll on the volume of intermediation by banks. During the most severe time of
the crisis from mid-2008 to mid-2009, there has been a dramatic fall in the
volume of new loans by monetary financial institutions (MFIs) to non-financial
firms for all maturities (Chart 7). The volume of new long-term loans, which
are important for long-term productive investment, declined markedly in the
first half of 2012 (Chart 7) and their stock shows a significant downward trend
at the very short end (Chart 8). ESMA(2012) reports that banks have restricted credit to corporates even in cases where companies generate a
positive cash flow, which would allow for the servicing of debt. In addition,
banks have reduced cross-border lending, which has led global companies to
increasingly rely on their own domestic financial institutions further reducing
the availability of debt capital for SMEs. Chart 7: MFI loans (flows) to non-financial Chart
8: MFI loans (stocks) to non-financial corporates in the Euro Area corporates
in the Euro Area Source: ECB Moreover, stress in bank funding, tighter regulation and risk
management requirements are also driving an increase in "home bias",
impacting the cross-border financing. Note that home bias is a well-known
phenomenon in finance.[30]
Investors are reluctant to acquire the full benefits of portfolio diversification
and hold a disproportionate share of local assets. Reasons for this are (i)
asset trade costs in international financial markets (such as transaction costs
or differences in tax treatments between national and foreign assets),( ii)
informational frictions and behavioural biases as well as (iii) costs of
hedging (e.g. real exchange rate when investing in/outside Eurozone and
no-tradable income risk)[31]. A well- functioning Single Market for financial services can
stimulate cross-border long-term investments. Unfortunately, cross-border
lending has fallen substantially as a result of the financial crisis. The share
of cross-border loans in the money markets between mid-2011 and mid-2012
plummeted 33%.. Where the need for investments is greatest, lending rates in
some countries are increasing despite the low base rate. In fact, private-sector
borrowing costs have started to diverge substantially according to geographic
location. Companies may have similar financial strength and growth prospects,
but they may be "punished or rewarded" in the markets for the budget
and economic policy shortcomings of their respective home country. Some
difference in private-sector borrowing costs is to be expected given that some
Member States are growing whereas others are shrinking; but the current pricing
differentials suggest market fragmentation (redenomination risk) is partially
to blame, in addition to the differentiation in fundamentals and sovereign
default risks. This is potentially inefficient, as financially-weak firms in
strong countries are able to survive, whereas strong and fundamentally sound
companies in programme countries may have to leave the market. Demand for long-term loans has decreased Negative developments in long-term lending result from
worsening demand and supply conditions. It is hard to separate out whether an
observed level of bank lending is the product of banks being unwilling to lend
more, or of the private sector being unwilling to borrow more. The slowdown in
economic activity has lowered the profitability expectations and the quality of
loan applications has deteriorated following the downturn in the economic
conditions. Therefore corporates have reduced their demand for credit owing to
lower capital formation. This is evident from the ECB bank lending survey, in
which participating banks reported a further net
decline in the demand for long-term loans in the third quarter of 2012, which
is more pronounced than the decline in demand for short-term loans (24% for
long-term compared to 17% for short-term loans). Chart 9: Expected
demand for loans or credit lines to non-financial corporates (net-% of banks
reporting a positive contribution to demand) Source: ECB (2012) The Euro Area bank lending survey,
3nd quarter of 2012. Lack of confidence combined with ultra-low
interest rates incentivises forbearance. Low interest rates may, in a systemic
crisis, incentivise banks to speculate with the prospects of resurrection by
postponing the necessary balance sheet repair and engage in "ever-greening
of loans" policies (the rolling-over of impaired loans as interest-only
loans, since the opportunity cost of receiving payment in the future over today
is lower, which allows to hide impairments from supervisors and creditors). Low
interest rates allow banks to disguise underlying credit weakness and continue
lending to "bad" firms (and thus avoid capital losses). This reduces
the outlook and profitability of healthy firms and thus discourages new
long-term investments and the entry of new players. In addition, new lending is
further curtailed if banks hold onto low return-generating loans, as they may
be constrained in attracting new funding, given the uncertainty with respect to
their true solvency. 7.3. Opportunities for long-term investors Insurance
companies, pension and mutual funds are the biggest institutional investors in Europe. Together, they hold an estimated total of €13.8 trn of
assets, equating to more than 100% of the region's GDP.[32] As
banks are less able to meet the long-term funding needs of borrowers for the
reasons outlined above, this creates an opportunity for insurers and pension
funds (the biggest institutional investors), because they tend to have
long-dated liabilities, which match the part of the lending market from which
banks are retreating. This advantage arises from the economics of the insurance
and pension market: insurance undertakings can fund loans with predictable long-term
liabilities, such as annuities, and therefore will be less likely to face
liquidity runs and be forced into a fire sale of the loans. In the past banks have been involved in long-term
project financing (e.g. infrastructure) and have invested in illiquid assets.
But today and in the near future, banks might need to reduce their new
investments across different illiquid asset classes, because of their funding
constraints and in order to improve capital and liquidity positions. This
creates opportunities for long-term investors, such as investment funds and
insurance companies, to re-enter the market.[33]
Estimates show that for Germany,
France and the UK, which constitute more than 50% of the total European
insurance market, moving into illiquid asset classes (such as commercial
mortgages, infrastructure projects, SME lending etc.) could increase the value
of the insurance industry in these countries by 50%.[34] Long-term
projects, which often require a considerable amount of funds and know-how in
their implementation, have intrinsic risks. Insurers and pension funds are more
likely to carry the long term financing risk, but not the project and the
implementation risk. Closer cooperation between investors and public authorities
may help to successfully carry through these projects. In the context
of asset allocation, insurance undertakings and pension
funds tend to invest more in securities (shares and bonds) than providing
direct loans. EIOPA data show that insurance undertakings remain biased towards
investments in government bonds, which make up 25% of total assets, followed by
financials with 18% and non-financial corporates with 13% (Chart 10). However,
in the last 12 months, the relative share of equity has
declined slightly, while the share of non-financial corporate has risen. Against this
background, a better channelling of long-term resources via capital markets and
reduced dependence on bank funding is required. Nevertheless, such a
transformation in funding structure may take some time. Chart 10: Asset composition of
European insurance companies Source: EIOPA (2012): EIOPA risk dashboard
September 2012. 8. Capital markets and other sources of finance European non-financial companies finance
their investment largely through bank loans, but since the onset of the crisis
they have relied more on market-based funding,
including different financial instruments, such as equity, debt securities,
inter-company loans and trade credit. In terms of firms’ capital structure, equities
are still the most important source of financing, counting for about 48% of
external financing sources, followed by intercompany loans (around 20%) and
trade credit (around 10%) during the crisis period (Q3 2008 – Q2 2012).[35] When non-financial
companies are observed altogether, including small-and
medium-size companies (SMEs), debt
securities play a minor role. However, for large corporates they are an
important source of funding. Corporate income tax (CIT) system influences
considerably the financing of (long-term) investments. It is a well-known fact
that CIT in many Member States favours debt over equity, as interest payments
are deductible from CIT while there is generally no such relief for the return
on capital. Financing neutrality is a desirable design for a taxation regime
that can be reached through different options, such as a comprehensive business
income tax (CBIT) where the deductibility of interest payments on debt is
(fully or partly) removed, an allowance for corporate equity (ACE) where a
notional interest deduction on equity is granted, or a cash-flow taxation of
companies which would also exempt from tax a notional return to capital,
irrelevant of the financing source. The latter two approaches have the
advantage that they would in addition not distort marginal investment and would
tax economic rents. In the current
market context, direct access to capital markets seems to offer European
corporations some advantages for funding compared to bank debt. Longer
maturities and often lower interest rates than bank loans are among the obvious
advantages. But most importantly, having access to bond markets broadens the
range of alternative sources of funding available to non-financial corporates
in difficult times for bank lending. Corporate bonds markets are gaining
importance In contrast to the tight bank credit conditions, debt
markets have shown more positive development. Based on the balance sheet
information for 161 European firms, Fitch (2011) reported how bank debt has
decreased since 2008, whereas bonds have increased over recent years The increase in corporate bond funding is also evident from the
development of the aggregate outstanding amounts of debt securities issued by
non-financial corporations in the euro area. These totalled €940 bn in July
2012 (90% long-term securities), having risen from about €652bn at the
beginning of 2008 (Chart 11). Total amounts outstanding have been increased
since the beginning of the year, showing similar trends as in 2009. As one
would expect, highly-rated companies account for most of the outstanding
volume. However, there is an increasing importance of BBB and BB rated
corporates in this market. Chart 11: Outstanding amount of debt securities issued by euro area
NFCs (€ million) Source: Source: ECB funding
disintermediation Total figures of corporate bond issuance by
non-financial firms show a considerable improvement in the EU in recent years
compared with the pre-2007 levels (Chart 12). Although both in the USA and the
EU, bond issuance by non-financial firms has followed the up and down swings of
the business cycle, the EU new bond issuance for the 2007-2011 period exceeded
the $ 200 bn mark reaching over 400 mill in 2009. These levels had never been
reached in the EU during the best years of the business cycle between 1999 and
2005. However, although EU corporate bond markets have developed in the recent
years, the non-financial corporate bonds account still only for 15% of
non-financial corporate debt (compared to 47% in the US), as mentioned earlier
in the paper. Chart 12: Annual Bond Issuance by Non-financial Firms in the
EU, USA and Japan (1999-2011) Source: Dealogic It is important to note that the different impact that
the financial crisis has had in different Member States has also quite
differently affected the balance between debt and equity finance between Member
States.[36]
In the pre-crisis period, debt financing for Spanish and Italian firms was
larger than equity financing, but debt financing decelerated remarkably during
the crisis. By contrast, in other countries, inter-company loans and debt
securities played an important role to replace reduced bank lending. Enable access to bond markets for SME The evidence shows that debt capital markets represent
an important alternative source of funding, but at the moment they are
accessible mainly for large corporates domiciled in larger countries with more
developed corporate bond markets. Small-and medium-sized companies (SME) that
face the more severe consequences of the credit crunch cannot afford the costs
of bond issuance. However, in countries where the economy is faring
relatively better through the crisis, there are signs that an increasingly
broader spectrum of firms is gaining direct access to capital markets in Europe. In particular, SME high yield bond issuance has become considerably important in Germany. Driven by the financial crisis, family-run SMEs companies willing to keep full
control of the company have resorted to bond issuance given the difficulties
that they find in securing bank funding. Four of the eight German exchanges
have started trading “Mittelstand bonds” over the last two years. Issues range
from €25 to €225 mn. Retail investors acquire some of them, but institutional
investors hold between 60 and 75% of these bonds, as yields are attractive for
these investors with 7 to 9%. In Stuttgart, the BondM platform gives mid-cap
SMEs the possibility of issuing bonds that can be directly sold to retail
investors without an investment bank underwriting the issue. Covenant and
documentation provisions and costs are also kept to a minimum. The volume of corporate bonds for medium-sized companies is relatively
small, but the trend to increase capital markets assess for medium-sized
companies is likely to continue. For mid-caps and SMEs, which have
historically faced difficulties in accessing funding, the main cause is the
lack of credible information about them. This results in increased costs and
difficulty in evaluating their credit worthiness by potential providers of
funds. Research on SMEs is costly and investors are
generally not eager to pay for it. Provisions should be implemented to make
existing research and ratings information available to a wider set of potential
investors and thus helps reduce information asymmetries associated with smaller
companies. In some countries, such as the US, the SME market is sustained by a
market maker model based on spreads. Other models exist as well, as some market
participants believe that the market maker model does not propose enough
transparency.[37] In order to
facilitate outreach to SMEs, their visibility might be facilitated through
evaluations and improved information provided by credit scoring companies.
Knowing their own score and understanding how it has been calculated may help
SMEs to negotiate with their banks or other financing solutions. Moreover, the
demand for external credit worthiness evaluation has increased, as in some
countries midsize companies have and will continue to develop a stronger
capital market orientation. Demand for rating equivalencies, credit standing
certificates is also increasing in the ‘customer-supplier-relationship’, e.g.
in the automotive and construction industry. Developing harmonised minimum
quality standards on external credit scoring for SMEs would facilitate (cross
border) financing of their investments and deepen market integration. Options
in this regard are discussed in the Green Paper. Equity
markets and IPOs Many claim that the economy, businesses and
investment projects need more equity, than debt. Equity can be a better
financing instrument for long-term, high-risk investments, as well as for
investments with significant information asymmetries and moral hazard. Given
that the crisis was fuelled by overreliance on debt, equity is probably a more
appropriate financing instrument at present. However, since the crisis,
macroeconomic uncertainty and the low interest rate environment may have
affected companies’ demand and risk appetite for long-term equity capital.
Investors have instead sought refuge in government debt instruments with strong
creditworthiness. In addition, preference for debt over equity investment
continues to be affected by the differing tax treatment (see below). These
developments appear to have had a bigger impact on mid-caps. The financial
crisis appears to have accelerated a long-term trend increase in bond
purchasing that started at the beginning of the last decade. The cost of equity
capital has remained high while the cost of debt finance has fallen. Overall,
this highlights the equity gap in Europe, which is likely to take time to
address. In the recent
years, exchanges have tended to act more as providers of liquidity rather than
sources of additional capital. For example, in some cases equity markets are
used for fast "exit", i.e. to extract cash from companies, rather
than for cash injection. This trend became quite pronounced during the crisis,
where the number of listed companies, as well as the amount of capital
injected, experienced a considerable fall. According to FESE, the number of
listed companies in the last five years has been reduced by 27% (from 11,914 in
2007 to 9,031 in 2011), while the capital injected to them experienced a sharp
drop by 65%.[38]
Currently, just a small part of capital (ca. 5%) is used for IPOs, whilst
before crisis this was around 20%. Besides the
weak economy, and the low level of share prices that makes IPO unattractive for
the listed firms, there might be other structural factors that explain low
capital flows. One reason is that the business models of exchanges are based
mostly on trading blue chips; hence there are little incentives to raise new
capital and attract new IPOs. Concentrated trading on blue chips might crowd
out mid-caps. Kay (2012) reports that corporates in the UK are financed either through internal funds or alternative means, such as private equity
or debt issuance and mainly loans for mid-caps and SMEs. However,
providing liquidity is an important function of secondary markets. Liquid and
well-functioning secondary markets encourage investments in primary markets
too, as this enables investors to sell their investments quickly and at low
costs when needed. 9. Public
policy instruments Public-Private Partnership (PPP) is one
instrument to facilitate financing of long-term investments, especially for
those projects with public good character. However, the use of PPS decreased
despite a number of steps that have been taken following the Commission
Communication in 2009.[39]
The revival of this market, notably for trans-border investments, is important.
Some sectorial regulations (e.g. the unbundling directive or those on feed-in
tariffs, both in the energy sector) may create disincentives for long-term
investments. In addition, Member States lack a credible long-term pipeline of
potential PPP projects. A European framework for PPPs promoting transparency,
appropriate risk transfer arrangements and deal structuring, and learning from
the past experience and public finance initiatives could support their enhanced
use and impact. Public
procurement sets the demand from the state (and
local actors) for products, services and infrastructure. It may help public
authorities to give incentives for innovation and attract investors into
long-term projects. However, existing legal uncertainty arising from the
absence of clear rules on the award of concession contracts creates
constraints. Therefore, in December 2011, the Commission proposed a directive[40] with the aim of
providing a clear and simple framework for the award of such contracts. State
Aid rules provide frameworks for public support to
make investments more attractive for private investors. Examples include aid to
infrastructure; support to R&D and innovation; regional development;
efforts to stimulate low-carbon energy or broadband investments; and, measures
to stimulate risk finance.[41]
The 2012 State Aid Modernisation initiative aims to orient scarce public funds
towards efficient and well-designed aid which promotes growth-enhancing
objectives, addresses proven market failures, has an incentive effect, while
keeping distortions of competition limited. Export
credit. Several national public export credit
guarantee schemes exist in Europe today, which provide support to
capital-intensive investments requiring long-term finance for projects in the
EU. It could be useful to analyse whether an EU Export Credit Mechanism could
help the financing of long-term investment, in particular outside the EU and in
non-EU currency denominated projects, in complement to those national
approaches. 10. Conclusion A range of factors should be considered in
order to effectively finance long-term investment and growth in the European
economy. These include accumulating sufficient funds for productive long term
investment; addressing misalignments and inefficiencies in the financial
intermediation process; as well as encouraging and fostering positive trends in
intermediation, such as the latest developments in corporate bond markets.
However, bank credit has been the predominant source of funding for the real
economy in Europe and banks will continue to play a very important role in the
financing landscape in the future. A well-functioning banking system remains
important for successful intermediation. At the same time, market-based
financing will slowly increase in importance, helping to bring the loan to
deposit ratio in Europe to levels comparable to other regions of the world. Market-based
financing increases diversification of external funding sources for companies
and from a financial stability perspective increases the robustness of
financing investments to negative shocks. Bond issuance seems to have become a
viable alternative source of funding for the bigger and best placed financial
corporations, as the crisis has put pressure on firms to find alternative
funding sources. Developing and deepening the capital markets is another step
forward required to support effective financing of long-term investment. There is no "one size fits all"
solution to boost the long-term financing of the European economy. As discussed
in the Green Paper, a debate is needed to address a broad range of
interconnected factors: ·
The capacity of financial institutions to
channel long-term finance; ·
The efficiency and effectiveness of financial
markets to offer long-term financing instruments; ·
The role of public policies in catalysing
long-term saving and financing; and ·
The ease of SMEs to access equity. 11. References ·
Allen & Overy (Dec. 2012): The future of
credit. ·
BIS (2012): Annual Report. ·
BME (2007): The EU market for consumer long term
retail saving vehicles comparative analysis of products, market structure,
distribution systems and consumer saving patterns. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/docs/cross-sector/study_en.pdf ·
ECB (2012)a: The Euro Area bank lending survey,
2nd quarter of 2012. ·
ECB (2012)b: Financial Stability Review. ·
EIOPA (2012): EIOPA risk dashboard September
2012. ·
EFAMA (2012): Asset Management in Europe: Facts and Figures.
http://www.efama.org/Publications/Statistics/Asset%20Management%20Report/Asset%20Management%20Report%202012.pdf ·
ESMA (2012): Securities and Markets Stakeholder
Group – Report on Helping Small and Medium Sized Companies Access Funding. https://eiopa.europa.eu/fileadmin/tx_dam/files/publications/reports/Risk_Dashboard_Sept2012.pdf ·
EU COM (2011): Industrial R&D investment
sideboard. http://iri.jrc.ec.europa.eu/research/scoreboard_2011.htm ·
EU COM (2011) 112: A Roadmap for moving to a
competitive low carbon economy in 2050. http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/roadmap/documentation_en.htm ·
EU COM (2011) 169/3: Proposal for a Council
Directive amending Directive 2003/96/EC restructuring the Community framework
for the taxation of energy products and electricity. http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/com_2011_169_en.pdf ·
EU COM (2012): Capital movements and the
investments in the EU. Commissions’ services paper on market monitoring. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/capital/docs/20120203_market-monitoring_en.pdf ·
Fitch (2011): European corporate funding
disintermediation ·
French, K.R and J.M., Poterba, 1991. Investor
Diversification and International Equity Markets, American Economic Review,
American Economic Association, vol. 81(2), p. 222-26, May. ·
Llewellyn Consulting (2012): Financing European
growth: the challenges for markets, policy makers and investors. ·
Lucas, R., (1982):. Interest Rates and Currency
Prices in a Two-Country World. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 335-359 ·
Kapoor, S and Oksnes L (2011): Funding the New Green Deal: Building a green financial system.
http://re-define.org/sites/default/files/GEF-Funding%20the%20GND%20web.pdf ·
Kay J. (2012): The Kay review of equity markets
and long term decision making ·
Kennedy C. and Corfee-Morlot J. (2012):
Mobilising Investment in Low Carbon, Climate Resilient Infrastructure. OECD
Environment Working Papers, No. 46 ·
McKinsey Global Institute /MGI (2010): Farewell
to cheap capital? The implications of long-term shifts in global investment and
saving. ·
McKinsey Global Institute / MGI (2011): Debt and
deleveraging: The global credit bubble and its economic consequences (Updated
analysis). ·
McKinsey Global Institute / MGI (Dec. 2012):
Investing in growth: Europe's next challenge. ·
Mirrless J. (2011): Tax by design. Oxford
University Press, http://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/5353 ·
Mishking F. (2012): The Economics of Money,
Banking, and Financial Markets. Ch. 8: An Economic
Analysis of Financial Structure, 10th Edition, ·
OECD (2011): Financial stability, fiscal
consolidation and log term investment after the crisis. OECD Journal: Financial
Market Trends, Vol. 2011, Issue 1. ·
Oliver Wyman (2011): The real financial crisis:
Why financial intermediation is failing. State of the financial service
industry report 2012 ·
Oliver Wyman (2012): The €200 bn opportunity:
why insurers should lend more. ·
Smith R. and Walter I. (2012): Global
Banking. Oxford University Press, 3d edition. ·
The Social Protection Committee (2008):
Privately Managed Funded Pension Provision and their Contribution to adequate
and sustainable pensions. http://ec.europa.eu/social/main.jsp?catId=752&langId=en&moreDocuments=yes
·
World Economic Forum (2013): The Green Investment
Report, Green Growth.
http://www.weforum.org/issues/climate-change-and-green-growth [1] See MGI (2010). [2] The two terms “financing long term investments” and “long
term financing” will be used synonymously throughout this paper. [3] Connecting Europe Facility: About EUR 500 billion in
transport, EUR 200 billion in energy and EUR 270 billion for fast broadband
infrastructures. [4] The total need was estimated for the EU27, using 2011
GDP data at current prices, constant investment rate at 19.8% and assuming the
GDP deflator of 1.6 and an average increase of real GDP of 1% until 2020. [5] See MGI (2012). [6] See EU COM (2011) 112 [7] See
World Economic Forum (2013) [8] See Kapoor
et al. (2011) [9] http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/reform/index_en.htm [10] See COM (2011)
169/3 [11] See OECD study from Kennedy C. et al. (2012) [12] Countries referred to in Annex 1 of the UN Framework Convention on
Climate Change (UNFCCC) [13] In the US, over two thirds of the R&D investment
comes from R&D high intensity sectors (pharmaceuticals, healthcare
equipment, biotechnology and ICT) whereas in the EU, only one third comes from
those sectors and about half comes from medium-high R&D-intense sectors.
See EU (2011): Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard, figure 3. [14] See EU (2012): Capital movements and the investments in
the EU. [15] See MGI (2011) for development in different countries.
Note that cash holding is the positive cash balance that remains after savings
are used for investment, acquisitions, debt payments and share repurchases. [16] Based on Fitch (2011) and own estimations of changes in
cash and cash equivalent positions of 170 large European non-financial corporates. [17] Adverse selection occurs before a transaction and
refers to the fact that bad borrowers (in terms of credit risks) are the one
most likely to seek loans, and moral hazard refers to the risk of the
borrower's engaging in activities that are undesirable from the lender's
perspective. For more details see Mishkin 2012, Chapter 8. [18] See BME report (2007). [19] See Oliver Wyman (2012) and BME (2007). [20] An
overview of the economics of savings taxation can be found in the
Mirrlees-Review. See http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview/design/ch13.pdf. [21] For an overview of tax incentives see for example The Social
Protection Committee (2008), section 4.2. . [22] See BME (2007). [23] Examples include where there is a 'collective action' problem,
where LTI in an innovative industry may have ripple effects on other firms
which are not 'captured' by the investing firm, and public goods (referring
here to goods which no-one can be excluded from using, e.g. clean air). [24] For example, see the ‘Kay Review of UK Equity Markets and Long-Term
Decision Making: Final Report’, July 2012. [25] See Llewellyn Consulting (2012): Financing European
growth: the challenges for markets, policy makers and investors. August 2012. [26] This structural bias is highlighted in the recent
report of the High-level Expert Group on reforming the structure of the EU
banking sector. See http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/bank/docs/high-level_expert_group/liikanen-report/final_report_en.pdf. [27] See BIS 2012, annual report. [28] Funding ratio refers to the
proportion of the sum of retail and long term funding to the total funding. [29] According to MGI 2011, the past experience shows that deleveraging episodes last six to seven years
on average and reduce the ratio of debt to GDP by 25 percent. [30] See French, K.R and
J.M., Poterba, 1991 for home bias in equity markets. [31] Non-tradable
income risk refers to the fact that investors receive a part of their income
that cannot be traded in financial markets. see Lucas (1982).. [32] See Fitch 2011 and EFAMA (2012). [33] See Allen and Overy (2012). [34] See Oliver Wyman (2012). [35] See ECB (2012)b, chapter 2.3. [36] See ECB (2012)b. [37] See ESMA 2012. [38] See FESE: http://www.fese.be/ [39] See
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2009:0615:FIN:en:PDF. [40] See
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/publicprocurement/modernising_rules/reform_proposals_en.htm. [41] See
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/legislation/horizontal.html. The
Guidelines on State aid to promote risk capital will be revised in 2013, in the
context of the State aid modernisation initiative.