All official European Union website addresses are in the europa.eu domain.
This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website
Document E2009C0532
EFTA Surveillance Authority Decision No 532/09/COL of 16 December 2009 amending, for the 76th time, the procedural and substantive rules in the field of State aid by introducing a new chapter on criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification
EFTA Surveillance Authority Decision No 532/09/COL of 16 December 2009 amending, for the 76th time, the procedural and substantive rules in the field of State aid by introducing a new chapter on criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification
EFTA Surveillance Authority Decision No 532/09/COL of 16 December 2009 amending, for the 76th time, the procedural and substantive rules in the field of State aid by introducing a new chapter on criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification
OJ L 332, 15/12/2011, p. 14–19
(BG, ES, CS, DA, DE, ET, EL, EN, FR, IT, LV, LT, HU, MT, NL, PL, PT, RO, SK, SL, FI, SV)
In force
15.12.2011 |
EN |
Official Journal of the European Union |
L 332/14 |
EFTA SURVEILLANCE AUTHORITY DECISION
No 532/09/COL
of 16 December 2009
amending, for the 76th time, the procedural and substantive rules in the field of State aid by introducing a new chapter on criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification
THE EFTA SURVEILLANCE AUTHORITY (1),
HAVING REGARD to the Agreement on the European Economic Area (2), and in particular Articles 61 to 63 and Protocol 26 thereof,
HAVING REGARD to the Agreement between the EFTA States on the Establishment of a Surveillance Authority and a Court of Justice (3), and in particular Article 24 and Article 5(2)(b) thereof,
RECALLING the Procedural and Substantive Rules in the Field of State Aid adopted on 19 January 1994 by the Authority (4),
Whereas:
Pursuant to Article 24 of the Surveillance and Court Agreement, the Authority shall give effect to the provisions of the EEA Agreement concerning State aid,
Pursuant to Article 5(2)(b) of the Surveillance and Court Agreement, the Authority shall issue notices or guidelines on matters dealt with in the EEA Agreement, if that Agreement or the Surveillance and Court Agreement expressly so provides or if the Authority considers it necessary,
The European Commission published a Communication on the criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification (5) on 11 August 2009,
That Communication is also of relevance for the European Economic Area,
Uniform application of the EEA State aid rules is to be ensured throughout the European Economic Area,
According to point II under the heading ‘GENERAL’ at the end of Annex XV to the EEA Agreement, the Authority, after consultation with the Commission, is to adopt acts corresponding to those adopted by the Commission,
The Authority consulted the Commission by a way of letter on the subject dated 27 November 2009 (Event No 538332) and the EFTA States by a way of letter on the subject dated 16 October 2009 (Event Nos 5333819, 533835 and 533836),
HAS ADOPTED THIS DECISION:
Article 1
The State Aid Guidelines shall be amended by introducing a new chapter on criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification. The new chapter is contained in the Annex to this Decision.
Article 2
Only the English version is authentic.
Done at Brussels, 16 December 2009.
For the EFTA Surveillance Authority
Per SANDERUD
President
Kristján Andri STEFÁNSSON
College Member
(1) Hereinafter referred to as ‘the Authority’.
(2) Hereinafter referred to as ‘the EEA Agreement’.
(3) Hereinafter referred to as ‘the Surveillance and Court Agreement’.
(4) Guidelines on the application and interpretation of Articles 61 and 62 of the EEA Agreement and Article 1 of Protocol 3 to the Surveillance and Court Agreement, adopted and issued by the Authority on 19.1.1994, published in the Official Journal of the European Union (hereinafter referred to as ‘OJ’) L 231, 3.9.1994, p. 1 and EEA Supplement No 32 of 3.9.1994, p. 1 (hereinafter referred to as ‘the State Aid Guidelines’). The updated version of the State Aid Guidelines is published on the Authority’s website: http://www.eftasurv.int/state-aid/legal-framework/state-aid-guidelines/
ANNEX
CRITERIA FOR THE ANALYSIS OF THE COMPATIBILITY OF STATE AID FOR THE EMPLOYMENT OF DISADVANTAGED AND DISABLED WORKERS SUBJECT TO INDIVIDUAL NOTIFICATION (1)
1. Introduction
1. |
The promotion of employment and social policy are among the aims of the EEA Agreement and of the EFTA States (2). Unemployment, and in particular structural unemployment of certain categories of workers, remains a problem in some parts of the EFTA States. State aid in the form of subsidies to wage costs, where wage cost means the total amount actually payable by the beneficiary of the aid in respect of the employment concerned, comprising: (a) the gross wage, before tax; and (b) the compulsory contributions, such as social security charges; and (c) child care and parent care costs (‘wage subsidies’), can provide additional incentives to undertakings to increase their levels of employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers. The objective of such aid is thus to encourage the recruitment of the targeted categories of worker. |
2. |
This Chapter gives guidance on the criteria the EFTA Surveillance Authority (hereinafter referred to as ‘the Authority’) will apply for the assessment of State aid in form of wage subsidies that needs to be notified individually pursuant to Article 6(1)(h) and (i) of the Act referred to at point 1j of Annex XV to the EEA Agreement (Commission Regulation (EC) No 800/2008 of 6 August 2008 declaring certain categories of aid compatible with the common market in application of Articles 87 and 88 of the Treaty (General Block Exemption Regulation)) (3), as adapted to the EEA Agreement by Protocol 1 thereto (4) (hereinafter referred to as ‘the General Block Exemption Regulation’). This guidance is intended to make the Authority’s reasoning transparent and to create predictability and legal certainty. |
3. |
This guidance applies to State aid in the form of wage subsidies for disadvantaged workers, severely disadvantaged workers and disabled workers within the meaning of Article 2(18), (19) and (20) of the General Block Exemption Regulation. Any individual measure, whether granted ad hoc or on the basis of a scheme, will be subject to this guidance when its grant equivalent exceeds EUR 5 million per undertaking per year for the employment of disadvantaged workers and severely disadvantaged workers (hereinafter referred to together as ‘disadvantaged workers’) and EUR 10 million per undertaking per year for the employment of disabled workers (5). |
4. |
The criteria set out in this guidance will not be applied mechanically. The level of the Authority’s assessment and the kind of information it may require will be proportional to the risk of distortion of competition. The scope of the analysis will depend on the nature of the case. |
2. Positive effects on the aid
2.1. Existence of an objective of common interest
5. |
Certain categories of workers experience particular difficulty in finding jobs, because employers consider them to be less productive or have prejudices against them. This perceived or real lower productivity may be due either to lack of recent experience in employment (for example, young workers or long-term unemployed) or to a permanent disability. Because of their perceived or real lower productivity, the workers are likely to be excluded from the labour market unless employers are offered compensation for their employment. |
6. |
It is socially desirable that all categories of workers are integrated in the labour market. This means that a share of the domestic income may be redistributed to the categories of workers concerned by the measures. State aid may help disadvantaged and disabled workers to enter the labour market or stay in the labour market by covering the extra costs resulting from their perceived or real lower productivity. |
7. |
EFTA States should demonstrate that the aid will address the objective of common interest. In its analysis, the Authority will, among other things, consider the following elements:
|
2.2. State aid as an appropriate policy instrument
8. |
State aid in the form of wage subsidies is not the only policy instrument available to EFTA States to encourage employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers. EFTA States can also use general measures such as reduction of the taxation of labour and social costs, boosting investment in education and training, measures to provide guidance and counselling, assistance and training for the unemployed and improvements in labour law. |
9. |
Where the EFTA State has considered other policy options, and the advantages of using a selective instrument such as State aid for a specific undertaking are established, the measures concerned are considered to constitute an appropriate instrument. The Authority will in particular take account of any impact assessment of the proposed measure the EFTA State may have made. |
2.3. Incentive effect and necessity of the aid
10. |
State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers must result in the aid beneficiary changing its behaviour so that the aid results in a net increase in the number of disadvantaged or disabled employees in the undertaking concerned. Newly recruited disadvantaged or disabled employees should only fill newly created posts or posts that have fallen vacant following voluntary departure, disability, retirement on grounds of age, voluntary reduction of working time or lawful dismissal for misconduct. Posts resulting from redundancy are not to be filled with subsidised disadvantaged or disabled workers. Thus, State aid cannot be used to replace workers in respect of whom the undertaking no longer receives a subsidy and who have consequently been dismissed. |
11. |
EFTA States should demonstrate to the Authority the existence of the incentive effect and the necessity of the aid. First, the beneficiary must have submitted an application for the aid to the EFTA State concerned before the categories of workers concerned by the measures were employed. Second, the EFTA State must demonstrate that the aid is paid in respect of a disadvantaged or disabled worker in an undertaking, where the recruitment would have not occurred without the aid. |
12. |
In its analysis, the Authority will consider, among other things, the following elements:
|
2.4. Proportionality of the aid
13. |
The EFTA State must demonstrate that the aid is necessary and the amount is kept to the minimum in order to achieve the objective of the aid.
EFTA States should provide evidence that the aid amount does not exceed the net additional costs of employing the categories of workers concerned by the measure compared to the costs of employing workers who are not disadvantaged or disabled (6). In any case, aid intensities must never exceed those laid down in Articles 40 (7) and 41 (8) of the General Block Exemption Regulation. Eligible costs, to which aid intensities are to be applied, must be calculated in accordance with Articles 40 (9) and 41 (10) of the General Block Exemption Regulation. |
3. Negative effects on the aid
14. |
If the aid is proportionate to achieve the objective of the aid, the negative effects of the aid are likely to be limited and an analysis of the negative effects may not be necessary. However, in some cases, even where the aid is necessary and proportionate for a specific undertaking to increase the employment of categories of workers concerned by the measure, the aid may result in a change in the behaviour of the beneficiary which significantly distorts competition. In those cases the Authority will conduct an analysis of the distortion of competition. The extent of the distortion of competition caused by the aid can vary depending on the characteristics of the aid and of the markets affected (11). |
15. |
The aid characteristics that may affect the likelihood and the extent of the distortion are:
|
16. |
For example, an aid scheme used to encourage undertakings in general in an EFTA State to employ more disadvantaged or disabled workers is likely to have a different effect on the market than a large amount of aid given ad hoc to a single undertaking to enable it to increase its employment of a certain category of workers. The latter is likely to distort competition more significantly as the aid beneficiary’s competitors become less able to compete. The distortion will be even greater if the labour costs in the beneficiary’s business represent a high share of the total costs. |
17. |
In assessing the market characteristics, which can give a much more accurate picture of the likely impact of an aid, the Authority will among other things consider:
|
18. |
The structure of the market will be assessed through the concentration of the market, the size of undertakings (12), importance of product differentiation (13), and barriers to entry and exit. Market shares and concentration ratios will be calculated once the relevant market has been defined. In general, the fewer undertakings there are, the larger their share of the market, and the less competition one would expect to observe (14). If the affected market is concentrated with high barriers to entry (15) and the aid beneficiary is a major player on it then it is more likely that competitors will have to alter their behaviour in response to the aid, for example postpone or abandon the introduction of a new product or technology or exit the market all together. |
19. |
The Authority will also look at the characteristics of the sector, such as the existence of overcapacity and whether the markets in the industry are growing (16), mature or declining. For example, the presence of overcapacity or of mature markets in an industry may increase the risk of aid leading to inefficiency and displacement of output among undertakings which do not have subsidised workers. |
20. |
Finally, the measure will be placed in the context of the situation on the labour market, that is to say, unemployment and employment rates, wage levels, and labour law. |
21. |
Wage subsidies may in particular cases lead to the distortions of competition discussed in paragraphs 22 to 27. |
22. |
The substitution effect relates to the situation where jobs given to a certain category of workers simply replace jobs for other categories. A wage subsidy which targets a specific subgroup of workers splits the labour force into subsidised workers and unsubsidised workers, and may induce undertakings to replace unsubsidised workers with subsidised workers. This occurs because relative wage costs for subsidised and unsubsidised workers are changed (17). |
23. |
Since undertakings which employ subsidised workers compete in the same markets for goods or services as those which do not employ subsidised workers, wage subsidies can contribute to the reduction of jobs elsewhere in the economy. Such a situation occurs when an undertaking employing subsidised workers increases output, but displaces output among undertakings which do not employ subsidised workers and, as a result, the aid crowds out unsubsidised employment. |
24. |
Employment costs form part of the normal operating costs of any undertaking. It is therefore particularly important that aid should have a positive effect on employment and should not merely enable undertakings to reduce costs which they would otherwise bear. For example, wage subsidies reduce the ongoing costs of production and thus would make entry more appealing and enable undertakings with otherwise poor commercial prospects to enter a market or introduce new products to the detriment of more efficient competitors. |
25. |
The availability of State aid may also affect an undertaking’s decision to leave a market where it is already operating. Wage subsidies could reduce the size of losses and enable an undertaking to stay in the market for longer — which may mean that other, more efficient undertakings that do not receive aid are forced to exit instead. |
26. |
In the markets where wage subsidies are granted, undertakings are discouraged from competing and may reduce their investments and attempts to increase efficiency and innovation. The aid beneficiary may delay the introduction of new less labour-intensive technologies because of a change in relative costs for labour-intensive and technology-intensive production methods. Manufacturers of competing or complementary products may also decrease or delay their investment. As a consequence, the overall investment level in the industry concerned will decline. |
27. |
Wage subsidies within a particular region may result in some territories benefiting from more favourable production conditions than others. This may result in the displacement of trade flows in favour of the regions where such aid is given. |
4. Balancing and decision
28. |
The last step in the analysis is to evaluate the extent to which the positive effects of the aid outweigh its negative effects. This will be done on a case-by-case basis for all individual measures. In order to balance the positive and the negative effects, the Authority will assess them and make an overall assessment of their impact on producers and consumers in each of the markets affected. Unless quantitative information is readily available the Authority will use qualitative information for the purposes of the assessment. |
29. |
The Authority is likely to take a more positive stance and therefore accept a higher degree of distortion of competition if the aid is necessary and well-targeted to achieve the objective of the aid and is limited to the net extra costs of compensating for the lower productivity of the categories of workers concerned by the measure. |
(1) This Chapter corresponds to the Communication from the Commission of the European Communities – Criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of State aid for the employment of disadvantaged and disabled workers subject to individual notification (OJ C 188, 11.8.2009, p. 6).
(2) Article 66 et seq. of the EEA Agreement and Article 5 of Protocol 31 on social policy to the EEA Agreement.
(4) Joint Committee Decision No 120/2008 of 7.11.2008 (OJ L 339, 18.12.2008, p. 111, and EEA Supplement No 79, 18.12.2008, p. 20) entered into force on 8.11.2008.
(5) Due to their specific nature, individual measures applying to the compensation for the additional cost of employing disabled workers and additional costs incurred by social enterprises of which the grant equivalent exceeds EUR 10 million per undertaking per year will be assessed on the basis of Article 61(3)(c) of the EEA Agreement. For ad-hoc aid for the employment of disadvantaged workers below EUR 5 million and ad-hoc aid to large undertakings for the employment of disabled workers below EUR 10 million, the Authority will mutatis mutandis apply the principles as outlined in this guidance, though in a less detailed manner.
(6) Net additional costs take into account the costs corresponding to the employment of the targeted categories of disadvantaged or disabled workers (for example, due to lower productivity) and benefits, which the aid beneficiary extracts from this employment (for example, due to an improvement of the image of the undertaking).
(7) The aid intensity for disadvantaged workers must not exceed 50 % of the eligible costs.
(8) The aid intensity for disabled workers must not exceed 75 % of the eligible costs.
(9) For the employment of disadvantaged workers eligible costs are the wage costs over a maximum period of 12 months following recruitment. However, where the worker concerned is a severely disadvantaged worker, eligible costs are the wage costs over a maximum period of 24 months following recruitment.
(10) For the employment of disabled workers eligible costs are the wage costs over any given duration during which the disabled worker is being employed.
(11) A number of markets can be affected by the aid, because the impact of the aid may not be restricted to the markets where the aid beneficiary is active but can extend to other markets, for example input markets.
(12) Size of the undertaking can be expressed in the terms of market shares as well as turnover and/or employment.
(13) The lower the degree of product differentiation, the greater the effect of the aid on competitors’ profits will be.
(14) However, some markets are competitive despite there being few undertakings present.
(15) However, granting aid sometimes helps to overcome entry barriers and allows new undertakings to enter a market.
(16) The existence of growing markets will usually lead to a less pronounced effect of the aid on competitors.
(17) Such substitution effect depends on the elasticity of demand for labour, both for subsidised and unsubsidised workers.