EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 26.4.2018
SWD(2018) 138 final
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
IMPACT ASSESSMENT
Accompanying the document
Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council
on promoting fairness and transparency for business users of online intermediation services
{COM(2018) 238 final}
{SEC(2018) 209 final}
{SWD(2018) 139 final}
Table of Contents
1Introduction
2Problem Definition
3Why should the EU Act?
4Objectives: What should be Achieved?
5What are the available Policy Options?
6What are the impacts of the retained policy options?
7Comparison of options
8Preferred Option
9Monitoring and Evaluation of Impacts
1Introduction
1.1Political Context
In its 2015 Digital Single Market Communication the Commission stressed that 'the market power of some online platforms potentially raises concerns, particularly in relation to the most powerful platforms whose importance for other market participants is becoming increasingly critical'. Following a public consultation as well as in-depth research, the Commission presented an overall assessment of the opportunities and challenges in the online platforms environment in a Communication in May 2016. The Communication recognised the value added of platforms as drivers for innovation and growth in the digital economy. Platforms play an important role in the development of the online world and create new market opportunities, notably for SMEs. Online platforms increase consumer choice in terms of products and services set at a competitive price, thereby enhancing consumer welfare. At the same time, the Communication identified a series of concerns relating to potentially harmful trading practices in relations between platforms and their professional users, and announced a more detailed assessment thereof.
Initiated with an open public consultation closed in Spring 2016, this fact-finding exercise included notably (i) a survey completed by 3,549 businesses users of online platforms, complemented by 50 in-depth interviews and several in-depth case studies; (ii) a study on the terms and conditions of online platforms (iii) a study on issues related to data access in the platform-to-business relations, (iv) workshops with business users of online platforms as well as with online platforms, (v) a significant number of bilateral discussions with stakeholders including online platforms themselves, but also with civil society, (vi) focus groups with business users and with online platforms for options design, as well as (vi) internal research on the legal and economic aspects of online platforms and their business-to-business (B2B) practices. The Commission also organised a stakeholder workshop bringing together online platforms and business associations representing them, which addressed the practices reported during the B2B fact-finding exercise.
In its mid-term review of the Digital Single Market Strategy in May 2017 (Mid-Term Review), the Commission identified the promotion of fairness and responsibility of online platforms as an area where further action is necessary to ensure a fair, open and secure digital environment. The Commission therefore, committed to 'prepare actions to address the issues of unfair contractual clauses and trading practices identified in platform-to-business relationships, including by exploring dispute resolution, fair practices criteria and transparency. These actions could, on the basis of an Impact Assessment and informed by structured dialogues with Member States and stakeholders, take the form of a legislative instrument. This work will be finalised by the end of 2017. The Commission will also continue to use its competition enforcement powers wherever relevant.'
The European Parliament welcomed the Commission's fact-finding exercise and initiative on B2B practices. It expressed concerns about a series of practices and called on the Commission 'to propose a pro-growth, pro-consumer, targeted legislative framework for B2B relations based on the principles of preventing abuse of market power and ensuring that platforms that serve as a gateway to a downstream market do not become gatekeepers.' The European Economic and Social Committee noted that online platforms benefit from a strong first-mover advantage, and that those exploiting network effects can become an unavoidable trading partner for businesses.
On the same topic, the Committee of the Regions stressed that 'early action to prevent fragmentation in the first place would still be far less difficult than ex-post harmonisation of 28 national framework'.
In his Letter of Intent accompanying the 2017 State-of-the-Union address, President Juncker reiterated the Commission's mid-term review commitment as a key part of the Digital Single Market initiatives, announcing an 'Initiative on Online Platforms to safeguard a fair, predictable, sustainable and trusted business environment in the online economy'. In the Commission's Roadmap for a more United, Stronger, and more Democratic Union for the European Council in Tallinn this initiative was announced for 20 December 2017. In response to these announcements, the European Council of October 2017 called for 'increased transparency in platforms’ practices and uses'.
This Impact Assessment follows up on the Commission's commitment in the Mid-Term Review. The objective of this initiative is to maximise the potential of the highly beneficial online platform ecosystems. To this end, this Impact Assessment assesses options to improve predictability and redress possibilities for EU business users that trade on online platforms, whilst maintaining an innovation-friendly environment without unnecessary burden for online platforms. In order to achieve this balance, the retained options all incorporate an important staged approach, focusing on transparency and bilateral conflict resolution in a first step, subject to transparency-enabled monitoring.
1.2Legal context
There is no specific legislation at EU level addressing platform-to-business relationships. The initiative which would stem from this Impact Assessment would be the first action at EU level specifically targeting commercial contracts between online platforms and their business users.
EU Competition lawon the one hand, focuses on anticompetitive behaviour and mergers. The EU antitrust rules tackling anticompetitive behaviour are enforced on case-by-case basis ex post, prioritising inter alia those cases with a potential impact beyond the case itself. The trading practices described in Section 2.1.1 do not necessarily have an anticompetitive object or effect under Article 101 TFEU. Moreover, to be able to rely on Article 102 TFEU to investigate a potential abuse by online platforms of a dominant position, the respective platforms must be dominant in the relevant market. As a result, competition law at EU or national level does not address the type and breadth of issues outlined in this Impact Assessment. This initiative will therefore, aim at complementing the enforcement of EU competition law.
Consumer law, on the other hand, does address a range of potentially harmful practices, at EU level notably through the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive (UCPD) and the Unfair Contract Terms Directive (UCTD). While these directives define a number of relevant concepts, such as 'professional diligence' and 'good faith', their scope is explicitly limited to business-to-consumer transactions. Conversely, the Misleading and Comparative Advertising Directive (MCAD) covers certain B2B relations. It aims at protecting business users against misleading advertising and the unfair consequences thereof and lays down the conditions under which comparative advertising is permitted. However, the provisions set forth in the MCAD are limited to advertising practices and do not generally address the P2B trading practices identified in this Impact Assessment.
While voluntary initiatives exist to tackle harmful trading practices in commercial contracts for example, in the food supply chain, these are sector specific. The types of potentially harmful practices that arise in the food supply chain and the unilateral practices described in Section 2.1.1, together with the different business models that operate, are very different and warrant separate treatment.
1.3Scope of the Impact Assessment
This Impact Assessment analyses the relations between online platforms and their business users (so-called 'platform-to-business' relations, abbreviated as 'P2B' hereafter). It does not focus on the relation between consumers and online platforms, but does have regard for effects on consumers of the P2B dynamic, where relevant. The analysis focuses on online platforms that provide intermediation services for transactions between EU business users and consumers located in the EU.
Annex 1 and Annex 8.3 show the compatibility of the P2B scoping definition with other EU policy initiatives and existing legislation. Where necessary, the Commission services will naturally also ensure full coherence of the technical legal definitions used for the different upcoming EU initiatives that – for distinct purposes – touch in some way on the online platform economy (i.e. the present P2B initiative, the New Deal for Consumers and the digital services tax). The Table below is an extract focusing on current major initiatives in the field of taxation and consumer protection.
Legal instrument
/draft
|
Definition
|
Platforms
in scope
|
Platforms
out- of -scope
|
DRAFT PROPOSAL Art. 3(1)(a) of Council Directive establishing a Digital Services Tax
(Digitax)
|
Multi-sided digital interface - the making available to users of a multi-sided digital interface which allows users to find other users and to interact with them, and which facilitate the provision of underlying supplies of goods or services directly between those users, irrespective of where the transactions are ultimately concluded
Although borrowing from the definition of online intermediation services in the P2B initiative, this definition of multi-sided digital interfaces has a slightly broader scope (as it includes B2B & C2C/P2P platforms) in light of its purpose which is to identify taxable revenues, rather than contractual imbalances in bargaining power. Whereas pure C2C/P2P platforms are frequently provided for-profit, which can be subject to the digital service tax, they do not exhibit the potentially harmful commercial issues targeted by the P2B initiative. The definition in the Digitax proposal will therefore include online intermediation services for the purpose of levying the digital service tax (DST), but not conflict with the definition used in the P2B initiative. The slight difference in intended scope between the respective proposals is implemented in the Digitax proposal by defining the term user as any individual or business, as opposed to using the separate definitions of business users and consumers in the P2B proposal. Apart from this, the definition of multi-sided digital interface will be aligned with the definition of online intermediation services, both of which target the intermediaries' role in facilitating direct transactions between their users.
|
B2B, B2C, C2C/P2P online platforms
for the purposes of levying the digital services tax (DST)
|
All online platforms below this turnover threshold:
> EUR 750 million global revenues; and
> EUR 50 million EU taxable revenues
|
DRAFT PROPOSAL Art. 2(19) of Directive 2011/83/EU (Consumer Rights Directive -revised CRD)
|
'Online market place' means a service provider, as defined in point (b) of Article 2 of Directive 2000/31/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 8 June 2000 on certain legal aspects of information society services, in particular electronic commerce, in the Internal Market (‘Directive on electronic commerce’), which allows consumers to conclude distance contracts on the online marketplace’s online interface
This definition identifies one specific type of online intermediation services for the purpose of tackling the targeted issue of private providers in the collaborative economy not identifying themselves as such vis-a-vis buyers – resulting in the latter not being aware that the CRD protections do not apply. This notwithstanding the conclusion of a contract on the platform's interface, which can give the impression that a contract is in fact concluded with a trader (i.e. the platform). The obligation that the revised CRD will impose on online market places by means of this definition is accordingly strictly meant to protect consumers, not businesses. The P2B proposal at the same time explicitly sets out that online market places are one type of online intermediation services, with the latter definition clearly going beyond for a different purpose (to protect businesses). The concurrent application of online market places and online intermediation services therefore will not involve any potential conflict.
|
Goes beyond "intermediation" as any service providers' website could be covered
All B2C and C2C/P2P online platforms as well as any website used to offer services (i.e. app stores, e-commerce market places, OTAs, webshops, to the extent they allow online contract conclusion)
|
B2B online platforms
|
Annex 1.14 further substantiates the appropriateness of the scoping definition. The Impact Assessment covers services offered by online platforms whose business model is to intermediate or facilitate transactions between consumers and business users (so called "multi-sided" platforms and where a (P2B) contractual relationship exists between the platform operator and the business user. The Impact Assessment analyses services offered by online e-commerce marketplaces, app stores, business pages on social media, ride hailing, online travel, hospitality, food delivery and product comparison platforms.
The Impact Assessment thus covers on the one hand intermediation services that enable a direct commercial transaction between a customer and a business user to be concluded online, on the market place. Examples of such services covered by the analysis are e.g. Amazon Marketplace, App Store, Google Play, Zalando, Booking.com, Expedia, Deliveroo, Etsy, etc.
The Impact Assessment covers, on the other hand, services that are designed to increase business users' visibility and ultimately facilitate transactions between them and consumers and where the business user enters into a contractual relationship with the platform. Examples of such services include: Facebook (business pages), Google My Business, Immoweb, Autoscout, la Fourchette (restaurant booking), price comparison websites (to the extent that business users present on those websites have a contract with the platform), etc.
More in detail, the initiative would cover the following online platforms:
1) Marketplaces on which a commercial transaction between a customer and a business user takes place
Characteristics: The transaction and payment takes place on the platform.
Common business model: The platform charges a commission.
Services therefore included:
vE-commerce market places (Amazon market place, eBay, Etsy, Zalando, Fnac MarketPlace, Opodo, Chrono24 Trusted Checkout, Booking.com, Expedia, Hostelworld, Tripadvisor Instant Booking, Skyscanner Direct Booking, Uber, Airbnb, Deliveroo, Uber Eats, Upwork, Idealo.de, Kindle Direct Publishing, Vimeo (can rent movies), Xbox self-publishing games, Facebook – direct buy function integrated in profiles & Messenger)
vApp stores (Google Play, Opera Mobile Store, Samsung Smart TV, LG Smart World, Sony Playstation, Oculus Gear VR, Alexa Skills)
2) Online platforms bringing together users with the aim to "facilitate" a commercial transaction (which does not necessarily take place on the platform itself)
Characteristics and business models:
·The business user has a contractual relationship with the platform.
·The consumer joins the platform for a variety of reasons, sometimes pro-actively looking for a possibility to choose between a variety of offers (e.g. houses to buy or rent).
·The transaction itself does not usually take place on the platform itself. The consumer may contact the business user directly, often through the platform (e.g. make a call, schedule a visit, etc). The actual payment can take place outside of the platform.
·The business user may be charged by the platform in different ways, such as:
oListing fees (the level of which may depend on level of service provided – e.g. additional promotion, improved content, better visibility)
oCharges per click
oCommissions
Services therefore included (in addition to 1): Facebook (pages, marketplace), Google My Business, Instagram (profiles used by artists, makers), Olx classifieds, Ebay classified ads, Immoweb, Funda, Autoscout, Instagram ('shop now' button), la Fourchette (restaurant booking), SoundCloud (can purchase tracks), price comparison websites (to the extent that business users present on those websites have a contract with the platform).
Examples of services/platforms that are not covered by the above definition of online platforms:
·Peer-to-peer platforms, i.e. without the presence of "business users" (e.g. WhatsApp, Skype, Facebook messenger, BlaBlaCar, CouchSurfing)
·Activities where business users don't have a contractual relationship with the online platform (such as Facebook profile, Google Search, Twitter, SnapChat).
oWhy is Google Search excluded from the above online platform definition (cf. Section 4.1.3 below)?
While consumers/users of search arguably have a contractual relationship with the platform (by clicking search they enter into a contract), the business users do not have a contractual relationship with the platform: Their websites are crawled, indexed, tagged without the knowledge or active participation of the business. The business model of search engines is to provide information to users and monetize it by showing them advertising. As such, search engines do not "intermediate transactions".
·Non-platform businesses (i.e. without the element of intermediation): Amazon retail, Zalando retail, Spotify, Netflix, Expedia business of purchasing bulk from hotels and reselling on own platform, cloud services.
·Pure B2B platforms (which cannot be accessed by consumers). Examples: SAP hotel booking, Salesforce AppExchange, Microsoft Azure Market Place, GE Predix, Amadues/Sabre's Global Distribution Systems, Siemens AI platform, advertising exchanges (connecting publishing companies and advertising agencies)
oWhy are B2B platforms excluded?
In the B2B context the clients tend to be big, sophisticated companies which are not easily swayed by the platforms choice of ranking. If products or services are delisted, corporate clients can insist that they be reinstated. Corporate clients have more leverage over platform decisions.
·Advertising activities. Advertisers pay for a service that allows them to reach a specific target audience that they can define, usually by means of a tailor-made advertising campaign rather than a direct digital presence on the platform itself. Consumers cannot choose which ads they will see. Ads do not always lead directly to a transaction. The technical tools used to host and serve the advertisement, which include ad serving tools and ad exchanges, are also not visible to the consumer. Examples are Google Doubleclick, Adjug, AOL, Bing Ads.
·Payment platforms (which cannot be used to initiate transactions, or to find products and services). Payment intermediaries fulfil a supplementary service supporting transactions. Like postal companies, payment intermediaries provide a service helping the parties complete the transaction. Once the consumer has already chosen the product or service and agreed on the price they use online payment services to send the money to the seller. Examples are: Apple Pay, PayPal, Klarna, Amazon Pay, Adyen, etc.
·Search engine optimisation software, which is one-sided service provided to businesses, not being visible to consumers.
·Ad-blocking software, as there is no intermediation of transactions. Although advertisers can in some cases pay for being whitelisted, the ad-blocking software does not itself enable transactions or even the actual serving of advertisements.
·Technology platforms connecting hardware and applications. There is no direct contact with both business user and consumer, and these are not directly connected with the provision of goods or services. Examples are: Android, Windows, Linux, Unix, iOS operating systems.
Online payment intermediaries are not online platforms where consumers choose from a variety of offers to conclude a transaction and where B2C transactions are initiated. Payment intermediaries fulfil a supplementary service supporting transactions. Like postal companies, payment intermediaries provide a service helping the parties complete the transaction. Once the consumer has already chosen the product or service and agreed on the price they use online payment services to send the money to the seller.
Online general search engines pro-actively index websites outside any contractual relationship with website operators for the purpose of returning the most salient results to users' search queries. These services are already defined in Directive (EU) 2016/1148 as digital services that allow users to perform searches of "all websites".
Issues relating to the ranking of business users in search services can be exacerbated by a lack of clarity and predictability around the functioning of ranking in online general search engines, as these services are an important source of Internet traffic to business users' presence on online platforms. For example, business pages of restaurants on social media, the online presence of hotels on OTAs as well as mobile software applications available in mobile app stores are all indexed by online general search engines. Online general search engines moreover are often the source of the significant majority of Internet traffic for smaller standalone websites, including those operated by business users outside their presence on other online platforms (e.g. hotels' own websites, or retailers' own webshops). One policy option identified in this Impact Assessment report is therefore to strengthen the effectiveness of the proposed legal transparency obligation on ranking by extending exclusively this provision to the separate category of digital service that are online general search engines.
A comprehensive explanation of the scoping approach is also available in Annex 1.6. Annex 4.1 provides more explanations as to who is affected by the initiative.
2Problem Definition
The core problem addressed in this Impact Assessment is that European businesses – online platforms as well as their business users – cannot fully exploit the potential of the online platform economy. For business users, this is due to a number of potentially harmful trading practices and a lack of effective redress mechanisms in the EU to tackle those unilateral trading practices. For online platforms, the underexploited potential is due to the risks they face in scaling-up and operating across the single market due to a potential loss of business users' trust as well as an emerging fragmentation of the single market. As regards the latter, the national platform-measures that have been adopted so far imply a real longer-term risk for the online platform economy as its single market-potential would be undermined by legal regimes that differ between Member States along a potentially long list of parameters (e.g. type of online platforms covered, type of trading practices covered, the use of exemptions, etc.). A key driver of this risk of fragmentation is the general pressure on national legislators and authorities to regulate the novel online platform-business models, which is fuelled partly by the very problems that this initiative aims to directly address: dependent businesses being subject to a range of potentially harmful trading practices in regard of which existing national legislation does not provide effective redress.
The above problem can cause significant harm as it limits sales for EU businesses through online platforms, which has a negative impact especially on the cross-border sales of non-platform businesses, and thus limits consumer choice and the innovation capacity of EU businesses.
Any quantitative estimates of these problems are likely to be conservative, as evidence shows a significant underreporting of issues by business users due to a fear of retaliation. This problem has a strong EU dimension, as online platforms connect buyers and sellers across national boundaries, and therefore enable e-Commerce inside the Digital Single Market.
Figure 1: Overview of the problem analysis
The drivers of the problem can be traced to the core characteristics of multi-sided online platforms intermediating transactions between business users and consumers. A relatively small number of online platforms increasingly provide the main connection between business users and consumers in each sector, which results in an increased dependency of businesses on these online platforms. Strong, data-driven network effects reinforce this dependency and together, these effects lead to an imbalance in bargaining power.
This dependency situation allows for a number of potentially harmful trading practices on the part of online platforms which limit business users' sales through online platforms and undermine their trust. These practices are not associated with any structural changes in the supplying industries. Practices identified and detailed in this IA are: sudden, unexplained changes in terms and conditions without prior notice; the delisting of products and services and the suspension of accounts without clear statement of reasons; issues related to ranking (including paid-for ranking) of businesses and products; unclear conditions for access to, and use of data collected by platforms; the discrimination of businesses and favouring of platforms' own competing services, and most-favoured nation clauses. The current regulatory framework may not be effective in preventing some of these practices, or in providing redress.
At the same time, the emerging regulatory fragmentation in the EU complicates the regulatory environment for online platforms and constitutes a significant risk for the EU platform economy. Compared to other Single Market areas, the platform economy possesses an intrinsically cross-border nature (and, in many cases indeed, global). The highly targeted but diverging national platform-specific legislations which start appearing therefore, establish a real risk of re-fragmentation of the single market.
The number of enterprises affected varies depending on the sector, but can be estimated to reach today at least 1 million merchants in the EU, combining sectors such as online retail, hotels and restaurant businesses, app stores, etc. The unrealised potential of the platform economy (in terms of reduced turnover due to sales not realised by business users) due to the unfair practices at stake, can be estimated to amount to between € 3.97 to € 15.85 billion per year and indirectly implies a loss of commissions for online platforms of between € 0.4 and € 1.6 billion. (see Section 2.3.2).
The market dynamics are unlikely to change significantly as the number of businesses who would like to use online platforms to reach markets and consumers is expected to grow much faster than the number of online platforms that provide intermediation services. As a result, the dependency and unequal bargaining power will only deepen. As a consequence, the market itself is unlikely to resolve the potentially harmful trading practices and the absence of effective redress mentioned above due to a misalignment of interests (explained in section 2.2). Absent EU action to address P2B issues, regulatory interventions at national level can be expected to increase in the near future. This would lead to an artificial fragmentation of the single market in the naturally EU cross-border P2B space. The resulting market re-fragmentation would prevent platforms from scaling up, thus undermining the potential of the platform economy. Online platforms are important drivers for innovation and digital transformation. A healthy platform economy, with confident business users and growing online platforms, is hence key for digital growth.
2.1Problems
This section focuses on the three closely interlinked problems observed: potentially harmful trading practices, a lack of redress available in relation to these practices and an emerging re-fragmentation of the single market.
Potentially harmful trading practices
A study for the European Commission found that nearly half (46%) of business users experience problems with online platforms in the course of their business relationship, with varying impacts. Such problems include potentially harmful trading practices, the main categories of which are set out in the following sections. Of those users that did experience problems, 21% said that these problems occurred often. Heavy users of online platforms, that is to say those that generate over half their turnover via online platforms, are far more likely to experience problems (75%) and more frequently (33% report experiencing problems often).
Evidence from the same surveys also indicates that potentially harmful unilateral trading practices are not limited to the very largest online platforms, or to specific sectors. Respondents to the survey asking to identify online platforms that generated the most issues identified a broad range of online platforms covering different sizes and sectors. Numerous different actors were indeed identified in this way within each of the categories of online platforms, ranging from app stores to marketplaces to online travel agents and social media. Other study results in addition show that in the vast majority of cases business users cannot negotiate contracts, supporting the finding of relative market strength. It is noted in this regard that relatively small online platforms (including in the bracket between micro- and small enterprises, as identified in the Commission's SME definition) can indeed provide access for business users to very large consumer groups, and the example of Instagram that managed a base of 30 million users with 13 employees is one of many examples that supports the above finding that not only the very largest online platforms can exhibit an imbalance in bargaining power that enables potentially harmful unilateral trading practices to occur. Further clarifications on the evidence base are provided in Annex 1.7.
2.1.1.1Sudden unexplained changes in terms and conditions unilaterally imposed by platforms without prior notice
Online platforms tend to use standard terms and conditions, which business users generally do not have a chance to negotiate. One out of five business users surveyed consider terms and conditions inherently unfair, and for 72% of this 20% gave the main reason for unfairness as the impossibility to negotiate contractual clauses. Online platforms' terms and conditions can also be characterised by a general lack of clarity, even for legal experts. Online platforms argue that, given the large number of individual business users, it is not feasible to negotiate clauses with each user. The fact-finding supporting this Impact Assessment also showed that business users are exposed to sudden, unilateral changes of terms and conditions. Almost 50% of the terms and conditions investigated even grant online platform operators an explicit right to unilaterally change the terms and conditions. In addition, the content of changes is not always made clear to business users.
Whilst regular changes to terms and conditions are necessary to adapt to changes in the business environment and to legislation, the problem of sudden, unexplained changes can be substantial for the weaker party. 19% of the businesses reported problems related to sudden changes in terms and conditions. Business users argue that frequently they do not have enough time to make the necessary adaptations to their business operations when substantial features of the service are changed. Examples include changes to return and exchange policies of e-commerce platforms communicated through hyperlinks in routine emails to the business users, or announcements of increases in the price of apps by up to 25% to reflect currency fluctuation.
Some companies reported losses in turnover caused by such practices varying between 20% and 95%.
2.1.1.2Delisting of products, services or businesses or suspension of accounts without clear statement of reasons
Businesses using online platforms are often reliant on traffic from these online platforms for sales, and the delisting of certain products or services or the overall suspension of their account has a strong impact on their business. While delisting and/or suspension can be justified by a variety of legitimate reasons, including the take-down of illegal or harmful content, or as a consequence of other non-compliance with the terms of service, few, if at all, safeguards are in place for arbitrary delisting or suspension of accounts on online platforms. In particular, business users pointed to a frequent absence of a clear statement of reasons when delisting suspension occurs. Consequently, they have few levers to remedy the situation leading to the sanction, or to seek redress and challenge the delisting or suspension.
Respondents to the survey who reported having had issues linked these to the suspension of their account (11%), and to other access conditions to the online platform including instances of delisting (15%). Such practices were registered most often in the e-commerce and app store environments.
2.1.1.3Issues related to ranking of business users or their offers
There is a lack of meaningful accountability and predictability for the business user with regards to ranking systems used by online platforms. In the study, 12% of the respondents having encountered problems in their business relationship with the online platform (and 15% of the 'heavy users') claimed these were due to biases in the search related practices. According to the study results, such issues occur most frequently in the e-commerce and hospitality sectors.
Business users are heavily impacted by their position on the online platforms' page. The ranking of a product or service in search results on the online platform has an important impact on consumer choice and, consequently, on the businesses' revenues.
In some of the biggest EU Member States, online platforms (as defined in this Impact Assessment) already account for a share of over 40% of total desktop Internet traffic in the e-commerce and hospitality sectors (see section 7.2.5. of the Annexes to this report). The largest part of this share (70%-80%) is accounted for by direct Internet traffic and therefore does not rely on referrals by online general search engines. These figures underline the crucial market gateway that online platforms represent for business users.
Notwithstanding, online general search engines continue to be important as an indirect source of Internet traffic for business users on platforms. For example, business pages of restaurants on social media, the online presence of hotels on OTAs as well as mobile software applications available in mobile app stores are all equally indexed by online general search engines.
Online general search engines in addition originate the vast majority of Internet traffic for smaller, standalone websites. This applies equally to websites run by business users of online platforms outside those platforms. In the e-commerce and hospitality sectors, Internet traffic in the eight largest EU Member States generated by online general search engines accounted for, respectively, >50% and >70% of total desktop Internet traffic received by these websites (which percentages constitute multiples of the share that search traffic accounts for in respect of the 100 most well-known websites in these Member States). A recent Eurobarometer survey on the use of online platforms also found that nearly nine in ten Internet users in the EU use search engines websites at least once a week.
At the same time, 66% of EU SMEs also explain that their position in search results of general search engines and online platforms has a significant impact on their sales.
Studies also show a significant and positive relationship between the first position of a product in a ranking and the choice of consumers. Conversely, there is a negative effect of low ranking. The top five search results attract 88% of the clicks
, while it is very rare – a chance of 1.11% or less – for a user to click anywhere beyond the 10th site in a search result
. It should also be noted that online general search engines continue to be the most common starting point for online research both on desktop as well as on mobile devices,
and therefore continue to be important for business users of online platforms as well as for standalone websites, which may be part of one and the same company.
Online platforms and online general search engines are distinct types of online services, with the latter indexing websites without necessarily entering into contractual relations with the website users. Online search engines also generate revenue from advertising rather than from intermediating B2C transactions and they necessarily have to index the entire Internet in order to provide a quality service (i.e. there is no room for specialisation in general search). At the same time, online visibility for small businesses is dependent both on online platforms as well as on online general search engines. There are, at the same time, no indications that the concurrent importance of online platforms and online general search engines will change significantly in light of foreseen technological developments.
Online platforms as well as online general search engines explain that ranking algorithms are increasingly complex and are oftentimes at the core of the service innovation proposed to consumers: the better the user experience, the more successful the online platform or online general search engine and, consequently, the benefits also for the business user.
Some online platforms offer instructions and support to their business users for optimising their ranking (See Annex 7.3), including information on how to encode meta-data for the services and products listed, or parameters on e.g. sales and user reviews which would help rank higher. Other online platforms, however, are opaque and vague in their terms and conditions and businesses reported unclear criteria, including special programmes offered to some business users, fast-changing parameters in the ranking of offers, and fear of arbitrary dimming of ranking by the online platform. Uncertainty about the main search parameters, including the risk of demotions, can add to the lack of predictability that both business users of online platforms as well as websites face when trading online. This behaviour has indeed entirely undermined the effect of voluntary efforts to reassure business users. As regards the other ("searcher") side of the online general search market, a recent Eurobarometer survey moreover found that 19% of Internet users in the EU do not trust that the search results provided to them are the most relevant to their query.
In addition, rankings of business users and their offers can be influenced by (additional) payments by the business users whose products and services are made more visible in the rankings (paid-for ranking). The increase in visibility afforded by paid-for ranking can be achieved via direct payment for advertising (business pages can for example "boost" their visibility on social media), or sometimes through an increase in the commission paid per transaction (as commonly seen in the hospitality sector). Business users have argued that it is often unclear to what extent the increased commission leads to a higher ranking or frequency of display of higher ranking in consumers' searches. As such, they pay without being certain to what extent the service is delivered to them.
As far as transparency of paid-for results towards consumers is concerned, under the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive (UCPD)
, online platforms as well as online general search engines are required to distinguish paid-for results from "organic" search results. However, while informative to the consumer, the distinction between paid-for and organic search results is not sufficient to reassure business users of fair delivery of the improved paid-for ranking service across the different consumer segments and in comparison to other competing businesses.
On the other hand, wide ranging disclosure of ranking algorithms is generally accompanied by attempts to manipulate rankings ('gaming'), as business users are incentivised to gain a higher ranking without necessarily improving the quality of the product or service.
2.1.1.4 Issues related to data access and use
Further data sharing and use across the value chain is a first condition for maximising the value of data. At the same time, economic theory is not conclusive as to the role of data in network effects around online platforms or the impacts of data flows across the value chain. Online platforms aggregate large amounts of personal and non-personal data, both at the very core of the online platforms' business model, and the online platforms' ability to build and maintain a user base on both sides of the market depends to a large extent on the collection and retention of data.
Preliminary results of the study on data in P2B relations show that business users do not have consistent views as to their level of satisfaction with the data access policies of the online platforms they use. Some argue that they lack access to specific types of information regarding their customers, while others acknowledge that they can access a large variety of data, but that they lack the resources or skills to exploit it. The variety of data types businesses can access is not consistent across online platforms. In some cases, this is a matter of competing offers between online platforms providing similar services: e.g. market analysis either as part of the service to business users or against a fee. In addition, third parties also frequently aim at providing their data-related services to business users active on online platforms.
Limited access to data and limited skills to procure, analyse and exploit data-driven market insights have a negative effect on businesses' ability to grow. At the same time, developing data sharing policies, legal provisions and facilitating technically access to data is costly on the online platforms' side, in addition to potentially affecting, in some cases, the relevance of the intermediation business model of the online platform.
Preliminary results of a study on data access commissioned by the European Commission also identified a specific issue for business users mainly active in the hospitality and e-commerce sectors. The vast majority of online platforms do not give business users the opportunity to ask for customers' consent to obtain and process his or her certain personal data, in particular e-mail addresses, even after the completion of a transaction and the payment of the commission to the respective online platform. In the Flash Eurobarometer 439 42% of the respondents said that they usually do not get the data they need about their customers from online marketplaces. The business users claim that not having this possibility increases their dependency on the online platform as a gateway to consumers and prevents them from scaling-up by, inter alia, building an independent customer base, improving their direct marketing or independent online presence as well as offering customer-tailored services. Online platforms responded that they offer ways of contacting customers, in some cases including marketing against a fee, for business users via their platform systems. Their business model is typically built on commission per transaction intermediated by the online platform and both consumers and business users are naturally incentivised to avoid concluding transactions on the platform and preventing direct contact between customer and business users helps to avoid 'free-riding' behaviour. Some online platforms also indicated that they are required to shield customers from direct contact with business users to comply with EU data protection rules.
Beyond claims to access specific types of data, there is a lack of clarity as to the conditions for access and use of data, both regarding online platforms' collection and use of businesses' and transaction data, and the conditions for business users to use data collected from the online platform. 25% of non-heavy users and 33% of the heavy users of online platforms responding to a Study said the problems they have encountered were caused by the lack of transparency of online platforms' policies and practices on data and content. Further research into the online platforms terms and conditions shows that online platforms frequently include general, and often unclear clauses restricting to a certain extent the use of particular types of data by the business user outside of the environment of the platform. The clauses are generally rooted in the protection of the online platforms' trade secrets, databases or to impede the use of data collected from the platform's environment to compete against the online platform's intermediation business model.
2.1.1.5Discrimination of businesses and favouring of online platform's own competing services
Online platforms sometimes play a dual role, for example by both providing the online market place and selling their products and services on their own market place. When such online platforms apply differentiated treatment to their own products or services such treatment is generally not made transparent to their business users. The favouring of own products or services by online platforms was identified as one of three most commonly experienced problematic trading practices by business respondents to the public consultation on platforms.
Favouring of own products or some business users takes place e.g. through more favourable ranking, use of transaction data to learn from downstream competitors and improve online platforms' own competing service, or by charging additional fees to third party business users but not to online platforms' own services.
The "bundling" of auxiliary services like advertising or payment to the online platforms' intermediation service was also reported in this context, as the choice for a business user to use such auxiliary services would effectively be limited to the relevant online platforms' own solutions. 11% of business users surveyed in a study for example linked the problems they experienced to limitations placed on payment possibilities. Some app developers reported adapting to the online platforms' commission on auxiliary payment services by applying a net price increase of 30%. A third of a sample of online platforms used terms and conditions that were not transparent as to the pricing of the main online platform (intermediation) service and auxiliary services.
2.1.1.6Most-favoured nation (MFN) clauses
Issues have also arisen in the context of so-called 'most-favoured nation' ('MFN') clauses, also known as 'parity' or 'price-parity' clauses. These are common in Online Travel Agents ('OTAs'), but also exist to a more limited extent on e-commerce platforms, app stores or price comparison tools. MFN clauses require the supplier to offer a product or service on an online platform at the lowest price and/or on the best terms offered either through its own distribution channel(s) ('narrow' MFN clauses) or on all sales channels ('wide' MFN clauses).
The ongoing monitoring by competition authorities regarding MFN clauses in the hospitality sector constitutes an important element of the baseline scenario in this Impact Assessment. While the economic literature suggests that MFN clauses can create efficiencies in particular market contexts, certain MFN clauses used specifically by OTAs have been investigated by several national competition authorities. The German competition authority prohibited HRS' and Booking.com's MFN clauses in 2013 and 2015 respectively. In close coordination with the Commission, the French, Swedish and Italian authorities accepted Booking.com's commitment to reduce its wide MFN clauses to narrow clauses EU wide, thereby accepting the use of such clauses in the future. Following the decisions, a group of 10 national competition authorities and the Commission decided to carry out a monitoring exercise to assess their effects. The enforcement measures resulted in increased room price and room availability differentiation on OTAs, but there is no clear evidence that they have led to lower commission rates charged by OTAs. The heads of the European Competition Network (ECN) therefore agreed to keep the online hotel booking sector under review, to re-assess the competitive situation in due time and to coordinate new enforcement actions or market investigations within the ECN. Competition law can therefore provide, in certain instances, the possibility to redress and correct some of the identified problems regarding MFNs on a case-by-case basis.
MFN clauses in the online hotel booking sector are also regulated by several national laws. The French 'Loi pour la croissance, l'activité et l'égalité des chances économiques' (Loi Macron) adopted on 5 August 2015 foresees that hotels remain free to grant any rebate or pricing advantage of any kind to customers through their direct sales channels. A new Austrian law amending the Austrian Federal Act against Unfair Competition and the Austrian Price Marking Act and an Italian law, which entered into force respectively on 1 January 2017 and on 29 August 2017, also prohibit any MFN clauses in agreements between OTAs and hotel operators (i.e. wide and narrow MFN clauses, and regardless of the size of the OTA). A draft law containing a similar per se ban of MFN clauses imposed by OTAs has recently been proposed by the Belgian government and has been notified on 4 December 2017 to the Commission under Directive 2015/1535/EU, which establishes a transparency procedure for rules applying to information society services.
Lack of effective redress
When business users attempt to solve the potentially harmful trading practices described above, they are often unable to find a solution. According to a study carried out for the European Commission, almost a third (32%) of all problems in P2B relations remains unsolved and a further 29% can only be resolved with difficulties. As regards online general search engines, a recent survey found that 32% of EU businesses selling online disagreed that a reliable dispute resolution system is available to solve disputes with the operator of online general search engines. Reasons for business users not to take any steps at all notably include the perceived ineffective nature of existing redress mechanisms, a fear of damaging the business relationship with the online platform and the difficulty of available procedures.
The dependency-induced fear of retaliation of business users (Section 2.2.5) indeed limits the effectiveness of any existing type of redress, whether judicial or out-of-court. In addition, online platforms generally use exclusive choice of law and forum clauses. In the inherently cross-border digital economy, the widespread use of such clauses significantly raises the existing barrier to access justice, as any national court seised by a business user will first need to settle the complex question of whether it is competent to deal with the case at hand regardless of the applicable law and competent forum determined by contract. Existing national B2B fairness legislation, which can in theory be relied upon by businesses in certain Member States to seek relief against alleged potentially harmful behaviour, is therefore significantly impaired in terms of its use in the online platform economy.
Other important factors that limit the effectiveness of judicial redress are linked to (1) lack of knowledge of judicial redress possibilities due to the small size of the companies, (2) disproportionate costs of seeking international judicial redress, especially for the micro-enterprises and/or where jurisdictional redress would involve the jurisdiction of a third country, and (3) judicial redress being too lengthy.
Study results in this regard show that only 4% of business users of online platforms that took action when faced with a problem went to court in the EU, and this formed the only exception of an external redress mechanism used by these business users where even the majority of issues (55%) could not be resolved (45%) or only with difficulties (10%).
Participants in a Commission workshop also indicated that online platforms currently either do not offer internal redress mechanisms, or that such mechanisms are ineffective, in particular for claims where the business user's interest opposes that of the platform. External procedures are found to be ineffective for different reasons, including a fear of retaliation on the side of business users, high costs and the length of procedures. Similarly, some retailers that participated in the Commission's e-commerce sector inquiry stress the importance of the transparency of the notice and take down process on e-commerce market places, and consider that the possibilities of retailers to defend their interest and request review of the decision taken by the marketplace are not sufficient.
Existing and emerging regulatory fragmentation of the Digital Single Market
The existing legal framework at both EU and Member State-level does not effectively address the problems identified in this Impact Assessment.
General B2B fairness rules exist in some Member States, but they are not geared towards the platform-specific problems identified above.
Similarly, existing initiatives targeting harmful trading practices in the offline world are designed to tackle practices relevant to the sector or context in which they arise. For example, the Supply Chain Initiative aims at increasing fairness in commercial relations along the food supply chain. A set of principles on good practices in vertical relationships in the food supply chain were devised by industry voluntarily in November 2011. The Commission is considering further action to improve the position of farmers in the food supply chain, in light of the outcome of the work of the Agricultural markets Task Force and the High Level Forum for a Better Functioning Food Supply Chain. This is framed around addressing problems such as fairer payment periods for suppliers, prohibitions on the last minute cancellation of perishable goods, requirements for contributions to promotional or marketing costs, claims for wasted or unsold products and requests for upfront payments to secure or retain contracts. None of these overlap with the platform-specific problems identified above.
Creating a single rule to address potentially harmful practices in the online and offline world would not address the specificities and the problems businesses face in the sector they operate in. It also does not recognise the differences in the business models. This may be because of the very different business models and the fact behaviour may not be seen both offline and online (for example, algorithms play no part in the placement of a product on a supermarket shelf). In fact, a single rule could extend a solution beyond what is necessary to address the problems identified.
At the same time, a number of Member States (Austria, France, Italy, Germany and Belgium) have already adopted, or are considering adopting, online platform-specific legislation.
·As explained in Section 2.1.1.6 above, France, Austria and Italy have adopted laws prohibiting MFN clauses imposed by OTAs on their business users. Belgium in addition notified a draft law to the Commission on 4 December 2017, which contains a similar MFN-ban. These laws constitute per se prohibitions (i.e. regardless of the market size of these firms) of the use of MFN clauses, without distinguishing between sales channels (OTAs, hotels' websites or offline), by one specific category of online platform (i.e. OTAs) in their relations with business users. This approach contrasts with the competition-law based commitment-approach focusing only on wide parity clauses that was taken by a group of Member States. These national laws banning the use of MFNs by OTAs also differ in their respective design. The French law in this regard contains an additional requirement, as compared to the Austrian and Italian laws, requiring the contract between hotels and OTAs to determine a fixed room price. Online platforms have indicated that such a requirement forces their cross-border operations to be segmented along, in this case, the French borders, which they moreover consider virtually impossible to comply with.
·In 2016, France adopted Law N. 1321, which defines online platforms and requires these firms to provide further transparency towards consumers on e.g. terms and conditions, certain mandatory pre-contractual information or on the way in which goods, content or services are ranked and whether there are any contractual or financial relationships influencing this.
·The Italian Parliament has considered two proposals that aim to regulate some platform-relevant aspects. Proposal N.2520 aims to abolish certain restrictions imposed by platforms, specifically app stores, impeding mobile device users' freedom and ability to access or remove apps as well as to switch services. This obligation could imply significant cost for both app stores as well as their business users (independent app developers), as the same content may have to be made available across different platforms and corresponding operating systems (source code). Moreover, it could affect competition between online platforms also to the detriment of their business users, as it would no longer be possible to distinguish on the basis of richness or quality of content. Proposal N. 3564 has as its main objective to ensure fairness and transparency regarding security, health, taxation in the collaborative economy. Platforms intermediating connections between consumers and business users are expressly excluded from the Proposal, because the focus is solely on relationships between consumers, but it is not clear is self-employed business users would be unequivocally out of scope.
·The German government issued a White Paper on Digital Platforms which envisages the creation of a 'Digital Agency' to safeguard effective and systematic market control of digital platforms and proposes a comprehensive framework for the use of data and to introduce basic transparency and information duties for digital platforms.
None of the above already enacted or envisaged national platform-measures comprehensively cover the set of potentially harmful trading practices identified above, and they in any event suffer from the difficulty to be enforced (especially through private litigation) in the inherently cross-border platform economy. They do not therefore provide effective redress for business users of online platforms against potentially harmful trading practices. Certain types of specific business users (e.g. hotels) may nonetheless, depending on their Member State of establishment, benefit from a higher perceived level of legal protection on targeted issues, which can lead to an uneven playing field in online intermediated trade – even within one and the same Member State. Moreover, some of these Member State measures may raise issues of compatibility with EU law. At the same time, these national platform-measures imply a real longer-term risk for the online platform economy as its single market-potential would be undermined by legal regimes that differ between Member States along a potentially long list of parameters (e.g. type of online platforms covered, type of trading practices covered, the use of exemptions, etc.). A key driver of this risk of fragmentation is the general pressure on national legislators and authorities to regulate the novel online platform-business models, which is fuelled partly by the very problems that this initiative aims to directly address: dependent businesses being subject to a range of potentially harmful trading practices in regard of which existing national legislation does not provide effective redress.
2.2Drivers
This Section outlines the market dynamics and the drivers of the problem. A detailed analysis of the market structure is presented in Annex 7.2. Annex 1.8 gives an overview of drivers.
Online platforms intermediate an increasing number of transactions and are increasingly the main vehicle for market access
The European e-commerce market has been growing at a dynamic pace. In 2016, two thirds of internet users made online purchases, while the value of the market was estimated at over € 500 billion
, which is a 13% increase in comparison to 2015.
This growing digital trade is increasingly intermediated by online platforms. The retail value generated by EU third party sellers on platforms represented 22% of total online retail sales in 2016, and in countries such as Germany over 37% of total internet sales were generated by third party sellers. Online platforms that host third party sellers are now leaders of internet retailing. The biggest marketplaces, such as Amazon, Alibaba's Tmall and eBay account for $365 billion in sales worldwide in 2016. Sales of online-only retailers in the EU more than doubled between 2011 and 2016, reaching €111 billion in 2016. Sales over platforms now account for over half of all online sales in retail. According to Euromonitor, the online retail value generated by third party sellers in the EU in 2016 was €54,566.5 million, representing 22% of total online retail. Other estimates suggest that around 60% of private consumption and 30% of public consumption of goods and services related to the total digital economy go via online intermediaries. Online marketplaces enable businesses to take advantage of the growing markets through existing infrastructure that is already trusted by consumers. For this reason, 71% of the consumers who participated in a survey on online platform transparency found online market places to be the preferred source to buy goods or services for private use. Online sales accounted for 9% of global retail sales in 2016 and that figure is expected to rise to 13% in 2021. However, the impact of online retailing is much stronger due to web-influenced cross-channel sales: more than half of total retail sales in Europe in 2020 (€957 billion out of €1 793 billion) is estimated to be influenced by e-commerce, up from €603 billion in 2015.
In 2016, online booking channels captured 49% of all travel bookings in Europe. The two biggest online travel agents have now over 60% of European "market share" of OTAs in Europe, although through a large number of important online platforms. Online travel agents are particularly important for small, independent hotels - one study shows that independent hotels make up 67% of total room supply in the EU and that 71% of their online bookings are made through online platforms.
App developers generally distribute their apps through app stores and some studies estimate the EU app industry to amount to €63 billion by 2018, while the global mobile apps revenue is estimated to increase from $69.7 billion in 2015 to $188.9 billion in 2020. The use of social media promote and drive traffic to the services and products offered by business users: 89% of business user respondents to the surveys in a study carried out for the European Commission use social media for business purposes. At a global level and in Europe, Facebook has a clear market lead in this category, claiming over 2 billion of active users through its various owned online platforms (in June 2017, out of 2.5 billion). Finally, the importance of online platforms can be further illustrated by the example of private motor insurance in the UK, where more than 50% of overall sales volumes during the period 2013-2015 is generated via online intermediaries.
The relevance of organic search as a source of traffic grows. In the case of (i) accommodation and hotels, one quarter of all traffic is generated by organic search results, (ii) online retail, 28.6% is generated by organic search results, while (iii) for government sites, 43% of all traffic comes from organic search.
The retail sector shows a high degree of dependency. For example in Germany, 43% of total Internet traffic related to eCommerce goes to the top 10 online platforms in this space. Notwithstanding, organic search still does constitute a major source of traffic, including for online platforms – in France, over 33% of total traffic of the top 10 online retail platforms is referred by organic search.
As of April 2017, Google is the leading search engine – it has 88.56% of worldwide desktop market share, with other search engines (such as Yahoo!, bing and Baidu) sharing the remaining part of the market
. In Europe, Google's market share was 92,5% and bing's 3.3% in May 2017.
At present, more than a million EU enterprises trade through online platforms in order to reach their customers. Online platforms have become central to the businesses using them: almost half (42%) of SME respondents to a recent Eurobarometer survey on online platforms use online marketplaces to sell their products and services. Online platforms have also become enablers for cross-border trade. Through the intermediation of online platforms, businesses can de facto reach consumers across the entire European Single Market, as well as in global markets. A recent survey among 49 081 SMEs active on Facebook showed that nearly half of exporting SMEs (45%) report that more than 75% of their international sales depend on online tools or platforms. Research, such as the comparative study on one e-commerce platform and overall international trade flows, shows a significant smaller effect of geographic distance on trade when online platforms intermediate transactions - up to 65% for the study quoted. These findings are supported by the conclusions of a public consultation, where all categories of stakeholders agreed in the public consultation that one of the most important benefits offered by platforms was the access they offer to new market and business opportunities.
Successful platforms enjoy unprecedented, strong network effects
Indirect network effects can be at the heart of the business model of online platforms: the increase in the number of users on one side of the platform (e.g. sellers, content creators, service providers) makes it more attractive to users on the other side (e.g. consumers, viewers) and the other way around. In the online world, these network effects are of an unprecedented magnitude, scale and speed. While the increase of cost to provide services to additional users on either side of a networked market grows increasingly slowly, the value of the network increases very rapidly with the number of additional users on either side. Platforms thus create their economic value by attracting and retaining users on both sides of the market, while the investment e.g. in infrastructure for supporting additional users is marginal: when a platform scales to millions of consumers, functions such as customer or business support are frequently automated in order to maintain low scaling costs.
Consequently, there is a tendency towards market concentration around a few big platforms ('market tipping'), where the biggest entry barrier for new competitors is attracting a sufficient number of users on each side of the market. This translates into having a small number of large platforms intermediating transactions (and access to consumers) for a large number of smaller business users, for each type of platform and sector.
Direct and indirect network effects also exist in the offline world. However, research shows significant differences of scale and greater asymmetries induced by network effects in the online world. In certain specific areas such as online publishing, detailed models have demonstrated in quantitative terms that online network effects far outstrip their offline counterparts. Data-driven advantages additionally reinforce the concentration and dependency, as explained in the next Section.
Platforms benefit from a data-driven competitive advantage
The virtuous circle of online platforms' growth can also be fuelled by data-driven indirect network effects. Successful platforms can have access to large quantities of fine-grained consumer and business user data, and develop state-of-the-art data and analytics infrastructures to draw intelligence and market strategies out of the insights they obtain. The more users a platform has on each side of the market, the larger the scale of the collected data. The more varied the services offered to a single customer (e.g. buying products, intermediating communication, social networks) the richer the data collected. The combination of scale and variety improves insights e.g. about user profiles and preferences, and may reinforce the 'winner-takes-most' dynamic.
Moreover, one of the key factors that allow platforms to attract users and encourage consumer loyalty is the convenience of use and quality of service: they improve recommendation engines, adjust the matching mechanisms to reflect individual consumer preferences and make it easier to find the right product. Platforms can also enable users to build their online reputation through rating and review systems. All of these features are built and improved through the use of high quality, variety and volumes of data. Consequently, the largest players on each market are also best placed to deliver the best user experience. This can create positive data-driven feedback loops leading to increased returns to scale, scope and network effects, thus accelerating platforms' development and creating a virtuous circle of growth
.
Imbalanced bargaining power and dependency of business users on online platforms
The market dynamics described here-above, i.e. a growing intermediation of transaction through online platforms, strong indirect network effects fuelled by data-driven advantages by the online platforms, can lead to an increased dependency of businesses on online platforms as quasi 'gatekeepers' to markets and consumers. While not an issue in itself, this exposes business users to potentially harmful trading practices described earlier in Section 2.1.1.
This tendency can be exacerbated by the imbalance of power in a business user – platform relationship. Indeed, a small number of medium-large platforms intermediate the biggest shares of transactions in several categories of B2C platforms. This asymmetry between the relative market strength of a small number of leading platforms – not necessarily dominant in the sense of competition law – is combined with a highly fragmented supply-side of many small business users, with the exception of those areas where the natural number of suppliers is limited (e.g. airline ticketing). The final report on the E-commerce Sector Inquiry of the Commission revealed that the overwhelming majority (89% for the EU as a whole) of businesses selling via online marketplaces generated each an annual turnover lower or equal to € 50 000 in 2014, irrespective of the Member State in which they were established. In December 2016, there were 724 000 active developers developing for Google Play, 494 000 for iOS App Store and 69 000 for the Amazon Appstore.
Similar trends are seen in the hotel industry, where some 200 000 hotels and 1.8 million cafés in Europe are selling their services on platforms. 92% of these establishments employ fewer than 10 people
, while around 60% of hotels have fewer than 25 rooms
.
Typically, smaller business users have no ability to organise themselves and negotiate better terms either individually or collectively with the online platform. They generally need to adhere to the terms and conditions pre-set by the platform.
In addition, a study by the JRC shows how the majority of business users multi-home within each platform-segment. The study explains that platforms have little incentive to focus their business strategy in attracting business users rather than customers. The economic literature characterises such dynamics as 'competitive bottlenecks'
, where platforms compete aggressively for the buyers, often subsidizing that side, and recoup the costs through higher prices, or lower quality of service on the seller side.
Given that business users appear to be commonly multi-homing, switching among platforms could theoretically appear as a solution for a business user experiencing problems with the platform on which he is present. However, this is not necessarily the case since business users engage in multi-homing to reach the maximum number of consumers who single-home (at least for a specific purpose) on different platforms. Switching between platforms could not allow business users to sell to an optimal number of consumers, thus negatively impacting their turnover and their ability to optimise network effects and scale-up possibilities. Multi-homing does not necessarily, therefore, diminish the importance of the platforms' gateway function and does not allow business users to be more independent vis-à-vis platforms – it rather appears a symptom of the bottleneck theory, as explained above.
Business users fear retaliation
Businesses fear commercial retaliation in the case of complaints against the platforms, amplified by the relative dependency and asymmetries. This leads to the impossibility of estimating with precision the scale of the harm, very likely significantly underreported. This underreported friction in platform-to-business relations is set to increase with growing online intermediated trade and may affect business users' in online platforms going forward.
For example, in the online hotel booking segment, a recent market investigation by 10 EU competition authorities and the Commission also found that hotels' fear of retaliation, which retaliation could for example take the form of a less favourable display or the loss of preferred partner status, was quoted by 33% of responding hotels as one of the reasons they maintained the same price between the two most important online travel agents. Other data sources indicate that in the context of online market places, 60% of sellers are fearful of being banned from online platforms.
2.3Consequences
If extrapolated to the 1 million EU businesses selling goods and services via online platforms, the findings of the study carried out for the European Commission and explained above would show that P2B issues tend to impact a large number of business users, e.g. 460,000 enterprises would encounter problems, 200,000 enterprises would consider terms and conditions unfair, and more than 50,000 would encounter issues related to search and ranking. In addition, almost one third of the issues encountered would remain unresolved.
Direct loss in sales through platforms
Nearly half (46%) of all businesses experienced problems with varying gravity and/or disagreements with online platforms, according to a study for the Commission. Amongst the causes listed by business users, several are regarded and analysed in this Impact Assessment as potentially harmful commercial practices. The study also surfaced evidence from business users illustrating the impact of these trading practices on sales through platforms. For example, sudden changes in terms and conditions without sufficient time to adapt led to significant reduction in sales ranging from 20% to 95%. Multiple business users flagged the danger of delisting and suspension for their business, indicating that the viability of the business would be at risk and reported loss of turnover of up to 10% for several weeks or months and, as reported in anecdotal evidence, having to lay-off up to 20 employees due to a suspension. It is assumed that the negative impacts of rankinglead to a loss in yearly turnover of between 1% and 2%, most of which is permanent due to the difficulty in redirecting sales to other channels. These assumptions have been applied to the total turnover in the different sectors considered, but exclude the issue of ranking in online general search engines for which insufficient evidence is available at present to allow a robust quantification of any systematic negative impacts.
On that basis, the reduction of sales through platforms for EU business users caused by the practices at stake can be estimated to amount to between € 1.27 and € 2.35 billion per year.
Further dampening effect through lack of trust
The dependency-induced fear of retaliation leads to an underreporting of actual problems, while individual potentially harmful trading practices have an important knock-on effect on the wider trust in online platforms. The subsequent uncertainty experienced by business users leads to an economic under-utilisation of the potential of the online platform economy as business users are reluctant to enter into or expand their business relationships with online platforms.
A recent industry survey showed that more than 60% of sellers on the biggest e-commerce marketplace fear being banned. Another industry survey also found that 25% of app developers view the app stores themselves as their greatest threat. Finally, a recent Eurobarometer survey found that 19% of Internet users in the EU do not trust that the search results provided to them are the most relevant to their query.
If the additional dampening effect of this uncertainty and fear can be assumed to lead to a further reduction of total sales by business users on marketplaces by a conservative 1-5%, an estimate of € 2.7 to € 13.5 billion of turnover not realized on online platforms can be arrived at.
Combined with the estimates of direct losses in section 2.3.1, these figures lead to a total estimated reduction in platform turnover by business users of € 3.97 to € 15.85 billion per year. Assuming that online platforms charge, on average, a 10% commission, online platforms would forego commissions of between € 0.4 and € 1.6 billion.
These figures are consistent with independent estimates by the JRC. The aggregated impact in the EU economy due to the uncertainty linked to opaque practices by online platforms is estimated by the JRC to be in the range of € 2 to € 19.5 billion per year.
Fewer EU cross-border sales
Online platforms are of great importance for businesses' cross-border sales. On average only 9% of retailers in the EU sell online cross-border today, while more than 50% of SMEs selling through online marketplaces sell cross-border. Online marketplaces thus facilitate cross-border sales in the Digital Single Market especially by the smallest retailers. They reduce trade costs for SMEs, in particular those related to differences between languages and regulatory frameworks, and at the same time provide them with a global presence and reach previously reserved to large (multinational) retailers. It is estimated that the 'distance effect' on trade flows (a measure of trade frictions) is 65% smaller on an e-commerce market place than for total trade due to the effect of the online marketplace in reducing information frictions associated with geographical distance. The importance of online intermediated trade for SMEs is well illustrated by the following example: where eBay created an online webpage integrated into the eBay platform for the small retailers in the small German towns of Diepholz and Mönchengladbach, the 79 retailers participating in these towns’ eBay platforms sold more than 87 500 items with a total value of more than € 3.2 million, and delivered to 84 countries in a year.
Since selling on online platforms reduces the costs of exporting and makes the seller's goods or services easier accessible to customers in other countries, when sellers are forced to divert sales away from online platforms to other channels the share of cross-border sales is likely to fall. Individual sellers are likely to find it difficult and expensive to replicate in-house the services (like product offer translation, multi-lingual customer support, international shipping, regulatory compliance) which the online platform can supply at a significantly lower price due to its scale. Similarly, if business users are reluctant to enter into or expand their business relationships with online platforms, they will most likely sell less cross-border. As a consequence, factors limiting the take-up of online platforms by third-party sellers also limit the growth of cross-border sales.
EU consumers have more limited choice
It is widely acknowledged that online platforms have recently dramatically contributed to increases in consumer access to goods and services, especially cross-border. Around 60% of private consumption and 30 per cent of public consumption of goods and services related to the total 'Internet economy' go via online platforms
. The value of goods and services purchased by private households and the public sector via online intermediaries was valued at € 270 billion in 2014, corresponding to 2.5 per cent of the total final consumption in the EU-28 countries
.
That means that if business users suffer a loss of sales through platforms or if they choose to limit their presence on platforms for reasons of fear or lack of trust, consumers would be more likely to be faced with reduced choice of competitive products/services as compared to a situation where business users would be able and prepared to reap the full potential of the platform economy. As described in the previous Sub-section, this applies especially to cross-border sales of smaller companies.
Innovation capacity for businesses may be undermined
Online platforms are major investors in innovative technologies such as artificial intelligence, internet of things and data analytics. At the same time, enterprises that depend on online platforms to reach customers are de-incentivised and sometimes stopped from innovating in areas that would compete directly with the intermediary's role – e.g. developing online market analysis and strategies based on consumer behaviour and preferences on which many of the platform innovations are based. While this may in certain cases spur innovation from the side of the businesses that use these platforms
, they are unlikely to be able to innovate enough to become independent, particularly as platforms invest heavily in innovation in order to cement their market power in their relevant markets.
The consequence is that the incentives to innovate for smaller companies shift to complementary areas to platforms, which does not – in itself – relieve the dependency and the exposure to some of the potentially harmful practices. At present no robust quantitative estimates for these innovation dynamics exist, but the acquisitions and partnerships of online platforms with major deep tech businesses point to an increasing differential in innovation capacity of the intermediaries. Where conditions for accessing and using data are unclear, this can have a chilling effect on business users' investment in developing their capability or in contracting third-party services for data-driven innovations. With the rapid developments in data analytics and data-driven business intelligence, access to data is an evolving problem.
2.4How would the problem evolve absent intervention?
B2C e-commerce revenue in Europe is forecast to amount to ~ € 250 billion in 2017, up from € 108.7 billion in 2012 and expected to grow steadily in the future, at rates much higher than the average growth rate of the economy. This in itself makes this sector particularly important to the overall EU economy. This growth is primarily driven by fast evolving consumer demands for e-commerce in the EU. Given, explained above, the platforms' incentives to grow, big platforms can be expected to continue expanding. The overall growth rate for online intermediaries is of around 10% per year since 2013 (based on 2012 estimates) and exceeds by far the growth rates in other sectors. The growth of online intermediaries is expected to continue over the coming years facilitated by an increasing use of cloud computing and a rapid growth in e-commerce. It is estimated that 40% of retail online sales will be conducted through online marketplaces by 2020. The use of search engines is also expected to grow, as a result of growth in the number of websites, which have currently reached over 1.3bn, up from 207 million in 2010. As a result, platforms will increasingly develop the potential to become 'gatekeepers'.
This would increase platforms' bargaining power and business users' dependency. The likely aggravated P2B issues could be expected to lead to further regulatory intervention across the EU Member States and undermine business user trust. In a similar way, the number of cases being considered by EU Member States’ courts leads to further divergent or unpredictable outcomes. For example, in Germany and in France there are cases pending in courts, which relate to P2B fairness standards. The outcome in those cases differed from first to second instance and it is unknown what highest court shall render as its final judgment. Furthermore, the fragmentation which results from different legislative approaches between Member States concerning terms and conditions, is exacerbated due to the varying levels of enforcement between them. For instance, in France, there is a political commitment to ensure the efficient enforcement of the P2B legislation in place. In December 2017 the French authority for competition, consumers and repression of fraud, DGCCRF opened an investigation into P2B clauses and their compliance with the legal standards. It has already obliged some companies to remove MFN clauses from their terms and conditions. Whereas in Germany – where supervision of MFN clauses takes place only from a competition law angle - a recent judgment concluded the validity of both wide and narrow MFN clauses under competition rules.
At the same time, the market position of the existent larger platforms would strengthen (due to data-driven network effects), which coupled with the single market fragmentation and more limited growth (because of reduced trust in the platform economy) would make market entry difficult for new platforms. If less business users decide to be present on a limited number of platforms, this could lead to reduced quality and choice for consumers in the longer term.
2.5Conclusion of Problem Definition
EU businesses cannot exploit the full potential of the platform economy because of issues in the platform-to-business relations and emerging re-fragmentation of the single market.
Business users active on platforms face a number of potentially harmful trading practices for which there is a lack of effective redress. According to a study carried out for the European Commission, these trading practices would concern a large number of business users. The results of the study show that 46% of business users encounter problems in their relation with platforms while this percentage is higher (75%) for business users realising more than half of their turnover on platforms. Almost one third of issues remain unresolved while 29% are solved only with difficulties. The potentially unfair trading practices listed in this section risk gradually undermining business trust in the platform economy. Trust is primordial to the platform economy since it allows increasing the number of users on both sides thus optimising data-driven network effects which fuel online platforms' growth. It can be reasonably assumed that potentially unfair and non-transparent P2B practices are therefore not only detrimental for business users (since they lead to direct loss in sales) but could also negatively impact the growth of the online intermediation sector and reduce platform operators' revenues (through unrealised commissions). The long-term sustainability of the platform economy is therefore closely linked to issues encountered by business users in their relations with platforms.
Platform operators are increasingly faced with emerging national legislations which start fragmenting the naturally cross-border market for online intermediation in the EU. The uncoordinated adoption of national legislations - whether platform-specific or covering B2B issues in general but applicable to platform businesses – may result in divergent regulatory measures across the EU and carry the risk of hampering online platforms' ability to scale up. The EU platform economy is of intrinsic global nature and is by definition cross-border. Scaling-up is core to platforms' business strategies as it allows for stronger network effects. Start-up and small online platform operators would be the most heavily impacted by a fragmented market for online intermediation because of their more limited capacity to comply with different national rules. If emerging re-fragmentation expands to other Member States (which could be expected given the growing online intermediated trade and the increasing importance of platforms as a gateway for SMEs to access new markets), it would negatively impact the emergence of new platforms in the EU. Without facing competition from new market players, existing platforms would reinforce their market strength. This would further increase their bargaining power and could be expected to increase business users' dependency and the size of the problem.
Such dynamics would be detrimental to the Digital Single Market in terms of innovation, growth and consumer benefits. Online intermediated trade has important impact on the digital economy. The less businesses use platforms, the less they seize innovation opportunities and the less they are able to embrace digital transformation. P2B issues are hampering the potential of the platform economy thus preventing it to fully contribute to a well-functioning Digital Single Market.
3Why should the EU Act?
3.1Legal Basis
Given (i) that the initiative constitutes a core part of the Digital Single Market strategy, (ii) the intrinsic cross-border nature of online platforms, and (iii) the risk of further regulatory fragmentation regarding online platforms, Article 114 TFEU (Title VII Common rules on competition, taxation and approximation of laws) is identified here as the relevant legal basis for this initiative. Further explanation is provided in Annex 1.10.
3.2Subsidiarity: Necessity of EU action
The intrinsic cross-border nature of online platforms implies that the objectives cannot be reached effectively by Member States alone. Leading online platforms such as Booking.com, Facebook and eBay are legally established in one Member State, but provide access to almost the entire EU population, both from their place of normal residency as well as while travelling across the EU. Importantly, a platform such as Facebook is at the same time used for commercial communications by 90% of the respondents to the Commission's fact-finding on platform-to-business relations. EU action, therefore, constitutes the only way to ensuring that the same rules apply to online platforms and the business users active on them, also regardless of the law and forum identified in contractual terms. On the specific set of issues described here, the European Council 'underlined the necessity of increased transparency in platforms' practices and uses' as part of a future oriented regulatory framework for the EU.
3.3Subsidiarity: Added value of EU action
EU action would ensure that business users trading on platforms can fully leverage the potential of the Digital Single Market, as the same P2B protection will apply to them regardless of which Member States they sell into. It will also facilitate the scaling-up of platform start-ups, as compliance costs are lowered and legal certainty enhanced.
Furthermore, EU action would avoid further fragmentation of the Single Market into different, potentially contradictory frameworks – including the resulting jurisdictional issues. This is expected to increase the incentives for new platforms to develop.
The initiative would, therefore, contribute to releasing the full potential the platform economy could offer in terms of increased competitiveness, innovation, growth and jobs.
Further explanation on subsidiarity is provided in Annex 1.11.
4Objectives: What should be Achieved?
Figure 2: Objectives tree
4.1What are the general policy objectives?
The general policy objective is to ensure the functioning of the Digital Single Market in line with Article 114 TFEU, and considering the inherent cross-border nature of the online platform economy and the dramatically increasing role that online platforms play in intermediating access to the Digital Single Market.
Releasing the full potential of the online platform economy therefore constitutes a broad general objective – implying that more businesses operate via online platforms in general, and that more consumers use online platforms to access goods and services.
This requires a fair, trusting and innovation-driven ecosystem around online platforms across the EU, in which business traders have the necessary safeguards to prevent harm from unfair trading practices, general lack of redress, and regulatory fragmentation across the EU.
4.2What are the specific objectives?
The initiative pursues the overarching objective of establishing a fair, trusting and innovation-driven ecosystem around online platforms in the EU. In particular, it aims at the following specific objectives:
Ensuring a fair, transparent and predictable treatment of business users by online platforms (specific objective 1)
The first specific objective of the intervention would be to provide a clear set of minimum standards that platforms need to provide, notably in terms of transparency on those aspects of their relationship where asymmetries of bargaining power are particularly pronounced. To this end, the initiative aims at defining basic rules for online platforms and their business users. The objective is to facilitate the business users' relations with online platforms thus allowing businesses to concentrate on their core activities and to fully grasp the opportunities offered by the various forms of online intermediation on which businesses rely to access markets. This in turn should lead to a predictable business environment for those enterprises which use online platforms to reach consumers.
Setting effective and agile redress for businesses, adaptable to the evolving market (specific objective 2)
The second objective is to ensure the enforcement of the above rules by appropriate redress mechanisms, all internal, external and judiciary. These mechanisms should ensure the necessary speed, independence, affordability and anonymity, to overcome the observed regulatory gap in terms of ineffective internal redress offered by platforms, the lack of an external redress mechanism and the limited use of judicial remedies. The aim is to closely monitor the functioning of the mechanisms to ensure their effectiveness and adapt them to the changes observed in the platform-to-business relations.
Preserving a predictable and innovation-friendly legal environment for online platforms within the EU, without placing undue administrative burden on platforms (specific objective 3)
Reaching a critical mass is essential for platforms' business model. The third objective is therefore to define clear requirements at EU level for online platforms, thereby allowing online platforms to operate at a larger EU scale without creating unnecessary and disproportionate burdens. This would set the basis for more consistency in national legislations by providing a common framework of high level rules within which Member States can set national legislations if needed. This would entail helping start-up platforms to scale up by providing a clear overview of the legal requirements they have to comply with, thus ensuring greater regulatory certainty.
Operational objectives are defined in Section 0.
How do the objectives link to the problem?
The overarching objective of a fair, trusting and innovation-driven platform ecosystem is directly linked to the two main problems identified in the problem tree, i.e. emerging difficulties for platforms to operate in the Single Market and impossibility for EU business users to fully exploit the potential of the platform economy.
A healthy platform ecosystem would help address the issues business users face in their relationship with platforms. A predictable regulatory environment for both online platforms and their business users (specific objectives 1 and 3) coupled with effective redress mechanism for business users (specific objective 2) would contribute to releasing the full potential of the platform economy. The overarching objective of establishing a fair, trusting and innovation-driven online platforms ecosystem in the EU would thus contribute to the better functioning of the internal market. A healthier platform ecosystem would also help prevent the fragmentation of the internal market which could otherwise occur as a result of uncoordinated efforts by Member States to solve platform-specific issues at the national level.
The more specific objectives 1, 2 and 3 allow addressing the different problems identified in the problem tree. All three specific objectives aim at creating the appropriate regulatory tools to safeguard the single market dimension of the platform economy and address the emerging fragmentation of the single market.
A more fair, transparent and predictable treatment of business users (specific objective 1) coupled with effective and agile redress possibilities adaptable to the evolving market conditions (specific objective 2) would act on the imbalance of bargaining power and help addressing potentially harmful trading practices and address the lack of effective regulatory tools against potentially harmful trading practices. This could be expected to lead to less P2B issues, which would in turn prevent any need for intervention at national level. This would help preventing further legal re-fragmentation of the single market across Member States, which could create future obstacles to cross-border trade and jeopardise the functioning of the Digital Single Market.
In addition, such improved business environment may also be expected to increase business users' trust in the platform economy and lead to an increased use of online platforms. Given the intrinsic global and cross-border nature of online platforms as well as the importance of online intermediated trade for SME's exports, such increased use of platforms may be expected to lead to more cross-border sales, thus reinforcing the single market dimension.
The objective of a predictable and innovation-friendly legal environment for online platforms within the EU without placing undue administrative burden on platforms (specific objective 3) aims at ensuring that any set of rules to the benefit of business users will be proportionate and non-intrusive for platforms. Possible new rules at EU level - such as the ones presented and assessed in this Impact Assessment - will provide more regulatory predictability for platforms at EU level. It would thus allow preserving the existing cross-border dynamics of the platform economy by setting a common framework for Member States' possible regulatory approaches.
4.3Consistency of the objectives
This initiative aims at ensuring a fair, predictable and ultimately trusted legal environment for business users and B2C online platforms alike that will limit the occurrence and/or the impact of the problematic P2B practices identified in Section 2.1 thereby safeguarding trust in the platform economy and preventing further legal fragmentation of the Digital Single Market.
The initiative thus contributes to the goals of Digital Single Market Strategy by creating a clear and stable legal environment for B2C online platforms and their business users to tackle market fragmentation and allow all players to tap into the new market dynamics under fair and balanced conditions.
The initiative is also consistent with a number of other EU policies and rules. It complements EU policies and rules in the area of consumer protection by aiming at providing a targeted fairness framework also for certain B2B relations, namely for the relations between B2C online platforms and their business users. To this end, it also builds on relevant findings made as part of the Fitness Check of the EU's consumer protection acquis, which exercise explicitly excludes any follow-up in the area of B2B or P2B relations.
It also complements Regulation 80/2009 on a Code of Conduct for computerised reservation systems, which contains a set of obligations for a specific type of B2B platforms (computerised reservation systems, also called Global Distribution Systems, GDS) that allow travel agencies to compare information and book tickets from a large number of travel service providers worldwide. The initiative, although building on a different design for conflict resolution, is not in friction with ODR-Regulation and the ADR-Directive. This initiative shares the objectives of those instruments, i.e. to offer a low cost and accessible out of court conflict resolution. However, achieving the same objectives within the P2B-relationship as those of the ODR- Regulation and the ADR-Directive requires a more targeted design for conflict solution. More particularly, this initiative builds on the presumed incentives of platforms to settle disputes with their business clients. The design for conflict solution in this initiative is also more specific if compared to the one of the ODR-Regulation and the ADR-Directive because of the specificity of the problems identified.
Finally, it complements the EU competition rules, which allow tackling anticompetitive behaviour and mergers the potentially harmful trading practices identified in Section 2. 1, as explained further in Annex 8.3.
To the extent that the fair and trustworthy legal environment that this initiative aims at ensuring would involve increased access to and use of personal data by business users of B2C online platform, such access and use would have to be compliant with the requirements of the General Data Protection Regulation ('GDPR'), in particular the principles of purpose limitation and lawful processing, and with Article 8 of the Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union ('CFR'). Where platforms act as processors of personal data
an obligation of increased transparency in changes to terms and conditions will also support the implementation by platforms of the new obligations under the GDPR
. This increased transparency in the contractual platform –business relationship will, in turn, positively impact on the data subjects' rights related information on changes in the data processing policy of platforms because it will better enable the data controller to keep the data subject informed about data processing issues.
The EU is committed to high standards of fundamental rights. The specific objective of timely, effective and trustworthy redress for business users contributes to enhancing business users' right to an effective remedy and to a fair trial (Article 47 CFR) as far as it would involve improved access to the judiciary. It would be neutral to this fundamental right, if it provided business users with additional out-of-court redress mechanisms, while simultaneously not impeding the platforms' right to take legal steps including going to court. Moreover, the fair and trustworthy legal environment that this initiative aims to create shall balance the business users' and the B2C online platforms' respective freedoms to conduct a business (Article 16 CFR).
5What are the available Policy Options?
5.1What is the baseline from which options are assessed?
Under the baseline option, EU action would continue to be limited to possible ex-post enforcement of the existing competition and consumer protection frameworks in targeted cases with no new rules at EU level. This scenario is described in Section 2.4. In the baseline scenario, the drivers of the problem description will only gather in strength, and inevitably increase the dependency and the relative market strength of online intermediaries over their business partners. In the baseline option, different online platforms will implement different – potentially contradictory – policies for each of the identified problems. Smaller businesses, who (as is demonstrated above) generally need to multi-home to optimise their revenues, will be confronted with a confusing mix of different practices and problems, depending on country of operation or type and brand of online platform. Specifically, there is no incentive at present for market players to provide for effective dispute resolution across the board - and certainly not outside their own platforms.
Concerning the individual problems, it is possible that the strength of evolution of the underlying drivers even increases the range of potentially harmful trading practices. The baseline scenario also implies that no effective, continuous monitoring of the evolution of potentially harmful trading practices, would take place.
Fragmentation across the Digital Single Market is likely to increase as national legislators seek to address largely cross-border issues with national rules, which are likely to target only specific regulatory interests in individual Member States.
5.2Description of the policy options
The policy options considered are as follows:
-Policy option 0: Baseline – no EU action taken
-Policy option 1: Non-legislative approach / pure self-regulation
-Policy Option 2: Co-regulation implying (i) on transparency: legal principles with significant scope for industry implementation, (ii) on redress: co-regulatory cascade of redress mechanisms; focus on industry action, playing on light-touch reputational levers, and (iii) on monitoring: EU Observatory to monitor emerging issues – partly informed by the new legal transparency obligations – and to inform potential future review of initial light-touch Regulation. Policy Option 2 could take the form of one of the four options 2a, 2b, 2c or 2d such as explained in Table 1 below.
-Policy option 3: Mandatory, binding rules for all aspects
-Policy Option 4: Extension of existing rules to P2B
The above list of policy options has been identified on the basis of the following approach. First, a range of substantive policy elements have been considered for each specific issue identified in the problem statement, referred to in Annex 10 as 'content' options as they seek to address the subject matter of the problem at hand. Second, these option elements have been assessed on the basis of their effectiveness, cost efficiency and coherence (Tables 1 and 2 of Annex 10). Third, the specific retained measures for each issue identified have been combined in policy options. Finally, a variety of legislative or non-legislative instruments have been considered for the so identified policy options, ranging from self-regulation to co-regulation, or to full mandatory binding measures (see also Sections 5.3 and 5.4). Option 4 departs from this approach since it is an extension of existing rules to the P2B issues identified.
Table 1 below presents for each option the measures aiming at addressing (i) potentially harmful trading practices, and (ii) inefficient redress alongside (iii) the elements that are part of the envisaged monitoring exercise at EU level.
Table 1: Presentation of the policy options considered
|
Policy option 0: Baseline – no EU action taken
|
Policy option 1: Non-legislative approach / pure self-regulation
|
Transparency measures:
-Invitation to industry to develop measures of its choice to address the problematic potentially
harmful trading practices identified, particularly focussing on developing principles and best
practices for changes to terms and conditions, for delisting/suspension.
-Encouragement of industry to improve transparency on data policies, differential treatment
and auxiliary services.
-Structured dialogues with industry aiming at addressing emerging issues in paid-for
ranking, encouraging voluntary standards and private audits.
|
Redress: Call on the industry (i) to improve their internal complaint-handling mechanisms accessible
for business users, and (ii) to set up an external independent redress mechanism at EU level to
provide business users with an additional venue for redress.
|
Monitoring: An EU Observatory of the Digital Platform Economy ('EU Observatory') would be set
up, having as part of its mandate to monitor the evolution and emergence of issues related to
data access and use by both platforms and their business users. This would include sharing of
both non-personal and personal data, e.g. e-mail addresses, with business users, and to what
extent business users request access to such data in full compliance with the GDPR.
|
Policy option 2a: limited scope of legal transparency principles, maximum focus on
voluntary industry action
|
Transparency: Builds on Option 1, but includes legal transparency obligations for platforms on
limited issues, i.e. terms and conditions and delisting. Foresees the following measures:
-improve clarity & availability of terms and conditions.
-give reasonable notice period before introducing changes to terms and conditions
-list the objective grounds for suspension or termination of use of platform
-provide a statement of reasons for any decision to suspend or terminate use of a platform, referring
to predetermined objective grounds
-invitation to industry to voluntarily explore practical solutions that improve predictability around:
the functioning of ranking mechanisms, including the use of any mechanism that allows business
users to influence their prominence against remuneration; any preferential treatment of platforms'
own products or services; access to personal and other data; the use of MFN clauses, the verifiability of paid-for prominence in ranking (relevant to specific e-commerce areas) potentially developing
industry standards and proactively running audits and monitoring the functioning of the wider
digital advertising space.
|
Redress:
-Legal obligation for platforms (i) to provide internal complaint-handling mechanisms, with
detailed mechanism to be specified in industry codes, and (ii) to either list a mediator or
make reference to organisations providing mediation services set up by platforms, together with
a legal obligation to act in good faith in relation to any mediation attempts.
-Call on industry to set up an external organisation that can provide industry-specific mediators at
EU level to provide business users with an additional means out of court for redress with
legal obligations as to their effectiveness.
-Invitation to industry to voluntarily explore developing further recommendations on the
internal complaints-handling mechanism in the form of codes of conduct.
-Right for business associations or representative bodies to seek action in court to obtain
injunctive relief to ensure high-level legal obligations on redress (internal complaint-handling &
good faith mediation) are complied with.
|
Monitoring: In addition to the tasks in Option 1, the EU Observatory shall monitor the evolution
and emergence of issues related to: preferential treatment of a platforms' own products or
services; use of MFN clauses by online platforms and test the reasons provided by platforms to
justify their use. The EU Observatory shall act as a repository for public reports on the effectiveness
of internal complaint-handling mechanism and refusals by a platform to engage in any
mediation attempts. Platforms are required to report in a non-detailed manner on the use of
the internal complaint-handling system. A medium-term review clause would be considered.
|
Policy Option 2b: Co-regulation with horizontal application of legal transparency principles to
all trading practices.
|
The legal transparency principles would extend to all potentially harmful trading practices: clarity
& availability of terms and conditions, delisting, ranking, discrimination, data and MFNs. Industry
would continue to play important role in developing codes of conduct or standards to provide
practical solutions to implement these legal principles. Redress and monitoring measures are
identical to those under option 2a.
|
Policy option 2c: horizontal application of legal transparency principles to all trading practices,
scope extension to online general search
|
Transparency: Building on option 2b, the scope of the legal transparency obligation on the core issue
of ranking would be expanded to encompass both online platforms as well as online search
engines. The role for industry in providing practical solutions for meaningful ranking transparency
in general search would be ensured through developing codes of conduct or standards to
provide practical solutions to implement these legal principles.
|
Redress builds on option 2a, by additionally granting associations or representative bodies
of businesses whose websites are indexed by online general search engines the right to seek action
in court to obtain injunctive relief to ensure high-level legal obligation on transparency on ranking
in online general search is complied with (c.f. Sections 7.2.1 and 7.2.3).
|
Monitoring is identical to Option 2a (and hence also to 2b).
|
Policy option 2d: horizontal application of legal transparency principles to all trading practices,
scope extension to online general search and targeted legal obligation on email addresses
|
Transparency: Building on option 2c, this option adds a legal obligation for platforms to give
business users the opportunity to ask, in line with the GDPR, for customers' consent to obtain
and process their e-mail addresses after the completion of a transaction and the payment of
the commission to the respective platform.
|
Redress is identical to 2c and monitoring to 2a (and hence also to 2b and 2c).
|
Policy option 3: Mandatory, binding rules for all aspects
|
Transparency: Building on both Options 2b and 2d, to cover all the legal obligations in Options 2b
and 2d, but elaborated to include all legal or technical details, including those left to codes of
conduct in Options 2b and 2d above. Option 4 adds further prohibitions and legal obligations
in relation to data and MFNs as follows: (i) an obligation for platforms to extend data access rights
to business users for specific categories of data, (ii) a ban on contractual clauses that prevent
business users from retrieving and/or using specific types of data outside the platform, and (iii) a prohibition of most-favoured-nation clauses (whether on price, availability, quality) for platforms.
|
Redress: (1) Legal obligation on industry to set up internal complaint-handling mechanisms to
include all legal or technical details, including those left to codes of conduct in Options 2b and
2d above. (2) An obligation for Member States to ensure effective enforcement and efficient
dispute resolution of the P2B rules by designating competent authorities, who would be capable
of imposing sanctions.
|
Monitoring is identical to Option 2.
|
Policy Option 4: Extension of existing rules
|
Transparency measures: (i) include platform-specific practices in the blacklist in the annex of the
UCPD; (ii) include platform-specific practices in the grey list in the annex of the UCTD,
(iii) include platform-specific practices in the blacklist in the annex of the MCAD.
|
Redress measures: (i) extend the scope of the UCPD to cover B2B relationships P2B relations;
(ii) extend the scope of the UCTD to cover B2B relationships including platform-to-business relations,
(iii) extend the content of the MCAD to also cover existing contractual relationships and to broaden
the scope to particularly address platform-to-business relations.
|
Monitoring: extension of the available monitoring mechanisms under consumer law to businesses.
|
As explained in the beginning of this section, a wide range of other measures (than those listed in the table) have also been considered for the policy options described above to address the identified problems. However, these option elements have been discarded at an earlier stage and not retained for further examination for various reasons that are listed in Table 3 of Annex 10. The most prominent grounds for discarding these option elements were a lack of effectiveness or disproportionality.
While options 2b and 2c mainly differ on the scope of the ranking and the legal standing obligation, this differential element between the two options is important since it allows expanding the benefits of the initiative to online general search. The difference between the two options is thus important since it allows under option 2d (i) covering business users' dependency on online general search ranking which directly influence businesses websites' visibility and Internet traffic, and (ii) granting legal standing to business associations to act on behalf of professional website owners to enforce this transparency requirement only.
As to the single differential element between options 2c and 2d, it is also a significant one. Option 2d adds a legal obligation for platforms to give business users the opportunity to ask, in line with the GDPR, for customers' consent to obtain and process their e-mail addresses after the completion of a transaction and the payment of the commission to the respective platform. While this additional element may from the outset appear as a detail, it is a strong distinguishing feature between 2c and 2d. Due to the data-related aspect of email addresses, the impacts of options 2c and 2d are very different as explained in Section 6 (Impacts) and Section 7 (Comparison of Options).
5.3Legislative or non-legislative character of options
Option 1 is a non-legislative instrument, e.g. a Commission Communication, calling on the industry to address the identified problems by means of self-regulation. Option 2 – with its four sub-options - embodies a co-regulatory approach including a set of obligations enshrined in a new legal instrument alongside non-legislative measures requesting further actions by the industry. Option 3 comprises full regulation by a new legislative instrument imposing legal obligations to addressing the problems identified in this Initiative. Option 4 implies the revision of existing EU law to extend the scope of the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive and the Directive on unfair terms in consumer contracts to B2B relationships and to amend the content of those directives and the MCAD to allow them to address platform-specific issues effectively. All options are supported by the establishment of an EU Observatory of the Online Platform Economy flanked by a wider non-legislative Commission initiative as explained in the Table 1 above.
5.4Discarded Options
Options 1, 3 and 4 are discarded because they are either manifestly ineffective or evidently disproportionate. Particularly, proportionality is of crucial concern for this Initiative, because it embraces a light-touch and principles-based approach as the first step of the underlying two-step approach. Based on the principle of proportionality in Article 5(4) TEU any EU action shall not exceed what is necessary to achieve the objectives of the Treaties.
5.4.1Non-legislative approach (Option 1)
In choosing this option the Commission would adopt a non-binding document such as a Communication, inviting industry to develop measures to address the most problematic potentially harmful trading practices. This document would set out the principles and behaviour to be followed by platforms when dealing with their business users. This would include requirements for platforms to ensure transparency to business users in key areas such as the rolling out of changes in terms and conditions, reasons for delisting or suspension, and their data policy. However, the Communication would not specify the measures that online platforms should take to achieve these objectives: these would be left up to online platforms to determine. To solve the problem of ineffective redress, the soft law document would call upon online platforms to adapt their internal escalation procedures, and to set up an EU-level external redress mechanism.
Structured dialogues with industry would aim at addressing emerging issues on paid-for ranking, encouraging voluntary standards and private audits, as well as addressing emerging issues on data access.
In addition, a monitoring strategy would be established to regularly assess the evolution of all the problems above and emerging in the digital platforms economy. The strategy would be implemented through the establishment of the EU Observatory with a mandate to collect evidence, analyse, give guidance on and make policy recommendations for the evolution and potentially need for further regulatory intervention. Issues would include, but not be limited to, discrimination, business disputes and functioning of mediation mechanisms, emerging data issues like access to and sharing of personal and non-personal data, and MFN clauses.
However, pure self-regulation is unlikely to be effective. Limiting EU action to only self-regulation and certain accompanying measures would essentially rely on the platform industry's own incentives and willingness to change the status quo. While both platforms and their business users have an interest to maximise interactions and transactions with end consumers on platforms, their short-term interests in tackling issues arising in their business relationship are only imperfectly aligned. For example, vertically integrated platforms might have a natural vested interest in keeping the conditions for delisting and differential treatment opaque so as to preserve their margin of manoeuvre for favouring own downstream entities without much publicity. Improving the situation for business users, for instance by setting up an external redress mechanism, would also entail certain efforts and sometimes costs for platforms. In addition, there is no guarantee that the majority of platforms would adopt the non-binding best practice, or sign up to the voluntary measures, limiting the effectiveness of this non-legislative option
Previous experience with the Supply Chain Initiative (SCI) in the food sector suggests that purely voluntary initiatives are not suited for creating a functioning independent redress mechanism and enacted fairness rules that are attractive and credible for both sides of the market. The SCI is a joint initiative launched by seven EU-level associations in November 2011 with the aim to increase fairness in commercial relations along the food supply chain
. Despite some progress (elaboration of principles of good practice and setting up of a governance group), agricultural providers – the main supposed beneficiaries of the scheme – did not sign up to the scheme because of confidentiality and enforcement concerns. Five years after its creation, the SCI still had no independent chair
and the Agricultural Markets Task Force concluded that it needed improvement 'so as to render it more effective and attractive, including for farmers'
. In the meantime, 20 Member States have already adopted national legislation and initiatives to combat potentially harmful trading practices in the food supply chain, and that more are planning to do so in the near future
.
In the meantime, Member States risk adopting further regulation for B2B relations of online platforms, thereby increasing legal fragmentation. Furthermore, even if self-regulatory rules would eventually be adopted, those would be non-binding and non-enforceable. This would hamper the rules' effectiveness. Similarly, enforcement concerns were one of the reasons for producers, the weaker side of the market, not to join the SCI. A pure self-regulatory option is therefore discarded.
A wide range of other option elements were also considered for the policy options but not retained due to lack of effectiveness or disproportionality (see Table 3 of Annex 10). A full overview of options elements (both retained and discarded) is in Annex 9 and their assessment in Annex 10, tables 1 and 2.
Mandatory, binding rules for all aspects (Option 3)
As explained in Section 5.2, the identified problems could also be addressed in a fully-fledged, exhaustive and binding act that includes all necessary details, legal or technical, in the basic act itself. These detailed rules would leave the industry without any margin to set its own rules. In light of current evidence, however, the more far-reaching data obligations for example are disproportionate. To extend data access rights would entail significant legal and technical costs for platforms. Importantly, the impact of mandated access to specific sets of data for business users on the platforms' business model cannot be precisely quantified. A ban on contractual clauses that prevent the retrieval or use of specific types of data is too broad for a variety of reasons, including the protection of business secrets and more generally, platforms' business models as an intermediary. A wide block ban of such clauses would favour business users (beyond general fairness principles) but create significant risk of harm to platforms and consumers. Similarly, a prohibition on MFN clauses would be disproportionate in view of the current evidence. Also, a full per se prohibition of MFN clauses would not be compatible with EU competition rules.
This approach would provide significant clarity and redress possibilities to business users of platforms. It does not seem appropriate however for a fast-moving technological, economic and legal environment where industry involvement and more flexibility to necessary adaptations of rules are prone to lead to a more future-proof framework. Detailed legislation indeed risks both being rendered obsolete as a result of technological developments, as well as intervening in a disproportionate manner in the highly beneficial platform-model.
Therefore, the fast-moving nature of the platforms space renders it ill-suited to detailed regulatory frameworks. This finding also underpins the Commission's stated problem-driven and principles-based approach to regulating online platforms. As a result, exhaustive EU legislation is discarded as an option.
5.4.2Extension of existing EU rules (Option 4)
As already stated in Section 1.1 and described in Annex 8.1 EU Competition law focuses on anticompetitive behaviour and mergers. The harmful practices described in Section 2.1.1 do not necessarily infringe EU competition law rules. Moreover, to be able to rely on Article 102 TFEU to investigate a potential abuse by online platforms of a dominant position, the respective platforms must be dominant in the relevant market. EU Competition law tackling anti-competitive behaviour is in addition enforced on a case-by-case basis ex post, prioritising, inter alia, those cases with a potential impact beyond the case itself. This Initiative therefore aims at complementing the enforcement of EU Competition law in a horizontal and light-touch manner, rather than relying on case-specific interventions.
Notwithstanding the previous paragraph, one of the policy options that have been considered as potentially feasible is the extension of existing EU rules to tackle the potentially harmful trading practices and the inefficient redress identified. Particularly, the UCPD and UCTD aim at protecting consumers against certain unfair commercial practices and contract terms respectively. Given the broad scope and the general nature of the instruments they already cover digital platforms and their business users in relation to their actions geared towards consumers.
It does not, however, seem to be proportionate and efficient to simply broaden the scope of these instruments for various reasons to address both the lack of redress and the potentially harmful trading practices.
First, these instruments address all practices that consumers face vis-à-vis businesses throughout the various transaction phases and regardless of the distribution channel or product. Given that the concerned practices are specific to the platform economy and the business models involved it would be disproportionate to extend the UCPD and UCTD to the general B2B sphere implying application to any business relationship in the EU and not just covering the relationship between platforms and their business users. Furthermore, to be effective it would not be sufficient enough to broaden the scope of the current instruments, because the practices listed in the annexes of the instruments have been designed for the offline world and the B2C relationships in mind focusing on fundamentally different aspects and not covering the specific problems. However, given the current evidence base adding the identified potentially harmful practices to the annexes of UCPD/UCTD would be too invasive at this stage and would go far beyond addressing the problems identified.
In addition, splitting up the identified problems based on the rationales behind both instruments would imply an incoherent approach, because the Annex of the UCPD is a blacklist prohibiting all practices per se, while the Annex of the UCTD is a grey list including only indicatively potentially problematic practices. This incoherence would be fortified, because the UCPD is a so-called 'full harmonisation Directive' and the UCTD is minimum harmonising giving the Member States a margin of discretion in regulation further.
Second, the problem identified as part of the present Initiative can be summarised as the cumulative effect of potentially harmful trading practices occurring in light of the absence of effective redress. The impact of the problem is direct economic harm to businesses and emerging regulatory fragmentation. Additional transparency and monitoring would be required in a first step to determine the precise impact of any individual trading practices. Combined transparency and redress measures would in addition already help to prevent direct economic harm resulting from such trading practices. It would not, however, be justified at this stage to categorise any individual trading practices as unfair per se, which would result from an extension of the consumer protection acquis to B2B relations.
As already set forth in Section 2.1.3., several Member States have adopted general fairness rules for B2B relationships, and 10 Member States have also extended UCPD and UCTD to varying degrees to B2B relationships (a more detailed description is available in Annex 8). It is evident that neither the existing national B2B fairness rules nor the extension of UCPD or UCTD provide an adequate and effective way for business users to resolve any disputes with platforms. If the platform-specific problems identified are not included in or covered by the blacklist of the UCPD or the grey list of the UCTD, business users would still need to bring an action before the courts to enforce their rights based on the general fairness test of UCPD or UCTD. Therefore, the crucial problem of lack of effective redress would not be tackled sufficiently. The practice of imposing exclusive choice of law and forum clauses often used by platforms in their terms and conditions further undermines the effectiveness of the extension, because in these cases business users cannot rely on European rules. Furthermore, given the expected ineffectiveness of the extension of the UCTD and the UCPD adopting a broad scope covering all B2B relationships in the EU is blatantly disproportionate.
Alongside the inefficiency and disproportionality of the scope broadening itself one has also to bear in mind that both the UCPD and the UCTD are cornerstones of EU consumer protection legislation. Any possible extension or review must inevitably take into account the instruments' rank as well as the other existing EU consumer law instruments and cannot be analysed in isolation. An extension of consumer protection instruments to cover certain aspects of B2B relations would also raise the concern whether such extension could have a – negative – impact on the high level of EU consumer protection.
Another option would be to take the MCAD as a basis as it applies to B2B relations, and extend it to tackle potentially harmful trading practices identified in this initiative. The MCAD prohibits traders from engaging in misleading advertising and lays down rules for comparative advertising. The report of the Fitness Check of Consumer and Marketing law concluded on the need to consider changes to the rules on misleading and comparative advertising in business-to-business (B2B) relations, largely confirming the findings of the 2012 Commission Communication announcing the intention to revise the MCAD
. The Inception Impact Assessment on a targeted revision of EU consumer law directives, however, underlined that the findings of the Fitness Check would inform future action in the area of B2B relations (notably on platform-to-business relations) within the Digital Single Market context
. Simply adding P2B specific rules to the MCAD would indeed not be effective as the existing horizontally applicable provisions of the MCAD require a revision that goes further than the scope of the present initiative limited to P2B relations. Furthermore, the MCAD addresses advertising and marketing in the B2B sphere, which are predominantly pre-contractual activities. The majority of the practices identified in this Initiative arise in already existing contractual relationships between business users and platforms. To be able to use the MCAD to address the identified practices one would need to revise the rationale and substantive content of the MCAD completely. Equally to the argumentation above on the UCPD and UCTD the business users would need to rely on the general fairness test of the MCAD by taking legal actions, if the platform-specific practices are not included in the blacklist in the Annex. Experiences show that the latter possibility has already proven to be inefficient to address the business users' lack of redress and based on the existing evidence including platform practices in a blacklist would be disproportionate.
As a result of the foregoing arguments the option to create an add-on or opt for a revision of existing EU legislation, namely UCPD, UCTD and MCAD, is discarded and will not be considered further. To be effective and proportionate this Initiative aims at creating a new self-standing instrument to address the identified harmful practices and the inefficient redress.
Conclusion
The non-legislative approach of Option 1 is unlikely to be effective, in the absence of sufficient incentives in the industry to address the problems identified in a across all Member States, and across all platform types. Previous experience with the Supply Chain Initiative (SCI) in the food sector suggests that purely voluntary initiatives are not suited for creating a functioning independent redress mechanism and enacted fairness rules that are attractive and credible for both sides of the market.
Mandatory, binding rules for all aspects (Option 3) are inappropriate for a fast-moving technological, economic and legal environment where industry involvement and more flexibility to necessary adaptations of rules are prone to lead to a more future-proof framework. Overly detailed, binding legislation risks being obsolete due to technological developments and intervenes disproportionately in the highly beneficial platform-model.
The extension of existing EU rules is analysed under Option 4, in the context of possible extensions of the Directives on Unfair Commercial Practices, Trading Practices, or on Misleading and Comparative Advertising. None of the possible extensions however, can be consider effective or proportionate for the specific problems at hand – the UCPD or UCTD instruments focus on a wide array of consumer related practices, which go far beyond the issues identified here. Modifications to the MCAD would not be effective as the existing horizontally applicable provisions of it require revision that goes further than the scope of this initiative limited to P2B relations, and focus furthermore on pre-contractual activities.
5.5Retained options - co-regulatory Options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d
As shown in Table 1 in Section 5.2, option 2b builds on option 2a, and options 2c and 2d build on option 2b. Both option 2c and option 2d are composed of the legal transparency requirements in six areas of concern (changes to terms and conditions, delisting, discrimination/preferential treatment, ranking, general data policy and MFNs), but options 2c and 2d also include additional provisions. Option 2c provides for an extended scope of the transparency requirement for ranking to also cover online general search engines. Under option 2c, the redress-related measures applicable to online general search engines concern only the ranking transparency obligation and are limited to granting legal standing to business associations to act on behalf of professional website owners to enforce this transparency requirement only. In addition to this scope extension in 2c, option 2d foresees an obligation for platforms to give any business user the opportunity to ask, in line with the GDPR, for customers' consent to obtain and process their e-mail addresses after the completion of a transaction and the payment of the commission to the respective platform.
Co-regulation has the advantage of guaranteeing a predictable legal framework while simultaneously giving sufficient flexibility to industry to shape and decide on their voluntary commitments, respecting the speed of innovation. Experience has also shown that, in line with the argumentation in Section 5.4.1. on a non-legislative approach, pure self-regulation is insufficient, particularly where it is built on purely private and voluntary commitments, and more so in this sector where the short term interests of platforms and business users are not aligned. A clear legal framework is necessary and can be provided by adopting a new legal instrument. This leaves room for industry to develop codes of conduct to further elaborate on their substance by platforms, who have expressed in consultations that they are willing to openly engage in self-regulation. The options could be based on the 'Principles for better co- and self-regulation' developed by a Community of Practice established by the European Commission in its conception as well as its implementation.
The rules contained in the co-regulatory instrument would be self-standing and be immediately relied upon by business users and platforms. They can form the baseline for any self-regulatory addition. Depending on the co-regulatory model chosen, any self-regulatory addition would be screened and added to the body of rules if it strikes a satisfactory balance between the interests of platforms and their business users. This would usefully specify and enlarge the body of applicable and enforceable rules and promote buy-in from industry, both platforms and business users. The co-regulatory technique would enable a good balance to be struck between a limited number of general rules in the legislative instrument and the more detailed or technical rules that could be filled in by industry. This would make the instrument more future-proof since outdated technical rules could be modified more easily than by a revision of the basic act and would benefit from first-hand experience of the industry itself. The additional benefits of co-regulation include increased transparency, the simplification of rules that can automatically have sector support ensuring they can be swiftly adopted and properly implemented and help contribute toward a sense of co-responsibility of the industry and businesses involved, which will have a positive knock-on effect on elements of co-regulation that involve reputational levers. Option 2 with its sub-options is retained for further analysis. The impacts of the co-regulatory options are assessed in Section 6.
6What are the impacts of the retained policy options?
This Section summarizes the main impacts of the retained policy options as compared to the baseline, namely co-regulatory options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d.
6.1Impact on internal market
The impact on the Single Market of the co-regulatory options is two-fold. The substantive rules proposed will provide business users with greater legal certainty when using online platforms to trade in the internal market and provide concrete tools to seek redress in case of problems, thus supporting the growth of the Digital Single Market. Also, the monitoring and review clauses will allow regulators to adapt rules to the observed market reality to help business users find the appropriate support, gradually creating a common understanding of the issues identified and solutions to address them. This would possibly allow some alignment of platform-related rules across the EU. Further fragmentation will also be limited by encouraging Member States to cooperate through the EU Observatory.
Growth
The initiative's aim is to increase legal certainty in the platforms environment. This is why all retained options can be expected to have a positive impact on user trust and on growth of the platform economy. As a result of the proposed measures, more business users can be expected to sell over platforms or to expand their share of online sales through platforms. All retained options would therefore contribute to optimising businesses' turn-over realised on platforms, thus limiting the chilling effect that the currently observed potentially harmful trading practices have on sales (see Section 2.1.1.) A comparison of the total 2016 value of e-commerce with the total offline retail value or 2.56 trillion EUR shows it is likely the current e-commerce growth trend will continue, and the growing importance of online platforms along with it. In light of these statistics, the growth of the platform economy can legitimately be expected to have a positive effect on overall growth in the Digital Single Market.
Increased trust in the online environment will attract more business users, having thereby a positive impact also on online platforms' turnover. As the number of sales carried out over online platforms increase, so too will the commissions received by online platforms. Based on the calculations above, assuming that an average commission charged by platforms is 10%, platforms can be expected to receive additional commissions ranging from EUR 38 million to EUR 70.5 million if exclusively the effect on direct sales through platforms is taken into account. Adding the reversal in the dampening effect increases this estimate to a range from EUR 119 to EUR 476 million. Through their role as enablers of cross-border trade, the growth of online platforms resulting from all retained options will therefore benefit the internal market growth.
As compared to the baseline, user trust (as a trigger for growth) can be expected to increasingly gain in strength from options 2a to 2d, with option 2d bringing potentially a higher trust level since comprising the most comprehensive set of business user–friendly measures. At the same time, option 2d - by allowing business users access to their customers' email addresses carries the risk of free-riding by businesses. Due to these opposite effects that Option 2d would have on business users and platform operators, its impact on growth of the Digital Single Market would be more difficult to predict.
The value of e-commerce in the European Union was estimated to more than 500 billion EUR in 2016, a 13.5% increase from 2015
; in 2017 the growth is estimated at another 14% year on year
. 22% of the 2016 e-commerce value is estimated to have been generated by EU third party sellers on online platforms
. Trade intermediated through online platforms is expected to follow an upward trend as most consumers opt for platforms when purchasing goods and services online: in a recent study, 71% of them preferred platforms for their purchasesAll retained options will reduce potentially harmful trading practices online. The impact of the potentially harmful trading practices identified in the problem statement can be expected to drop by a minimum of 30%. The drop in the impact of potentially harmful trading practices can be estimated to be reflected in the unrealised potential in terms of turnover and of the dampening effect that was previously identified. If one assumes on that basis that a similar share (30%) of unrealised potential in terms of turn-over businesses realise on platforms could be addressed and that the same share (30%) of the dampening effect as estimated in Section 2.3.2 could be reversed, this would lead to a positive impact on the platform economy of respectively between € 381 million and € 705 million per year in terms of increased turn-over, and of between € 810 million to € 4.05 billion per year of reversed dampening effect. These figures are likely to be higher in the future because trade on platforms is growing every year.
The assessment of impact on growth of the options must take into account both the possible positive effects of the increase in trust in the platform environment, as well as downside risks resulting from the costs of the proposed measures and possible repercussions on online platforms' practices, fees to business users and consumer prices. Overall however, the costs created by the initiative are expected to be limited under all scenarios, as described in the section on compliance costs (cf. sections 6.2). Online platforms will therefore have little incentive to pass on costs to consumers or to limit access to (small) business users. These dynamics are assessed in more details in the relevant sections 6.2.3 (impact on businesses) and 6.6 (impact on consumers).
Preserving the cross-border nature of the platform economy – preventing fragmentation of the internal market
While none of the retained options aim at harmonising national B2B fairness legislation, each of the retained options will complement national B2B legislation with high-level transparency rules. Given the more limited scope of option 2a, this option carries a greater risk of fragmentation as opposed to options 2b, 2c and 2d, if MS consider that not the entire set of problems faced by businesses is adequately addressed.
The proposed rules will provide more clarity and regulatory predictability for platforms at EU level as to the requirements they need to comply with. It would allow preserving the existing cross-border dynamics of the platform economy by setting a common framework for Member States.
Given the absence of the regulatory backstop on key issues such as ranking, data access policies, discrimination and MFNs, the effect of EU monitoring pushing on reputational levers to effectuate a fairer and more predictable business environment for business users of online platforms would be limited under Option 2a as compared to the baseline. Indeed, the legal transparency obligations on these issues foreseen under options 2b, 2c and 2d will be accompanied by enhanced external scrutiny of online platforms' trading practices which should incentivise these firms to pro-actively improve the situation for business users, for example by solving issues out-of-court (bilaterally or through mediation). .Option 2a - by leaving four out of six of the most frequently observed high-impact trading practices to be addressed through self-regulation - carries a more pronounced risk of fragmentation as opposed to options 2b, 2c and 2d. Given the absence of the regulatory backstop on key issues such as ranking, data access policies, discrimination and MFNs, the effect of EU monitoring pushing on reputational levers to effectuate a more fair and predictable business environment for business users of online platforms would be limited under Option 2a as compared to the baseline. Indeed, the legal transparency obligations on these issues foreseen under options 2b, 2c and 2d will be accompanied by enhanced external scrutiny of online platforms' trading practices which should incentivise these firms to pro-actively improve the situation for business users, for example by solving issues out-of-court (bilaterally or through mediation). Options 2b, 2c and 2d would thus help to ensure a more harmonised approach to platform-to-business relationships within the EU. These options would thus have a positive impact as compared to the baseline scenario in which Member States are increasingly adopting or considering legislation addressing specific platform-related aspects. The scope, addressees and level of intervention of these national measures vary significantly, which leads inevitably to a fragmentation of the inherently cross-border platform environment. In each option, a key role of the EU Observatory would be to monitor further the internal market dimension of the platform economy. In addition, the EU observatory will help allow building a common EU understanding of what issues are, thus allowing for more consistent regulatory approaches when such are deemed necessary at national level.
6.2Impact on enterprises
Impact on online platforms
6.2.2.1Compliance costs
The costs are expected to result from three main factors: (a) the implementation of the different transparency requirements; (b) the setting up of internal redress mechanisms and external organisations that can provide industry-specific mediators; and (c) the reporting obligation on the functioning of the internal redress mechanism.
The implementation of the transparency requirements will result in one-off costs to adapt the implementation and communication of platforms' terms and conditions, and updating these standard contracts where needed (costs related to the legal expertise, revision and publication of their terms and conditions). Once these procedures are carried out, platforms will face running costs when modifying and communicating changes to their terms and conditions. However as changes are not expected to occur more frequently, these costs are likely to be equivalent to those that online platforms currently face. Clearly, it is good business practice, even for very small platforms who want to build a customer base, to have clear and transparent terms and conditions on their different policies on matters such as delisting, ranking or access to data. Options 2b, 2c and 2d foresee legal transparency obligations on more complex issues such as ranking, data access, discrimination and MFNs.
An independent study on contractual arrangements between platforms and their business users examined options which closely match the retained options assessed here. Their independent impact assessment identifies major benefits for business users that would correspond to little or no impact for larger online platforms, especially as the legal framework would leave these firms free to change the rules applicable to their ecosystem, or even to delist large numbers of offerings, as long as this is done in line with pre-defined objective aims and in a non-discriminatory fashion. Exclusively the rule requiring data on transactions to be provided (which is similar to the data-relevant aspect of policy option 2d), is estimated to imply some initial costs for platforms and possibly impact their willingness to invest in innovation.
Option 2c would extend the legal transparency obligation on ranking to the area of online general search, where complex algorithms determine the saliency of search results on the basis of a search index that can cover, in principle, most of the openly accessible Internet.
Providing meaningful transparency on ranking in this fast-moving area implies, in theory, more significant compliance costs. Transparency measures would have to capture the high frequency with which changes to the functioning of online general search engines' ranking mechanisms are implemented, and "translate" their functioning into useable guidance for the appropriate audiences – which may cover a broad spectrum of businesses ranging from technologically illiterate firms to digital natives. However, the major providers of online general search engines already today offer some transparency to inform webmasters how to achieve high quality search results, although the level of detail provided differs significantly. The main transparency tools developed by the three major online general search engines active in the EU are described in Annex 7.2.5. In addition, Search Engine Optimisation (SEO) strategies have developed around online general search engines, which could be leveraged for the purpose of "communicating" effectively with the target audiences.
A legal requirement to be transparent about ranking policies would give more prominence to these existing practices and give them legal character. The majority of tools allowing for search optimisation put in place by online general search engines are publicly available but the level of detail and exhaustiveness differs, and these are not, in general, tailored to the business audience and their availability to the general public is not guaranteed.
Option 2d would require online platforms to ask consumers for their consent to share some data with business users. This measure would require a technical adjustment on the side of platforms to allow consumers to express their consent (the data itself can be shared through existing communication channels). The request would be conditional on the completion of a transaction on the respective platform and to the payment of the platform's commission. Nonetheless, if the sellers have their own sales channels, it may also allow them to circumvent the platform for future transactions and disrupt a core aspect of the platform business model.
Setting up internal and external organisations that can provide industry-specific mediators mechanisms will also be linked to compliance costs. These are also set out in Annex 4. Regarding internal redress, platforms that already have a dispute settlement mechanism may be required to upgrade their systems to comply with the quality standards set out in the legal act, notably speed and effectiveness (e.g. identifying a clear contact point for submitting complaints). Those that do not will face both set-up and running costs, which may be offset over time as a result of increased or more efficient platform-use. The cost of such mechanisms varies considerably according to the size of the platform. These costs can be estimated to lie in the range of a 0.4 to 1% increase in the cost base for smaller platform companies, and a one-off cost of 0.03% of total turnover for larger ones. While the administrative burden resulting from this particular measure may not always be completely offset, platforms may in many cases be able to develop intelligent solutions to lower costs, such as using the same or similar technologies and operational structures for customer support to also provide for internal redress for businesses. They are also likely to have a commercial incentive to follow the example of larger players. Therefore, the actual additional cost is likely to be lower and likely to be on top of sunk costs for investments already made. The cost is therefore expected to be limited in all cases but can be estimated to be largest for the smallest companies, in relative terms. This supports considering an exemption of certain categories of companies. The majority of platform business models generate income from commissions on transactions concluded between business users and consumers.
The obligation to allow for P2B disputes to be escalated internally is not likely to fundamentally change the economics of running an online platform: most platforms already possess such systems, meaning that they are fully compatible with the intermediary business model. The options also preserve the platform operators' flexibility and ability to curate the content. In addition, there is no clear evidence to suggest that the additional costs would necessarily be passed on to either party in the intermediated transactions, because most online platforms in their early stage of development run losses in order to capture a wide user base on both sides of their networked market. The costs of the external organisations that can provide industry-specific mediators will be determined by the set-up chosen by industry. However, they are also likely to be limited, not least because online platforms will be incentive to spread the costs widely across the entire industry. Online general search engines will not be under an obligation to engage in good faith in mediation, and they are therefore equally excluded from the obligation on the Commission to encourage the setting up of industry-specific mediation organisations. This reflect the issue-specific approach taken in respect of online general search engines, which exclusively covers ranking transparency. Contacts with industry show that industry is willing to take part in voluntary initiatives of this kind, mitigating the risk of low-industry buy-in. In addition, the use of mediation has been shown to limit costs (e.g. for litigation) when it is successful, so the shared investment in a trusted mediation body amounts to savings elsewhere.
The compliance cost associated with giving legal standing to business associations to act on behalf of business users to enforce the foreseen legal obligations can be estimated qualitatively as follows. On the one hand, additional legal costs may arise for online platforms if they have to defend against cases brought under the enforcement provision of the rules. At the same time, the regulatory assumption is that compliance with the mostly one-off transparency obligations will be high, especially in light of the proposed monitoring efforts, and the technical legal grey zones would be small, and therefore limited costs arising from litigation would be incurred. Safeguards against frivolous litigation include limiting the nature of cases that can be brought to injunctive relief (and not compensatory), and requiring that associations are non-profit in character.
Finally, the reporting obligation relating to the internal complaint-handling mechanism that is included in all co-regulatory policy options will be designed to limit costs for the platforms concerned. The reporting obligation would cover a limited number of elements such as the total number of complaints received, the subject matter of the complaints, the time period needed to process the complaints and the decision taken. Online platforms can largely automate data collection and reporting. Many collect this type of information already for quality management purposes and would, therefore, only incur very limited costs for transmitting the data to the EU Observatory on a regular basis.
6.2.2.2Impact on smaller online platforms
SME online platforms will also benefit from the growth of the platforms environment. At the same time, all retained co-regulatory options will entail limited, mostly one-off costs associated directly with changes to contractual terms and conditions to accommodate the legal obligations in relation to transparency (cf. Annex 12.2 for a more detailed description of impacts). The enhanced transparency that would result from the implementation of the foreseen legal transparency obligations can benefit smaller online platforms as there will be more scope for competitive differentiation. At the same time, any costs resulting from possibly increased litigation are expected to be limited, given the principles-based nature of these obligations, and the important scope for implementation by industry. Small online platform providers will accordingly be able to exclude any significant litigation costs by providing transparency at a general level, while staying abreast of, or getting involved - should they voluntarily opt to do so - in industry discussions on codes of conduct on each of the various potentially harmful trading practices.
Option 2a implies in this regard, relative to the other co-regulatory options, the lowest number of legally binding obligations and therefore the most limited cost increase compared to the baseline. Option 2b allows addressing the unfair practices identified while preserving platforms' ability to set freely their business strategies. The compliance cost entailed by Option 2c could possibly be higher for smaller online general search engines which have not developed guidance for businesses on how to optimise their appearance in search results. These firms could however try to limit their compliance costs by using as an example the existing transparency provisions developed by bigger online general search engines. A transparency rule for search engines would indeed help spread best practices and possibly creates incentives for small platforms to use quality saliency of information/data, or to guarantee absence of any conflict of interests (e.g. concerning advertising-based business models) as criteria of competitive differentiators. The main argument against ranking-related transparency obligations is that spammers could game online general search engines, which would be detrimental to society. The proposed transparency obligation would not, however, require disclosing any trade secrets and foresees an important scope for industry efforts to provide practical tools for meaningful transparency – including ways to prevent the gaming of search results. While the marginal cost of adding the transparency requirements should therefore not be overestimated, policy option 2d may create higher costs for small platforms. The need to share email addresses with business users who have obtained consumers' consent may put constraints on small platforms in their development phase, preventing them from scaling up. Option 2d may therefore have a negative impact on small platforms. Option 2a implies in this regard, relative to the other co-regulatory options, the lowest number of legally binding obligations and therefore the most limited cost increase compared to the baseline.
Imposing new legislation could in theory lead to increased difficulties for new market entrants. In this case it can rather be expected that the provisions will provide start-ups with greater clarity on the requirements they need to comply with across the EU when entering the market thus benefitting from a more predictable regulatory environment. Such legal transparency requirements could also provide additional competitive parameters that can be leveraged to distinguish the start-up platforms from established players and thereby enhance market entry. At the same time, while an efficient and speedy internal dispute resolution process could be possibly ensured through automated systems - chatbots can be used for a first screening of complaints, with justified claims eventually being dealt with in person - the creation of an internal escalation mechanism, may require that small platforms put in place processes that go beyond their current capacities.
This type of considerations raises the question whether specific thresholds are needed to exempt some types of enterprises from the proposed regulation. Irrespective of which of the four retained options would appear as the most appropriate on the basis of the comparative analysis performed in Section 7, the evaluation of the regulatory burden of this Initiative requires an assessment of whether micro-enterprises or other categories of companies should be exempted from its scope in line with the Think Small First
and the Better Regulation principles
. The following section analyses this question.
6.2.2.3Impacts for Options for thresholds for exemption
Several questions arise when considering options for thresholds: For which measures are thresholds needed? If they are needed, how should they be set? Which measurements or proxies can be used to determine their level and to verify compliance easily?
The main considerations in relation to thresholds concern the degree to which the underlying problem analysis applies to smaller online platforms and the regulatory burden which would stem from the proposed intervention. Different "threshold" possibilities are considered below while Section 8 dealing with the preferred policy option presents the conclusions of the analysis.
(A): A threshold exempting some categories of online platforms from those measures for which a significant impact cannot be excluded, based on impacts assessed above
One option would be to exempt smaller platforms from those measures for which an administrative burden cannot be fully excluded, i.e. from the most burdensome measures in relative terms. This approach would mean that the relevant legal transparency obligations foreseen under the various co-regulatory options apply to all online platforms, while the internal redress mechanism which appears more costly (cf. Section 6.2.1.2) is not applicable to a certain category of smaller platforms.
As to the precise setting of the threshold, the SME definition based on the double criterion of staff headcount and turnover/balance sheet has been considered. The question is whether the threshold should be set at the level of a small or micro-enterprise? Available data does not allow drawing a clear distinction between the impacts of the internal redress on these two types of platforms. In order to avoid any disproportionate burden it seems therefore more appropriate to exempt all online platforms constituting a small enterprise (< 50 employees) from the obligation to provide for an internal complaint-handling mechanism. This would support the scaling up of both start-up and emerging small platforms.
By excluding platforms with < 50 employees from the internal redress measure, 47% of all EU platforms would be exempted from this specific obligation, while a large proportion of all transactions would nonetheless be covered
. This option would reflect the light-touch approach behind the transparency requirements which would apply to all companies. The extra burden associated with the initiative would be limited, and the measure may provide a competitive edge to very small platforms who want to build a customer base; they would be able to attract customers by offering them clear and transparent terms and conditions, similarly to bigger platforms.
Instead of using the staff headcount and/or turnover, an option would be to use different proxies when defining the thresholds, such as number of website visits/month (as in the Loi Lemaire), or number of registered users (as the German NetzDG definition). This would potentially allow targeting the exemption more narrowly to start-up and scale-up platforms that can be guaranteed not (yet) to have significant user bases. These metrics are however disconnected from need to limit the impact of the cost of internal complaint-handling, as even online platforms having significantly less than 50 employees may command relatively large user bases; these firms have frequently been seen not yet to generate any turnover and may precisely be unable to absorb such costs. Also, large variations in user numbers or website visits are possible depending on the date, either seasonal or due to fast growth periods, leading to uncertainty for the business on whether it is concerned or not by the rules. Basing thresholds on number of registered users would also decrease platforms' incentives to increase their user base thus artificially limiting network effects which are at the core of platforms' business models. Although the number of website visits and active users are routinely measured by online platforms themselves, they are not publicly reported. The criteria used in the SME definition seem therefore more appropriate for the purpose of setting a meaningful threshold.
(B): A horizontal threshold exempting some categories of platforms (micro- or small-) from the entire measure
This option may be designed to exempt from the entire measure those platforms which qualify either for micro- or for small-enterprises. Excluding exclusively micro-enterprises from the entire measure would risk putting the threshold too low, thus imposing the more burdensome internal redress obligations to platforms which may not be ready yet to absorb such measure as many such companies are still in the seed phase. As explained above, the proportionality principle rather suggests for not only micro- but also small enterprises to be exempted from those measures for which the regulatory burden may be more significant. On the other hand, if a single horizontal threshold is set for all small platforms, this would imply that almost half of all existing online platforms are exempted. This may appear unjustified given the light touch approach of the legal transparency requirements proposed, the exemption of these platforms from the most burdensome obligation and the fact that platforms having between 10 and 50 employees can already fulfil an important gateway function. Thus, a horizontal threshold applicable to the entire initiative, while clear and simple for implementation, does not appear appropriate to the measures proposed. The latter rather call for a targeted threshold taking into consideration in particular the more burdensome nature of the internal redress rule.
(C) A dual threshold combining (A) and (B)
Another option would be to combine the internal-redress related threshold with a general micro-enterprise exemption applicable to the entire measure (C).
(D): No threshold – the proposed measure applies horizontally to all platforms
This option would imply that not only the relevant legal transparency requirements would be applicable to all types of platforms but all proposed obligations. In light of the above explained need to account for the more burdensome nature of the internal redress mechanism, option D does not appear to constitute an effective alternative.
Table 3 shows the distribution of employees in EU and Global Platform businesses, including search engines (red colour in the table)
.
Table 3: Distribution of employees in EU and Global Platform businesses
Staff headcount
|
Number of EU Platform Businesses
|
Number of Global Platform Businesses
|
<10
|
1772 + 34 = 1806 = 25%
|
3333 + 82 = 3415
|
<50
|
3298 + 82 = 3380 = 47%
|
6472 + 160 = 6632
|
<200
|
3904 + 113 = 4017 = 56%
|
7871 + 194 = 8099
|
|
Total EU Platform Businesses
= 7012 + 113 = 7125
|
Total number of Global Platform Businesses = 19526 + 194 = 19720
|
Impact on non-EU platforms
According to data available to the Commission there would currently be approximately 12 500 non-EU platforms active in the market world-wide. The elements presented for the co-regulatory options are applicable to EU platforms and would apply equally to these non-EU platforms, if they intermediate between EU business users and consumers located in the EU. While the measures would not restrict the platforms' freedom to determine the law and forum applicable to contractual issues, these clauses should not prevent the enforcement in (EU) courts of the envisaged P2B rules by business users - obviously in full compliance with private international law, including the Hague Convention or the Rome I, Rome II and Brussels Ibis Regulations. The mediation possibilities which would be offered constitute a considerable change to the current situation in which EU business users do not have any other choice but to revert to the extra-EU court set by a non-EU platform in its terms and conditions. However, it should be noted that submitting to the outcome of mediation proceedings will remain voluntary, both for EU and non-EU platforms.
Impact on business users
Compliance costs linked to the co-regulatory options will not have a short term effect on the fees and commissions applied by online platforms. Compliance costs linked to establishing transparent terms and conditions are, as explained in the previous sections, limited and apply to platforms, not their business users. Certain platforms might decide to use the opportunity created by the implementation of a legislative initiative to increase the fees applied to business users, who may in turn pass these on to consumers. If these increases were to be substantial, the effects described above would be limited by a dampening effect on sales. However, it is unlikely that platforms will significantly increase their levels of fees or commissions, as the compliance costs of the co-regulatory options are limited and because business models in the platform economy frequently accept growth at high internal costs in order to acquire users on both sides of the platform, in order to leverage the network effects.
In the event that platforms consider transferring the additional costs incurred onto the sellers, the additional burden on the business user is foreseen to be highly limited. Using the estimates under 6.2.1, should platforms transfer the entirety of the one-off cost of setting up an internal redress mechanism towards its existing business users, the additional cost increase for each seller is foreseen to be minute. Beyond the increased sales through platforms, the creation of an effective redress mechanism will be particularly positive for business users. In combination with the greater clarity provided by the transparency measures on the reasons for differences with platforms, business users will have a greater chance of quickly and effectively solving disputes with online platforms. This may mean that more business users find grounds under which they can take problematic cases to court, using for instance collective interest litigation. Nonetheless, it will be in the interest of both business users and platforms to make greater use of the possibilities offered by mediation, which both co-regulatory options make more readily available. Mediation has been shown to be a more flexible and cost-effective solution. A European Parliament study on the cost of (non-)mediation has shown that an average cost to litigate in the EU is more than € 10,000, while the average cost to mediate is approx. € 2,500. Therefore when mediation is successful, it could save € 7,500 per dispute
.
As regards potential retaliatory actions from platforms towards the businesses active on them, neither of the options retained is estimated likely to trigger them. The fear of retaliation expressed in parts of the stakeholder consultation process concerned measures taken by certain platforms against individual businesses, or groups of businesses, as payback for specific actions. The co-regulatory options retained do not, however, single out particular businesses or specific actions that might single out a particular business to a platform. They rather increase clarity on the grounds for suspension or termination on the use of a platform, how ranking operates including mechanisms that allow business users to influence their prominence etc. and give more time to react to changes in terms and conditions or understand why a decision has been taken to delist or suspend them. Furthermore, the specific measures put forward in the proposal (redress mechanisms, observatory, etc.) contain safeguards against businesses being endangered for making use of the new functions: the use of external mediators must fit the criteria of anonymity and independence, the internal redress mechanisms would be open for use to all the businesses on a platform, therefore making it hard for the platform to reasonably single out and punish against one single business, etc. In addition, a platform choosing not to adopt the new features designed to enhance trust and increase the quality of the experience for a business would find itself at a disadvantage compared to other platforms that choose to attract businesses by improving the quality of the seller's experience, and therefore, risk losing its market share among sellers.
None of the options will create significant costs for SME business users. On the contrary, SME users of platforms stand to gain from measures that will provide them with greater ease of doing business and enhanced legal certainty. This includes in particular the measures on transparency and minimum notice periods for changes to terms and conditions, transparency on the reasons for suspension or delisting, and transparency on the criteria for paid ranking results. These measures would lead to savings for smaller business users, as they would be spared the costs linked to reinstating accounts or products that have been blocked. In the case of paid-for ranking results, the increased transparency around the auctions oftentimes used to award increased visibility would be beneficial to smaller business users, as they could either choose not to participate where the resulting ranking is unlikely to be satisfactory, thus saving them the cost of participation, or choose to participate, and gain increased exposure. This was confirmed in the replies to the Commission's consultation of SMEs through the Small Business Act Follow-up Group.
Businesses' turnover is in addition directly impacted by the visibility they get on online general search engines. A transparency obligation on ranking in general search, such as foreseen under policy option 2c, would allow more predictability for business users. As explained in section 2.1.1.3, the legal transparency obligation on ranking would thereby additionally cover 20%-30% of total Internet traffic received by online platforms and respectively >50% and >70% of Internet traffic received by retailers' and hotels' own websites. Given the regular and high rate of algorithms changes done by online general search engines, such obligation would help businesses to develop better informed search optimisation strategies. This would be particularly beneficial for enterprises with little or no online presence.
6.3Impact on public authorities
National authorities will not be directly impacted by any of the co-regulatory options. Over time, the obligation on platforms to list national mediators in their terms and conditions and to engage with them in good faith might lead to more P2B cases being brought before such mediators. Mediation is a private activity which will not impact public authorities. Member States will moreover not be required to adapt their existing certification schemes for mediators; those that already have such schemes in place will simply provide this existing service also for any new mediators that may enter the specialised area of P2B relations. Any possible burden on national court systems is also expected to remain limited as a result of the layered design of the legal redress provisions. All co-regulatory options rely on out-of-court, alternative dispute settlement mechanisms to solve substantive issues arising between business users and online platforms. The legal provision granting standing to business associations is a tool to encourage online platforms to actually engage in these out-of-court mechanisms to effectively resolve disputes without having to resort to national courts. In Member States, the mere threat of possible collective interest litigation is a sufficient deterrent to encourage industry compliance with obligations. It will not be possible for these associations, as representatives of the business users, to rely on the foreseen legal instrument to instigate court cases concerning substantive issues relevant to individual business users. Rather such cases shall be limited to the prevention or termination of non-compliance with the obligations in the foreseen legal instrument, which will be limited to those that do not make the necessary adaptations.
6.4Impact on innovation, competitiveness, competition
Online platforms are important drivers and enablers of innovation (Section 2.3.5), thus contributing to digital transformation of the economy and enhancing businesses' competitiveness. Business users, in turn, are important innovators, using the innovation-enabling software "building blocks" and market access provided to them by online platforms. The millions of sellers active on e-commerce market places provide constant feedback to online platform operators on logistical, software and commercial problems encountered and on possible innovative ways to address them. App developers provide a constantly improving richness of content that no single platform could have imagined or engineered. Research confirms this key role played by communities, networks and user involvement in platform innovation. Regulatory action on P2B relations could hamper the innovation capacity of online platform ecosystems only if it were too interventionist, as it would divert resources from innovation activities to regulatory compliance activities. All retained options are designed to be proportionate and do not interfere with platforms' business models. The coherence with innovation is indeed also a specific criterion against which each content option has been checked (see table 2 in Annex 10). Conversely, the impact in terms of innovation on the side of business users can be similarly expected to be positive, as business users trading via platforms can benefit from a more predictable and contestable business environment and focus even more on product and service improvements and innovation.
All co-regulatory options that aim at releasing the full potential of the online platform economy can thus positively impact innovation both on the side of the platforms and of the business users. It is legitimate to expect an increase in platforms' innovation expenses under options 2a, 2b and 2c. Different from them, policy option 2d may have a negative impact on innovation, as data lies at the centre of platforms' business models. The innovation-related considerations for each policy options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d are detailed in Annex 12.4.1.
In terms of competitiveness, EU-based online platforms will not be undermined by the proposed measures, irrespective of the policy option chosen. On the contrary, the platform ecosystem may be expected to become more competitive as a result of this initiative aiming at greater predictability for the platform ecosystem. Policy options 2a, 2b and 2c will, although to a different extent, have a positive or neutral impact on the three components of competitiveness as defined in the Better Regulation toolbox, i.e. price- , innovation- and international competitiveness. Notwithstanding their broader scope, policy options 2b and 2c are light-touch and do not imply significant costs for online platforms. Also, since all platforms intermediating between EU-based business users and consumers will have to comply with the measure, any risk of European platforms being undercut by platforms not complying with the proposed measure is minimal. Rather than driving operators of online platforms out of Europe, the proposed measure is estimated to increase trust and lead to an increase in the number of businesses present on online platforms. The impact of option 2d on competitiveness is more difficult to predict: its immediate impact on business users would be increased revenues due to improved customer base but it may affect negatively platforms. If it leads to their reduced ability to innovate and compete, this effect could be passed on business users in the longer term (cf. annex 12.4.2).
In terms of competition, the co-regulatory options retained would set a standard for higher quality of service thus creating the opportunity for start-up platforms to compete on the basis of the better business environment they would offer to professional users. Options 2a, 2b and 2c would thus likely create the right regulatory environment for increased competition as compared to the baseline scenario on both sides of the market - among platforms and among businesses present on these platforms. Increased competition could be expected to lead to higher quality products/services provided to business- and end-users.
Under option 2a, the mandatory transparency provides additional competitive parameters for start-up platform companies. Even small increases in user trust will equally support the growth of existing platforms as well as the emergence of start-up platforms. Increased transparency though non-binding for some of the issues would possibly give the right signal to more businesses to use online intermediation; this could in return lead to more competition.
In option 2b, the increased trust resulting from the resolution of disputes with online platforms will expand the business user base of existing platforms. This will feed into the existing network effects laid out in the problem statement. The resulting renewed dynamism of the platform economy would a priori allow the emergence of new, small platforms. Legally binding transparency rules on all six issues identified and appropriate redress tools could also be expected to contribute to more competition among business users.
Option 2c would extend these above effects to online general search engines and the business users who use them as a gateway to customers. This option may be expected to have an indirect positive effect through enhanced transparency as a complementary tool to competition law.
The positive effect on online platforms will be more limited in option 2d, where the risk of free-riding by business users is greater; the number of business users active on platforms may not increase as much, if platforms are faced with the need to redesign their business strategies. The dynamics behind each of the four options are explained more in detail in Annex 12.4.3.
6.5Employment and social impact
The overall impact of the co-regulatory options on social welfare including in particular employment and related social impact are likely to be positive, building further on the 4.7 million jobs which can be roughly attributed as being generated by business users in the platform economy. As described above the measures aiming to full potential of the online platform economy will lead to an increase in turnover for both business users and platforms. The increase of business users' turnover may be expected to lead to increased employment opportunities. This expectation would probably be less valid for online platforms despite the fact that they will see their revenues from commissions increasing (as a result of the increase in sales over platforms). Given that platforms are innovation-driven, it would be difficult to predict whether they would use increased revenues to create additional jobs instead of investing in research and development.
In addition, while the primary impacts of the initiative are of an economic nature, some beneficial social impact in particular for self-employed individuals is conceivable. A large part of sellers on e-commerce market places are self-employed individuals, with 89% of all sellers achieving a turnover of less than € 50,000. In addition, both options will cover collaborative economy platforms to the extent these host professional users. Whether a user of a platform is considered professional or not depends on national rules in the EU. However, the proposed obligations would lead to greater transparency, predictability, and certainty for all users. Overall, although difficult to quantify, it is therefore reasonable to assume that the proposed options will provide more predictability also to the benefit of a large number of particularly vulnerable economic actors. The net benefit of the initiative – improved businesses' access to innovation and business opportunities created by inline platforms, increased competition leading to lower prices, higher quality and broader choice for consumers of goods and services offered on online platforms - should outweigh the costs.
6.6Impact on consumers
The impacts on consumers in terms of costs, choice and trust can be estimated as follows.
In terms of costs for consumer, the nature of the platform economy business-model (focused on consumer acquisition even at a loss, attention economy, generally low switching costs in many markets), combined with the proportionate nature of the obligations in all the retained options indicates that costs for consumers would not increase. On the contrary, the expected increase in the number of platforms and businesses active on these platforms would likely lead to increased choice for consumers on online platforms and increased competition among business users for these consumers, thus better prices and quality.
Option 2d, however, might increase in some consumer costs as platforms may be partially deprived of one of their key assets, i.e. consumer data. As the exact share of consumers who would agree to this measure is difficult to estimate, it is equally difficult to determine whether platforms would pass on possible losses from this measure to consumers.
When analysing impacts on consumers under option 2c, it is important to underline the value added that online general search engines have brought for them – in one-click consumers have access to a huge variety of information, businesses, goods and services. While the ranking transparency obligation does not target "consumer users" (i.e. searchers), a transparency obligation would indirectly contribute to safeguarding and possibly strengthening this positive effect. A transparency obligation would incentivise search engine operators to be more cautious and transparent in those instances where there a conflict of interest could exist between their own services and competitors' services. This would possibly contribute to a more impartial and pro-competitive outcome for consumers.
Business-oriented fair practices would also complement consumer protection rules, thus enhancing end-users trust in the platform economy, giving them confidence in buying online thus benefitting from larger cross-border offer. This could support the existing trend of growing consumer trust in e-commerce. More than one in two Europeans now buy online (55% of consumers in 2016). Since 2014, consumers' levels of trust have increased by 12 percentage points for purchases from retailers located in the same country (72.4% of consumers are confident buying online in their own country) and by 21 % for purchases from other EU Member States (57.8%).
6.7Environmental impact
No direct environmental impact of the measure is expected.
6.8Impact on fundamental rights
All co-regulatory options fully comply with the Charter of Fundamental Rights ("CFR"), in particular with Articles 8, 16 and 47 CFR. The rationale behind this initiative is to establish a more balanced commercial relationship, while ensuring that platforms maintain full discretion over their business concepts. The underlying analysis showing this compliance is available in annex 12.8.
6.9Summary of impacts of the retained policy options
Summary of impacts of retained options
Type of impact
|
Option 2a
|
Option 2b
|
Option 2c
|
Option 2d
|
Internal market fragmentation
|
Neutral to positive: legal transparency and redress measures will increase legal certainty. However, with various high-impact trading practices being left to self-regulation (ranking, data, discrimination, MFNs), this options may not prevent direct harm to businesses. The effect of EU monitoring / pushing reputational levers will also be less pronounced in the absence of legal transparency obligations on all high-impact trading practices. The risk of fragmentation thus remains large since national authorities would continue intervening to solve existing imbalances.
|
Positive: reduced need to intervene at national level to resolve them. The new rules together with the EU observatory will help allow building a common EU understanding of what issues are, thus also allowing for more consistent regulatory approaches when such are deemed necessary at national level.
|
As in option 2b: transparency and redress measures will increase legal certainty, and monitoring tools will help limit further fragmentation.
|
As in previous options 2b and 2c: transparency and redress measures will increase legal certainty, and monitoring tools will help limit further fragmentation.
|
Growth
|
Neutral to positive: increase in trust in the platform environment will support growth in sales, while limited legal obligations represent minimal compliance costs. Leaving high-profile issues such as ranking, data, discrimination and MFNs to self-regulation can however undermine some of the trust-building effect of the legal measures on terms & conditions, delisting and redress, following increasing awareness and concern among businesses.
|
Positive: increase in trust in the platform environment will support growth in sales realised on online platforms. This impact, positive both for platforms and business users would contribute to mitigating possible impact of compliance costs. The expected growth of the platform economy in conjunction with foreseen growth of online activities could be expected to contribute to digital growth within the internal market.
|
Positive impacts as in Option 2b, extended also to the online general search environment.
|
Uncertain: risk of free-riding by business users limits positive impact on sales realised on online platforms. While growth in the online intermediation could be suboptimal, it could possibly be compensated to some extent by growth in online sales on business users' own websites.
|
Platforms
|
Minimal costs: The legal transparency obligations on terms and conditions and delisting imply only limited costs for platforms while allowing them to benefit from increased trust.
Smaller platforms are exempted from the most burdensome internal redress mechanism obligation. The two-step approach will ensure that thresholds are adapted if needed to respond to the evolution of the fast-changing platform economy. Threshold for small platforms will support emergence of new players.
|
Limited costs: the impacts of 2a are also valid here. The extension of the legally binding nature of the requirements to all areas of issues would create some additional one-off and running costs as compared to 2a. These costs remain limited to ensure the effectiveness of the obligations and exempt small platforms from disproportionate burden (possibility for thresholds to be reviewed in a second step). The limited regulatory costs are expected to be outweighed by the increased growth opportunities for platforms (more sales would also translate in increased commissions for platforms) created by positive indirect network effects. Small platforms can benefit from appropriate thresholds to grow. A clear and predictable regulatory environment would also support emergence of new players.
|
Limited costs: the extension of the ranking transparency requirement and parts of redress would create some limited costs for online general search engines. The additional trust for search engines which would result from the initiative is expected to counterbalance the limited costs.
|
Negative to neutral: While thresholds may help small platforms to develop new business models, this option may impact platforms' business strategies. It does imply relatively high costs for platforms without creating benefits to compensate for costs.
|
Business users
|
Positive: proposed measure, while not binding for all issues, would offer a higher quality experience for business users.
|
Positive: Business users would benefit from greater predictability. Clarity of platforms' policies and improved access to redress would allow businesses to better grasp the innovation and business opportunities offered by online intermediaries. Business users' sales would grow as a result from their increased trust in the platform economy and stemming strengthened network effects.
|
Positive: In addition to benefits identified under option 2a, businesses would be able to develop better informed search optimisation strategies. This would be particularly beneficial for SMEs and enterprises with no or emerging online presence.
|
Positive to neutral: In addition to benefits under option 2c, option 2d would allow business users to expand their customer base. Potentially negative effects are however not to be excluded in the longer term if platforms' environment dynamics change as a result of option 2d's impact on platforms' business strategies.
|
Public administrations
|
Limited costs: legal obligations require mostly one-off implementation and are easy to monitor. Moreover, instead of relying on public enforcement that would have to be financed by national or EU administrations, the co-regulatory design of this policy option foresees private litigation by representative associations and therefore implies no additional costs. Finally, the Commission will bear the costs of EU Observatory and portal.
|
As Option 2a.
|
As Option 2a.
|
As option 2a.
|
Employment and Social impact
|
Neutral to positive: growth of the platform economy will contribute to maintaining the 4.7 million jobs created by business users of platforms.
|
Positive: as in option 2b but the maintaining effect on employment could be expected to be stronger due to the additional incentives provided by the legal character of transparency measures for all six issues. Expected positive social impact.
|
Positive: As option 2b, option 2c could be expected to lead to increased employment opportunities for businesses dependent on online platforms and on general search engines. Should the positive effect be more limited than expected, option 2c would contribute to maintaining existing jobs.
|
Uncertain: impact would depend on whether the immediate effect of possible increase in number of jobs by business users would outweigh possible job cuts. The latter would be due to potential decrease in business opportunities in the platform economy as a result of option 2d – related obligations.
|
Innovation
|
Neutral to positive: any action injecting trust would increase sales, thus creating revenues for innovation. However, as with the foreseen impact on growth, the limited scope of the legal transparency obligations can undermine some of the trust-building effect of the intervention and thereby limit the positive impact on innovation.
|
Positive: growth of sales will create revenues for innovation both for platforms and business users.
|
Positive: Better insight in ranking policies could help business users grasp innovation opportunities offered online.
|
Negative: may interfere with platforms' ability to develop new data-driven services and products. This could in turn reduce innovation opportunities offered to business users.
|
Competitiveness
|
Neutral to positive: costs will be particularly limited and price-competitiveness therefore unaffected; innovation could increase and support international competitiveness.
|
Positive: competitiveness would be reinforced through the enhanced incentives for platforms to compete on the basis of greater transparency and increased quality of service. Positive impact on trust and presumably growth of the sector would support international competitiveness through increased innovation opportunities for business users and platforms. Start-up and small platforms could use increased transparency and redress standards (incentivised through the measure) to build a competitive advantage.
|
Positive: As in option 2b. In addition, if greater insight in SEO leads businesses to access new markets and embrace innovation (cf. above) this could translate in strengthened positive impact on competitiveness.
|
Negative to neutral: limited impact on price-competitiveness but negative impact on innovation and international competitiveness.
|
Competition
|
Positive: the mandatory transparency provides additional competitive parameters for start-up platform companies. Even small increases in user trust will equally support the growth of existing platforms as well as the emergence of startup platforms.
|
Positive: expansion of user base will support emergence of new, small platforms.
|
Positive: Increased pro-competitive effect among platforms through enhanced transparency. Potential indirect effect: competition among business users could potentially increase due to greater insight in ranking policies.
|
Negative to neutral: as for option 2c but the business model of platforms may be impacted by sharing of data, which makes the effect uncertain on inter-platform competition. Uncertainty is also true for business- and end- users – the potential positive effect expected could be counteracted by consumers concluding fewer transactions because of the increased burden to prior respond to email sharing requests.
|
Consumers
|
Neutral to positive: linked to growth, the limited scope of the legal transparency obligations can undermine some of the trust-building effect of the intervention and thereby limit the positive impact on consumer choice.
|
Positive: improved P2B relations will allow maintaining and possibly increasing consumers' choice in terms of quality goods and services offered at a competitive price. Legal transparency obligation on ranking combined with EU monitoring may in addition have particularly important indirect positive effect for consumers that will be able to make more informed purchasing decisions.
|
Positive indirect effect: could contribute to a more impartial, pro-competitive outcome in the form of higher relevance results being more easily identifiable.
|
Uncertain: sharing of data is a direct burden for consumers. If considered too heavy by them, the email-related obligation may result in reduced purchase on online platforms. This could negatively affect indirect network effects and lead in the long term to reduced consumer choice.
|
Environment
|
Neutral
|
Neutral
|
Neutral
|
Neutral
|
Fundamental rights
|
The legal transparency and redress measures will help safeguard the freedom to contract (to conduct a business), by improving the situation for business users without affecting online platforms' freedom to determine their business concepts implemented in general terms and conditions. These measures will also improve the right of access to justice for business users, by addressing importing barriers to accessing cross-border justice.
|
Legal measures on technically complex issues such as ranking imply some risk of legal uncertainty for online platforms, which should however be alleviated by the co-regulatory design that uses technologically neutral legal principles to be implemented by industry. These measures combined with the legal redress measures at the same time ensure the appropriate respect for business users' freedom to contract as well as for their right of access to justice.
|
The targeted legal transparency obligation on ranking in online general search strengthens the positive impact of policy options 2a and 2b on business users' right to conduct their business, while leaving the corresponding right of providers of online general search engines unaffected.
|
Article 8 CFR is safeguarded, as compliance with GDPR would be ensured. The data sharing obligation however risks negatively affecting online platforms' freedom to conduct a business.
|
7Comparison of options
7.1Comparative analysis of retained co-regulatory options
This Section discusses the effectiveness, efficiency, coherence and proportionality of the four retained policy options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d (such as defined in Table 1 and summarised in the introduction to Section 6) in comparison with the baseline scenario. The baseline scenario (option 0) as basis for comparison is described in Section 2.4 and 5.1.
All four retained options consist of measures on transparency and redress, and are intended to leverage the foreseen enhanced monitoring of the platform economy
. The options are largely similar with respect to the redress (see Section 7.1.1 in this respect) and monitoring tools proposed. The comparison of the options on the basis of their effects against the baseline would hence mainly be influenced by the nature of the transparency obligations in each of the options: option 2a imposes legal transparency obligations on two out of the six most frequently observed, potentially harmful trading practices, option 2b proposes legal transparency obligations also in respect of the four practices left to self-regulation in 2a; option 2c extends the legally binding transparency obligation on ranking also in a targeted manner to the issue of ranking in online general search, while option 2d adds the obligation for platforms to provide any business user with the opportunity to ask, in line with the GDPR, for customers' consent for the business to obtain and process their e-mail addresses after the completion of a transaction and the payment of the commission to the respective platform. The fact that the vast majority of platforms do not allow this has been identified as a crucial problem for business users related to data as described in Section 2.1.1.
Effectiveness
Objective 1: Ensuring a fair, transparent and predictable treatment of business users by online platforms
Options 2b, 2c and 2d address the potentially harmful trading practices identified in the problem statement thus contributing to ensuring a fair and predictable business environment for platforms’ business users. In particular, (i) the transparency requirements on ranking, discrimination, data and MFN clauses, (ii) the obligation on platforms to provide information about substantial changes in terms and conditions, and to grant firms a reasonable notice period to adapt to the changes announced, and (iii) enhanced redress possibilities for platforms' professional users, together with the continuous monitoring of the platform ecosystem contribute to a fairer, more predictable and trusted business environment based on a set of enforceable rules.
Options 2b, 2c and 2d are all more effective in reaching the first specific objective as compared to the baseline, as they all provide for greater predictability and transparency on elements of the relationship between platforms and businesses. Given that the scope of the legal measures foreseen increases from policy option 2b to policy option 2d, the effectiveness of each of these three options as compared to the baseline also increases from 2b to 2d.
Option 2d is thus particularly effective in achieving specific objective 1 since it provides for a significant increase in transparency offered to business users who would in addition have access to email contacts of their customers. Option 2a differs in that the action it foresees to address four out of the six harmful trading practices is limited to self-regulation. By leaving significant issues in relation to transparency on data access policies, ranking, MFNs and discrimination to industry, option 2a is, however, likely to be less effective as the participation in self-regulatory schemes is less likely to be uniform across the Digital Single Market. Option 2a could thus be expected to lead only to a modest improvement over the baseline.
Options 2c and 2d foresee the inclusion of online general search engines in the initiative. These two options thus allow the initiative to simultaneously cover the two most important ranking-based originators of Internet traffic (online platforms and online general search engines). Options 2c and 2d appear therefore highly effective in achieving the objective of more transparent and predictable environment for businesses dependent on both online platforms and online general search engines. The effectiveness of Option 2b as regards Objective 1 is between that of Option 2a and 2c and 2d, and therefore intermediate.
Objective 2: Setting effective and agile redress for businesses, adaptable to the evolving market
All retained policy options offer solutions to the lack of redress issue identified (thus contributing to achieving specific objective 2) through the proposed set of enforcement measures. The latter consists of (i) the obligation to provide for effective internal complaint-handling, (ii) the obligation to identify mediators and to engage with them in good faith, and (iii) the provision on standing for business associations (collective injunctive redress). In addition, the redress-related measures include the dual call on industry to voluntarily (a) explore developing codes of conducts for the internal complaint-handling, and (b) set up an external independent redress mechanism at EU level responding to an effectiveness legal requirement. Whereas standing for business associations is meant exclusively to enforce the light-touch transparency & redress obligations in the P2B Regulation,
the obligations on internal complaint-handling and mediation are intended to allow business users to bring complaints on any substantial issues arising out of their contractual relationship with online platforms (including any alleged act in breach of any legal obligation).
Option 2a, can be expected to contribute to a more limited extent to offering effective redress for the four harmful trading practices of ranking, MFNs, discrimination and data left to self-regulation. In the absence of a regulatory backstop in the form of legal transparency principles and standing to enforce these transparency principles by business associations, business users could reasonably be expected to feel less empowered for these four specific practices to confront online platform providers in light of the very significant fear of retaliation.
As explained in Table 1, options 2c and 2d involve an issue-specific extension of the intervention to ranking in online general search. To ensure proportionality in light of the fundamental differences between online platforms and online general search engines (cf. section 2.1.1.3), the improved redress for issues with online general search engine providers will be limited to legal standing for business users' representative organisations.
The issue of ranking is nonetheless the most business-critical issue that has arisen in this context, hence its inclusion in the retained policy options policy (namely 2c and 2d) in the first place. The apparent reduced scope of issues that may be brought before the out-of-court redress mechanisms in relation to issues encountered with online general search engines (i.e. limited to ranking) as compared to the three categories of online platforms therefore does not negatively affect the effectiveness of policy options 2c and 2d. The latter options actually imply a higher degree of effectiveness in achieving specific objective 2, relative to options 2a and 2b, by virtue of the range of issues which can be challenged in a redress process.
Objective 3: Preserving a predictable and innovation-friendly legal environment for online platforms within the EU, without placing undue administrative burden on platforms
In addition, all three options 2b, 2c and 2d would set a harmonised legal framework for P2B relations on all core potentially harmful trading practices that have been observed, contributing to creating a predictable and innovation–friendly legal environment for platforms (specific objective 3). The platform economy would thus benefit from more consistent regulatory approaches across the EU.
None of the options aims to harmonise national B2B fairness legislations. Nonetheless, the legal framework the co-regulatory options propose, combined with (i) the increased industry involvement through voluntary commitments, and (ii) the collaborative monitoring with Member States would limit the legal fragmentation of the internal market and ensure a more harmonised EU approach to P2B practices across the EU, thereby supporting a more predictable regulatory environment at EU level and increasing businesses' trust thus benefitting the growth of the entire platform sector through amplified network effects.
Option 2a cannot meet the third specific objective of ensuring regulatory predictability for online platforms and general search engines since this option would not sufficiently contribute to addressing the emerging issue of legal fragmentation. This relatively weak effect would result, on the one hand, from less effective and patchier industry-led action on complex issues such as ranking in the absence of a principles-based harmonised legal backstop. On the other hand, leaving the four most controversial commercial issues observed (ranking, discrimination, data and MFNs) fully to self-regulation, while nonetheless introducing a legal framework for the overall P2B relationship within which these occur, risks increasing political pressure on national regulators to take more far-reaching action on these topics.
Options 2b and 2c, through a comprehensive set of measures could be expected to contribute to a general legal framework and EU level and increase platforms' innovation capacity. The option is therefore more effective than the baseline in ensuring an innovation–friendly legal environment for platforms as foreseen in specific objective 3.
This effect is not as clear under option 2d which risks running counter to platforms' innovation incentives. The obligation for platforms to allow business users to ask for customers' consent for further processing of their e-mail addresses impacts data which is a core element of platforms' business models. More information would be needed to assess the effects on competition and innovation as well as on any potential free-riding phenomenon. Option 2d thus risks being relatively ineffective in reaching specific objective 3.
Conclusion on Effectiveness
Option 2a incorporates - relative to the other co-regulatory policy options - the greatest degree of uncertainty in terms of its effectiveness to achieve specific objectives 1 and 2. It will nonetheless provide a legal framework for platform-to-business relations incorporating important redress provisions to help minimize frictions in platform-to-business relations. This framework will also leverage the foreseen enhanced monitoring of the online platform economy, including on those potentially harmful trading practices left to self-regulation. In absolute terms, policy option 2a can therefore be expected to contribute to achieving specific objectives 1 and 2 as compared to the baseline with moderate effectiveness. As regards specific objective 3 however, policy option 2a would have more limited effectiveness since it leaves a relatively large scope for fragmentation to increase.
Option 2b is effective as regards all three objectives: it provides a holistic set of transparency measures for a predictable business environment in areas that matter for businesses, while allowing redress for these issues, and at the same time providing an innovation-friendly business environment for online platforms.
Option 2c is more effective still since its expanded scope also covers online general search the expected positive effects of the transparency obligation and of the legal standing provision as appropriate and proportionate. Increased trust and legal certainty would extend also to the online general search environment. The extension of the scope to online general search engines would help optimising businesses' online visibility across the board. Greater transparency would also increase trust in online general search engines.
Option 2d appears effective in achieving the first and second specific objectives, but significantly less effective on objective 3, by potentially circumventing the business model of online platforms.
Efficiency
Option 2a is expected to lead to rather limited implementation costs. The broader range of issues left to self-regulation by industry suggest that option 2a would be less burdensome for platforms since they would be essentially free to respond to the call for transparency on a number of more complex and important commercial issues. At the same time, the benefits brought by this policy option could also be more limited by leaving four out of the six harmful trading practices out of the scope of the regulation. The limited costs should thus be compared with the more likely limited benefits.
Option 2b is a cost-efficient solution to ensure increased transparency, effective redress and, as under the other co-regulatory policy options retained, an appropriate monitoring of the platform economy. As described in Chapter 6 and Annex 4.1.2, the measures on transparency will require relatively small adjustments to be made by online platforms (one-off costs to adjust their terms and conditions, including legal and communication costs, and limited running costs when their terms and conditions change, which would be similar to the baseline scenario), and would provide greater legal certainty to business users.
The possible risk of any negative impact on legal certainty for online platforms is also limited, given the important scope for industry action in implementing the details, and the generally aligned incentives (as described in more detail in chapter 6). Exempting certain categories of online platforms (e.g. smaller ones) from the potentially more burdensome legal obligation to provide effective internal complaint-handling mechanisms, while enabling these firms to opt-in, would at the same time ensure that the cascade of legal obligations to provide redress is cost-efficient, in particular also in light of the co-regulatory design of the measure (building on existing best practices) and the largely aligned incentives of platforms and business users to minimize frictions.
The legal redress obligations also build on the out-of-court dispute settlement with a strong track record in solving P2B issues (online mediation) and open these for all business users, regardless of their size. The provision giving legal standing to representative organisations to bring injunctive actions to enforce the effectiveness of internal complaint-handling mechanisms and platforms' mediation efforts will in this regard help nudge even very small business users past their fear of retaliation, as they could anonymously report structural deficiencies. This effect will be further reinforced by the foreseen enhanced monitoring of the online platform economy. Research has also shown that collective redress measures are beneficial to SMEs
. Finally, the foreseen monitoring measures would create limited costs for public authorities, which would mostly be covered by running administrative budgets. And although the monitoring measures are light-touch, they have an immediate reputational effect and are important in informing the review of the intervention. Overall, option 2b is an efficient measure that effectively reaches the objectives of the action while limiting costs. While online platforms may face increased public scrutiny in areas of commercial relevance (like data access policies or the use of MFN clauses), increased transparency together with continuous EU monitoring of the platform economy and public scrutiny should yield increased trust and improved competition to the benefit of all market participants.
Option 2c would extend the compliance requirements to online general search engines. As explained in Section 6, these costs would be related to (i) the implementation of the ranking transparency obligations and (ii) the legal standing obligation from which some limited litigation costs could stem. The additional compliance costs are expected to be rather limited both for bigger search engines (which have provided SEO guidelines that could be usefully re-purposed for business users, or serve in some cases as inspiration for ways to provide meaningful transparency), and for smaller ones (since they would be able to equally draw from existing best practices). Assuming that meaningful transparency requirements are implemented, additional litigation costs would be limited to non-compliance cases. It is important to stress that this option does not generate costs due to loss of business or trade secrets related to disclosure of algorithms, as the requirements would be limited to providing necessary and sufficient information to provide businesses with an understanding of the link between ranking and features of their products and services, as well as the necessary predictability.
At the same time, by covering also ranking issues in online general search, Option 2c would create additional benefits. Businesses would be able to develop better informed search optimisation strategies, greater insight in which could lead businesses to access new markets and embrace innovation opportunities offered online, thus also enhancing their competitiveness. Option 2c could also be expected to have a pro-competitive effect between search engines and comparison sites through enhanced transparency, as public ranking policies can provide a greater scope for differentiation by start-ups, new entrants as well as existing players. Competition on quality of products and services among business users dependent on search engines for their marketing strategies could potentially also increase due to greater insight in ranking policies – to the extent such business users' website design are currently sub-optimal for achieving visibility. It is not excluded that Option 2c therefore equally contributes to a more impartial outcome for consumers in the form of higher relevance results being more easily identifiable. A transparency obligation set in EU law would strengthen businesses' ability to use such a provision in court proceedings. Finally, it would also be a helpful complement to enforcement tools under competition law since it would allow greater insight in possible discriminatory behaviours. The additional trust for search engines which would result from the initiative could be expected to counterbalance the limited costs.
The implementation costs of 2d stem from the additional measure (as compared to 2c) to allow consumers to express their consent to share some data with business users requires only a technical adjustment on the side of platforms, as the data itself can be shared through existing communication channels. Importantly, such a possibility for business users will be linked to the completion of a transaction on the respective platform and to the payment of the platform's commission. Nonetheless, if the sellers have their own sales channels, it may also allow them to circumvent the platform for future transactions and disrupt a core aspect of the platform business model. The increase in free-riding behaviour by business users could endanger online platforms' business models, resulting in decreases in sales through online platforms, limited innovation, and an increase in prices, including for consumers. As a result, despite its limited implementation costs, the negative impacts of option 2d are not negligible and it is not considered efficient in comparison with the baseline scenario.
Conclusion on Efficiency
All three Options 2a, 2b and 2c are efficient. Option 2a implies limited costs but its benefits would also be limited. Compared to Option 2b, Option 2c would create larger benefits even though these would also be achieved at a somewhat higher marginal cost. Option 2d appears inefficient; it would entail important costs while there is uncertainty as to the benefits it could bring.
Coherence
In their objectives, all retained co-regulatory options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d are coherent with the Digital Single Market Strategy, because they aim at ensuring a fair, open and secure digital environment such as announced in the Commission's DSM mid-term review. It needs to be noted however that the implementation of option 2d may not de facto lead to a strengthened Digital Single Market, as certain consequence of circumventing the platform's intermediation role are not fully understood. Given the importance of platform innovation and the importance of the platform economy for digital transformation and growth, option 2d may, by intervening in online platforms' business model, have a detrimental impact on platforms' incentives and opportunities to innovate and thus negatively impacting the growth potential of the Digital Single Market.
All retained co-regulatory policy options are also consistent with the Communication on Illegal Content, as measures providing greater clarity reasons for delisting will also support intermediary liability actions. Finally, the measures on redress included in both options are consistent with the New York Convention on Arbitration given that this Convention does not preclude the creation of platform-internal or external dispute settlement mechanisms.
All four retained options are in addition consistent with the Trade Secrets Directive
and any information or data lawfully acquired in a P2B2C relationship will continue to enjoy trade secret protection, if it falls under the definition in the Directive. Consistency with the GDPR is also ensured in both options, because the access to personal data remains subject to the full compliance with the GDPR, in particular on the further processing of e-mail addresses in option 3 requiring a valid and informed consent by the data subject as stipulated in Art. 6 of the GDPR.
All options are have been verified to be coherent with current proposals in the area of copyright (including the aspects related to press publishers rights), consumer law, and upcoming proposals in the field of taxation.
In addition, all four options are coherent with competition law. The Commission would continue using its competition law enforcement tools under all four co-regulatory options retained.
Finally, the definitions covered by all four options are coherent with definitions used in EU existing legislation and currently ongoing Commission initiatives. For the purpose of exhaustiveness, Section 8.3 of the Annex contains an exhaustive overview of all current and proposed definitions for comparison purposes. The Table in Annex 1.3 is an extract focusing on comparison/compatibility with major initiatives in the field of taxation and consumer protection.
Conclusion on Coherence
Options 2a, 2b and 2c are all three coherent with other EU policies and with fundamental rights. Option 2d appears not fully aligned with the objectives of the DSM strategy, as the straight circumvention might impact the platform ecosystem and slow down innovation.
Proportionality
EU level action is appropriate due to the intrinsically cross-border nature of online platforms. EU level action is the only way to provide the necessary high-level and harmonised legal framework for platforms to scale up, which is an indispensable condition for their business strategies and overall economic growth. From that perspective, all four retained policy options are appropriate since they provide for an action at EU level.
Option 2a is in principle proportionate since it provides, at limited costs, a comprehensive set of measures that could allow all three specific objectives to be achieved. However, by leaving issues around internal discrimination, data, ranking and MFNs to self-regulation, policy options 2a incorporates the risk of increased fragmentation. The proportionality of option 2a should thus be assessed in light of the extent to which the option contributes to achieving the objectives of the initiative.
Options 2b and 2c offer EU business users trading on platforms an improved and more predictable business environment. At the same time, platforms remain free to set the general policies for their market places and are offered the opportunity to shape their voluntary commitments by way of industry codes of conducts within a principles-based legal framework. These options thus avoid intrusive full-fledged legislation, providing instead an adequate response to these specific problems, whilst safeguarding the innovation capacity of platform firms. In addition, the important harmonising effect of the options will facilitate the scaling-up of online platforms to the benefit of all actors in online intermediated trade as harmonised EU rules will inherently lower compliance costs and enhance legal certainty in particular for cross-border operations.
Option 2c implies obligations also for online general search engines. Due to their somewhat different nature
, online general search engines (regardless of their size) have to index the largest possible number of websites, while also competing on the quality of their algorithms, which are therefore subject to, in some cases, thousands of changes every year. The scope for complaints against online general search engines could thus be higher and potentially concern a broader range of issues; the related litigation costs could thus also be important. In order to ensure the proportionality of the measure and avoid burdensome costs for online general search engines, option 2c foresees an issue-specific extension of the intervention to ranking in online general search. In addition to a targeted legal transparency obligation, option 2c exclusively provides that online general search engine providers will be called upon to voluntarily explore developing codes of conducts. Option 2c ensures the proportionality of costs by the light-touch nature of the legal transparency obligation, which does not provide for any algorithms' disclosure and which builds on existing practices in terms of transparency (Search Engine Optimisation). In addition, the redress measures that could be invoked against providers of online general search engines would be limited to the light-touch enforcement mechanism foreseen for the initiative
, and concern a more limited legal transparency obligation (limited to ranking) than that envisaged for business users of online platforms.
Option 2d does not appear to be a proportionate solution since it goes beyond what is necessary to achieve the objectives defined. A sufficient level of transparency and predictability for business users could be achieved without risking interfering in the platforms' business strategy. While the technical costs associated with sharing consumers' email addresses are limited, it is difficult to qualify and quantify the further effects this option may have on the platform economy.
The proportionality of the co-regulatory options also lies in their two-step approach which is tailored to platforms' fast changing technological and economic environment. The EU Observatory will follow both the general evolution of the platform economy and the specific issues described in this Impact Assessment, informed amongst other by the legal transparency obligations. Requiring platforms to report in a non-detailed manner
, capable of being performed using automated data collection and reporting techniques, is a proportionate way to encourage the use of the internal complaint-handling system to show how effectively it functions. The value of such increased transparency, particularly as the statistics shall be available to the general public, reflects the objective of transparency rules in other sectors, for example, in investor-state arbitration with the aim of, inter alia, increasing accountability and promoting good governance.
Options 2b and 2c will thus ensure that the approach put in place remains proportionate to the issues encountered in P2B relations. Policy option 2c will likely increase the effectiveness of the intervention as opposed to policy option 2b. While this would imply additional costs as compared to option 2b, the measures of option 2c are proportionate to what is strictly needed to contribute to achieving the objectives; i.e. the measures foreseen with regard to online general search engines are limited to the only issue of ranking transparency and to the legal standing for representative organisations to act on behalf of their business members.
If platforms fail to put in place the voluntary approach recommended by the Commission, stricter and more intrusive rules could be put in place if justified in light of observed developments. In addition to constituting a pre-condition to effective monitoring, the legal transparency obligations also have an important potential to increase peer competition as they provide new competitive parameters.
Finally, all retained options foresee the inclusion of a targeted exemption of online platforms constituting a "small enterprise" from the obligation to provide effective internal complaint-handling mechanisms, in line with the "Think Small First" principle. It should be noted that the obligation to provide effective internal complaint-handling mechanisms sets only high-level effectiveness and accessibility criteria, which will leave online platforms free to implement cost-effective technical solutions resulting in lower than average costs. For example, platforms would be free to reuse consumer-facing support mechanisms also to provide complaint handling for the business side of their operations.
The targeted exemption will guarantee that where an administrative burden resulting from the Initiative cannot be fully excluded, only companies that are sufficiently mature to absorb this burden are covered. The internal redress – related obligation will at the same time extend to all platforms that have a very large number of business users and which are therefore most likely to face capacity constraints in complaint-handling in the absence of proper procedures.
In addition to a targeted exemption, the proportionality of the retained policy options could be further ensured by horizontally exempting very small online platform firms from the overall P2B initiative. Depending on the threshold that may be used, a significant number of smaller online platform companies in the EU would not, in that case, face any additional burden, while being able to benefit from the enhanced user trust that the Initiative should yield
. At the same time, the cost-benefit ratio of such an exemption can be estimated to be relatively neutral, as the additional burden on very small platforms to provide for transparency obligations in their terms of reference can be expected to be minimal.
Conclusion on Proportionality
Option 2a is a proportionate choice since it implies limited burden on platforms and no obligations on online general search engines.
Options 2b and 2c appear both as proportionate since they allow meeting the objectives of the initiative while imposing relatively reasonable level of burden.
Option 2d appears disproportionate since it implies relatively high burden for fulfilling the objectives of the initiative.
7.2Conclusion
The following table summarises the comparison of the retained policy options 2a, 2b, 2c and 2d in terms of effectiveness, efficiency, coherence, and proportionality.
It is important to stress that the definitions covered by all four options are coherent with definitions used in EU existing legislation and currently ongoing Commission initiatives. For the purpose of exhaustiveness, Section 8.3 of the Annex contains a detailed overview of all current and proposed definitions for comparison purposes.
Comparison of policy options
|
Effectiveness
|
Efficiency
|
Coherence
|
Proportionality
|
Option 0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
Option 2a
|
+
|
++
|
+++
|
+
|
Option 2b
|
++
|
+++
|
+++
|
+++
|
Option 2c
|
+++
|
+++
|
+++
|
+++
|
Option 2d
|
++
|
-
|
++
|
-
|
Option 2a - Foresees self-regulation on ranking, discrimination, data & MFNs and legal principles on the issues related to terms and conditions and delisting; excludes issues encountered in online general search as well as the data-related obligation for platforms to share email addresses with their business users
Option 2a is of limited effectiveness. While it would increase legal certainty through legal transparency and redress measures, the risk of direct harm to businesses and of fragmentation remains important since some high-impact trading practices (ranking, data, discrimination, MFNs) may not be sufficiently tackled through self-regulation. Reputational levers of EU monitoring would also be underexploited in the absence of legal transparency obligations on all high-impact trading practices. In terms of efficiency, this option while achieved at a lower cost may underperform with regard to the achievement of the objectives set by the initiative thus leading to limited benefits. The limited effectiveness of Option 2a has been taken into consideration in the scoring of proportionality. Option 2a is in principle proportionate since it provides, at limited costs, a comprehensive set of measures that could allow all three specific objectives to be achieved. However, by leaving issues around internal discrimination, data, ranking and MFNs to self-regulation, policy options 2a incorporates the risk of increased fragmentation. The proportionality of option 2a should thus be assessed in light of the extent to which the option contributes to achieving the objectives of the initiative.
Option 2b - Foresees legal principles on all issues; excludes issues encountered in online general search as well as the data-related obligation for platforms to share email addresses with their business users
Option 2b is effective since it would lead to a more predictable, transparent and innovation-friendly environment for business users. The new rules together with the EU observatory will help allow building a common EU understanding of what issues are, thus also allowing for more consistent regulatory approaches when such are deemed necessary at national level. Increased trust in the platform environment will impact in a positive way both platforms and business users, contributing to mitigating possible compliance costs. In terms of efficiency, the regulatory costs are expected to be outweighed by the increased growth opportunities for platforms created by positive indirect network effects which would support in growth in sales through online platforms. Option 2b appears as an effective, efficient and proportionate option coherent with other EU policies.
Option 2c - Foresees legal principles on all issues; covers issues in online general search, excludes the data-related obligation for platforms to share email addresses with their business users
Option 2c has a higher overall effectiveness compared to Option 2b, but also achieved at a higher cost. It allows expanding the expected positive effects of the transparency obligation and of the legal standing provision to online general search as appropriate and proportionate. Online search engines also exhibit dependency-enabled unilateral behaviour targeted by the initiative, as ranking practices directly influence websites' visibility and internet traffic received. The limited extension of the scope to the transparency obligation for ranking and to the enforcement provision on legal standing for representative bodies is a proportionate and effective way to ensure clarity as regards the complementarity of the initiative with competition law while option 2c implies higher costs as compared to option 2b - since it creates costs for online general search engines - it also creates additional benefits. The inclusion of online general search engines in the initiative allows simultaneously covering the two most important ranking-based originators of Internet traffic (online platforms and online general search engines). Option 2c would help introducing more transparency and predictability for business users across the board thus addressing the issues identified around ranking transparency more comprehensively. Option 2c would ultimately create positive impacts in terms of online visibility for business users, increased pro-competitive effect (between comparison sites and search engines), and preserved quality of search results for end-users. In addition, associations or representative bodies that have a legitimate interest in representing businesses whose websites are indexed by online general search engines would have the right to seek action in court to enforce – exclusively – the legal transparency obligation on ranking in online general search. Option 2c is proportionate since the measures it proposes are targeted to the sole ranking-related issue identified in online general search. Option 2c foresees therefore a scoped transparency obligation (limited to the single issue of ranking), and a minimal redress measure limited to granting representative associations with legal standing to act on behalf of their business members in relation to the ranking transparency issue. Finally, option 2c is coherent with other EU policies and fundamental rights.
Option 2d - Option 2d is particularly effective in fulfilling specific objectives 1 and 2 since it allows for an exhaustive set of measures to address all issues identified. Option 2d appears however less effective in reaching specific objective 3 of creating a predictable and innovation–friendly legal environment for platforms. The extended data-related obligation for platforms to share customers' email addresses may have an impact on platforms' business models thus possibly reducing innovation incentives. This option is thus disproportionate and not fully coherent with the objectives pursued by the DSM strategy.
8Preferred Option
Option 2c is the most effective of the retained options in reaching the specific objectives of the intervention, most notably in terms of ensuring fair, transparent and predictable treatment of business users. Option 2c allows expanding the expected positive effects of the transparency obligation and of the legal standing provision to online general search. It allows the inclusion of online general search engines in the initiative thus simultaneously covering the two most important ranking-based originators of Internet traffic. Businesses would be able to develop better informed search optimisation strategies, which would be particularly beneficial for SMEs and enterprises with no or emerging online presence. This option is of comparable efficiency as option 2b, which represents the closest regulatory alternative to option 2c. In addition, option 2c provides for equal treatment between online platforms and general online search engines, as regards dependency-induced potentially harmful ranking practices. Consequently, to maximise the effectiveness of the policy intervention and to ensure a level playing field, Option 2c is selected as the preferred option.
8.1Overview of the measures
The Preferred Option is a co-regulatory set of measures combining obligations imposed in a legal instrument, self-regulatory measures by platforms to set up an independent mediator, and the establishment of an EU Observatory of the Online Platform Economy to monitor the problems identified. It is informed by and builds on the on best practices such as the Audio-visual Media Services Directive (AVMSD) and the experience in the Supply Chain Initiative (SCI).
Targeted EU-wide transparency measures are both the most proportionate way to effectively tackling established potentially harmful trading practices, as well as a precondition to effective monitoring (cf. Section 8.1.1 below on transparency and Section 8.1.3 on monitoring). Such transparency measures also have the potential to improve competition – and indirectly the quality and redress available to business users – by pushing reputational levers. This is also critical to developing a more trusted business environment. EU-wide measures to ensure effective out-of-court redress possibilities for business users are in addition required to minimise inadvertent economic damage arising out of any P2B issues. Such redress measures underpin the effectiveness of the proposed transparency measures. Transparency measures such as an obligation to state objective reasons for delisting in turn constitute an absolute precondition to enabling effective redress. This increased clarity develops trust and helps businesses overcome the fear of retaliation. The high-level nature of the transparency and redress rules would allow industry, if it chose to do so, to additionally develop codes of conducts, which could spell out legal and technical details of their practical implementation sensitive to the fast changing technological and economic environment in which they operate. The transparency and redress actions will also be flanked by the separate establishment of an EU Observatory of the Online Platform Economy to ensure effective monitoring in close collaboration with Member States. The harmonised transparency and redress measures combined with collaborative monitoring will help prevent further fragmentation by avoiding direct economic harm to EU business users and by allowing the preparation of well-informed responses at EU-level – which may be justified to regulate emerging potentially harmful trading practices in a second step.
Enhanced transparency to tackle potentially harmful trading practices
1.Legal obligation to inform business users of significant changes to contractual terms and conditions, and to provide a reasonable notice period to allow business users to adequately prepare for the anticipated changes. Online platforms would remain free to legally design solutions that effectively result in business users being provided with a period during which they can continue to trade subject to the existing terms and conditions.
2.Legal obligation to provide relevant business users with an actionable statement of reasons upon delisting of their accounts or of individual products and services.
3.Legal obligation to state in contractual terms and conditions the general criteria of the ranking mechanism on the platforms, as well as conditions for use of any mechanism that allows business users to influence their prominence against remuneration. It will be explained that all these obligations shall be without prejudice to the protection of trade secrets under Directive (EU) 2016/943 and that, therefore, the required description will be at a general level, while accurately reflecting the norm for the relevant online intermediation service, based on historic data. In addition, the Commission could work with the relevant online platform and online general search engine providers to explore practical tools for meaningful transparency, to improve the verifiability of this paid-for prominence within the specific e-commerce area, to potentially develop industry standards and proactively run audits; and it could monitor the functioning of the wider digital advertising space.
4.Legal obligation to clearly explain to business users whether platforms' competing services or goods (e.g. own apps, owned retailer operations or other services of the same type as the business users') enjoy any preferential treatment (e.g. pre-installation of apps) as compared to that reserved to business users. The description would be at the general level rather than at the level of individual products or goods offered through those services in order to ensure proportionality. This will include any specific measures or behaviour concerning access to personal or non-personal data, ranking, remuneration for the use of the platform or ancillary services (e.g. the provision of delivery services or payment facilities).
5.Legal obligation to clarify transparently the data policy regarding business users.
6.Legal obligation to unequivocally state as part of platforms' general commercial proposition to business users whether they demand – contractually or otherwise – best prices and/or product selections to be offered to their market places. This will be combined with a legal obligation for online platforms to make easily available to the general public unambiguous explanations as to the relevant commercial, legal or any other considerations underpinning the use of such most-favoured-nation clauses. For this to be proportionate, it will be limited to a targeted and understandable description of key elements such as the need to prevent free-riding in light of the size of the platform.
The preferred Option 2c adds a targeted transparency obligation for providers of online general search engines to the above transparency obligations for providers of online intermediation services. Providers of online general search engines would under this option be obliged to make a description of the main ranking parameters used to operate their search ranking mechanism available to the general public. The obligation would build on real-life examples of meaningful transparency (cf. Annex 7.3), and defines a legal standard on the basis of industry best practice. The transparency obligations shall be without prejudice to the protection of trade secrets under Directive (EU) 2016/943 and, therefore, the required description will be at a general level, while accurately reflecting the norm for the relevant online general search engines, based on historic data.
Improved internal, external and judicial redress available to business users
Redress possibilities for business users will be improved by a combination of measures, listed below. The resulting structural redress and some of the legal obligations tackling individual harmful trading practices will be directly mutually reinforcing.
1.Encouragement for platform operators to set up external organisations that can provide industry-specific mediators independent mediators, which should – if industry does in fact set them up – comply with certain effectiveness principles to be spelled out in law. These mediators would provide an additional pool of mediators in addition to those that already exist.
2.Legal obligation for platform operators to put in place an effective and accessible internal complaint-handling mechanism. The functioning of such internal complaint handling systems would be monitored for effectiveness, and subject to further recommendations or industry codes-of-conducts.
3.Legal obligation to issue annual public reports on the effectiveness of the internal appeals mechanisms, which will be designed to limit costs for the platforms concerned. Rather than implying any continuous publication of data (feeds), the reporting obligation would take the form of high-level reports published only annually and these reports would moreover cover only a limited number of elements such as the total number of complaints received, the subject matter of the complaints, the time period needed to process the complaints and the decision taken. Online platforms can largely automate data collection and reporting.
4.Legal obligation for platform operators to list in their contractual terms and conditions existing mediators who meet certain objective quality criteria, and with whom they are willing to engage. This shall include any platform-specific, independent mediators. Platform operators will in addition be subject to a legal obligation to act in good faith towards attempts by their business users to engage with such mediation process in the EU.
5.Formulating the legal transparency and redress obligations as mandatory rules to the greatest extent possible (cf. Annex 1.4 in this respect) as a key element to improve the chances of enforcement of the proposed targeted legal obligations in EU courts notwithstanding the exclusive choice of law and forum clauses included in the contracts between online platforms and their business users that frequently designate non-EU courts.
Granting to associations or representative bodies that have a legitimate interest in representing business users the right to seek action in court to remedy or prevent economic harm arising as a result of general non-compliance with the proposed legal obligations for online platforms. Annex 1 explains the compatibility with the Commission's collective redress Recommendation of 2013. Although the principal aim of the Initiative is to improve bilateral conflict resolution rather than judicial redress in a first step, granting representative organisations legal standing is a key element to convince EU Courts to enforce the proposed targeted legal obligations in EU courts notwithstanding the choice of law and forum clauses included in the contracts between online platforms and their business users that designate non-EU courts. This approach builds on case-law of the CJEU that explains that actions by representative bodies, which are in the collective interest (as opposed to merely in the interest of a group of specifically identified individuals) are not subject to the jurisdictional provisions included in any private contracts. Therefore, such actions are more likely to be capable of being brought before the court of the Member State where the alleged (future) harm will occur. This provision therefore also helps to address the fear of retaliation, as it will enable representative bodies to act in the collective interest of business users, who may prefer to remain anonymous, to ensure the effectiveness of the proposed legal obligations. While firmly based on existing case-law of the CJEU, the effectiveness of this specific provision on legal standing for representative bodies will benefit from any further horizontal action the Commission may take as part of its follow-up to the 2013 Recommendation on Collective Redress (2013/396/EU) and accompanying study on its implementation. This study has recognised that collective redress mechanisms for consumer matters for injunctive relief are in place in all EU Member States, and that deficiencies remain only in respect of collective redress – the latter not being part of this proposal. It is also complementary to the pending revision of the Injunctions Directive, as part of which several options to protect the collective interests of consumers are being explored. Although providing standing to business organisations (in addition to consumer organisations) to strengthen this enforcement is one of the options considered, this will indeed not provide the required enforceability of the proposed P2B rules which aim to protect individual businesses rather than consumers. This option may nonetheless work in synergy with this proposed revision and the improvements that shall flow from it and lead to an increase in the number of business associations broadly monitoring law compliance in the field of online platforms, in particular on the issue of ranking transparency where consumer protection rules (the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive) complement the business-facing transparency measure included in the Preferred Option. In addition, under the preferred option 2c, associations or representative bodies that have a legitimate interest in representing businesses whose websites are indexed by online general search engines have the right to seek action in court to enforce – exclusively – the legal transparency obligation on ranking in online general search.
8.2Scope of application of the Preferred Option
The Preferred Option would apply to platforms falling in the scope of this Impact Assessment, as specified in Section 1.3, including online search engines. A detailed explanation of the legal definition is provided in Annex 1.12 (cf. also annex 1.4).
The geographical scope of the Preferred Option would be based on the contractual relations of online platforms with EU business users. Online platform companies would be covered regardless of whether they are established in the EU, as long as they intermediate between EU business users and consumers located in the EU. Similarly, online search engines would be covered regardless of whether they are established in the EU, as long as they allow users located in the EU to perform searches of websites of business users established in the EU. This would prevent online platforms from excluding relations that are capable of producing effects in the EU from the scope of the intervention by simply diverting this to a .com domain name operated from outside the EU. Evidence suggests, however, that virtually all important non-EU platforms have an EU establishment, which reduces the risk of avoiding application significantly. Furthermore, the proposed provision on legal standing granting associations or representative bodies having a legitimate interest in representing business users the right to seek action in court to remedy or prevent economic harm arising as a result of general non-compliance with the proposed legal obligations will further reduce this risk.
8.3Thresholds
On the basis of the analysis in Section 6 platforms qualifying as a small enterprise would be exempted from the internal redress mechanism. While available data does not allow drawing a clear line as to whether this threshold should apply to micro- or small enterprises, the proportionality principle would advocate for setting the internal mechanism-specific threshold at a higher level. This would prevent any disproportionate regulatory burden to be imposed on start-up and scale-up platforms. Either the turnover or the employee count of a platform can be considered to be acceptable metrics to determine the threshold. Indeed the Recommendation on the Definition of SMEs combines both factors in its definitions as a cumulative requirement. Turnover is an indicator of the number of transactions intermediated by a given platform, and once a platform exceeds a turnover of EUR 10 million (threshold above which an enterprise is considered as medium-sized) both the degree of intermediation can be assumed to be significant, while such platforms can then also be assumed to be able to absorb the additional cost of the measure. At the same time, employee count is frequently easier to measure, and platforms may already exercise relative bargaining power before generating significant turnover, as a general characteristic of the platform business model. As to the possibility to set an additional threshold exempting enterprises from the entire regulation, the analysis of pros and cons does not allow concluding on the need to add a horizontal exemption to the internal mechanism-specific one (cf. Section 6.1.2.3).
Given the fast moving nature of the platform environment, any threshold which would be set, may need to be reviewed to ensure that it continues capturing platforms displaying specificities underlying the problem identified. A review clause should therefore allow for a revision of the threshold if needed. The work carried out under the Observatory would allow monitoring the efficiency of the proposed threshold and adjusting it as appropriate.
8.4Stakeholders' views
Business users are generally supportive of the intervention proposed under the Preferred Option and generally in favour of a stronger and co-regulatory intervention. The main requests by business users focus on effective redress options, greater transparency of platforms' ranking practices, the prohibition of MFN clauses, and transparency in delisting processes. Some business users also ask for an access to data obligation requiring platforms to share certain data, e.g. customer names, addresses, telephone numbers, email addresses and provenance. In business users' view, more transparent ranking criteria would give the possibility to business users to make informed and substantiated complaints towards the platforms. Platforms should instruct business users of the reasons having led to their de-ranking or the suspension. Business users stressed the need for legislation to set up a contact point or a support function to deal with errors in ranking algorithms.
Online platforms- most would agree that providing an explanation to a business user in case of delisting or take-down of an offer seems to be a reasonable legal obligation - provided their legal obligations to take down illegal content and cooperate with investigations are respected. Online platforms do not see the value added of external dispute resolution, because they trust their own internal dispute resolution systems. While platforms do not generally see a problem with implementing notice periods for changes in terms and conditions, they are, however, not in favour of rigid notice periods.
Regarding transparency around rankings and data use, platforms would agree with high-level disclosure as in the Preferred Option, but warn of "gaming" and manipulation of algorithms subject to too much transparency. Generally platforms appear supportive of the idea of monitoring the platform economy, if such monitoring is not intrusive in their trade secret policies.
Online general search engines already provide substantial guidance on how to optimise the ranking, but warn of the ineffectiveness of disclosing algorithms, not least in light of many and frequent changes to search algorithms, as well as on the risks to manipulation of search results.
Based on a questionnaire and a meeting with national authorities, many national experts are of the view that addressing issues around terms and conditions is core to the entire P2B issue. They also consider that the proportionality of a transparency obligation would depend on the precise wording and on the size of the platform. On issues such as notice periods views diverge depending on the experience at national level ranging from no need to regulate to mandatory fixed notice terms. Some national experts are also of the view that terms and conditions should be simplified in order to make them transparent and user-friendly for businesses – similarly to B2C legislation. National experts supporting a legal transparency obligation find legitimate the requirement on platforms to provide a statement of reasons for delisting. National experts share the general view that delisting-related requirements should be aligned with illegal content/notice and action procedures. A transparency obligation on ranking criteria is overall considered proportionate and legitimate. The experts with more experience on ranking issues are supportive of measures solving the problems encountered in a timely manner, although some say that the issue should be left to commercial and competition law. A general preference to (i) opt for a transparency obligation covering ranking practices in general, and (ii) work towards identifying best practices in ranking captures the broad consensus view. On data, non-discrimination and MFNs experts cautioned that further reflection was needed. However, there is an overall agreement among experts on the importance of effective redress. Some concerns exist that internal complaints mechanisms could be more burdensome for SMEs. Some national experts are in favour of promoting existing best practices (possibly as part of a self-regulatory measure). Experts representing national authorities overall recognise the interest of the monitoring exercise. They are, however, generally opposed to the creation of a new body or European Agency created for that purpose.
Although the Preferred Option was not tested with consumer organisations, consumers are expected to be supportive of the Preferred Option despite the high-quality products/services they are currently benefitting from. Longer term competition- and choice-related considerations have been put forward by one consumer association in one of the Commission's workshops. A representative of this association has in particular argued in favour of some stricter non-discrimination measures more in line with the telecommunications regulatory framework.
9Monitoring and Evaluation of Impacts
Monitoring of the evolution of impacts constitutes a key part of the intervention in this domain, as the online platform economy remains a dynamic, fast evolving area of the economy. The monitoring is therefore divided into two strategic parts, the EU Observatory of the Online Platform Economy, and the specific monitoring of the evolution of impacts related to the regulatory and self-regulatory components of the intervention.
9.1EU Observatory of the Online Platform Economy
The European Commission will monitor market indicators for the online platforms environment through the EU Observatory, consisting of a group of independent external experts, supported by a dedicated Commission secretariat and by a study which will provide a website, as well as evidence and data gathering capacity.
This analysis includes data such as, but not limited to: number and types of businesses trading on online platforms, number and type of complaints handled through internal and mediators, number of cases successfully solved, the amount of time needed to resolve the case, the place of establishment, size of online platforms trading in the EU including turnover realised in the EU market as an online intermediary. Through the EU Observatory, the Commission will also monitor emerging challenges and opportunities for the EU in the wider digital platforms economy and online general search. This implies data and evidence gathering on matters such as access to data flows and their monetization opportunities controlled by platforms; transparency and accountability in the wider online advertising ecosystem; alleged discriminatory practices of platforms competing with their users; use and effect of MFN clauses including the justifications put forward by platforms or algorithmic decision-making in online platforms. In the context of search engines, data gathering and analysis will also cover issues such as: conditions for inclusion in and display of search results. This will include the use of third party content, including issues on access to data and the monetisation of the original content that this may raise and the information given to users when such content is displayed. It will also gather impacts from regulatory trends in the Member States or where relevant in third countries and on this basis prepare a set of evidence-based analytic papers to inform EU policy making. To this end, the Observatory will conduct data and evidence collection, collect opinions from a broader stakeholder base and experts and interact with and consider results of relevant research and studies, including European Commission funded studies and projects. Given the diverse nature of issues emerging in the Online Platform Economy, the Observatory would also liaise with relevant expert bodies at EU and national level to ensure holistic, multi-disciplinary outputs to inform EU policy-making.
The Commission will also analyse how to enhance the monitoring of the online platform economy through a dedicated study supporting the work of the EU Observatory, additional data sources and data collection, as well as collaboration with national statistical offices and Eurostat.
9.2Specific indicators and operational objectives
Table 5 below summarises the specific objectives as well as a series of quantitative and qualitative indicators to be used for monitoring the effectiveness and efficiency of the Preferred Option. Importantly, the procedural monitoring will be accompanied by a monitoring of emerging practices on both the platforms' and the business users' side. Consequently, the impact of the Initiative will be assessed in the context of an evaluation exercise and activate, if so required, a review clause 3 years after entry into force of the adopted instrument.
Table 5 : Indicators of impact for the purpose of monitoring and evaluation
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 26.4.2018
SWD(2018) 138 final
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
IMPACT ASSESSMENT
ANNEXES
Accompanying the document
Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council
on promoting fairness and transparency for business users of online intermediation services
{COM(2018) 238 final}
{SEC(2018) 209 final}
{SWD(2018) 139 final}
Contents
1.
Amendments to the IA following the RSB opinion
1.1.Summary of amendments following the RSB opinion of 22 March 2018
1.2.Summary of amendments following RSB opinion of December 2017
1.3.Summary of amendments after the second submission
1.4.Mandatory rules - enforcement
1.5.Compatibility with other EU instruments on redress
1.6.Definitions and Scope: A precise, future-proof and evidence-based approach
1.7.Evidence-base & types of issues covered
1.8.Overview of problem drivers
1.9.Conclusion of Problem Definition
1.10. Legal basis
1.11. Subsidiarity: EU action required to provide harmonised framework for cross-border, online platform-specific issues
1.12. A light-touch and staged co-regulatory option geared to online intermediation
1.13. High-level but effective transparency obligations with a scope for self-regulation
1.14. Effectiveness of a legal definition of online intermediation services
2.
Procedural Information
2.1.Identification
2.2.Organisation and chronology
2.3.Regulatory Scrutiny Board
2.4.Evidence
2.5.External expertise
3.
Stakeholder Consultation
3.1.The stakeholders engagement strategy
3.2.Bilateral meetings
3.3.The Outcome of the Public Consultations
3.3.1.Public consultation on online platforms, 24 September 2015 until 6 January 2016
3.3.2.Public consultation: Building a European Data Economy, 10 January to 26 April 2017
3.3.3.Flash Eurobarometer 439: The use of online marketplaces and search engines by SMEs, 6 July 2016
3.3.4.Survey of business users, 5 December 2016 – 2 February 2017
3.3.5.Problem definition: targeted workshops
3.3.6.Options design and evaluation
3.3.7.Questionnaire "Online platforms and platforms-to-business relations for Member States
3.3.8.Meeting of the eCommerce expert group of 24 October 2017
3.3.9.Stakeholder workshop effective dispute resolution and the fundamental right to conduct a business, 6 July 2017
3.4.Feedback to the Inception Impact Assessment
4.
Who is Affected by the Initiative and How?
4.1.Who is Affected ?
4.1.1.Business users
4.1.2.Online platforms
4.1.3.Online General Search Engines
4.1.4.Consumers
4.1.5.Public authorities (national and European Commission)
4.2.Summary of cost and benefits of the preferred option
4.3.Stakeholders' views
4.3.1.Business users
4.3.2.Platforms
4.3.3.National authorities
4.3.4.Consumers
5.
Analytical Models Used in Preparing the Impact Assessment
6.
Synthesis of JRC economic research papers
7.
Description of Main Market Players and Analysis
7.1.Growing digital trade is increasingly intermediated by online platforms
7.2.Market dynamics
7.2.1.Online market places
7.2.2.App stores
7.2.3.Social media, content and communication platforms
7.2.4.Online travel and hospitality platforms
7.2.5.Search engines
7.2.6.Overview of main market players
7.3.Transparency of online general search engines
7.4.Benefits of B2C online platforms for consumers, businesses and the economy as a whole
8.
Regulatory Analysis: status quo
8.1EU competition law
8.2Jurisdiction of courts and applicable law: diverging national approaches
8.3EU acquis: other relevant acts
8.4B2B rules at EU and national level
8.5Emerging national legislation for the platforms' environment: relevance for P2B
8.6. P2B Fairness standards in third countries
8.7.Landscape in the Member States illustrating standing given to representative associations.
9.
Overview of option elements to address the individual problems
10.
Individual assessment of option elements
11.
The SME Test – Summary of results
12.
In-depth analysis of impacts assessed in Section 6
12.1. Impact on internal market
12.1.1.Growth
12.1.2.Preserving the cross-border nature of the platform economy – preventing fragmentation of the internal market
12.2. Impact on enterprises
12.2.1.Impact on online platforms
12.2.2.Options for thresholds for exemption
12.2.3.Impact on non-EU platforms
12.2.4.Impact on business users
12.3.Impact on public authorities
12.4.Impact on innovation, competitiveness, competition
12.4.1.Innovation
12.4.2.Competitiveness
12.4.3.Competition
12.5. Employment and social impact
12.6. Impact on consumers
12.7. Environmental impact
12.8. Impact on fundamental rights
12.9. Summary
1.Amendments to the IA following the RSB opinion
The following table summarises how the comments of Regulatory Scrutiny Board have been addressed following its final opinion.
1.1.Summary of amendments following the RSB opinion of 22 March 2018
(1)
The detailed analysis of the various online business models at stake helps to better understand the scope of the initiative. To provide a comprehensive overview, the analysis related to the multi-faceted online platform business models should be included in the core of the report, rather than in the annex. The report should provide more explanation as to the approach taken to identify these online services and include them in the scope of the initiative. It is not evident whether the extension aims at protecting businesses from search engines deliberately de-ranking them in search results, or rather to enable businesses to exploit the disclosed ranking algorithms to artificially improve their position. As the main online search engines already have disclosed information on the rankings, the report should assess to what extent an action on this issue is necessary at the EU level.
|
The relevant explanations have been moved from the Annexes to the main report in Section 1.3, with additional explanations on how they have been identified. Footnote 16 explains the approach taken to identify the platforms.
The aim of option 2c and its extension to search engines is clarified in Table 1, and in the impact section 6.
|
(2)
The report should clarify the rationale behind the design of the many options. In particular, the report should better substantiate the choice of measures in option 2 and 3, as both options differ only on one single issue.
|
The design of the options has been clarified in Section 5.2.
Regarding the choice of measures in options 2 and 3, the new Section 5.4.2 (which substantiates why option 3 has been discarded) also allows better understanding of the choice of measures between options 2 and 3.
However, given that options 2 and 3 strongly differ on the implementation instrument - co-regulation versus full regulation, it is our understanding that what the Board meant in its opinion is that "the report should better substantiate the choice of measures between options 2b and 2c". These two co-regulatory options indeed defer only on a single issue. The choice of measures between 2b and 2c has therefore also been further explained in Section 5.2. In addition, for the sake of completeness, this has also been done for options 2c and 2d (end of Section 5.2).
Finally, a short summary overview of all four co-
|
|
regulatory options has been added in Section 5.5.
|
The report should further explain the perceived contradiction between the various calls and invitations on industry (voluntary measures) and legal obligations to comply with the voluntary measures potentially agreed upon, for example, concerning an external independent redress mechanism.
|
Section 5.2, Table 1 (Option 2), 6.2.1.1 and 8.1.2 updated to refer to external organisations that can provide industry-specific mediators, rather than external redress mechanisms, which is used to refer to an external venue for redress similar to the SCI.
Section 5.4.1 emphasises the difference between a pure voluntary approach and the adoption of voluntary measures. Section 8.1 emphasises that the voluntary measures are supplementary to already effective tools, which will enhance the implementation of the Regulation so it is sensitive to industry’s needs.
|
The reasoning behind the choice of the co-regulatory approach and the immediate discarding of all other approaches is insufficiently developed and presented.
|
Sections 5.4.1, 5.4.2 and 5.4.3 have been developed to substantiate the discarding of Policy Options 1, 3, and 4.
|
(3)
The report should further detail what 'independent flanking measures’ will look like. It should explain to which extent the effectiveness of the initiative depends on the successful implementation of these flanking measures.
|
The reference on independent flanking measures has been deleted. There is no direct relation between the effectiveness of the initiative and broader, data-related initiatives under the data economy package, although data-sharing will be examined in the observatory, as explained on page 41.
•Summary table on impacts has been moved from the annexes to the main IA report as Section 6.9.
•Annex 12 on the comparative analysis of the retained options has been moved to the main IA report as Section 7.1.
|
Important parts of the annexed material could be moved to the main text. The addition of a lot of new information has fragmented the main report and the annexes, reducing the informative value of the main report.
|
|
The Board takes note of the quantification of the various costs and benefits associated to the preferred option of this initiative, as assessed in the report considered by the Board and summarised in the attached quantification tables
|
|
1.2.Summary of amendments following RSB opinion of December 2017
RSB comment
|
Amendments made to the IA
|
(1) As intermediation by online platforms is wide-ranging and fast-changing, the report has to make clear what is and what is not in the scope of the intervention. The report should more precisely define online platforms and/or their services it intends to regulate in order to avoid legal uncertainty for platforms and businesses entering into contractual relations. The current definition is fairly broad and risk to impose constraints on platforms not involved in unfair trading practices (e.g. payment platforms). The report should test whether the definitions are future proof. This report opts for a regulation, which is directly applicable. The positioning of the initiative in relation to the EU competition law needs to be further clarified.
|
The revised IA clarifies the scope of the intervention and the definition of the types of online platform services which fall in the scope. The IA also explains the rationale behind the proposed definition of scope and demonstrates that it is futureproof (Annexes 1.4 and 1.2). Examples of services falling in/out of scope are provided in Section 1.3 and Annex 4.1.1, 4.1.2).
The work on the definition of the scope is informed by the drafting of the legal instrument. A legal definition of online intermediation services that reflects the precise scope has been developed. It is to be noted that the EU has a proven track record on developing similar horizontal and technologically-neutral legal definitions (information society services in ECD and online market places & search engines in NIS Directive). Further analysis has been carried out to ensure that the P2B scoping definition is compatible with other EU policy initiatives and existing legislation (cf. table on comparison of definitions in Annex 8.3 on EU acquis (table) as well as in Section 1.3 (IA Scope).
As regards scope, detailed discussions with all relevant Commission services have taken place that confirmed that the initiative should cover social media, e-commerce market places and app stores, whereas payment services, advertising services and B2B platforms are out of scope. In addition, the inter-services discussions covered the appropriateness of extending the scope of the initiative to online general search engines. Based on available evidence and building on the existing legal definition of online search engines in the NIS Directive, a targeted extension of the initiative has been judged possible. This extension would not cover all issues but be limited to the issue of ranking in online general search engines and to the enforcement provision on legal standing for representative bodies of online general search engines. This has been reflected as a co-regulatory sub-option (option 2c).
The legal context of the initiative as well as its complementarity with competition law and parallel initiatives tackling unfair business practices in the off-line world (the food supply chain) has been clarified (cf. Introduction Section 1).
|
(2) The report should better demonstrate the magnitude of the problem. In particular, the report should present the available evidence with more caveats, as it mostly derives from stakeholder consultations representing business traders. The report does not indicate whether unfair trading practices are mainly used by major larger players or frequent across platforms or sectors. The analysis should be balanced and take care of possible bias. The initiative will be based on article 114, but the report only identifies fragmentation related to emerging national legislative initiatives. The single market dimension needs to be substantiated. The report should clarify that the initiative does not intend to tackle directly technical issues linked to the operation of platforms. In addition, the report should present a more comprehensive picture of the market structure to support the analysis it contains.
|
The revised IA further clarifies the scale of the problems and the need for intervention (problems (section 2.1), drivers (section 2.2), consequences (section 2.3). A substantiated overview of the problem definition can be found in annex 1.7. The presentation of the problem statement has been revised to clarify the intervention logics. The revised IA explains how self-selection bias in the evidence-base has been controlled for. The revised IA clarifies that the P2B issues encountered are common to the entire sector and not only to big platforms.
The single market dimension has been specified throughout the report (but mainly in Sections 2 and 3, annexes 1.8 and 1.9) to highlight more clearly the cross-border digital single market aspects of the underlying problem. Mainly, the revised IA clarifies the risk of an artificial legal re-fragmentation of the naturally cross-border online platforms market. Section 3 has been substantially revised, including also additional arguments why the solution must also be of an EU-wide nature.
The market structure has been developed in more detail to better demonstrate the dynamics of the platform economy (cf. Section 2 and Annex 7). The same section has also been expanded to online general search engines.
The revised IA also further qualifies the objectives (cf. Section 4) to allow better understanding of the inter-linkage with the problems identified.
The revised IA clarifies that purely technical issues are not covered by the initiative.
|
(3) The report should provide a more thorough analysis of impacts and cover more aspects. In particular, the report should discuss in more detail the risks of unintended consequences when introducing the initiative. This should include possible consequences for platform to consumer relations or higher charges to traders. It should also consider the possibility of reduced access to the platform, which is indicated by fear of retaliation by some firms, and an acceleration of vertical integration between platforms and suppliers. As the platform industry is very dynamic and the regulation does not have a precedent in EU legislation, there may be risks of other inadvertent changes in the behaviour of platforms and businesses, competition between platforms or emergence of innovative solutions. These risks may be quite high and should, therefore, be presented in the report.
|
The impact analysis has been extended in terms of impact on consumers, growth, cost-benefit analysis, competitiveness and competition (Section 6 with further substantiation in Annex 13).
The revised IA more thoroughly assesses potential risks, and highlights why the initiative will not negatively impact smaller market players, be they platforms or SME business users. A more thorough explanation of the impact on SMEs has been included at Annex 11 using the SME test.
It also substantiates why consumers will not be negatively affected by the initiative, as the underlying model indicates the net effect points to preserving or and even improve their benefits from the platform economy.
A summary of impacts for all options is presented in the table of Annex 13.9.
|
Moreover, the report should present the criteria for establishing exemptions from the provisions of the regulation and how the proposed thresholds relate to the current and expected market structure and use of unfair trading practices throughout the industry.
|
An analysis of thresholds has been introduced (Section 6.2.1.3). It covers a number of questions: For which measures are thresholds needed? If they are needed, how should they be set? Which measurements or proxies can be used to determine their level and to verify compliance easily? The analysis leads to the conclusion (in section 8.3) that small enterprises (i.e. those employing less than 50 persons) should be exempted from the obligation to have an internal redress mechanism, while the question whether a global microenterprise exemption is needed is left open.
|
(4) The report should address the proportionality of the measures and their effectiveness. Given the network effects of the platforms and their quasi monopolistic position, some of the transparency enhancing measures may not bring the desired effects, for instance the transparency on the changes to general terms and conditions or the justification for the use of most-favoured nation clauses. The report should indicate the type of information expected under the new disclosure obligations. It could at least refer to best practices in that respect.
Similarly, the report should demonstrate the proportionality of the redress mechanisms. The implications (costs, enforcement) of the reporting on litigations are not explored. The report also needs to justify the recourse to collective redress in business-to-business relations to solve ineffective redress, in particular as this has not so far been deployed at the EU level. The report should discuss the outcomes of the 2013 Commission's recommendation on collective redress mechanisms at national level. On this basis, the report should clarify whether further measures are necessary to strengthen collective redress for platforms at EU level. If so, the report should substantiate the choice of an EU legally binding instrument, such as a regulation, and detail the minimum requirements it intends to propose. The report should clarify how the initiative relates to the pending review of the injunction directive, in particular when addressing business-to-business relations. In general, the vague definition of the scope of the initiative makes the analysis of the proposed solution difficult as regards its effectiveness, efficiency and coherence.
|
The overall rationale and proportionality of the package of measures has been set out in more detail in Section 8.1. of the revised IA, which now clarifies that the focus on bilateral conflict resolution and the use of collective redress is geared towards the particularities of the online platform economy. Sections 8.1.1 and 8.1.2. of the revised IA and Annexes 1.2 and 1.3 clarify that the collective redress provision is an enforcement measure inspired by existing CJEU case-law that is exclusively meant to ensure the enforceability of the proposed Regulation, rather than to provide a third layer of redress for individual business users. To reflect this purpose, collective redress will also be limited to injunctive (rather than compensatory) relief and therefore not imply additional costs. It shall also be aligned with the quality criteria in the 2013 Commission Recommendation on Collective Redress.
Section 8.1.2. clarifies the complementarity between this specific provision on collective redress and the approach taken in the Injunctions Directive, which is limited to the private enforcement of consumer protection legislation. The proposals for the legal text revising the Injunctions Directive and the proposed legal text for this Initiative have been aligned in consultation with DG JUST and the Legal Service.
See also further evidence introduced in Annex 8 confirming that problems encountered at Member State-level in relation to collective redress relate to compensatory redress and that legal standing to bring injunctive actions for organisations representing SMEs is an established phenomenon in the area of unfair trading practices in all EU Member States.
To make the nature of the type of collective redress measure proposed clearer throughout the revised IA, it is referred to as legal standing for representative bodies or collective interest litigation.
The substantive progress made recently with other services on the legal instrument has been translated into the formulation of real-life inspired, principles-based yet effective information obligations in Section 8.1.1. of the Impact Assessment report. It has in addition been clarified in the same section that the information obligations only apply to the extent online platforms unilaterally impose general terms and conditions, which reflects the imbalance in bargaining power.
Section 8.1 and Annex 1.11 explains in more detail how the targeted transparency measures are justified notwithstanding the strong position of "incumbent" platforms, as these obligations serve multiple purposes, including providing predictability for business users, to enable effective monitoring and to play on important reputational levers (which effect is reinforced by the dedicated monitoring function).
Finally, Section 8.1.2. clarifies that the disclosure obligations are limited to the minimum required for effective monitoring.
|
(5) The structure of the impact assessment report needs significant improvement, in particular as regards the presentation and the comparison of the options and their impacts. The split presentation and assessment of “content” and “instrument” options, the awkward discard of the baseline and the lack of clarity in the comparison of the impacts for each option package, create confusion and make difficult to understand the choice of the preferred option.
|
The structure of the IA has been corrected to comply with the Better Regulation guidelines and toolbox:
-the overview of options is in Section 5 (options tables have been simplified; the more exhaustive ones have been put in Annexes 9-10);
-impacts are assessed in Section 6 (further substantiated analysis can be found in Annex 13);
-a comparison table has been included in "Comparison" section 7 (the underlying in-depth analysis criterion by criterion for each option is available in Annex 12);
-the baseline scenario is considered and used as a basis for analysing and comparing the options;
-the list of retained options in the IA has also been expanded to reflect the broader range of options that are considered within the preferred co-regulatory design. This range now includes in addition to the two options initially presented to RSB: (a) an option (2a) that leaves transparency on the more complex issues of ranking, discrimination, data and MFNs fully to self-regulation, and (b) an option (2c) considering the appropriateness of including online general search engines in the scope of the initiative. This broader range of co-regulatory options is now dealt with exhaustively in section 5 (options), section 6 (impacts) and section 7 (options comparison).
|
1.3.Summary of amendments after the second submission
A comparison of definitions against the Digital Taxation and Consumer Rights Directive Proposal
Legal instrument
/draft
|
Definition
|
Platforms
in scope
|
Platforms
out- of -scope
|
DRAFT PROPOSAL Art. 3(1)(a) of Council Directive establishing a Digital Services Tax
(Digitax)
|
Multi-sided digital interface - the making available to users of a multi-sided digital interface which allows users to find other users and to interact with them, and which facilitate the provision of underlying supplies of goods or services directly between those users, irrespective of where the transactions are ultimately concluded
Although borrowing from the definition of online intermediation services in the P2B initiative, this definition of multi-sided digital interfaces has a slightly broader scope (as it includes B2B & C2C/P2P platforms) in light of its purpose which is to identify taxable revenues, rather than contractual imbalances in bargaining power. Whereas pure C2C/P2P platforms are frequently provided for-profit, which can be subject to the digital service tax, they do not exhibit the harmful commercial issues targeted by the P2B initiative. The definition in the Digitax proposal will therefore include online intermediation services for the purpose of levying the digital service tax (DST), but not conflict with the definition used in the P2B initiative. The slight difference in intended scope between the respective proposals is implemented in the Digitax proposal by defining the term user as any individual or business, as opposed to using the separate definitions of business users and consumers in the P2B proposal. Apart from this, the definition of multi-sided digital interface will be aligned with the definition of online intermediation services, both of which target the intermediaries' role in facilitating direct transactions between their users.
|
B2B, B2C, C2C/P2P online platforms
for the purposes of levying the digital services tax (DST)
|
All online platforms below this turnover threshold:
> EUR 750 million global revenues; and
> EUR 50 million EU taxable revenues
|
DRAFT PROPOSAL Art. 2(19) of Directive 2011/83/EU (Consumer Rights Directive -revised CRD)
|
'Online market place' means a service provider, as defined in point (b) of Article 2 of Directive 2000/31/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 8 June 2000 on certain legal aspects of information society services, in particular electronic commerce, in the Internal Market (‘Directive on electronic commerce’), which allows consumers to conclude distance contracts on the online marketplace’s online interface
This definition identifies one specific type of online intermediation services for the purpose of tackling the targeted issue of private providers in the collaborative economy not identifying themselves as such vis-a-vis buyers – resulting in the latter not being aware that the CRD protections do not apply. This notwithstanding the conclusion of a contract on the platform's interface, which can give the impression that a contract is in fact concluded with a trader (i.e. the platform). The obligation that the revised CRD will impose on online market places by means of this definition is accordingly strictly meant to protect consumers, not businesses. The P2B proposal at the same time explicitly sets out that online market places are one type of online intermediation services, with the latter definition clearly going beyond for a different purpose (to protect businesses). The concurrent application of online market places and online intermediation services therefore will not involve any potential conflict.
|
Goes beyond "intermediation" as any service providers' website could be covered
All B2C and C2C/P2P online platforms as well as any website used to offer services (i.e. app stores, e-commerce market places, OTAs, webshops, to the extent they allow online contract conclusion)
|
B2B online platforms
|
1.4.Mandatory rules - enforcement
In relation to measure 5 (Section 8) on "formulating the legal transparency and redress obligations as mandatory rules to the greatest extent possible as a key element to improve the chances of enforcement of the proposed targeted legal obligations in EU courts notwithstanding the exclusive choice of law and forum clauses included in the contracts between online platforms and their business users that frequently designate non-EU courts", it is important to note the explanation which follows in the next paragraph.
This provision is in line with Article 6(c) of the Hague Convention or as overriding mandatory provisions according to Article 9 of Rome I Regulation and Articles 6(1), 6(4) or 26 of the Rome II Regulation Rome II) and the judgments of the Court of Justice. Even if this would leave EU Courts needing to decide which law should be applied by reference to the domicile of the defendant because of Article 4 of the Brussels 1 Regulation, for example, the proposed legal instrument would be likely to apply to the online platforms targeted in this initiative.
This would be based on either (a) satisfaction of criteria in Article 63 of the Brussels 1 Regulation that captures the European online platforms and as such, would mean the rules in the proposed legal instrument would apply as it is EU law, or (b) based on national residual jurisdiction rules, which usually rely on the nationality of the parties, presence of the defendant within the Member State, the location of assets, where business is done, and the domicile of the claimant, would apply for those platforms who have headquarters in the US but have at least some presence and assets in the EU, as well as the fact the business user is domiciled in the Member State and the business occurs in the Member State determining the case, to fulfil this criteria.
1.5.Compatibility with other EU instruments on redress
The draft legislative text proposes quality criteria fully in line with the Commission's collective redress Recommendation of 2013.
The associations that can bring collective interest litigation will be verified at the time the action is brought on an ad-hoc basis, rather than by means of pre-designation of qualified representative bodies. Pre-designation can be a safeguard against frivolous damages claims. However, as the Report on the Commission’s collective redress Recommendation of 2013 found, fears regarding abusive litigation driven by profit interests of third party funders appear to be unfounded, particularly where the associations that can bring a claim are required to be non-profit.
Such abusive litigation is also arguably more likely to arise where damages could be awarded whereas this initiative is limited to injunctive (rather than compensatory) relief on the targeted legal obligations proposed here, as opposed to the aim of securing mass enforcement of the consumer protection acquis that the Injunctions Directive aims to facilitate. As the platform economy is still evolving, there are fewer representative bodies than exist for consumers and the population of business users is smaller than the class of consumers who could benefit from improvements to the Injunctions Directive. These differences justify this minor variation between approaches for this initiative and the approach in consumer law, which favours pre-designation.
1.6.Definitions and Scope: A precise, future-proof and evidence-based approach
The Impact Assessment covers those online platforms in relation to which each of the three interlinked parts of the problem that this initiative aims to address apply: unilateral trading practices, a lack of effective redress and risks deriving from emerging regulatory fragmentation. It is also these online platforms that exhibit most strongly the drivers underlying the problem.
Online platforms that have managed to build an important consumer-base consisting of private individuals that can single-home for a specific purpose (e.g. hotel booking, fashion purchases, app downloads, or connecting to a specific network of people) today already account for a significant share of the overall market (i.e. including online as well as offline sales channels). These firms can therefore constitute a crucial gateway (possibly one of several) to consumer demand for a large number of, in particular, small businesses.
This dependency-situation is characterised by the existence of a direct contractual relationship between the online platforms and each of their business users as well as their consumers, reflecting the intermediaries' degree of control over the initiating of transactions that they intermediate (i.e. they can demand to be compensated, and impose the legal terms).
Whether the transactions between businesses and consumers that these online platforms intermediate are ultimately concluded directly online, on their market place, or through other means (e.g. offline for hotel or restaurant booking platforms or on businesses' own websites for comparison websites that may re-direct but track consumers) does not affect their gateway-position.
As a result of this definition, certain categories of platforms such as B2B platforms, payment intermediaries, and programmatic advertising exchanges (used to serve digital ads on the wider Internet) are out of scope.
Payment processing constitutes an activity that is inherently auxiliary to the supply of goods and services and this can never be used on a standalone basis to initiate transactions (i.e. consumers do not use payment intermediaries as the starting point for finding any goods or services provided by third parties). Payment intermediaries are therefore, excluded.
Online platforms that aim to intermediate transactions between businesses (i.e. B2B platforms) do not exhibit a similar dependency of the provider-side of the market at present. These B2B online platforms are characterised by a different dynamic: both sides of the online platform tend to constitute large and savvy firms that do not easily bind themselves into imbalanced contractual relationships. A Commission study from 2006 in this regard already observed that businesses' awareness of risks involved with online intermediation constituted one of the main factors altogether holding back the development of large-scale B2B e-markets.
To the extent these exist today, B2B intermediary platforms such as cloud app stores for professional clients exercise less control over intermediated transactions as the B2C online platforms targeted by this initiative do; they for example do not take commission and the B2B cloud app store is rather ancillary to the core provision of Customer Relationship Management services.
Advertising exchanges are a particular category of B2B platforms, where advertisers and publishers of ad space (e.g. website owners) are the immediate clients. Although programmatic advertising inherently involves presenting businesses' ads to consumers with a view to concluding transactions, this constitutes a derived form of intermediation that is not covered by this Impact Assessment. Indeed, programmatic online advertising typically involves multiple types of consecutive online intermediation services used to deliver the advertisement, such as online ad serving tools or online advertising exchanges. In these cases, the consumers do not use the online intermediation services that they enter into a contract with (e.g. the general search service) for the specific purpose of finding the relevant advertisements and they cannot choose which advertisements they see.
The Impact Assessment accordingly takes a future-proof activities-based approach to scoping the relevant online intermediation services that it covers. Indeed, the category of "online B2C e-commerce market place" that enables B2C transactions to be initiated as well as concluded directly online covers a range of online platform services regardless of their fast-changing designs, including traditional online market places, direct "buy-now" buttons integrated with social media, e-commerce chat bots incorporated into interpersonal communications services
as well as voice-activated software application stores
. Such an activities-based approach is consistent with the regulatory approach of the E-Commerce Directive
.
The general concept of online intermediation services encompassed by the scope of this initiative is also agnostic to the CJEU Uber judgment, which concerns one specific type of service provided by the company Uber. This specific service, but not other intermediation services that Uber may provide, will no longer qualify as an online intermediation service on the basis of strict criteria used to establish control by Uber over the underlying service.
By designing specific legal definitional elements, a precise scoping of "online intermediation services" that are capable of exhibiting the dependency-related problems that this Initiative aims to address is possible. It is noted in this respect that existing legal definitions used in EU law in the area of digital do not capture the distinguishing intermediation-element that this initiative targets. For example, Art. 2(5) of Regulation 2017/1128 on cross-border portability of online content services in the internal market targets online services that buy and resell digital content (e.g. subscription-based Video-on-Demand services), rather than intermediating access between consumers and the producers of such content.
At the same time, whereas Art. 4(17) of Directive 2016/1148 concerning measures for a high common level of security of network and information systems across the Union does define online market places, this definition is both too broad as well as too narrow for the purposes of this initiative. It namely covers both B2B and B2C transactions, and extends far beyond intermediary platforms (to cloud services providers).
At the same time, its scope of application is limited to those digital services where contracts can be concluded online, whereas EU businesses actually depend also on online intermediation services that enable the initiating, but not necessarily the conclusion, of transactions online (e.g. business pages on social media, which are crucial for attracting "offline traffic", building on important consumer review systems).
The legal definition of online market place being explored in Art. 2(19) of the draft revised Directive 2011/83/EU on consumer rights equally fails to capture the intermediation-element, as it would extend to contracts concluded on any regular retailer's webshop ("online marketplace means a service provider, as defined in point (b) of Article 2 of Directive 2000/31/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 8 June 2000 on certain legal aspects of information society services, in particular electronic commerce, in the Internal Market (‘Directive on electronic commerce’), which allows consumers to conclude distance contracts on the online marketplace’s online interface"). Finally, the upcoming EU proposal for a Regulation on crowdfunding is highly narrow in scope, and merely defines crowdfunding platforms as "an electronic information system on which crowdfunding services are provided".
As described in more detail in section 8.2, the legal definitional elements of "online intermediation services" do allow this precise scoping of online intermediary platforms. A definition has been developed on this basis around four technologically-neutral elements that are shared among the relevant types of online intermediaries:
- the fact that their service constitutes an information society service, as defined in Directive (EU) No 2015/1535;
- allowing business users to offer their products and services to consumers;
- with the aim to facilitate direct transactions between business users and consumers, irrespective of where these transactions are ultimately concluded; and
- provided on the basis of contractual relationships between, on the one hand, the online intermediary and, on the other hand, each of those business users and consumers.
Moreover, one policy option identified in this Impact Assessment report is to strengthen the effectiveness of the proposed ranking transparency obligation by extending it to online general search engines. Under this option, the existing legal definition of online search engines
would be incorporated into the legal instrument to allow for this targeted extension. The use of this separate legal definition for a type of online service provider that is different from the online platforms targeted will only help confirm the precise scope of the concept "online intermediation services".
The proposed definitions and scope are furthermore coherent with proposals addressing digital services in other areas, in particular in the field of taxation. There, a preferred option targets revenues of a business resulting from the exploitation of digital activities characterised by user value creation, namely advertising revenue and revenue from services provided by online marketplaces/intermediaries. Given the different objectives of the interventions are different, the conceptual scope of the two initiatives complement each other, and present no contradiction.
1.7.Evidence-base & types of issues covered
Importantly, these results are based on surveys among randomly selected business users of online platforms, as well as on an existing independent panel of around 2 500 businesses where all participants were required to respond (i.e. regardless of whether they had experienced problems). The random selection of businesses should guard against important aberrations in the results due to self-selection bias. Moreover, it should be noted that the number of reported issues is largely consistent between the overall results and the independent business panel (37% of the panel members experienced issues, which figure amounted to 68% for heavy users, against 46% of all business users surveyed). Finally, these results were tested with stakeholders from different groups, including by means of a large number of bilateral meetings, (separate and combined) workshops with platforms and business users, a Member State survey, a public consultation, comments received to the Inception Impact Assessment for this initiative, several meetings of the e-commerce expert group, focus groups hosted by the Joint Research Centre's policy design lab and by means of further independent studies on platforms' data and terms and conditions.
1.8.Overview of problem drivers
Platforms are increasingly an important vehicle for market access
•Digital trade is growing and increasingly intermediated by online platforms
•Platforms are important gateways to new (cross-border) market and business opportunities
Platforms can benefit from virtuous growth cycle due to strong data-driven network effects of unprecedented magnitude, speed and scale proper to the online world
•Indirect network effects are at the heart of the business model of online platforms: the increase in the number of users on one side of the platform (e.g. sellers, content creators, service providers) makes it more attractive to users on the other side (e.g. consumers, viewers) and the other way around.
•The network value increases very rapidly with the number of additional users on either side, while the cost increase to provide services to additional users on either side grows increasingly slowly. Platforms thus create their economic value by attracting/retaining users on both sides of the market, while the cost for supporting additional users is marginal: when a platform scales to millions of consumers, functions such as support are frequently automated in order to maintain low scaling costs.
•These 'winner-takes-most' dynamics are reinforced by platforms' a data-driven competitive advantage. Platforms have access to high quality, variety and volumes of data. This gives them insight into users' profiles/preferences, allowing them to deliver the best user experience. This leads to increased returns to scale, scope and network effects.
Imbalanced bargaining power and business users' dependency
•Above specifics lead to tendency towards market concentration: the bigger a platform is the stronger the network effects, which leads to increased bargaining power
•Platforms' business strategies are mainly focused on attracting end-users – platforms compete aggressively for the buyers, subsidising that side of the market through higher price and/or lower quality of service offered on the seller (business users) side
•Most businesses thus need to be present on more than one platform within each segment to reach consumers
Fear of retaliation
The above described dependency (due to platforms' "gateway" function and resulting greater bargaining power) leads to fear of retaliation. The latter renders the quantification of P2B issues difficult, thus preventing their timely identification and resolution.
|
1.9.Conclusion of Problem Definition
EU businesses cannot exploit the full potential of the platform economy because of issues in the platform-to-business relations and emerging re-fragmentation of the single market.
Business users active on platforms face a number of potentially harmful trading practices for which there is a lack of effective redress. According to a study carried out for the European Commission, these trading practices would concern a large number of business users. The results of the study show that 46% of business users encounter problems in their relation with platforms while this percentage is higher (75%) for business users realising more than half of their turnover on platforms. Almost one third of issues remain unresolved while 29% are solved only with difficulties. The unfair trading practices listed in this section are gradually undermining business trust in the platform economy. Trust is primordial to the platform economy since it allows increasing the number of users on both sides thus optimising data-driven network effects which fuel online platforms' growth. Potentially unfair and non-transparent P2B practices are therefore not only detrimental for business users (since they lead to direct loss in sales) but could also negatively impact the growth of the online intermediation sector and reduce platform operators' revenues (through unrealised commissions). The long-term sustainability of the platform economy is therefore closely linked to issues encountered by business users in their relations with platforms.
Platform operators are increasingly faced with emerging national legislations which start fragmenting the naturally cross-border market for online intermediation in the EU. The uncoordinated adoption of national legislations - whether platform-specific or covering B2B issues in general but applicable to platform businesses – may result in divergent regulatory measures across the EU and carry the risk of hampering online platforms' ability to scale up. The EU platform economy is of intrinsic global nature and is by definition cross-border. Scaling-up is core to platforms' business strategies as it allows for stronger network effects.
1.10.Legal basis
The combined effect of potentially unfair trading practices, lack of effective redress, and emerging regulatory re-fragmentation
Today, online platforms are the most effective way to provide goods and services across borders (cf. section 2.3.3). This inherent cross-border nature of online platforms distinguishes the present initiative from the "traditional Single Market" approach, where existing national fragmentation inhibits the scaling up of predominantly national actors (e.g. national telecom operators, or incumbent energy suppliers).
The present initiative indeed rather involves a longer-term risk of what would essentially be a significant "re-fragmentation" of the Single Market, evidenced in the general pressure on national legislators and authorities to regulate the novel online platform-business models, including, in light of dependent businesses being subject to a range of harmful trading practices in regard of which existing national legislation does not provide effective redress.
This real risk of fragmentation is one part of a three-pronged interlinked problem, which otherwise includes unilateral P2B trading practices that are capable of causing direct harm to businesses and the ineffectiveness of redress in addressing such unilateral trading practices.
The present initiative therefore aims to prevent direct harm to businesses in the immediate term, and to safeguard the Single Market-potential of online platforms in the medium to long term, by improving business user trust and by enabling well-informed policy responses at the appropriate level. It therefore serves to protect the interests of all participants in the online platform ecosystems, and Article 114 TFEU constitutes the relevant legal basis.
1.11.Subsidiarity: EU action required to provide harmonised framework for cross-border, online platform-specific issues
EU action is the only way to prevent direct harm to businesses in the immediate term, and to safeguard the Single Market-potential of online platforms in the medium to long term. One part of the interlinked problem set is that existing redress possibilities including national rules are ineffective in tackling the online platform-specific cross-border trading practices. The ineffectiveness of existing redress combined with the occurrence of such trading practices is in fact not only causing direct harm to EU businesses, but also fuelling the long(er)-term risk of fragmentation, which would negatively affect the Single Market potential of online platforms.
EU action targeting online platforms will not result in any fragmentation in the legal framework within which EU businesses operate, as businesses use online platforms for a dedicated purpose (most efficient way to make direct cross-border sales to consumers) while facing specific problems (access to justice is particularly ineffective, and delisting, data & self-learning algorithms are not seen offline). Indeed, the set-up of online intermediation does not have an offline equivalent. Online platforms enable direct transactions between business users and consumers while maintaining a degree of control over them. Supermarkets do not enable such direct transactions, whereas shopping malls do but without maintaining control (in relation to shopping malls, it is noted that leases for retail space sometimes include turnover-based rent calculations which actually serve to protect the business user in case of disappointing "foot fall" – reflecting a bargaining position that is at least equal). Second, the combination of drivers underlying the problem in the present initiative is specific to online platforms, with in particular the size and nature of the data-driven indirect and direct network effects leading to a particularly important dependency of business users on platforms as the most effective gateway to very large cross-border consumer markets. Finally, the individual problems are equally specific to online platforms; in the offline world, the effects of paid-for placement are for example not opaque (all suppliers can visit the supermarket and verify). Also, the negative effects of unilateral P2B trading practices partly result from the lack of effective bilateral complaint-handling which, in turn, is due to the unparalleled size of businesses and products offered (even a specialised platform like Etsy.com has 2 million sellers).
1.12.A light-touch and staged co-regulatory option geared to online intermediation
The principal aim of the Initiative is to improve transparency and bilateral conflict resolution in a first step, focusing on internal complaint-handling and mediation, subject to transparency-enabled monitoring. This links to the particularity of online intermediation, where speed is crucial and issues can only be solved quickly by the platform itself. Indeed, 71% of business users that took action to resolve issues turned to the platform itself, but in the majority of cases (68%) the issue could not be resolved. And although currently used only to a limited extent, online mediation did allow problems to be resolved in a majority of cases (64% for heavy users).
The proposed regulatory framework therefore requires (and enables) monitoring rather than public enforcement. The proposed legal obligations in the Preferred Option nonetheless play on important reputational levers (that can influence both businesses and consumers) and will already help to prevent harm from P2B trading practices. Indeed, enhanced transparency on the "business-friendliness" of incumbent online platforms, combined with a dedicated monitoring function, should provide real additional competitive parameters for the thousands of online platform start-ups that exist in the EU as well as at global level.
The legal transparency and redress obligations at the same time mostly require a one-off implementation by the platform, and are relatively easy to monitor. The provision providing representative organisations with legal standing to bring actions on behalf of business users is therefore foreseen to ensure enforcement exclusively of these high-level legal transparency and redress obligations, in light of the main barriers to justice identified in online intermediation, i.e. the fear of retaliation and the use of exclusive choice of forum-clauses. To reflect this purpose, it will also be limited to injunctive (and not compensatory) relief and therefore not imply additional costs over and above those identified in section 6. It will at the same time be fully aligned with the quality criteria for representative bodies set out in the 2013 Commission Recommendation on Collective Redress. By limiting standing for representative organisations to applications for injunctive relief only, it is more effective and can avoid the problems encountered at Member State-level in relation to compensatory collective redress.
Indeed, legal standing to bring injunctive actions for organisations representing SMEs is an established phenomenon in the area of unfair trading practices in all EU Member States.
1.13.High-level but effective transparency obligations with a scope for self-regulation
The proposed legal obligations will balance the need to be concrete in order to provide the required legal certainty for both online platforms as well as their business with the need to prevent any significant compliance burden.
This will be achieved by providing clear yet technologically-neutral principles and concrete interpretative examples in a directly applicable EU Regulation. The transparency obligations will also translate only to targeted descriptions to be included in platforms' general terms and conditions rather than at the level of individual businesses, services or products, which approach reflects the dependency-situation that falls within the scope of the Initiative.
By way of example, on ranking it will be explained in the proposed legal instrument that the description of the main ranking parameters shall be general in nature and refer to the average situation applying for the relevant online intermediation services, which, however, will need to be based on real historic results. In this regard, it will be explained that by complying with this provision platforms must enable business users to obtain a reasonable understanding of the functioning thereof, to the extent these parameters do not individually or jointly constitute trade secrets as defined in Article 2(1) of the Trade Secrets Directive. Similarly, on the use of MFN clauses, online platforms will be required to provide only a targeted description of the main justifications for their use, while referring to concrete data and facts.
Such an approach is also based on selected real-life industry examples of meaningful transparency provided by certain – but not all – platform operators. For example, one particular collaborative economy platform that also hosts professional users provides a general page setting out the six main factors determining listing results, providing for each factor a concrete example of what is meant. In addition, this collaborative economy platform explicitly mentions that it may boost results of business users that are new to the platform.
Another vertically integrated e-commerce platform explicitly commits in its general terms and conditions to log and give access to all activities of business users on the platform in the form of statistics and reports.
Therefore, the legal obligations constitute self-standing rules. They however impose only minimum levels of required transparency and the Regulation will be drafted in a results-oriented manner, providing only interpretative examples of how the desired result may be achieved. Hence, the Initiative deliberately leaves room to industry to develop different methods to comply with the legal principles. In this regard, the foreseen dedicated monitoring exercises to specifically inform a possible review of the legal instrument will aim at triggering an important self-regulatory effort in a first step - with the potential for this to be incorporated in any future rules that may be required in a second step. The Initiative will include an encouragement to industry to draw up legitimate codes of conduct for the implementation of the legal principles in the most useful and efficient manner in light of evolving technologies. Moreover, the legal instrument will comprise a review clause that includes an explicit reference that any such legitimate codes of conduct may be taken into account in the evaluation by the Commission.
1.14.Effectiveness of a legal definition of online intermediation services
The legal definitional elements of "online intermediation services" allow a precise scoping of online platforms that can exhibit the dependency-related problems that the present Initiative aims to address.
First, all targeted platform services are provided as part of an "information society service", in line with the existing services-based definition in Regulation 2015/1535/EU. This limits the scope of the intervention to online services.
Second, online platforms can only act as a "gateway" to consumers in case their online intermediation services enable in some way commercial relations occurring between two different groups of direct users (business users and consumers) of the same online intermediation services. The definition will to this end refer to the existence of a direct contractual relationship between, on the one hand, the relevant information society service providing the online intermediation services and, on the other hand, each of its business users and private users (consumers), as the targeted multi-sided markets are without exception characterised by such triangular business-platform-consumer contractual relationships. A wide array of online tools that have some (one-sided or auxiliary) involvement in the commercial relations between business users and consumers but that do not constitute a "gateway intermediary" are thus excluded (e.g. ad serving platforms or search engine optimisation software). The notion of "consumer" in addition refers exclusively to private individuals under EU law, further limiting the scope of the initiative to online platforms that intermediate B2C commercial relations, where network effects and related imbalances in bargaining power are largest, and where evidence of harmful trading practices is available.
Third, the proposed legal transparency obligations will apply only to the extent online platforms unilaterally impose "pre-defined, standard terms and conditions", to reflect the superior bargaining power of the "gateway intermediaries" that the initiative targets.
Fourth, the "online intermediation services" will be defined as consisting in (i) "allowing business users to offer their goods and services to consumers", (ii) "with the aim to facilitate the initiating of direct transactions between business users and consumers, irrespective of where these transactions are ultimately concluded". Crucial gateway intermediaries including "local search" services where the transactional decision is taken online regardless of where the deal is ultimately concluded (e.g. offline for restaurants) will thereby be covered, whereas mere auxiliary activities such as online payment services will be excluded. The latter activity is namely inherently auxiliary to the supply of goods and services and can never be used on a standalone basis to initiate commercial relations.
The existing legal definition of online search engines
would be incorporated into the legal instrument for a targeted extension of the legal transparency provision on ranking. The use of this separate legal definition for a type of online service provider that is different from the online platforms, which will be targeted horizontally, would only help confirm the narrow scope of the concept "online intermediation services".
The additional inclusion of online search engines in the scope of the provision would, however, be limited to the provisions on ranking and legal representative standing, in order to maintain the balance of effectiveness, efficiency, and proportionality.
Alignment with future legal definitions, e.g. in the field of taxation is currently in progress, with due regard to the different objectives and the requirements to limit the unnecessary proliferation of legal definitions of platforms.
2.Procedural Information
2.1.Identification
This Staff Working Paper was prepared by Directorate F of Directorate General 'Communications Networks, Content and Technology' and Directorate E of DG GROW. The Decide reference of this initiative is PLAN/2017/1375.
2.2.Organisation and chronology
Several other services of the Commission with a policy interest in the initiative have been associated in the development of this analysis. An Inter-Service Steering Group (ISG) has been created to this effect. The ISG includes representatives of DG COMP, DG GROW, DG ECFIN, DG EMPL, DG JUST, DG TRADE, DG ENV, DG ENER, LS, EPSC, JRC, RTD, EAC.
The last meeting of the ISG, chaired by the Secretariat General of the European Commission was held on 30 October 2017. Minutes Ares(2017)5417127 of the meeting are enclosed.
2.3.Regulatory Scrutiny Board
This staff working document was discussed at the regulatory scrutiny board meeting of 29 November 2017. The Board issued a negative opinion.
2.4.Evidence
The options considered in this impact assessment were designed by taking into account the following main inputs, in addition to less central references quoted in the body of the Impact Assessment:
1.Studies commissioned by the European Commission
On business to business issues
§ECORYS, Business-to-Business relations in the online platform environment FWC ENTR/300/PP/2013/FC-WIFO, 2017 (commissioned by DG GROW & DG CNECT )
§ERNST&YOUNG, Contractual Relationships between Online Platforms and Their Professional Users, SMART 2017/0041 (commissioned by DG CNECT)
§VVA, Data in platform-to-business relations, Contract nr FWC ENTR/172/PP/2012/FC-lot2 Service contract Nr 645/PP/GRO/IM A/17/1131/10398, forthcoming (commissioned by DG GROW)
§GRAEF I. et al., Contractual terms and conditions of large e-commerce platforms, 2016 (commissioned by DG GROW)
§Flash Eurobarometer 439 "The use of online marketplaces and search engines by SMEs" of June 2016 (4 904 respondents)
On consumer issues
§LSE et al., Behavioural Study on the Transparency of Online Platforms, Request for Specific Services 2016 85 04 for the implementation of the Framework Contract no Chafea/2015/CP/01, forthcoming (commissioned by DG JUST)
§Ipsos Public Affairs Consumer market study on online market segmentation through personalised pricing/offers in the European Union, forthcoming (commissioned by DG JUST)
§GfK et al., Behavioural study on advertising and marketing practices in online social media, forthcoming (commissioned by DG JUST)
§VVA, Exploratory study of consumer issues in online peer-to-peer platform markets, May 2017 (commissioned by DG JUST)
§Special Eurobarometer 447 "Online platforms" of June 2016 (27 969 respondents)
§Standard Eurobarometer 86 "Public opinion in the European Union" of Autumn 2016 survey (27 818 respondents)
Research conducted by the Joint Research Centre
§
JRC research online platforms
§JRC, Quality discrimination in multi-sided markets
§JRC, Platform to business relations in online ecosystem
Other data sources
§Dealroom economic report and data set on online platforms in Europe
§
Eurostat 2017
: use of social networks by businesses
§
Eurostat 2017
: use of online advertising by businesses
§Report on the Monitoring Exercise Carried out in the Online Hotel Booking Sector by EU Competition Authorities in 2016
2.Industry surveys and studies consulted
§The Booksellers Association of the UK & Ireland, survey into business-to-business relations on online platforms of September 2017 (83 respondents)
§Amazon Webretailer survey (1 500 respondents)
§App Alliance survey (673 respondents)
§IAB programmatic advertising survey (1 232 respondents)
§Future of Business survey, report on international trade (49 081 respondents), by the World Bank, OECD, Facebook
§iOS developer survey
https://tapdaq.com/blog/apple-developers-think-you-are-just-one-inconsistent-loop
Survey among crowdworkers: "Unfair treatment by requesters and disinterest from platform.
http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_protect/---protrav/---travail/documents/publication/wcms_479693.pdf
Copenhagen Economics study
(for EDiMA) - online platforms the engines of the EU economy
§
Copenhagen Economics study
(for Ebay) - economics effects of marketplace bans
§Roland Berger report "
Fair play in the digital arena
" (for 1&1 in Germany)
§
Oxera study
(Google sponsored) on benefits of online platforms.
Technical appendix
3.Other sources
§Labour platforms EP report:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/IDAN/2016/587316/IPOL_IDA(2016)587316_EN.pdf
§
TNO NL report
- Digital platforms: an analytical framework for identifying and evaluating policy options
§UK House of Lords report on
Online platforms
§CNNum Report
§
Monopolkommission Special Report No 68 "Competition policy: The challenge of digital markets" of 2015
§UK CMA report price comparison tools
§
2.5.External expertise
The European Commission sought external expertise, as follows, before drafting this Impact Assessment. Views of the experts have contributed to the problem framing and evidence collection strategy. Consultation of experts listed here below does not imply automatic endorsement on their side of the Impact Assessment report.
·Andrei Hagiu, Harvard Business School in November 2015
·Annabelle Gawer, Imperial College of London in November 2015, February 2016
·Bernard Rieder, University of Amsterdam in November 2015
·Bruno Jullien, Toulouse School of Economics in November 2015
·David Evans, University of Chicago in October 2015
·Geoffrey Parker, Tulane University in February 2016
·Giorgos Zervas, Boston University in November 2015
·Inge Graef, Catholic University of Leuven in November 2015
·Jonathan Cave, University of Warwick in December 2015
·Jose Luis Moraga Gonzalez, Free University of Amsterdam in November 2015
·Lapo Filistrucchi, University of Florence in November 2015
·Marc Bourreau, Telecom – Paris Tech in November 2015
·Nicolai van Gorp, E-conomics in January 2016
·Peter Evans, Center for Global Enterprise in February 2016
·Pieter Nooren, Christine Balch, TNO in October 2016
·Viktor Mayer-Schönberger, Oxford Internet Institute, in December 2015
3.Stakeholder Consultation
3.1.The stakeholders engagement strategy
The Commission has consulted broadly on the business-to-business related issues emerging in the online platforms' ecosystem. First, preceding the Communication on online platforms, a wide consultation led to a clearer definition of the problem space and the start of an in-depth fact-finding exercise. Second, a series of workshops and broad consultation through several surveys informed the problem definition and led to preliminary policy options. Finally, in-depth focus groups, workshops, a questionnaire and open presentation to the Member States contributed to the design and testing of policy options.
In addition to the consultation tools used, the Commission's services have met or interviewed through bilateral meetings a series of stakeholders, as listed here-below.
In developing the stakeholder engagement strategy, the stakeholder mapping included: (i) a spectrum of business users of online platforms (to the extent possible per type of platform, size of companies, geographical spread in Europe), (ii) a long-list of online platforms (in different sectors, different company sizes, established in Europe or international), (iii) citizens (through consumer organizations and digital rights civil society representatives), (iv) third party services (e.g. payment or data intermediaries), and (v) academia.
The different consultation tools as well as brief summaries of their results are described here-below.
3.2.Bilateral meetings
In the course of the preparation of this fact-finding exercise, the Commission has engaged with the following stakeholders through bilateral meetings:
§ACCOR Hotels
§AGCOM
§Airbnb
§Akamai Technologies
§Allegro
§Alibaba
§Amazon
§App Developers Alliance
§Apple
§Bundesverband E-Commerce und Versandhandel Deutschland e.V. (bevh)
§Booking.com
§Cicero group
§Der Mittelstandsverbund – ZGV e.V.
§Deutsche Telekom
§Ebay
§Edima
§EFSI - European Federation for Services to Individuals (personal and household services)
§Enterprise Holdings
§ETSY
§ETTSA
§European Association of Communications Agencies
§European Booksellers' Association
§European eCommerce and Omni-Channel Trade Association (EMOTA)
§European Hotel Forum
§European Games Developer Federation
§Expedia
§Facebook
§Federation of European Publishers
§Gobee.bike
§Google
§Hilton worldwide
§HOTREC
§Independent Retail Europe
§idealo
§King Digital
§Mon Orxata
§Mozilla
§Mindbase
§Open Forum Europe
§Independent Retail Europe
§Rakuten
§Salesforce
§Sentiance
§Seznam - web portal and search engine
§Spotify
§SRIW/Bitkom
§Sugartrends
§TechUK
§The Booksellers Association of the UK & Ireland Ltd
§TripAdvisor
§Union des Métiers et des Industries de l'Hôtellerie
§United Internet Media and CEO of 1&1 Mail & Media Applications
§World Economic Forum
§Yelp, Inc.
§Zalando
3.3.The Outcome of the Public Consultations
3.3.1.Public consultation on online platforms, 24 September 2015 until 6 January 2016
The public consultation's objective was to gather evidence and views on the regulatory environment for platforms, liability of intermediaries, data and cloud and collaborative economy. It was launched on 24 September 2015 and closed on 6 January 2016.
More than 1036 replies were received via the procedures foreseen in the consultation. An additional 10 599 individual contributions were received via one single advocacy association, mostly addressing only some of the questions posed in the consultation.
Not all respondents answered every question or section. More than 80 percent of the respondents replied to the sections on 'platforms' and 'online intermediaries & tackling illegal content', around 60 percent of the respondents replied to the section on 'data and cloud computing' and around one third replied to the section on 'collaborative economy'.
As to the geographical distribution of responses:
·Replies came from 27 EU Member States.
·About 10 percent of the replies came from outside of the EU, more than half of them from the United States.
·The largest number of responses came from Germany (17 %), Belgium (13 %) and United Kingdom (11 %).
By category, the respondents were:
·462 individual citizens
·243 associations or trade organizations representing businesses
·2 "other"
·157 businesses, including suppliers using an online platform to provide services
·46 associations or trade organizations representing civil society
·46 online platforms
·34 research institutions or Think Tanks
·28 public authorities
·15 associations or trade organizations representing consumers
As pointed out in the qualitative analysis of the public consultation, businesses and associations of businesses were primarily concerned with platforms dominance leading to competition and fair-trading issues, copyright/IP rights protection, and to some extent the fairness of rankings and neutrality of online search results. Businesses and associations of businesses suggested that online platforms should display clearly their compliance with IP rights, clarity over usage of data, transparency / traceability of online service operators.
Most business and citizen respondents stated that platforms should be more transparent notably about search results, clarity about the actual supplier and reviews mechanisms. They also consider that online platforms do not provide sufficient information on personal and non-personal data collected an