EUR-Lex Access to European Union law

Back to EUR-Lex homepage

This document is an excerpt from the EUR-Lex website

Document 52017SC0114

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL to empower the competition authorities of the Member States to be more effective enforcers and to ensure the proper functioning of the internal market

SWD/2017/0114 final - 2017/063 (COD)

Brussels, 22.3.2017

SWD(2017) 114 final

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

IMPACT ASSESSMENT

Accompanying the document

Proposal for a

DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

to empower the competition authorities of the Member States to be more effective enforcers and to ensure the proper functioning of the internal market

{COM(2017) 142 final}
{SWD(2017) 115 final}
{SWD(2017) 116 final}


Table of Contents

1CONTEXT

1.1Why enforcement of the EU competition rules matters

1.2The role played by the national competition authorities

2What is the problem and why is it a problem?

2.1Untapped potential for more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules

2.2Underlying problem drivers

2.2.1Problem driver 1: Lack of effective competition tools

2.2.2Problem driver 2: Lack of powers to impose deterrent fines

2.2.3Problem driver 3: Divergences between leniency programmes in terms of summary applications, core principles, protection of self-incriminating material and interplay with individual sanctions can lead to less effective competition enforcement against cartels

2.2.4Problem driver 4: Lack of safeguards NCAs can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

2.3Who is affected by the problem?

2.4What is the EU dimension of the problem?

2.5How would the problem evolve, all things being equal?

3Why should the EU act?

4What should be achieved?

5What are the various options to achieve the objectives?

5.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

5.2Option 2: further soft action

5.2.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

5.2.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

5.2.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

5.2.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

5.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by both soft action and detailed rules where appropriate

5.3.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

5.3.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

5.3.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

5.3.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

5.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments to be effective enforcers

5.4.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

5.4.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

5.4.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

5.4.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

5.5Discarded option

6What are the impacts of the different policy options and who will be affected?

6.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

6.2Option 2: further soft action

6.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by soft action/detailed rules where appropriate

6.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

7How do the options compare?

7.1Comparison of the options

7.1.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

7.1.2Option 2: further soft action

7.1.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by soft action/detailed rules where appropriate

7.1.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

7.1.5Overview of how the options compare

7.2Preferred policy option

7.2.1All NCAs would have an effective enforcement toolbox

7.2.2All NCAs would be able to impose (or seek) deterrent fines

7.2.3All NCAs would have effective leniency programmes which would encourage companies to come clean across the EU

7.2.4All NCAs would have guarantees of independence and resources

7.2.5Nature of the instrument and legal basis

8Monitoring and evaluation


1CONTEXT

1.1Why enforcement of the EU competition rules matters

The EU competition rules seek to provide everyone in Europe with better quality goods and services at lower prices by ensuring that firms compete solely on their merits.

In a competitive market, the simplest way for a company to gain more market share is to offer a better price than its competitors. This is not only good for consumers - when more people can afford to buy products, it encourages businesses to produce and boosts the economy in general.

Competition also encourages businesses to improve the quality of goods and services they sell to attract more customers and expand market share. Quality can mean various things: products that last longer or work better, better after-sales or technical support or friendlier and better service. In a competitive market, businesses will try to make their products different from the rest so they are more attractive. This results in greater choice: consumers can select the product that offers the right balance between price and quality. To deliver this choice, and produce better products, businesses need to be innovative in their product concepts, design, production techniques, services, etc.

Competition within the EU also helps make European companies stronger outside the EU and able to hold their own against global competitors. Effective enforcement of the EU competition rules is therefore indispensable for the Union to both meet the challenges, and seize the opportunities, of globalisation.

The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) recognises the importance of fair competition in the internal market. Article 101 TFEU prohibits agreements between two or more companies which restrict competition. The most flagrant example of illegal conduct infringing Article 101 TFEU is the creation of a cartel between competitors to fix prices, to limit production or to share markets or customers between them. Instead of competing with each other, cartel members rely on an agreed course of action, which reduces their incentives to provide new or better products and services at competitive prices. As a consequence, their clients (consumers or other businesses) end up paying more for less quality. Prohibiting a cartel therefore has a direct positive effect on consumers, business and competition as a whole.

Article 102 TFEU prohibits firms that hold a dominant position on a given market from abusing that position, for example by charging unfair prices, by limiting production, or by refusing to innovate, all of which is to the detriment of consumers' interests and may lead to the exclusion of competitors from the market by other means than competing on the merits of the products or services provided. Stopping companies from abusing their dominant position allows other companies a chance to compete fairly and to grow.

Competition enforcement is about applying rules to make sure companies compete fairly with each other. This means that businesses benefit from a level playing field, allowing them to compete on their merits and capitalise on any competitive advantage they may have. Greater competition encourages enterprise and efficiency, which in turn benefits consumers.

Competition enforcement in Europe is a vital part of the single market . The single market is recognised as Europe’s best asset in times of increasing globalisation. The Commission is determined to build on the strength of the single market by making it fairer and deeper. 1 The European competition rules are one of the defining features of the single market: if competition is distorted, Europe cannot deliver on its full potential. Competition is not an end in itself. It is an indispensable element of a functioning internal market guaranteeing a level playing field. It contributes to an efficient use of society's scarce resources, technological development and innovation, a better choice of products and services, lower prices, higher quality and greater productivity in the economy as a whole.

1.2The role played by the national competition authorities

The EU Member States are essential partners of the European Commission for enforcing the EU competition rules. Since 2004, the national competition authorities of the EU Member States (NCAs) are empowered by Regulation 1/2003 2 to apply the EU competition rules alongside the Commission. Indeed, the NCAs are obliged to apply the EU competition rules to agreements or practices that are capable of having an effect on trade between Member States. For more than a decade both the Commission and the NCAs have enforced the EU competition rules in close cooperation in the European Competition Network (ECN). The ECN was created in 2004 expressly for this purpose. The ECN is recognised as a successful and innovative model of governance for the complementary implementation of EU law at both European and national levels.

Enforcement of the EU competition rules by both the Commission and the NCAs is an essential building block for the creation of an open, competitive and innovative single market and is crucial for creating jobs and growth in important sectors of the economy, in particular, the energy, telecoms, digital and transport sectors.

Enforcement of the EU competition rules is now taking place on a scale which the Commission could never have achieved on its own. Since 2004, the Commission and the NCAs took over 1000 enforcement decisions, with the NCAs being responsible for 85%. Action by a multiplicity of enforcers is a much stronger, more effective and better deterrent for companies that may be tempted to breach the EU competition rules. The Commission typically investigates anticompetitive practices or agreements that have effects on competition in three or more Member States or where it is useful to set a Europe-wide precedent. The NCAs are usually well placed to act where competition is substantially affected in their territory. NCAs have the expertise on how markets work in their own Member State. That knowledge is of great value when enforcing the competition rules. Action at national level promotes grass root support for competition enforcement. 3

The NCAs have tackled many anticompetitive practices with a direct impact on consumers and citizens/tax payers. For example, at the end of 2014, the French NCA fined manufacturers of home care and personal care products nearly €1 billion for having coordinated their commercial policy towards supermarkets, which allowed them to maintain artificially high prices for the end consumers. The level of the fines is linked to the significance of the concerned markets, namely around €4.7 billion for home care products and €7 billion for personal care products. The practices also had an important impact on consumers as these products account for a significant share of household spending as at the time of these practices consumers in France spent an average of €190 per year for personal care products alone. NCAs have also uncovered and sanctioned a significant number of cartels in the food sector. For example, in 2014, the Greek NCA fined poultry meat producers a total of €39.9 million for fixing prices of fresh and frozen poultry meat and for allocating customers.

Enforcement by the NCAs also benefits citizens/tax payers more generally where they uncover and bring practices to an end which are at the expense of public bodies, such as municipalities or the social security system. In 2011, the German NCA imposed fines totaling €20.5 million on manufacturers of fire-fighting vehicles for having fixed the prices and carved up the German market for fire-fighting vehicles among themselves. The infringement covered more than 80% of the market and caused many municipalities considerable financial harm. In 2014, the Italian NCA imposed fines of more than €180 million on two pharmaceutical companies for having hindered the use of an inexpensive drug for treating common eye diseases among elderly people, meaning that patients were forced to buy a more expensive product. The agreement resulted in an additional expense for the national health service estimated at more than €45 million in 2012 and incurring possible future costs of more than €600 million per year.

The NCAs thus play a key role in making sure that the single market works well and fairly. This benefits both businesses which can compete more fairly on more open markets throughout Europe, as well as consumers who get a better choice of goods at lower prices. However, there is potential for the NCAs to do more.

2What is the problem and why is it a problem?

2.1Untapped potential for more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules

A key goal of the decentralised system for the enforcement of the EU competition rules that was put in place in 2004 was to ensure greater, more effective enforcement by a multiplicity of authorities through-out the EU.

The European Commission estimated the annual customer benefits 4 of only its decisions prohibiting cartels (e.g. excluding other enforcement action under Articles 101 and 102 TFEU) for the period 2010-2015. This varied between €1 billion up to €10.8 billion, depending on the year considered: 5

Estimates of customer benefits resulting from cartel prohibition decisions at EU level

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

EUR billion

7.2-10.8

1.8-2.7

1.35-2.0

4.89-5.66

1.78-2.64

0.99-1.49

Model simulations show that the European Commission's cartel decisions and merger interventions have a sizeable impact on growth and jobs: GDP increases by 0.4% after five years and by 0.7% in the long run, and after ten years around 650 000 cumulated new jobs are created (the relevant simulations are based on a chain of assumptions which, however, do not undermine the usefulness of the analysis in getting a better understanding of the role of competition policy in society 6 ).

At national level, the Dutch competition authority estimated that the outcome of its actions in terms of the expected future benefits for consumers who will pay less for products and services at €260 million for 2014 (the relevant assessment appears to cover also merger control, and the relevant calculation method leads to results that might vary from one year to the next, however, it provides a useful proxy for the impact of the authority's enforcement activity 7 ).

Similarly the UK competition authority estimated that the average direct financial benefit to consumers of only its antitrust enforcement activities was £73 million averaged over a three year period. 8  These figures only take into account the direct price effect of competition interventions for consumers and the total benefits extend beyond prices and include effects on quality, choice and innovation. 9 The UK competition authority also estimated that for the period 2013 to 2016 the ratio of direct benefits to cost was £10.6 for every pound of relevant cost to the taxpayer. 10 .

Despite these positive outcomes, there is untapped potential for more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by the NCAs.

While it is difficult to determine the effects on economic growth from a lack of effective competition law enforcement, it has been estimated that each year losses of €181-320 billion – approximately 3% of EU GDP – accrue owing to the existence of undiscovered cartels. 11 It is difficult to assess how many anti-competitive cartels are undetected in Europe because companies inevitably try to keep them secret. However, a study indicates that less than 20% of cartels in the EU between 1985 and 2010 were detected. 12 Given that there is only limited knowledge available about the rate at which cartels are discovered, this study relies on methods frequently used only to make inferences in another discipline so its conclusiveness might be considered questionable by some. Nevertheless, its results provide very useful indications about the levels of undetected cartels in Europe. If one takes 15% as the rate of detection of cartels 13 and assumes that detected cartels are not too dissimilar to undiscovered cartels, the total value drained from the European economy by such collusion could be in the range of more than 3% of 2012 euro-area GDP. 14 Cartels typically increase prices: the empirical evidence in academic literature suggests that the median cartel overcharge lies between 17 and 30%. 15 When cartels are not detected, consumers have to bear the price of this overcharge.

A primary goal of competition policy enforcement is to deter anticompetitive behaviour by companies thereby maintaining a level playing field in product markets to the benefit of the end consumer. The deterrent effect of a cartel prohibition, for example, depends on the impact of the decision by the competition authority on the existing and future cartelists' perceived likelihood of getting caught and on the size of the expected fines. Attempts have been made to get rough estimates of the deterrent effects of inter alia prohibiting and sanctioning cartels. Surveys of competition lawyers and companies in the UK and the Netherlands indicate that the number of cartels deterred per cartel detected varies between 5 and 28. 16 Keeping in mind the caveats and uncertainties in measuring deterrence (the difficultly in knowing how many undetected cartels exist), there is survey evidence suggesting that the impact of deterrence in terms of avoided consumer harm is significant. For example, one study – basing itself on the existing literature and the European Commission's competition enforcement in 2012-2014 – uses lower and upper bounds (boundary) assumptions as to the amount of avoided consumer harm which is deterred resulting from each cartel detected and sanctioned. 17  The lower bound of the total avoided consumer harm is estimated to be between 10 and 30 times the harm caused to the customers of each detected cartel. While not possible to determine precisely, there are thus indications that the untapped potential of making competition enforcement more effective is considerable.

Experience shows that equipping a competition authority with additional tools significantly contributes to untapping the potential of its enforcement activities. For example, in the 20-year period spanning from 1990 until 2010, the Spanish Competition Authority uncovered and fined a total of only around 10 cartels. The introduction in February 2008 of a Leniency Programme, as well as bestowing the Authority with increased powers with which to carry out inspections, completely changed the picture. In the 6 year period between 2010 and 2015 this figure has increased five-fold with a total of 57 cartels being fined a combined total of 1,200 million euros. 18

The potential for more effective competition enforcement is also directly experienced by consumers and companies. According to a recent survey, over two-thirds (68%) of EU citizens have experienced a lack of competition in at least one sector that resulted in problems such as higher prices, less product or supplier choice, or lower quality. 19 EU citizens point to a range of sectors in Europe where they have experienced a problem resulting from a lack of competition, notably, the energy sector (gas, electricity etc-28%), transport services (railways, airlines -23%), and pharmaceutical products (21%). 20 In addition, the Consumer Markets Scoreboard regularly identifies markets in Europe which are not functioning well for consumers, in particular in terms of choice and problems experienced by consumers. 21

In the context of the European Semester, the European Commission has also identified a number of sectors where there is still scope for improving competition. For example, a limited degree of competition in the retail sector resulting in high prices for consumer goods can be observed in Belgium, Denmark and Finland. The business services sector in Austria and Malta is also experiencing low competition. Similarly, a lack of competition in the telecom and broadband sectors results in higher prices in Croatia and Cyprus. 22 The transport sector in Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, Germany, and Slovenia could also benefit from increased competition.

The lack of competition on markets is tackled in two main ways: (1) by removing anti-competitive regulatory barriers and (2) through effective enforcement of competition rules. Accordingly, the European Semester focuses not just on the elimination of regulatory barriers, but also on the establishment of an efficient competition framework in all Member States enabling NCAs to tackle anticompetitive conduct by companies. 23

For example, the achievement of the EU Energy Union strategy is dependent both on removing regulatory barriers and on effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by the Commission and the NCAs. To have secure, affordable, low-carbon energy for all EU consumers and businesses, energy must flow easily between EU countries. The European Commission is currently investigating contractual restrictions which may prevent the supply of gas into other countries. 24 However, in the gas and electricity businesses there are many complex relationships which the Commission cannot solve on its own. At some levels of the market, NCAs are very well placed to investigative anti-competitive restrictions. Some NCAs are focusing on these issues, 25 but more could be done. 26

There is a clearly established link between the role and the ability of NCAs to act and fully enforce the EU competition rules and ensuring competition on markets. According to the OECD, 27 there is solid evidence in support of each of the relationships shown below:

If competition authorities are not in a position to be effective enforcers, undistorted competition in markets is not ensured and the ensuing benefits in terms of higher productivity growth, which in turn generates economic growth, are not fully realised.

Studies have shown that the inability of competition authorities to apply the competition rules can have a negative impact on growth. 28 For example, the US National Industry Recovery Act, which selectively suspended anti-trust laws in the 1930s and authorised companies to establish cartels, brought a 10% reduction in manufacturing output. 29

76% of stakeholders in the public consultation launched by the Commission in November 2015 on how to empower the national competition authorities to be more effective enforcers 30 said that the NCAs could do more to enforce the EU competition rules. The NCAs themselves repeatedly call on the Commission to help them to be more effective enforcers, because they do not always have the means and instruments they need.

The level of enforcement of the EU competition rules is very unevenly spread in the EU. Some NCAs have adopted very few decisions applying the EU competition rules since 2004. For example, between 2004 and 2015, the Irish (2), Maltese (3), Estonian (4), Latvian (5), Luxembourgish (5), Cypriot (6), Bulgarian (7), Czech (10), Finnish (14) and Polish (14) NCAs adopted less than 15 decisions, whereas the French (119), German (113), Italian (112) and Spanish (101) NCAs took more than 100 decisions in the same period.

Although the number of enforcement decisions depends on a number of variable factors, for example authorities may invest much more time in complex cases or cases that involve a significant number of market players, the above data demonstrate that there is clear scope for more effective enforcement. Even those NCAs with a high number of enforcement decisions face issues such as their inability to impose effective fines (see section 2.2.2 below). Companies have little incentive to comply with competition law when they see that infringements are not sanctioned.

The inability of NCAs to realise their full potential to be effective enforcers of the EU competition rules undermines the enforcement of one of the key chapters of the EU Treaty on the functioning of the European Union and the decentralised system set up by Regulation 1/2003. 31 It also impairs one of the main facets of the single market, which is ensuring that competition is not distorted in Europe. A lack of effective enforcement by the NCAs means that the framework conditions for efficiently functioning markets and improved competition conditions in the internal market are not ensured.

For consumers, the lack of capacity of NCAs to un-leash their full potential to enforce the EU competition rules means that they miss out on the benefits of competition enforcement, namely lower prices, better quality, wider choice and product innovation.

Stronger application of the EU competition law principles across Europe would contribute to the achievement of the overall objectives of EU economic policy. This "benefits consumers, workers and entrepreneurs, and promotes innovation and growth, by controlling and restricting unfair market practices resulting from monopolies and dominant market positions, so that every individual has a fair chance of success". 32

2.2Underlying problem drivers

Assessments of the effectiveness of competition enforcement show that this is dependent on key aspects of competition policy design. This includes not only the content and scope of the substantive competition rules themselves, but also the independence of the competition authority when it takes enforcement decisions, the powers the authority has to detect, investigate, remedy and sanction competition infringements and the enforcement capacity of the authority in terms of its resources and budget. 33 In particular, the Buccirossi study which found a positive and significant effect of competition policy on productivity, established that the strength of this effect was found to be particularly marked for specific aspects of competition policy, including the degree of independence of the competition authority with respect to political or economic interests, the scope of the authority's investigative and fining powers and the quality of the human and financial resources a competition authority can rely on when performing its tasks. 34

Regulation 1/2003 focused on giving the NCAs the power to co-enforce the EU competition rules. It did not address the means and instruments of NCAs to apply these rules. This means that although the NCAs apply the same substantive rules, i.e., the EU competition rules, the means and instruments they have to enforce depends on what is available under national law.

In 2013-2014, the Commission carried out an assessment of the functioning of Regulation 1/2003. Based on the results of this analysis, the 2014 Commission Communication on Ten Years on Antitrust Enforcement under Regulation 1/2003 35 found that the new system has considerably increased the enforcement of the EU competition rules, with NCAs now as key pillar of the system. However, it found that there is scope for the NCAs to be more effective enforcers and identified a number of areas for action to boost effective enforcement by the NCAs. It concluded that action should be taken to guarantee that NCAs:

(1)have an effective enforcement toolbox to detect infringements and bring them to an end;

(2)can impose deterrent fines on companies;

(3)have leniency programmes which work effectively across Europe; and

(4)have adequate resources and can act independently when applying the EU competition rules.

The 2014 Communication built on the Report of Five Years of Regulation 1/2003, which found that empowering the NCAs to co-enforce the EU competition rules has positively contributed to stronger enforcement. 36 However, it concluded that there is room for improvement, in particular, to ensure that NCAs have effective enforcement powers and fining tools.

By way of follow-up to the 2014 Communication, extensive data collection was carried out by the European Commission in cooperation with all NCAs on the identified areas of action to have a detailed picture of the status quo. Although there has been a good degree of voluntary action at Member State level in the direction of giving NCAs the means and instruments they need to be effective enforcers, supported by extensive soft action (see section 6.1), there are four underlying problem drivers that undermine the ability of NCAs to be more effective enforcers and the decentralized system put in place by Regulation 1/2003. Annex IV contains a problem tree outlining the problem drivers and their consequences.

2.2.1Problem driver 1: Lack of effective competition tools

It is widely accepted that to be effective enforcers, competition authorities should be equipped with operational, well-designed tools to detect infringements and to bring them to an end. 37 Investigation and decision-making powers and procedures are the main working tools of competition authorities.

In this context, the core investigation powers are the power to inspect business and non-business premises, the power to issue requests for information, the power to gather digital evidence, and the power to conduct interviews. The core decision-making powers are the power to adopt prohibition decisions, the power to issue interim measures, and the power to adopt commitment decisions. Competition authorities should have the power to impose effective penalties for non-compliance with the investigation and decision-making tools and the power to set their priorities in full.

Lack of effective investigation and decision-making tools

The fact-finding done as follow-up to the 2014 Communication has shown that there is a patchwork of powers across Europe, with many NCAs not having the powers they need. 38 The scope of NCAs' investigative and decision-making powers varies considerably, which can significantly impact on their effectiveness.

For example:

With respect to the relevant investigation powers, some NCAs (Bulgaria, Denmark and Italy) lack the fundamental power to inspect the homes of business people for evidence of infringements. 39 This is a key gap in authorities' powers, as it is all too easy for cartelists to hide evidence at home. Indeed, nowadays this tool is becoming increasingly important as the distinction between work and home becomes more blurred with modern ways of working, for example, teleworking. If a NCA is unable to obtain evidence, infringements may not be pursued in full or can even remain unaddressed.

Example: Problems to gather evidence from laptop and phones

The power to effectively collect digital evidence from laptops and mobile phones is increasingly important nowadays where the storage and circulation of information is largely digital. In some cases, the evidence necessary to prove that e.g. companies engaged in a price-fixing cartel only exists in a digital form. 40 However, several authorities face key limitations:

6 NCAs cannot access data stored on clouds or servers located in other countries even though many companies routinely keep data there. Competition authorities need to be able to access the same data as the company being inspected.

5 NCAs cannot access mobile phones in inspections to check if company employees have any information about the alleged infringement, even though this is an obvious means for cartelists to communicate.

Nowadays there is an increasing amount of digital data to be searched when authorities carry out inspections. This fact, combined with the need to minimise the disruption caused by inspections, makes it ever more important for NCAs to have the power to continue making searches of the data gathered after the inspection is finished, e.g. at the premises of the authority (the so-called continued inspection procedure); see also the ECN Recommendation on the Power to collect Digital Evidence, including by Forensic Means. However, 7 authorities do not have effective powers to do so.

It is impossible to assess what and how much information those NCAs have missed without these powers, but it has led them to drop or partially drop cases, stop investigating individual companies because of a lack of evidence and it has been a factor in their decisions being over-turned in court. For example, the ability of one NCA to use the continued inspection procedure has recently been overturned by a court, meaning not only that it is prevented from exercising this power in future cases but the evidence it has collected via this procedure in other cases is open to challenge, undermining the operations of the authority. Similarly, at least 2 NCAs have recently been unable to collect evidence which was located on servers in other Member States, even though it was accessible to the companies being inspected. This loophole in NCAs' powers provides cartelists with means to collude which are safe from detection.

With respect to the relevant decision-making powers, 11 NCAs cannot impose structural remedies to restore competition on markets. Major structural problems on markets may call for structural solutions to ensure that competition works effectively. 41 For example, if vertically integrated energy incumbents foreclose the downstream supply markets by refusing indispensable access to transmission capacity, the abusive conduct stems from the very structure of the companies that can leverage their control of the network to maintain their dominance downstream. In such a case the divestiture of the transmission grid ensures that the abuse could never be repeated and it creates the conditions for undistorted competition downstream. Stakeholders, particularly businesses, highlight that the lack of NCAs' power to impose such remedies is particularly a problem for companies damaged by the anticompetitive behaviour of the infringer. Access to key infrastructure can be essential for companies which have been excluded from a market. If NCAs cannot impose effective remedies, they cannot ensure competition on these markets. The infringer continues to reap the benefits of a past violation to the detriment of consumers.

NCAs also face gaps or limitations if companies do not comply with their decisions, e.g. some NCAs do not have the power to impose deterrent fines in case of non-compliance with a commitment decision. Under a commitment decision, parties make voluntary commitments to address competition concerns and the competition authority by decision makes the commitments legally binding. 42 However, 11 NCAs either cannot fine failure to comply with such a commitment decision at all or the fines are set at a level which is too low to compel compliance. This means that authorities' powers lack teeth, e.g. companies easily enter into commitments which cannot be enforced and therefore no market change ensues.

Finally, 15 NCAs do not have the full power to set their priorities and decide which cases to dedicate their (often scarce) resources. 43 Stakeholders, notably businesses, report that the lack of the power of NCAs to set their priorities in full prevents them from focusing on infringements that cause the most harm to competition.

Most NCAs (22) lack the power to collect fines from companies that are located in other Member States, when these companies do not have a legal presence on the territory of the NCA concerned. For example, one NCA has not been able to collect fines from companies based elsewhere in the EU in eight cases. This gives such companies a safe haven from fines. This is a growing issue of concern given that many companies sell over the internet to potentially numerous countries, but only have a legal presence in e.g. one Member State.

Problems for cross-border cooperation to find evidence

Gaps and limitations in NCAs' powers also present a problem for cooperation within the ECN. One of the main elements of Regulation 1/2003 is that it provides for cooperation mechanisms that allow NCAs to investigate alleged infringements beyond the borders of their Member State. One NCA can ask another NCA to carry out investigative measures on its behalf. This means that NCAs are not prevented from gathering evidence simply because it is located in another jurisdiction. However, this mechanism does not work well if not all NCAs have effective powers to carry out inspections or to request information.

Example: How a lack of effective powers can impede cooperation within the ECN

The Dutch NCA was investigating a cartel involving Dutch and German companies and asked the German NCA to issue requests for information to the companies based in Germany to find information about this infringement. However, under German law the German NCA generally does not have the power to issue compulsory requests for information to companies in cases that can result in the imposition of a fine. It can only issue non-binding requests. This meant that when the German companies did not comply, the German NCA had no means of recourse and the Dutch NCA did not receive the information it asked for. 

Divergences in NCAs' powers, such as differences in rules on when a case becomes time-barred meaning that one authority may be able to act, but another could not, can also pose a problem for businesses operating cross-border. They want legal certainty as to whether proceedings can be brought against them.

In the public consultation, stakeholders indicated which tools they consider NCAs need (Annex V). There was also a clear demand from lawyers, business and business organisations for improvements in NCAs’ enforcement powers to be counter-balanced by increased procedural guarantees at national level, including ensuring that rights of defence can be effectively exercised (companies should receive a Statement of Objections and have effective rights of access to file) and effective judicial review.

2.2.2Problem driver 2: Lack of powers to impose deterrent fines

The ability of competition authorities to fine companies which breach competition law is a central enforcement tool. The purpose of fines is to punish companies which have infringed competition rules and to deter the same and other companies from engaging in or continuing illegal behaviour. EU law does not regulate fines imposed by NCAs 44 on companies for breaches of the EU competition rules. Each Member State has its own legal framework for imposing fines. However, in 2009, the European Court of Justice ruled that "the effectiveness of the penalties imposed by NCAs and the Commission is a condition for the coherent application of the EU competition rules". 45  

The fact-finding carried out has shown that there are a number of issues that affect the level of enforcement of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU and mean that companies can face very low or no fines at all depending on which authority acts, undermining deterrence and the level-playing field.

These issues are of two main types: (1) fines may not reflect the harm caused to competition, and (2) the nature of the fines imposed (criminal, civil or administrative).

Fines should reflect the harm caused to competition

There are differences in the methodologies for calculating fines that can have a significant impact on the level of fines imposed by NCAs. These differences mainly concern: (1) the maximum fine 46 that can be set (the legal maximum) and (2) the parameters for calculating the fine (see Annex VI).

For example, the legal maximum is calculated as a percentage of a given turnover in most Member States. There are however significant differences between Member States in the way the legal maximum is calculated in terms of the percentages applied, 47 and the turnover to which such percentages are applied. Most NCAs when calculating the legal maximum use the worldwide turnover of the corporate group that has been held liable for the infringement, but some base it solely on the national turnover or the turnover of the direct infringer. The entities for which the turnover is considered (the undertaking or the direct infringer) and whether the geographic scope of such turnover is worldwide or national make a big difference to the maximum level of the fine (depending on the size of the corporate group it can be significantly lower). In one Member State, only the direct turnover of the infringer is used and fines are limited to €16 million. For breaches of Article 102 TFEU, maximum fines of only €400 000 can be imposed. Such low legal maximums are highly unlikely to reflect the harm caused to competition and fines are likely to be under-deterrent, particularly for large multinational groups.

Such differences mean that fines vary by up to 25 times depending on which authority acts. Very low fines may be imposed for the same infringement, meaning that the deterrent effect of fines differs widely across Europe. The fines imposed may not reflect the harm caused to competition by the anti-competitive behaviour.

Example: Impact of divergences for calculating fines

To assess the impact of divergences in fining methodologies, the NCAs calculated the fine that they would impose in a hypothetical case.

The case was a simple cartel with several types of scenarios (small single companies which are not part of a group/large groups, sales at national level/worldwide level, single companies /multiproduct companies) and a range of different durations. Annex VII shows the results for a cartel that lasted 3.75 years.

The differences between NCAs in the fines that would have been imposed for the same infringement are significant. For example, for large groups, differences can be up to 25 times between the smallest and the highest fine, for the same type of company and infringement. Even for smaller groups, fines levels can differ substantially.

Another aspect which may lead to a situation in which fines do not reflect the harm to competition, is limitations regarding who can be held liable for paying the fine.

The concept of "undertaking" in EU competition law is established by the case law of the European Court of Justice. It means that different legal entities belonging to one "undertaking" can be held jointly and severally liable for any fines imposed on such "undertaking". 48 This sends a clear signal to the entire corporate group that the absence of good corporate governance and compliance with competition law will not remain unpunished. It also allows the fine to reflect the overall strength of the corporate group and not only that of the subsidiary, making it more meaningful and deterrent.

However, 5 NCAs cannot hold parent companies liable for infringements committed by subsidiaries under their control. Also, several NCAs cannot hold legal successors of an infringer (2 NCAs) and economic successors (8 NCAs) of an infringer liable for fines or there is uncertainty about whether national courts would uphold the application of these principles, despite the long established case law of the European Court of Justice. This means that companies can escape fines simply by merging with other companies or through corporate restructuring.

Example: Corporate restructuring to evade a fine

In Germany, an infringer can escape fines by transferring its assets to another entity of the group and becoming an empty shell that is not able to pay. The German weekly Wirtschaftswoche published in February 2015 a vivid article on the loopholes available in Germany to escape from competition fines. The German NCA has been unable to collect €128 million in fines from companies which took part in a cartel to fix the price of sausages. Two companies have escaped paying the fines simply by changing their corporate identity (see Annex VIII). Companies have also avoided fines after restructuring in other Member States, e.g. in Estonia a company active in the food retail sector avoided charges in a horizontal retail price fixing infringement after merging with another entity.

Moreover, some NCAs cannot effectively fine associations of undertakings, such as trade associations, either because national legislation prevents this possibility or because NCAs cannot impose fines that take into account the turnover of its members. 49 This is a problem because trade associations of e.g. lawyers, dentists etc. regularly participate in competition infringements (e.g. illegal agreements to fix the fees charged by their members) but typically have very little turnover compared to their members. NCAs need to be able to also fine the members of the association involved in the infringement to deter them. The fines imposed by NCAs without this power often have little deterrent effect and do not reflect the harm to competition.

Nature of the fines imposed can result in under-enforcement

The nature of the fines imposed by NCAs for the infringement of the EU competition rules varies across Member States. Fines can be either administrative (imposed by the NCA), civil (imposed by civil courts) or criminal or quasi-criminal (imposed mainly by criminal courts or, in some cases, by the NCA but according to quasi-criminal (misdemeanour) procedures).

In the majority of Members States fines are administrative. Civil fines 50 are imposed in three Member States. Criminal or quasi-criminal fines are imposed in five Member States: Denmark, Estonia, Germany, Ireland and Slovenia (see Annex IX).

Who imposes the fine

Member States

NCA (Administrative fines)

BE, BG, CY, CZ, EL, ES, FR, HR, HU, IT, LT, LU, LV, MT, NL, PL, PT, RO, SK, UK

Civil Courts

AT, FI, SV

Criminal Courts

DK, IE, EE (Art. 101), DE (in case of appeal when the case is reassessed according to criminal standards)

NCA but applying misdemeanour (quasi-criminal) standards

EE (Art. 102), SI

The fact finding has shown that for the period 2004-2013 in many of those Member States in which fines are primarily criminal, EU competition law is under-enforced or, even if enforced, sanctions are seldom imposed. Ireland and Estonia 51 for example, have reported only 1 and 3 decisions respectively during this period under both Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, meaning that there is virtually no enforcement of the EU competition rules in these countries. 52 For Article 101 cases, which include the most serious competition infringements, that is hard-core cartels (e.g. when competitors fix prices, divide up markets or allocate customers between them), a fine has never been imposed in Ireland and only once in Denmark during this period.

Moreover, in (quasi) criminal systems, the data illustrate that it is much more difficult to bring cases against infringements which are not hard-core cartels. Finding competition infringements, such as whether a company abused its dominant position, involves more complex economic facts, theories and analysis and is more resource intensive. In (quasi) criminal systems during the period 2004-2013, fines for breach of Article 102 have only been imposed once in Denmark and never in Estonia, Germany and Ireland. This means companies in a dominant position in these countries have much less to deter them from abusing their dominant position and using illegal means to exclude competitors from their market.

Most stakeholders stated in the public consultation that criminal systems, and to a lesser extent also civil systems, are less suited than administrative systems for the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules. 53  

The risk of under-enforcement imposed by systems that primarily apply (quasi) criminal sanctions was recognised, for example in a report of 2015 by the OECD reviewing the competition system in Denmark. This concludes that the imposition of criminal fines on undertakings has significant implications for the effective enforcement of EU competition law. 54 The Irish Law Reform Commission has launched an issues paper for consultation 55 in which it states that civil sanctions provide advantages over criminal prosecution. There are also calls for changing from civil to administrative models in several Member States to achieve more effective competition enforcement. The Swedish government commissioned an inquiry into this issue which was finalised in June 2016. The recommendation of the inquiry is that Sweden should change from its current civil system to an administrative system 56 in which the NCA is given the power to impose sanctions directly. The inquiry mentions as the main reasons justifying this change the gains in terms of efficiency that would be obtained and the advantages in terms of better cooperation with other NCAs that would result from having a more harmonised system. The Swedish NCA also publicly advocates for the power to impose administrative fines directly. 57

2.2.3Problem driver 3: Divergences between leniency programmes in terms of summary applications, core principles, protection of self-incriminating material and interplay with individual sanctions can lead to less effective competition enforcement against cartels

Since cartels are illegal, they are generally highly secretive and evidence of their existence is not easy to find. Cooperation by cartel members with competition authorities is therefore often crucial to uncover and punish these highly detrimental practices. Leniency programmes encourage companies to come clean about cartels in return for having no fines imposed (immunity) or a reduction in fines. They are therefore a key tool for the detection of cartels.

The mere existence of a (successful) leniency programme can destabilise existing cartels. 58 Currently the Commission and all Member States except Malta have leniency programmes in place. 

However, as shown in Annex XII, the number of (summary) 59 leniency applications varies widely across NCAs. Some NCAs are much more successful in attracting such applications. A comparison between the absolute number of leniency applications and the overall level of enforcement activity per NCA shows that whilst some NCAs can rely to a significant extent on immunity applications to feed their enforcement work stream, in other Member States leniency programmes generate none or much less of the overall enforcement activity. These differences in the success of the leniency programmes may be due to problems related to the single leniency programmes or to their interplay, which undermine their (single and collective) effectiveness.

To enable the NCAs and the Commission to uncover and sanction cartels, their individual leniency programmes have to provide companies with sufficient legal certainty about whether they will benefit from immunity, whether their employees are shielded from individual sanctions and whether self-incriminating material will be disclosed outside the context of the investigation.

The efficient interplay between the different leniency programmes within the ECN is just as important for the effective enforcement of the competition rules within the ECN since cartels often extend beyond national borders and companies may have to file leniency applications to authorities in several jurisdictions. If the core principles of the different programmes are too divergent, companies do not have legal certainty about their immunity status under the leniency programme(s) of the authority/ies that will eventually deal with their case.

Divergences and weaknesses exist mainly in the following areas:

Divergences in the treatment of summary leniency applications and in core leniency features

Despite some degree of convergence achieved by the non-binding 60 ECN Model Leniency Programme (MLP) endorsed in 2006, 61 important divergences remain. For example, summary applications are still not available before some NCAs. On core leniency features, divergences continue to exist regarding which companies can benefit from leniency and under which conditions. This leads to different outcomes when it comes to deciding which companies benefit from immunity, a reduction of fines or no reduction at all and in what order their applications are assessed as adding value for the case.

Lack of protection of leniency and settlement material

Companies that choose to cooperate under leniency programmes are required to disclose their participation in a secret cartel and provide self-incriminating leniency material. In case of formal settlements, parties to the investigation are required to acknowledge their participation in, and liability, for the infringement. 62 The level of protection granted for such material varies significantly between Member States. For example, in 20 Member States leniency statements are accessible to public prosecutors and/or the police, who could use it for other purposes than for the enforcement of the EU competition rules. In 12 Member States, civil courts in proceedings other than actions for damages have access to such statements. Such access can expose the companies that choose to cooperate with the competition authorities to liability to other proceedings being brought against them.

Lack of effective interplay between corporate leniency programmes with sanctions on individuals

Many Member States foresee sanctions on individuals for their involvement in anticompetitive behaviour. However, most leniency programmes lack arrangements to protect employees of companies which make leniency applications to NCAs and/or the Commission from individual sanctions. Individuals who may be subject to criminal proceedings may be deterred from helping their employers to collect the evidence required for a successful leniency application.

All the above shortcomings may weaken incentives for potential leniency applicants to cooperate with authorities. This in turn can lead to less effective competition enforcement in the EU, as less secret cartels are uncovered. More undetected cartels activity leads to a welfare loss across the EU.

For more detail on the existing divergences between leniency programmes in terms of summary applications, core principles, protection of self-incriminating material and interplay with individual sanctions as well as the feedback from the public consultation on these issues, see Annex XIII.

2.2.4Problem driver 4: Lack of safeguards NCAs can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

Independence

It is widely accepted by organisations such as the OECD 63 and UNCTAD 64 as well as academics 65 and stakeholders that the independence of competition authorities is a prerequisite for effective competition enforcement. 66 In the area of data protection, where EU law requires national data protection authorities to act with complete independence, the European Court of Justice has clarified that the independence of a public body normally means a status which ensures that it can act completely freely, without taking any instructions or being put under any pressure. 67 The legitimacy and credibility of NCAs actions vis-à-vis stakeholders is inherently linked to their ability to act impartially, free from external influence both from the companies they supervise and from political bodies. In recent years, the European Parliament has regularly emphasised the importance of having independent NCAs. It called on the Member States to ensure sufficient human and financial resources and independence for all NCAs and on the Commission to monitor their independence. 68

Regulation 1/2003 does not provide for specific requirements to safeguard the independence of NCAs. The degree of independence of NCAs from interference by public and private bodies when enforcing the EU competition rules is solely determined by national law and differs between Member States. However, when co-enforcing the EU competition rules together with the Commission, NCAs should, like the Commission, be able to carry out their enforcement tasks free from external influence. However, not all NCAs benefit from such safeguards. For example, NCAs in only 10 Member States are explicitly prohibited from seeking or taking instructions from any public or private body.

In the absence of enforceable safeguards at EU level for NCAs to enforce the EU competition rules without taking instructions from anyone, a risk of direct or indirect influence from other public or private bodies exists, even where according to national law they are formally deemed to be independent. For example, a genuine risk of influence by other state bodies exists where state-owned companies or activities by state bodies are the subject of an investigation by the NCA or where its enforcement action would interfere with other public interests. The absence of independence, which is essential to ensure objective market supervision, can result in different treatment of anticompetitive practices according to the type of company or sector involved. The fact that NCAs lack safeguards of independence and may be subject to instructions can have a direct impact on legal certainty and predictability for companies regarding the application of the EU competition rules. It also affects the legitimacy of the application of the EU competition rules by NCAs and may compromise the willingness of companies to invest.

Examples of interference with the independent functioning of NCAs

In one Member State, the NCA was asked to attend a Parliamentary Committee which mainly discussed an ongoing investigation of the authority and its fining policy in the presence of representatives of the company under investigation. Afterwards, the Committee recommended the NCA to reconsider its fining policy and some members questioned the proportionality of the fine in the case under investigation. The Committee's chairperson tabled an amendment to significantly lower the maximum level of the fine for certain infringements. This amendment was approved by a majority in the Parliament. It was only because the President vetoed the amendment that the legislative change ultimately did not go through.

In one Member State, an increase in vigilance by the NCA regarding the recovery of fines, which had been upheld in court, was criticised by the business community. Some companies exerted pressure on members of the parliament and the ministry to which the NCA is formally subordinated. As a result, the NCA had to discontinue the recovery of the largest fines it ever imposed.

In one Member State, administrative investigations took place into the NCA's enforcement actions, even in relation to a decision which had been upheld in court. These investigations undermined its operations and its credibility.

Resources

In order to act independently and effectively when enforcing the EU competition rules, NCAs need expert staff and sufficient resources to assess cases impartially and to defend their assessment before the courts. The NCAs have to be able to deal with powerful companies that are assisted by specialised teams of lawyers and economists. This issue was also recognised in the context of the European Semester where several Member States have been encouraged to ensure their NCAs have adequate resources, so that they could better contribute to achieving growth through more effective competition enforcement. 69  

Respondents to the public consultation also highlighted the link between having the necessary resources and being independent/effective. They considered having a safeguard of adequate and stable human and financial resources to be the most important measure to ensure the independence of NCAs. 70 In this context, stakeholders emphasise the need for specialised staff with proper expertise and measures enabling NCAs to attract and retain such people. Having insufficient resources is regarded as contributing to less effective enforcement and lower quality of enforcement decisions as authorities may not have the staff to invest in carrying out robust and detailed legal and economic analyses. For example, some NCAs do not have sufficient staff to conduct simultaneous inspections of all members of a suspected cartel but have to limit the search for evidence of anticompetitive conduct to key targets in the investigation with the risk of missing out on important evidence. One NCA had even to limit its inspection to one member of a cartel, which is not only ineffective but can also raise difficult issues such as claims of discrimination.

More generally, significant differences can be observed in resources among the NCAs in Member States with a similar GDP. NCAs in certain Members States are faced with limited human or financial resources (see Annex XIV for a comparison of the budget and staff of NCAs in Member States with a similar GDP). The following table illustrates the impact that the level of the budget of NCAs from Member States with similar GDP 71 has on their level of enforcement of the EU competition rules during the period from May 2004 until December 2014.

The NCAs in this table come from Member States with a comparable level of GDP. The table indicates that NCAs which have more limited resources (MS1 and MS2) have a significantly lower level of enforcement decisions (14 and 13 decisions respectively) compared to the NCAs with a higher level of resources (MS3 and MS4: 28 and 48 decisions respectively) in the same time period. Similar results are obtained for other groups of NCAs from Member States with a similar GDP (see the additional tables in Annex XVI). All the relevant observations presented below and in the Annex together reliably suggest a strong link between the budget available to NCAs and their level of enforcement of the EU competition rules.

2.3Who is affected by the problem?

NCAs are affected because gaps and limitations in their means and instruments undermine their ability to be effective enforcers. Many NCAs lack the necessary tools to find evidence of infringements, to fine companies which break the law, to act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules or to have the resources they need to perform their tasks. This can prevent them from taking action at all or result in them limiting their enforcement action. It also hinders them from cooperating effectively with their fellow competition enforcers in the European Competition Network. This is to the detriment of the European system of competition enforcement as a whole.

The lack of operational means for many NCAs results in untapped potential for more effective competition enforcement in Europe and thus missed opportunities for removing barriers to market entry, reinforcing the single market and creating more open competitive markets on which companies compete fairly and on their merits. This affects all businesses, irrespective of their size, including SMEs and start-ups. Businesses and consumers may particularly suffer in those countries where NCAs are less well-equipped to be effective enforcers. For example, if NCAs lack resources to pursue infringements of the EU competition rules, these stakeholders cannot reap the benefits of effective competition in the Member States concerned. Companies cannot compete fairly on the merits when there are safe havens for anti-competitive practices, e.g. because the evidence of the practices cannot be collected or because companies are not sanctioned for illegal practices. This can, for instance, prevent start-up companies from entering new markets, discouraging enterprise and efficiency.

Consumers are affected as there is scope for greater competition enforcement against anti-competitive practices which keep prices for goods and services artificially high.

Greater competition also stimulates productivity meaning that there is also untapped potential for innovation and growth in Europe.

Moreover, Regulation 1/2003 provides for a system of parallel competences where in principle any NCA or the European Commission is competent to take up a case to enforce the EU competition rules. The allocation of cases is done on a flexible basis within the ECN and means that enforcement is not hampered, e.g. because one authority lacks resources to investigate a particular case at a given moment in time. This system presupposes that for companies it does not matter which authority acts. However this is not the case when companies can have very different fines imposed on them depending on which authority takes up the case or when cases are time barred before some authorities but not others because of differences in rules on when NCAs can act. Gaps, limitations and divergences in NCAs’ means and instruments can thus result in different outcomes for companies. This can lead to costs and uncertainty for companies operating cross-border. For example, companies may think again about applying for leniency if they are not sure where they will come in the leniency queue, which can mean the difference between full immunity from fines to no reduction at all.

2.4What is the EU dimension of the problem?

Under Regulation 1/2003, the European Union decided to share its competence to enforce the EU Treaty rules on competition with the NCAs. The EU competition rules are now applied through-out Europe in 29 jurisdictions: they are enforced in 28 Member States, complemented by enforcement at the European level by the European Commission.

As explained in more detail in Section 3 below, the system of cooperation set up by Regulation 1/2003 has an obvious EU dimension with its cross-border cooperation mechanisms and enforcement actions and the inter-linkage of leniency programmes. Any gaps and limitations in the NCAs' means and instruments thus not only affect their individual capacity as effective enforcers, but that of the system as a whole.

2.5How would the problem evolve, all things being equal?

Some Member States may provide the NCAs over time with additional means and instruments to be effective enforcers. 72 However, most NCAs will continue to miss certain key tools to detect and sanction infringements or lack sufficient resources, affecting the decentralized system put in place by Regulation 1/2003.

Soft action has been used extensively to prompt voluntary action at national level and after more than a decade, the changes needed to make the decentralised enforcement system of Regulation 1/2003 work better and empower the NCAs to be more effective enforcers, are unlikely to ensue.

Section 5.2 lists the soft action that has been taken to try to support the NCAs having the means and instruments they need to enforce the EU competition rules. These measures serve as a soft framework of reference and show that there is considerable consensus within the ECN on the means and instruments authorities need to be effective enforcers. 73  

Efforts have also been made in the context of the European Semester process since 2011 and the Memoranda of Understanding of Specific Economic Conditionality with the so-called “programme” countries since 2010 to address shortcomings in several NCAs' enforcement and fining powers and their independence and resources. Both mechanisms have had mixed success, particularly in view of the fact that the EU lacks a clear legal basis to ensure the effective functioning of the NCAs. For example, the Council adopted Country Specific Recommendations addressing the degree of independence of NCAs or the level of their resources in certain Member States. However, even recurrent calls by the Council have not been effectively implemented. 74 For example, since 2013 the Austrian government has been repeatedly called on to substantially strengthen the resources of the NCA. Eventually in 2016 the staff of the authority was nominally increased by 10 additional case handlers, but no additional budget was granted to actually employ extra staff. Similarly, the Slovenian government was asked to increase the institutional independence of the NCA and to ensure sufficient budgetary autonomy. However, the legal framework has not been amended to avoid administrative investigations into the decision-making of the NCA which undermine its independence.

Another issue of concern is that achievements made to date are fragile. Even if NCAs have been granted effective means and instruments under national law, there is nothing to prevent a reversal of these changes. For example, one NCA lost the power to grant interim measures even though this tool is actively used by some NCAs to prevent anti-competitive action which could cause long-term damage to markets.

In essence, gaps or limitations in the means and instruments of NCAs to effectively enforce the EU competition rules will continue to result in NCAs refraining from enforcing or taking more limited action because they do not have the tools they need. For example, some NCAs cannot search homes and cars of businessmen for evidence of infringements, giving cartelists an easy loophole to exploit. This will continue to result in less detection of anti-competitive practices.

Some NCAs will still suffer from a severe lack of the resources they need to perform their tasks meaning they cannot be effective enforcers.

Divergences in NCAs' powers will continue to undermine the level playing field. For example, differences with respect to the main elements to be taken into account by all NCAs when calculating the fines means that companies can face very low fines for the same infringement depending on which NCA acts, undermining deterrence.

Companies which are considering reporting cartel behaviour to a number of jurisdictions in return for more lenient treatment may refrain from doing so because they lack the legal certainty they need about whether and to what extent they will benefit from this. If companies do not report secret cartels to competition authorities, detection levels fall.

A continued lack of safeguards for NCAs that they act only in the general interest of the EU without taking instructions from anyone when they enforce the EU competition rules will continue to undermine the legitimacy of competition enforcement.

Finally, the European system of competition enforcement has been designed in a cohesive way so that authorities can rely on each other to do fact-finding measures on each other’s behalf. For example, if evidence of an infringement that authority A is looking into may be found on the territory of authority B, authority A can ask authority B to conduct inspections or issue requests for information to try to find this information. But this system cannot work well where there are still gaps or limitations in authority B’s fact-finding powers, e.g. they cannot effectively gather data from mobile phones or laptops, when experience shows that evidence is often found on such devices. This means that cooperation within the ECN will continue to be less effective than it would be if all NCAs had adequate powers.

The above gaps, limitations and divergences in NCAs' means and instruments mean that the scope for more effective competition enforcement is untapped, to the detriment of the European system of enforcement as a whole.

In sum, in the absence of further action at EU level, the existing national competition frameworks will not allow the NCAs to enforce the EU competition rules more effectively across the EU. It will also mean that issues will persist, such as the broad range in the level of fines depending on which authority acts and the lack of legal certainty for companies considering reporting cartel behavior to different jurisdictions.

3Why should the EU act?

Regulation 1/2003, which enabled the NCAs to enforce the EU competition rules together with the Commission, is already in place for more than ten years. For the full potential of this decentralised system to be realised, NCAs need to be in a position to effectively enforce the EU competition rules.

NCAs are applying rules with a cross-border dimension

The EU should take action to address this, because the NCAs are applying rules which have a cross-border dimension. This means that there is an inter-linkage between enforcement action taken by a NCA in one Member State and the impact on competition in another Member State. The NCAs are obliged to apply the EU competition rules whenever trade between Member States may be affected. This criterion is easily fulfilled in the case of a cartel or an abuse of dominant position that covers two or more Member States. Action by one NCA to tackle predatory pricing engaged in by a dominant company in more than one Member State will benefit businesses present in all the Member States affected. Such anti-competitive behaviour has the aim of eliminating competitors and stopping it through enforcement action is in the interests of all affected competitors.

The effect on trade criterion can also be fulfilled in the case of anticompetitive agreements or abuses of dominance in a single Member State. For example, if a supplier sells to an exporter in the same Member State and that supplier prohibits exports to another Member State, this may have an effect on trade. Without the agreement the exporter would have been free to engage in export sales. Similarly, if companies enter into a price-fixing cartel that covers the whole of a Member State, this is normally capable of affecting trade between Member States, because such cartels typically exclude competitors from other Member States and reinforce the partitioning of the single market. Enforcement action by a NCA against such "national" cartels can thus have a positive impact on businesses from other Member States seeking to enter new markets.

Likewise, action taken by one NCA may have a positive impact on consumers in other Member States. For example, the Spanish competition authority imposed a fine on a cartel of Spanish producers of sherry destined for export under the trademarks of foreign distributors (so-called Buyers Own Brand market). The sherry producers reduced the supply of sherry for sale on this market to enable them to increase prices. These production limits were reinforced by additional anti-competitive measures, such as coordinated price increases. Because the sherry products concerned were intended for the export market, primarily to Germany, the Netherlands and the UK, it led to higher prices for sherry for consumers in these countries.

The decentralised enforcement system works well provided all NCAs have the necessary means and instruments to enforce. However, where a NCA lacks the necessary instruments and means to tackle an infringement of the EU competition rules, this can have direct consequences for businesses and consumers in other Member States. The inability of one NCA in Member State A to tackle a national wide cartel, e.g. because it lacks sufficient resources, is a problem not just for businesses and consumers in that Member State but also those in e.g. Member State B and C. However, Member States B and C are not able to address the lack of insufficient resources of the NCA in Member State A.

Ensuring that cross-border cooperation works effectively

Another issue is that only action at EU level can ensure that the system of cooperation set up by Regulation 1/2003 works sufficiently. One of the main elements of Regulation 1/2003 is that it provides for cooperation mechanisms that allow NCAs to investigate alleged infringements beyond the borders of their Member State. One NCA can ask another NCA to carry out investigative measures on its behalf to gather evidence located in another jurisdiction. As noted above in section 2.5, this mechanism does not work well if not all NCAs have effective powers to carry out inspections or to request information. Again, it is difficult to tackle this issue at national level. For example, if the NCA in Member State A needs the NCA in Member State B to gather evidence from companies located in its territory, but the NCA in Member State B does not have effective powers to gather this evidence, there is little that Member State A can do about this.

Interlinkage between competition authorities' leniency programmes in Europe

Leniency programmes are interlinked because companies regularly file applications to a number of EU jurisdictions and need guarantees of cross-border legal certainty. The experience of the last decade has shown that such cross-border legal certainty cannot be sufficiently achieved by Member States individually. Divergences in leniency programmes still lead to different outcomes for leniency applicants in terms of whether they benefit from immunity from fines or even from fines reductions at all. Companies which are considering reporting cartel behaviour to a number of jurisdictions in return for more lenient treatment lack the certainty they need about whether and to what extent they will benefit from this. EU action is needed to ensure that a leniency system is available and applied in a similar way in all Member States.

National laws can prevent NCAs from being more effective enforcers

A further reason underlining why EU action is needed is that in some Member States, national law prevents NCAs from imposing effective fines on companies for infringements of the EU competition rules. Infringing companies present in Member States where NCAs lack effective fining powers are thus sheltered from sanctions and have little incentive to act in compliance with EU competition rules. This reinforces market distortions through-out Europe and may undermine the single market. Moreover, the differences between the NCAs in the core principles for imposing fines mean that companies may face very different levels of fines depending on which authority acts. Only action at EU level can ensure that there are common core principles for imposing fines, thus, providing a more level playing field for businesses.

Measures taken to undermine the independence of the NCAs or to limit their resources necessarily emanate from the Member States themselves. For example, restrictions on independence can be motivated by the desire to exercise greater control over decision-making by the authority. Therefore it is not realistic that safeguards to prevent this at national level will always suffice. A government's ability to apply influence or pressure on a NCA may result in political considerations prevailing over sound competition enforcement based on legal and economic arguments, to the detriment of companies operating in the single market.

In sum, existing national competition frameworks will thus not by themselves allow the NCAs to enforce the EU competition rules more effectively across the EU. Moreover, the Commission cannot enforce any EU requirements regarding the investigation and sanctioning tools, resources and institutional structure of NCAs when enforcing the EU competition rules as long as such requirements do not exist. Accordingly, only an initiative at the EU level can empower the NCAs to be more effective enforcers by ensuring that they have more effective means and instruments to apply the EU competition rules.

In the public consultation, 64% of stakeholders said they would like action to be taken at both EU and national level, with 19% preferring exclusive EU action and 8% opting for solely national measures.

4What should be achieved?

Based on the problem and the four underlying problem drivers identified in section 2, the primary objective of this policy initiative is to make sure that the full potential of the decentralised system of enforcement put in place by Regulation 1/2003 is realised, by empowering the NCAs to be more effective enforcers. This would boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by the NCAs and the functioning of markets in Europe (general objective).

This requires the achievement of the following specific objectives:

1.    ensuring all NCAs have effective investigation and decision-making tools;

2.    ensuring that all NCAs are able to impose effective deterrent fines;

3.    ensuring that all NCAs have a well-designed leniency programme in place which facilitates applying for leniency in multiple jurisdictions; and

4.    ensuring that NCAs have sufficient resources and can enforce the EU competition rules independently.

5What are the various options to achieve the objectives?

The following policy options were considered to see if they achieve the above objectives and remedy the problem by tackling the underlying problem drivers identified in section 2:

Option 1: no EU action at all (the baseline scenario)

Option 2:    further soft action.

Option 3:    EU legislative action to ensure NCAs have minimum means and instruments to effectively enforce the EU competition rules. This would be complemented by soft action to put meat on the bones of these provisions, where appropriate. For certain limited and targeted areas, more detailed and uniform provisions may be provided for to the extent that minimum rules would not suffice.

Option 4:    EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments to be effective enforcers.

These options were developed taking into account the views of stakeholders. In the public consultation, stakeholders considered that the following measures should be taken:

Ensuring that NCAs have effective enforcement tools to investigate and take decisions (87%).

Having in place effective leniency programmes which encourage companies to come clean across Europe (82%).

Ensuring that NCAs have sufficient resources to perform their tasks (85%).

Ensuring that effective fines can be imposed (80%).

Giving NCAs safeguards that they enforce the EU competition rules in the general interests of the EU and do not take instructions from anyone (76%).

In the policy options identified, there was no need to provide for a differentiated scope, e.g. to exempt or to apply a lighter regime for SMEs, because empowering the NCAs to be more effective enforcers would benefit all consumers and companies, both large and small, by boosting effective competition enforcement and creating a more level playing field. It would not impact SMEs to a disproportionate extent compared to larger companies. In principle, all companies are subject to the EU competition rules provided there may be an effect on trade between Member States. Agreements between SMEs are not necessarily capable of affecting trade between Member States, because activities of SMEs are normally local or at most regional in nature. 75  Agreements of minor importance that do not have an appreciable effect on inter-state trade and on competition are not caught by Article 101 TFEU, unless these agreements are hard-core infringements such as price-fixing cartels. 76  For Article 102 TFEU to apply a company must have a dominant position, that is to say, substantial market power, which will not be the case for many SMEs. In sum, many agreements/behavior of SMEs fall outside the scope of the EU competition rules.

The policy options for each of the specific objectives identified are as follows (see Annex X for a schematic overview).

5.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

This is the baseline scenario, entailing no action at all at EU level to make sure the full potential of the decentralised system put in place by Regulation 1/2003 is realised by empowering the NCAs to be more effective enforcers. This essentially means keeping the status quo, taking into account the extent to which it is likely to change in the absence of EU action.

Some Member States may provide NCAs over time with some of the powers or resources they need or remove divergences in the national legal framework with regard to leniency or fines. However, this is unlikely to take place on the scale needed to make NCAs effective enforcers (see section 2.5).

5.2Option 2: further soft action

Soft action could take the form of ECN Recommendations or ECN Resolutions. "ECN Recommendations" are documents setting out the position of all ECN members and can be used as advocacy tools to influence policymakers. "ECN Resolutions" by the heads of the NCAs set their joint position to the extent possible within their national legal frameworks.

5.2.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

In 2012/2013, the ECN endorsed a set of seven detailed Recommendations on key enforcement powers that NCAs need. 77 Possible areas of soft action not covered by these Recommendations could include new ECN Recommendations on issues such as the use of behavioural remedies to ensure a return to competitive conditions on markets and formal settlement procedures.

5.2.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

The 2008 Key Principles for the Determination of Fines issued by the European Competition Authorities already provide general guidance on how fines should be calculated. 78 Soft action could be taken to convince Member States to apply the EU concepts of undertaking, parental liability and succession in line with the case law of the European Court of Justice, to ensure that associations of undertakings can be effectively fined and, in the case of Member States that have a primarily criminal enforcement system, to allow the imposition of administrative fines or the imposition of fines by civil courts.

5.2.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

The ECN MLP already set out the core principles of substance and procedure for effective leniency programmes, as well as on the protection of leniency materials. An extension of the ECN MLP or a separate ECN Recommendation could be envisaged to encourage the introduction of arrangements to protect employees of companies which apply for leniency from individual sanctions at national level.

5.2.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

The ECN Resolution of 2010 on the continued need for effective institutions calls for the competition authorities to be “adequately equipped for their tasks and be able to act under suitable conditions for the execution of their task, in an impartial and independent manner”. 79 Further soft action could provide for more detailed provisions on the independence and resources of NCAs.

5.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by both soft action and detailed rules where appropriate

5.3.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

EU action could be taken to provide NCAs with:

A minimum core set of operational investigative tools (that is, effective powers to inspect business and non-business premises, to issue requests for information and to gather digital evidence) For example, giving NCAs effective powers to gather digital evidence would ensure this option is future proof, as it would enable NCAs to access the same data as the company being inspected irrespective of how it is stored, including data stored on clouds, laptops and mobile phones. It would also allow NCAs to continue searches of large amounts of (typically digital) data at their premises to minimise the disruption caused by an inspection.

Decision-making tools (the power to adopt prohibition decisions - including the power to impose structural and behavioural remedies -, to issue interim measures and to adopt commitment decisions).

Backing up these tools with effective sanctions for non-compliance with them, e.g. the payment of a fine for failure to comply with an inspection and the power of NCAs to set their priorities in full.

Tools could also be put in place to address limitation periods and the inability of NCAs to enforce fining decisions cross-border.

The increase in the powers of the NCAs would be counter-balanced by ensuring that key procedural guarantees are in place in line with the EU Charter on Fundamental Rights, such as the obligation of NCAs to notify companies of the objections against them and by providing for effective judicial review of enforcement decisions.

5.3.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

Action could be taken at EU level to provide for minimum rules to ensure that:

(a) Fines are based on the key elements widely recognised as essential for calculating a fine:

The gravity and duration of the infringement, and

The potential application of aggravating and mitigating circumstances.

This would ensure that fines are related to the infringement and to the harm caused to competition. It would be complemented by soft action on non-core aspects such as which aggravating and mitigating factors could be taken into account and how to assess the gravity of the infringement.

(b) The legal maximum is set as a percentage of the total worldwide turnover of the undertaking. This would ensure that it is set at a level which ensures deterrence.

(c) The concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession are applied in line with the case law of the European Court of Justice as explained in section 2.2.2 and that associations can be effectively fined.

(d) There exists the possibility either to impose administrative fines or to apply to a civil court for the imposition of fines. This would mean that NCAs currently operating in a primarily criminal system would be given the option of deciding, depending on the facts and circumstances of the case, whether to follow an administrative track/seize a civil court or to follow the existing criminal route.

(e) All NCAs have the power to defend their cases in court (most already can do so).

5.3.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

EU action could be taken to ensure:

The core principles of the ECN MLP are translated into law in light of experience with their application, thereby introducing binding minimum rules for leniency programmes. This would reduce the current divergences between national programmes and ensure, for example, that summary applications are available in all Member States and are applied in the same way. In particular, NCAs would have in place leniency programmes that enable them to grant immunity from fines and reduction of fines to undertakings and companies would have to satisfy core common conditions in order to qualify for leniency. Further, it would be ensured that applicants that have applied for leniency to the European Commission can file summary applications in relation to the same cartel with the NCAs and that NCAs accept summary applications with the same scope as the leniency application filed with the Commission.

Minimum rules are in place to protect employees of leniency applicants with the Commission or other NCAs from sanctions.

There are binding uniform rules for the full protection of leniency and settlement material against disclosure outside the context of civil damages actions (the latter already being addressed by the Damages Directive 80 ). EU legislative action to this end would expand the protection granted by the Damages Directive to other procedures.

5.3.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

To ensure that NCAs are protected from external influence and they have sufficient resources when enforcing the EU competition rules, minimum rules would be introduced to ensure the independence of NCAs when they enforce the EU competition rules. This would cover the following requirements:

NCAs perform their tasks and exercise their powers independently and are not subject to any instructions from any other public or private body when enforcing the EU competition rules. In particular, it would be ensured that NCAs can take decisions independently from any political and business influence and that the staff and the members of a NCAs' decision making body refrain from actions and occupations that are incompatible with the performance of their duties during their term of office and for a reasonable period thereafter.

NCAs’ board/management cannot be dismissed for reasons related to the proper performance of their powers in the application of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU.

NCAs have adequate human and financial resources to perform their tasks. 81 This would simply provide that NCAs should have sufficient financial, human and technical resources to perform their tasks and would include a list of these tasks (e.g. conducting investigations, taking decisions. and cooperating with other authorities in the ECN).

5.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments to be effective enforcers

5.4.1Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

This would build on option 3 by providing NCAs with uniform (as opposed to minimum) investigation and decision-making powers, backed up by uniform sanctions for non-compliance. For example, when it comes to the power to adopt commitment decisions, it would regulate detailed issues such as having a mandatory market test for NCAs to get input from other market players on the suitability of commitments proposed by the parties under investigation to address competition concerns.

This option would also provide for a more complete competition toolbox, for instance, by including the power of competition authorities to conduct sector inquiries. This is a useful tool to allow competition authorities to assess whether there are indications to suggest that competition on market sectors of the economy is being restricted or distorted in an economic sector of the common market. Sector enquiries often provide a useful basis for NCAs to carry out enforcement. A sector inquiry can in addition provide empirical evidence that may be useful in reviewing the regulatory framework governing a sector. It would also provide for detailed procedural guarantees, such as detailed and uniform rules on access to an authority's case file and rules on the ability of complainants and third parties to intervene in proceedings.

5.4.2Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed 

Option 4 would go further than option 3 by introducing a uniform fining model through EU legislation so that only administrative fines on undertakings can be imposed. It would also provide for a uniform and detailed methodology for setting fines, determining all the parameters that are to be taken into account and prescribing how fines should be calculated and who can be fined.

5.4.3Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

On leniency, option 4 would involve introducing fully harmonized leniency programmes, with maximum requirements beyond the principles of the ECN MLP, to ensure that leniency applicants can file a single application with one authority that issues an immunity decision which is binding in all Member States and before the Commission (putting in place a so-called one-stop shop system). Similar to option 3, it would also include uniform and detailed rules to protect all leniency and settlement materials outside the context of civil damages actions and to protect employees of leniency applicants to either the Commission or NCAs from individual sanctions at national level.

5.4.4Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

In addition to the safeguards foreseen under option 3, this option would involve the introduction of uniform and detailed rules to also ensure the institutional and financial autonomy of NCAs. This would include the following requirements: (1) NCAs would be legally distinct from any other public or private body (structural independence); (2) NCAs would have full authority over the recruitment and management of staff; (3) NCAs would have a separate annual budget with full budgetary autonomy; (4) appointment of NCAs' board/management through a transparent procedure on the basis of merit.

5.5Discarded option

A further option would be for the Commission to take up cases where the NCAs are not able to act.

While it is not excluded that the Commission could do so in a very limited number of cases, intervention by the Commission on a more systemic basis is not feasible as the Commission also has limited resources to enforce the EU competition rules. Such intervention by the Commission would also directly contradict the decentralisation logic of Regulation 1/2003. By the end of the 1990s it became evident that the Commission could not meet the challenges of enforcing the EU competition rules and ensuring integrated markets on its own. The context had changed dramatically, with an EU that had increased from 6 to 15 Member States, and the prospects of more countries joining the EU in the medium term. In this situation, the Commission could not bear the responsibility for enforcing alone the EU competition rules throughout the EU. 82 Regulation 1/2003 therefore set up a system where the EU competition rules are meant to be applied effectively by a multiplicity of enforcers throughout the EU. To that end, Article 35 of Regulation 1/2003 stipulates that Member States must have NCAs in place that are empowered to apply the EU competition rules effectively.

This option was therefore discarded.

6What are the impacts of the different policy options and who will be affected?

An assessment is made of the available options as described in section 5 in relation to the general and specific objectives identified in section 4. Given that all the specific objectives share the same general objective, that is, to realise the full potential of the decentralised enforcement system put in place by Regulation 1/2003, boosting effective competition enforcement by the NCAs and the functioning of markets in Europe, they are assessed together.

The assessment of the impact of these options is to a large extent qualitative as a quantification of the effects of the proposed policy options is only partially feasible. For example, it is easy to determine that the costs and administrative burden of businesses of adapting to different procedural rules throughout the EU will be reduced, but they are very hard to quantify. This is even more true for effects on macro-economic variables like boosting economic growth and innovation and preventing harm to competition and consumers. An assessment is not made of environmental impacts, as no significant environmental impacts are expected.

6.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

Taking no action at EU level would mean that the problem and all four problem drivers identified in section 2 would largely persist (see section 2.5 on how the problem would evolve). Most NCAs will continue to miss out on effective tools to detect and sanction infringements. Some NCAs will still lack sufficient resources and safeguards of independence. Potential applicants for leniency will continue to be dis-incentivised to apply to authorities across Europe.

Economic impact

Functioning of the internal market and competition

The baseline scenario would have no impact, as without legislation the NCAs would not become more effective enforcers, and thus effective competition enforcement would not increase. This would mean that the potential of NCAs to enforce more effectively would remain untapped and no additional action would be taken to ensure more competition on Europe's markets, including tackling barriers to market entry. This would be to the detriment of the Commission's aim of reinforcing the single market.

Economic growth and productivity

The baseline scenario would have no impact, as the additional boost that more competition brings to productivity would not materialise.

Trade and investment flows

The baseline scenario would have no impact, as there would be no impetus to make Europe's markets more open and competitive. This would not make them more attractive to investors.

Position of SMEs

The baseline scenario would have no impact on companies, irrespective of their size. This would mean that in some Member States, SMEs and start-ups will continue to be prevented from entering new markets, because e.g. the NCAs in the Member States in question are not well-equipped to be effective enforcers against anti-competitive practices of dominant companies.

Innovation and research

The baseline scenario would not lead to more effective competition enforcement. Accordingly, companies would not get the impetus from increased competition which incentivises them to innovate and offer a better range of products and services.

Consumers and households

The baseline scenario would mean that consumers would not benefit from increased effective competition enforcement which can help bring prices down and ensure that they have better quality, wider choice and innovative goods and services.

Public authorities

The baseline scenario cannot ensure that NCAs are more effective enforcers. Effective enforcers are better value for money so the benefits of this would be lost. On the positive side, public authorities are unlikely to incur implementation costs.

Simplification and administrative burden on business

The baseline scenario cannot ensure that there are common (minimum or uniform) standards for NCAs' investigation and sanctioning tools, which reduce divergent outcomes for companies. The application of the EU competition rules would therefore not become more predictable and it would not improve the ability of NCAs to cooperate with each other. This would also mean that there would not be a reduction in costs for businesses of adapting to different procedural rules throughout the EU. Legal certainty would also not increase as NCAs would continue to have different means and instruments in place. Companies may think again about applying for leniency to different NCAs as they do not know whether they will benefit from immunity or even no reduction in fines at all.

Social impacts

Employment and labour markets

The baseline scenario would have no impact, as there would be no impetus to stimulate employment growth.

Effects on income, distribution

The baseline scenario will not boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules, leading to more competition on the market, which drives economic growth. EU citizens will therefore not realise the benefit of greater economic prosperity.

Impacts on Fundamental Rights (EU Charter of Fundamental Rights)

The baseline scenario may mean that issues of procedural guarantees in competition proceedings remain unaddressed.

6.2Option 2: further soft action

Further soft action would achieve the specific objectives as follows:

Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

Taking further soft action on targeted specific areas which have not been addressed by the ECN Recommendations on key enforcement powers, e.g. having an ECN Recommendation on formal settlement procedures, 83 may be a useful source of best practice on these issues for national legislators. However, it will not solve the problem that soft action has not been effective so far and many NCAs lack the investigation and decision making tools they need to be effective enforcers.

Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

Soft action could be taken to convince Member States to apply the EU concepts of undertaking, parental liability and succession in line with the case law of the European Court of Justice and to enable those Member States which operate in a primarily criminal enforcement system the imposition of administrative fines or the imposition of fines by civil courts. However, these issues are firmly established in national legal frameworks. For example, efforts in the context of the Memorandum of Understanding with Ireland to enable the Irish NCA to also impose administrative or civil fines failed because of a lack of an EU legal basis, as Regulation 1/2003 left it to national law to provide for sanctions for breach of the EU competition laws. 84  

Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

Soft measures could be taken to encourage the introduction of arrangements to protect employees of companies which apply for leniency from individual sanctions at national level. However, this is only likely to be effective where NCAs themselves are also responsible for imposing administrative sanctions on individuals. Ensuring that the employees of companies which apply for leniency are protected from criminal sanctions on individuals cannot be addressed exclusively through soft action, as the latter are firmly established in national legislation.

Further soft action to reduce the remaining divergences between national leniency programmes on substance and procedure and thus to improve their interplay in cross-border cartel cases appears unrealistic. The MLP has never been fully implemented throughout the EU: for example, it is not possible to get a reduction in fines in some Member States (rather only immunity from fines) and summary applications are not available in all Member States. These differences discourage companies from applying for leniency to a number of jurisdictions or from cooperating with the competition authorities at all. Moreover, the Court of Justice has recently ruled 85 that instruments adopted in the context of the ECN are not binding on national competition authorities and that thus Member States are not required to incorporate provisions of the ECN Model Leniency Programme in their leniency systems.

Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

Soft action could provide for more detailed safeguards on the independence and resources of NCAs. However, the 2010 ECN Resolution on the continued need for effective institutions which called for NCAs to be adequately equipped and to be able to act independently and impartially has not triggered any improvement. More detailed soft action is unlikely to achieve more change than the Resolution. Moreover, experience in the context of the European Semester and the Memoranda of Understanding with programme countries shows that soft action to ensure that NCAs can act independently and have the necessary resources when enforcing the EU competition rules is generally unsuccessful.

Impacts of option 2

Self-regulation on its own is unlikely to address the gaps and limitations that NCAs face and make the decentralised system put in place by Regulation 1/2003 work effectively. Soft action is not binding on Member States. 86  and has had minimal success to date. This option would therefore have very limited impacts.

Economic impact

Functioning of the internal market and competition

Little impact of soft action alone, as without legislation the NCAs would not become more effective enforcers, and thus effective competition enforcement would not increase. This would mean that the potential of NCAs to enforce more would remain untapped and no additional action would be taken to ensure more competition on Europe's markets, including tackling barriers to market entry. This would be to the detriment of the Commission's aim of reinforcing the single market.

Economic growth and productivity

Little impact of soft action alone, as the additional boost that more competition brings to productivity would not materialise.

Trade and investment flows

Little impact of soft action alone, as there would be no impetus to make Europe's markets more open and competitive. This would not make them more attractive to investors.

Position of SMEs

Soft action alone would have little impact on all companies, irrespective of their size. This would mean that in some Member States, SMEs and start-ups will continue to be prevented from entering new markets, because e.g. the NCAs in the Member States in question are not well-equipped to be effective enforcers against anti-competitive practices of dominant companies.

Innovation and research

Little impact as soft action alone would not lead to more effective competition enforcement. Accordingly, companies would not get the impetus from increased competition which incentivises them to innovate and offer a better range of products and services.

Consumers and households

Soft action alone would mean that consumers would not benefit from increased effective competition enforcement which can help bring prices down and ensure that they have better quality, wider choice and innovative goods and services.

Public authorities

Soft action alone cannot ensure that NCAs are more effective enforcers. Effective enforcers are better value for money so the benefits of this would be lost. On the positive side, public authorities are unlikely to incur implementation costs.

Simplification and administrative burden on business

Soft action alone cannot ensure that there are common (minimum or uniform) standards for NCAs' investigation and sanctioning tools, which reduce divergent outcomes for companies. The application of the EU competition rules would therefore not become more predictable and it would not improve the ability of NCAs to cooperate with each other. This would also mean that there would not be a reduction in costs for businesses of adapting to different procedural rules throughout the EU. Legal certainty would also not increase as NCAs would continue to have different means and instruments in place. Companies may think again about applying for leniency to different NCAs as they do not know whether they will benefit from immunity or even no reduction at all.

Social impacts

Employment and labour markets

Little impact of soft action alone, as there would be no impetus to stimulate employment growth.

Effects on income, distribution

Soft action alone will not boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules, leading to more competition on the market, which drives economic growth. EU citizens will therefore not realise the benefit of greater economic prosperity.

Impacts on Fundamental Rights (EU Charter of Fundamental Rights)

Soft action alone is likely to have limited impact and may mean that issues of procedural guarantees in competition proceedings remain unaddressed.

6.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by soft action/detailed rules where appropriate

This option is assessed on the basis that giving NCAs largely minimum rules (complemented by soft action and detailed rules as appropriate) to address the problem and the four problem drivers identified would boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules (for further details see section 5).

The four specific objectives would be achieved as follows

Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

Taking action at EU level to provide NCAs with minimum rules would ensure that NCAs have the core tools they need to detect and investigate infringements and to take enforcement decisions that stop anti-competitive practices. This would allow the NCAs to effectively enforce the EU competition rules in the digital context, for example, by enabling them to effectively collect data stored digitally, such as on mobile devices, to prove infringements.

These tools would be backed up with effective sanctions for non-compliance e.g. the payment of a fine for failure to comply with an inspection decision. This ensures that these powers are taken seriously by companies under investigation and cannot be easily ignored.

A recurrent call from some stakeholders was also for increased procedural guarantees when NCAs enforce the EU competition rules. It could be ensured that procedural guarantees are in place in line with the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights, such as ensuring that companies under investigation have the right to a formal document setting out the objections of the NCA against them so that they are provided with the information they need to defend themselves and can comment on the allegations made against them.

Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

By ensuring that all NCAs have minimum powers so that administrative fines can be imposed or the imposition of fines by civil courts can be sought, all NCAs which currently operate within a primarily criminal system could choose which route to take (either the criminal route or to opt for the administrative route/civil court route) depending on the facts and circumstances of the case. This option would also make criminal competition enforcement systems more effective by giving NCAs the power to bring and/or defend their cases before criminal courts. NCAs are best placed to explain their decisions and this avoids the duplication of costs and effort inherent in another body defending the case.

This option would also mean that fines better reflect the harm caused to competition by: (1) setting the legal maximum of fines at a level which ensures deterrence; (2) providing for core principles for the methodology for the calculation of fines (such as the duration and gravity of an infringement), complemented by soft measures; and (3) ensuring that the concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession are applied in line with case law of the European Court of Justice.

Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in their fight against cartels

Translating the core principles of the ECN MLP into law thereby introduce binding minimum rules for leniency programmes, would mean that current divergences between national programmes would be reduced and for example, summary applications would be available in all Member States and applied in the same way. Uniform rules would be put in place to ensure the full protection of leniency and settlement material outside the context of civil damages actions. This would preserve incentives for companies to provide information to competition authorities. Moreover, in order to ensure that companies are incentivised to apply for leniency, mechanisms could be put in place to protect employees of leniency applicants with the Commission or other NCAs from sanctions.

Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

By introducing minimum rules on the independence of NCAs, they would be protected from external influence when enforcing the EU competition rules, for example, by explicitly excluding instructions from any other body or prohibiting the dismissal of the board or management for reasons related to their individual decision-making. In addition, the introduction of an explicit requirement to make available adequate and stable human and financial resources would ensure that they will always have the necessary administrative capacity to effectively enforce the EU competition rules.

Impacts of option 3

It is not meaningful to set numerical figures on the extent to which effective enforcement of the EU competition rules would increase as a result of giving NCAs minimum powers to be effective enforcers. The number of cases brought depends on a number of variable factors such as the availability of information to the authority to detect infringements ex officio or as a result of a leniency application. Other factors also play an important role, for example, authorities will invest much more time and resources in complex cases which can set an important precedent for the market and have a much greater multiplier effect than more routine, less-resource-intensive cases. The scope of cases can also vary significantly, e.g. cases involving a large number of companies take more time to process.

Stakeholders who favour taking legislative action at EU level think that it would have a positive or very positive impact on: (i) the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules (92%) and (ii) legal certainty for businesses (85%). They consider that costs for businesses would decrease (52%) and cooperation in the ECN would be enhanced (83%). Taking action at EU level would have a positive impact on the legitimacy of decisions taken by NCAs (83%) and on the investment climate and economic growth (79%). 87  

Economic impact

Functioning of the internal market and competition

Giving NCAs minimum means and instruments to be more effective enforcers would lead to more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules and further spread the competition culture through-out Europe. This would result in more open competitive markets, where companies compete more fairly on their merits, and enable them to generate wealth and create jobs.

Studies illustrate the importance of the enforcement of competition law for ensuring competition on markets. 88 A study which examined how different antitrust systems affect the level of competition in individual countries found that increasing the range of instruments available to enforcement authorities has a significant impact on the intensity of competition in the country's economy. 89  

Studies also confirm the positive effects of competition on the productive efficiency of companies. This is due to a "between-firms" effect, by which better companies succeed while the worst ones fail and leave the market, and a within-firm effect by which companies in competitive environments are better managed.  90

One of the key functions of competition enforcement is to remove barriers for businesses to enter markets. Boosting effective competition enforcement would mean that the single market would be reinforced and be fairer for businesses and consumers.

Analyses of the impact of competition enforcement focus on the direct effects of enforcement actions and tend to ignore the more difficult to measure indirect benefits, namely the deterrent effect of such action. For example, imposing fines on companies that have taken part in cartels at a sufficiently high level is expected to deter other companies from entering into such agreements. 91

Economic growth and productivity

Giving NCAs minimum means and instruments to address the problems identified would enable them to be more effective enforcers, boosting the application of the EU competition rules. Greater competition boosts productivity - a key driver for economic growth. There are numerous empirical studies confirming that industries where there is a high level of competition experience statistically significant faster productivity growth. 92  

As noted above in section 2, according to the OECD there is solid evidence that enforcement of competition law leads to more competition on markets, which in turn results in higher productivity growth in affected industries, which translates into economic growth. 93 In a survey carried out by Ahn S. it was concluded that “A large number of empirical studies confirm that the link between product market competition and productivity growth is positive and robust. […] Empirical findings from various kinds of policy changes […] also confirm that competition brings about productivity gains, consumers’ welfare gains and long-run economic growth". 94

It is difficult to give estimates of the expected benefits to economic growth and productivity since the proposed changes are of a nature that is not easily quantifiable. This is because more effective competition enforcement is likely to give rise to general benefits to society and to the economy as a whole rather than to specific and quantifiable savings or benefits (such as for example a reduction of taxes). In addition, economic literature trying to measure those benefits is scarce.

Despite these obstacles, in two articles published in the Journal of Competition Law & Economics 95 and Review of Economics and Statistics 96 P. Buccirossi and co-authors developed a methodology to measure the impact that competition policy enforcement has on the economy. To our knowledge, this is the only available econometric approach trying to quantify the benefits of various detailed aspects of competition policy enforcement on the economy. The study found that about one fifth of industry productivity growth in a reforming economy (the UK) could be attributed to competition policy improvements. 97  

Based on this methodology it has been possible to estimate the order of magnitude of the impact that this option could have on the level of competition enforcement and hence on growth in Total Factor Productivity ("TFP"). A detailed assessment of this impact is provided in Annex XVI. TFP is a widely used measure of productivity in an economy which basically describes how efficient the economy is in the use of all (hence "total") relevant inputs. 98 Over the last decade TFP growth has had as an important impact on GDP in the EU as labour and capital, and it has become the most important factor in the last five years. As explained in more detail in Annex XVI, effective competition policy enforcement is expected to influence TFP growth because it helps keeping markets open, thereby ensuring that new innovative and more productive firms are not foreclosed from the market, and at the same time putting pressure on incumbents to either improve or lose market share. Also, effective competition policy ensures that prices for inputs in the productive process are not inflated by activities of cartels and anticompetitive mergers. Given that TFP growth in the EU as a whole has been below 1% for the last ten years (see Graph 1 in Annex XVI), calculations on the order of magnitude that the impact of this option will have on TFP following Buccirossi's methodology indicate that even a relatively small increase in the effectiveness of competition policy enforcement would give a significant boost to productivity.

For each country analysed, Buccirossi et al. constructed yearly "Competition Policy Indicators" (CPIs) with values between 0 and 1 intended to measure the quality of competition policy enforcement. As explained in Annex XVI, the CPIs covered seven features resulting in seven individual indicators which were used to calculate an aggregate CPI incorporating all the information on the competition policy regime of each country. These features include aspects such as independence, investigation powers, sanctioning policy, the availability of private damages and resources. Five are labelled as "institutional" features, and other two are called "enforcement" features. These features are used to measure different aspects of competition enforcement regarding four "limbs" of enforcement, namely: abuses of dominant position, hard-core cartels, other anticompetitive agreements, and mergers. Each feature is in turn formed by two or three "low-level indicators". The CPI is calculated by aggregating the values (between 0 and 1) assigned to each low-level indicator according to different weights given to each of the low level indicators, the type of feature and the enforcement "limb". Annex XVI provides more details on the specific weights used. They then estimated the effect of competition policy enforcement on TFP by using the CPI, together with several other variables within an econometric framework. 99 According to their calculations, the estimated coefficient of the CPI index is around 0.09. This means that an increase of 0.1 in the CPI index leads to an increase in TFP growth of 0.009 percentage point. For example, at the average values in the study of TFP (~1%) and CPI (0.4976), a 1% increase in CPI (e.g. an increase of 0.004976) would lead to an increase in the growth rate of TFP of 0.0448 percentage point (e.g. an increase of more than 4% in TFP growth, from 1% to 1.0448%). 100 Similarly, a 10% increase in the CPI might therefore be associated with an increase in the growth rate of TFP of almost 0.50 percentage point (e.g. an increase of some 50% in TFP growth from 1% to around 1.50%). Another way to look at this is to concentrate on countries with low CPIs, since it could be argued that it might be easier to raise the CPI from a low level, rather than increasing an already relatively high CPI. Using again a coefficient of 0.09, an increase of the smallest value of CPI in Buccirossi's dataset from 0.3167 to 0.3484 (equivalent to a 10% increase) would result in an increase in TFP growth of 0.29 percentage point (e.g. an increase of some 29% in TFP growth from 1% to 1.29%).

Although it is not possible to replicate the study of Buccirossi et al. in order to estimate the quantitative impact that all the measures proposed by option 3 would induce in the CPI, and hence in TFP growth, of each Member State, it is possible to carry out a qualitative assessment of such impact by assessing how the proposed measures would affect each of the features that form the CPI. Also, it is possible to provide some quantitative estimates of the impact that some of the measures of option 3 would have on CPI and TFP growth for those Member States affected by that particular measure. This more detailed assessment is provided in Annex XVI.

In particular, we have estimated the changes in TFP growth that would result from the following measures:

Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox: A Member State introducing one of the powers envisaged in option 3 (e.g. to inspect non-business premises) that it is currently lacking would increase the CPI in ~0.035 leading to an increase of TFP growth of 0.31% points (an increase of some 31% in TFP growth from 1% to 1.31%). Also, a Member State introducing the power to adopt interim measures would see as a result an increase of ~0.014 in its CPI leading to an increase of TFP growth of 0.12% points (an increase of 12% in TFP growth from 1% to 1.12%).

Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed: A modest improvement of 10% in this indicator as a result of option 3 would mean that a Member State with an average value for these indicators of 0.75 would have an increase in the CPI of ~0.004 leading to an increase of the TFP growth of around 0.04% points (from 1% to 1.04%). In the extreme case of a Member State with a NCA which in practice does not impose sanctions there would be an increase in the CPI of ~0.055 leading to an increase of the TFP growth of 0.50% points (an increase of some 50% in TFP growth from 1% to 1.50%.).

Specific objective 4: ensuring that all NCAs have the resources they need to carry out their work: A modest improvement of 10% in budget, staff, and staff skills indicators of a NCA would lead to an increase in the CPI of ~0.008 which in turn would translate into an increase of TFP growth of around 0.075% points (an increase of more than 7% in TFP growth from 1% to 1.075%).

In conclusion, while costs would be negligible for Member States little affected by the initiative, for those more significantly affected the benefits would be much larger. As demonstrated further in Annex XVI, even taking a very conservative approach and considering that the real impact would be a fraction of what could be expected, calculations indicate that achieving even a relative small increase in effective competition policy enforcement would increase productivity growth in a manner that in all likelihood would dwarf the costs of implementing the proposals in this option which, as explained below, are expected to be modest.

Similarly, another study of 32 jurisdictions applying competition law over 1992-2007 found evidence that budgetary commitments to competition enforcement authorities yield economic benefits in terms of improved economic growth: i.e. higher budgetary commitments to competition policy are associated with higher levels percapita GDP growth. 101  

There are also other research attempts which try to show the link between the microeconomic assessment of the enforcement of the EU competition rules by the European Commission in the area of cartels and mergers and EU macroeconomic performance. Although this work is based on a number of assumptions  102 it offers a good idea of the order of magnitude of the impact of the enforcement of the EU competition rules. As noted above, model simulations show that the Commission's cartel decisions and merger interventions have a sizeable impact on growth and jobs: GDP increases by 0.4% after five years and by 0.7% in the long run, and after ten years around 650 000 cumulated new jobs are created. 103  

Moreover, the positive effects on productivity growth are not only felt in the sectors where such increased competition takes place, but they also spread to downstream markets and throughout the economy. 104 Economic growth is therefore faster with policies that increase competition enforcement.

Trade and investment flows

Boosting effective competition enforcement would make Europe's markets more open and competitive and would make them more attractive to investors. In a review of earlier studies carried out in 2014, Gutmann and Voigt 105 found a significant relationship between the introduction of competition law and annual growth arising mainly from more investment, possibly as a result of more confidence and a lower perceived level of corruption.

Greater competition enhances the ability of businesses to compete, both on their home markets and internationally. In a study of 2008, Borrell and Tolosa 106 assessed the combined effect of competing and other policies, particularly open trade policies, concluding that competition law and policies aimed at opening trade reinforce each other and should be considered as complementary.

Position of SMEs

Creating a more level playing field in which a competition culture prevails enables all businesses to compete more fairly and grow throughout the single market, including SMEs.

Innovation and research

By boosting effective competition enforcement, businesses would compete more fairly on their merits. This incentivises them to innovate and offer a better range of higher quality products and services that meet consumers' expectations. Firms facing more competition from rivals innovate more than monopolies. Greater competition also drives efficiency in processes, technology and service.

Recent analyses have shown an "inverted U" relationship between competition and innovation, so that moderately competitive markets are likely to be more innovative than monopolies or highly concentrated markets or industries with a low cost price margin. Very recent empirical work has also confirmed that an increase in competition leads to a significant increase in research and development investment by neck-and-neck firms. 107  Conversely, the view according to which market concentration or large firm size is associated with a higher level of innovation is not supported by empirical evidence. 108

Consumers and households

More effective competition enforcement protects European consumers from business practices that keep the prices of goods and services artificially high, and ensures that they have better quality, wider choice and innovative goods and services at affordable prices. Numerous studies confirm the benefits of competitive markets for consumers. A survey carried out by Ahn S. found that “Empirical findings from various kinds of policy changes […] also confirm that competition brings about productivity gains, consumers’ welfare gains and long-run economic growth". 109  

As noted above, cartels typically increase prices: the empirical evidence in academic literature suggests that the median cartel overcharge lies between 17 and 30%. 110  A literature survey and meta-analysis of several hundred cartels across a large number of jurisdictions in the EU, North America and Asia found that the stronger the competition regime, the lower the cartel overcharge. 111

As noted above, the Directorate-General for Competition of the European Commission estimated the annual customer benefits of only its decisions prohibiting cartels only (e.g. excluding other antitrust actions) for the period 2010-2015. 112 This varied between €1 billion up to €10.8 billion, depending on the year considered. As already explained above, the relevant estimates are based on a number of assumptions such as, for example, on the increased price brought about by the cartel and on the likely duration of the cartel had it remained undetected.

Public authorities

A key benefit of giving NCAs minimum means and instruments to be more effective enforcers is that it would make them better 'value for money'. Removing gaps and limitations in NCAs’ means and instruments will enable NCAs to enforce more, leading to more competition on markets.

The UK competition authority estimated that the average direct financial benefit to consumers of its whole activity (which includes competition enforcement, merger control, consumer protection enforcement and market studies and market investigations) for the period 2013 to 2016 was £687 million per annum against an average cost of £65 million, yielding a ratio of direct benefits to costs of 10.6. The breakdown of the financial benefit by tool showed a contribution by the competition enforcement activity against anti-competitive practices of £73.6 million. 113  As already explained above, these estimates necessarily rely in part on assumptions. 114

The burden that would ensue from giving NCAs minimum rules to be effective enforcers is low compared to the scale of the benefits in terms of better enforcement and benefits for the economy, as indicated above, The legislative initiative would not bring about significant structural changes implying high costs such as those that could be expected with, for example, the creation of a new agency or regulator. All NCAs already have the basic framework in place for the enforcement of the EU competition rules.

It would involve the following costs (for further details see Annex XVI):

(1) The implementation of the legislative initiative: This would consist largely of the one-off administrative costs of adaptation of national legal systems These costs would be variable depending on the extent to which rules that empower NCAs to be effective enforcers are already in place but, based on the Commission's experience with the implementation of the Damages Directive 2014/104/EU, it would mean not more than 2 full time officials (FTEs) for 18 months for all Member States. This option also allows for national specificities to be taken into account, limiting adaptation costs. Costs would also ensue for those Member States where the NCAs do not have sufficient resources to perform their tasks. Given that the envisaged provision on resources is very basic, essentially to prevent NCAs from being in a situation where they cannot effectively enforce the EU competition rules, this cost has been estimated on the basis of what would be needed to ensure that all NCAs can effectively carry out simultaneous inspections of all/most members of a cartel). This would be confined to a limited number of Member States (increase of 4 to 10 FTEs for five Member States, meaning a total of some 35 FTEs).

(2) Costs for NCAs: This option is not expected to lead to significant additional costs. The legislative initiative is broadly focussed on giving more powers and instruments to the NCAs which per se do not imply any additional cost. Some training costs to be familiarised with the new powers/instruments could however be envisaged (up to 5 training days for 2 FTEs per NCA). Nevertheless, these potential costs would be partly offset by the cooperation/training possibilities that are currently in place: through the ECN meetings NCAs' officials would be able to exchange experience and know-how about the application of the new measures; and NCA's officials can also participate in the one month training programme organised annually by the Commission.

(3) Costs for the European Commission: The Commission is responsible for ensuring that appropriate IT platforms and tools are in place to ensure that authorities can cooperate effectively in the ECN. This is currently fit for purpose. These IT platforms and tools have to be updated continuously and any challenge resulting from this option would have to be integrated in this process.

Simplification and administrative burden on business

Common minimum standards regarding the investigation and sanctioning tools can reduce divergent outcomes for companies and make the application of the EU competition rules by NCAs more predictable. The competition authorities in the EU would be able to cooperate better with each other and the credibility of the ECN would be reinforced.

Costs for businesses involved in cross-border activities to adapt to different legal frameworks would be reduced or even fall and legal certainty would increase as all NCAs would have the same minimum means and instruments in place. This would, for example, further ensure the attractiveness of leniency programmes and incentivise companies considering applying for leniency to cooperate with NCAs through-out the EU. There would be rather limited adaptation costs for business in terms of familiarisation with new rules (which would vary depending on which Member States they operate), but this would be more than off-set by the benefits of operating in a more level playing field with greater legal certainty.

Social impacts

Employment and labour markets

More effective competition enforcement would lead to greater competition on Europe's markets. An overview by the OECD of the main literature covering the links and drivers between competition and employment confirms that competition stimulates employment growth in the long term. 115 The aggregate effect mainly results from a positive impact on total factor productivity growth which increases labour demand, and through aggregate demand, given that more competition lowers prices and therefore tends to increase real wages. This generates a virtuous circle of output and demand growth in the long run. 116  

In the short run, especially at individual company level, the response to increased competition can lead to an increase in unemployment, e.g. through process innovation that replaces labour intensive machinery with new machines to increase productivity at the cost of labour. However, econometric simulations of the effect of increased competition leading to redundancies in an industry demonstrate a return to a steady growth path with rising employment after two-three years. 117

Effects on income, distribution

Putting in place minimum rules for the NCAs to be effective enforcers will boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules, leading to more competition on markets. Greater competition stimulates economic growth, which in turn leads to greater economic prosperity for EU citizens.

Giving NCAs the minimum means and instruments they need to be effective enforcers can bring another positive impact, as competition may have a beneficial effect on equality. Although the effect of competition on equality has been little studied, many studies have shown that the increases in prices and the lower quality and choice that result from monopolies or restrictions of competition harm particularly the poorest. 118 Examples include Hausman and Sidak (2004) 119 (showing that in the US the poorer and less educated customers pay more for their mobile telephony services than better educated and more affluent customers) and a study with the OECD and the Mexican Federal Competition Commission carried out by Urzua (2013) 120 which concludes that “the welfare losses due to the exercise of monopoly power are not only significant, but also larger, in relative terms, for the poor. Moreover, the losses are different for the urban and rural sectors, as well as for each of the states of Mexico, being the inhabitants of the poorest ones the most affected by firms with market power".

A paper carried out by staff of the OECD on market power and wealth distribution concluded that market power may account for a substantial amount of wealth inequality, with market power accounting for between 10-24% of the wealth of the top wealth decile, and that Government action focussed on competition law enforcement and elimination of unduly anti-competitive regulation can limit illegitimate market power and may enhance equality of wealth distribution. 121

Impacts on Fundamental Rights (EU Charter of Fundamental Rights)

Right to good administration and right to an effective remedy & a fair trial (Articles 41 & 47)

Giving NCAs effective powers would be done to the extent that this is necessary and proportionate. These powers would be counter-balanced by ensuring that parties have effective rights to be heard, to access NCAs' case file and the right to a reasoned decision. Provision would also be made to ensure that companies have effective remedies to challenge enforcement measures.

Presumption of innocence and rights of defence (Article 48)

The rights of defence of companies under investigation would be ensured, e.g. right to formal notification of the NCA's objections under EU competition law and effective right of access to the file so that companies can prepare their defence.

Property rights/Freedom to conduct business (Articles 16-17)

Some measures such as ensuring NCAs have effective powers to inspect business and non-business premises, grant interim measures and behavioural and structural remedies could raise concerns as regards property rights and the freedom to conduct a business. However, these measures would be subject to strict safeguards and would only be used where necessary and proportionate. Parties to competition proceedings would have effective remedies to challenge these enforcement measures.

Personal data protection (Article 8)

The processing of data would be carried out only to the extent that it is necessary for the performance of a task carried out in the public interest, i.e. the enforcement of the EU competition rules.

Respect for private and family life (Article 7)

Currently a few NCAs lack the power to inspect the private homes of company directors and employees. Not having this power provides an easy loophole for cartelists to exploit. Experience shows that competition authorities do not use this power regularly but its very existence acts as a strong deterrent against hiding incriminating information at home. This power would be backed up by strict safeguards, including making its use subject to judicial authorisation.

6.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

This option would provide a more complete harmonisation so that NCAs would have detailed and uniform means and instruments. It would fulfil the specific objectives as follows:

Specific objective 1: ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

This would mean giving NCAs a uniform and complete set of investigation and decision-making powers, backed up by uniform sanctions for non-compliance. It would also provide for uniform and detailed procedural guarantees. Accordingly all NCAs would have an identical comprehensive toolbox with a high level of protection of procedural rights. Most feedback from stakeholders is that giving NCAs minimum effective investigative and decision-making tools would be sufficient to meet the objective of ensuring they are more effective enforcers. For example, obliging Member States to have a formal market test to assess the appropriateness of commitments proposed by parties under investigation would impinge on NCA's flexibility to get the same input by potentially swifter means. Similarly, designing detailed rules on access to the NCAs' case file would be very difficult as there are very different systems in place at national level. This is also the case when it comes to rules on the participation of complainants and third parties in competition proceedings where there are a large variety of systems in place ranging from the very informal, to systems with detailed procedural steps and rights and obligations for these actors. It is not apparent that having uniform and detailed rules on access to file or regulating the role played by complainants and third parties would lead to more effective enforcement. The fact-finding and the public consultation have not given rise to significant concerns in this respect.

Indeed, NCAs' tools should not be addressed in cases where there is not a clear need for action. For example, although 89% of stakeholders replied in the public consultation that sector inquiries are a tool that NCAs need to effectively enforce (and some NCAs face issues which make conducting such inquiries more difficult 122 ), most NCAs currently do not experience serious issues with the functioning of this instrument. EU legislative intervention on this aspect therefore does not seem merited.

Having uniform and detailed rules on NCAs' toolbox would prevent Member States from providing for more far-reaching powers or stronger procedural guarantees. It may also create rigidities by not leaving enough flexibility to Member States to adapt and change the toolbox as needed.

Specific objective 2: ensuring deterrent fines can be imposed

Introducing a uniform fining model through EU legislation so that only administrative fines on undertakings can be imposed (and no longer civil or criminal fines) would create a more level field for companies in terms of the sanctions to which they are exposed. However, this option would constitute undue interference in the design of Member State competition enforcement systems as this is a fundamental aspect of how enforcement systems are set up. The risk of exposure to criminal enforcement may also prompt companies to comply with the competition rules, so removing this possibility would not be in the interests of overall enforcement.

Having a uniform methodology for setting fines which fixes all the parameters (e.g. value of sales, gravity, duration) that are to be taken into account when imposing fines and prescribes how they should calculate such fines (for example, by determining the actual value which should be attributed to each of the parameters) would mean that the companies would have much greater predictability about the level of fine they would face, irrespective of which NCA acts. This would reinforce the single market. However, it would leave NCAs with limited flexibility to set fines in light of the facts of the specific case. Providing for uniform and detailed rules would also remove the flexibility needed to adapt the rules to new developments.

Specific objective 3: making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in the fight against cartels

Putting in place a one-stop-shop for leniency applications would go a long way towards ensuring a consistent application of leniency criteria, especially as the Commission would be best placed for dealing with all applications in a centralised manner. It would also be the least resource-intensive and most transparent way for applicants to file for leniency. However, depending on the set-up of the one-stop shop, this option would have major drawbacks. First, it would presuppose a full harmonisation of the leniency conditions, which would amount to a far-reaching interference in Member States' systems. For example, such full harmonisation would prevent Member States from devising a more generous leniency programme as regards certain conditions. More lenient conditions may be warranted in some countries where leniency programmes are still novel and a firm culture of cooperating with the NCA has not yet been established. A fully centralised system would also run counter to the current successful system of decentralised enforcement of the EU competition rules, parallel competences and flexible case allocation set out in Regulation 1/2003. Furthermore, a fully centralised system would place a very significant procedural burden on the Commission, which could have repercussions on the Commission's ability to deal with the substance of its own cartel cases and thus lead to under-enforcement at European level. The reduction in the burden for companies, which is the main advantage of all one-stop-shop solutions, does not appear to outweigh these disadvantages.

Specific objective 4: ensuring all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work.

While most respondents to the public consultation support the introduction of the independence safeguards foreseen under option 3, several stakeholders also plead for additional independence safeguards already in place for sectoral regulators. 123  They favoured in particular the introduction of budgetary autonomy and transparent appointment procedures for NCAs' management/board. The downside of this approach is that it would interfere more in the right of Member States to design their enforcement systems in light of their national traditions and specificities. It is not clear that these disadvantages would be outweighed by the benefits these uniform and detailed safeguards on institutional and financial autonomy could bring.

Impacts of option 4

Option 4 is likely to result in all of the impacts set out for option 3, but for some aspects to a somewhat greater extent. For example, by providing for more uniform rules, companies would be treated more consistently through-out Europe and the single market would be more complete. However, it is not evident that putting in place such more detailed and uniform rules would necessarily result in significantly more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules than by giving NCAs a minimum core set of means and instruments. Moreover, it would involve greater intrusion in Member States' legal traditions and specificities, preventing Member States from providing for further-reaching procedural guarantees.

Economic impact

Functioning of the internal market and competition

Same as for option 3, except that putting in place uniform and detailed rules would result in a more level playing field for businesses and make the single market even more complete.

Economic growth and productivity

Same as for option 3: giving NCAs the means and instruments they need to be more effective enforcers would boost productivity, which is a key driver for economic growth. As explained in the same context for option 3, it is difficult to give precise estimates of the expected benefits to economic growth and productivity that this option will bring about. Nevertheless, it is considered that the estimate increases in CPI and the resulting TFP growth presented in Annex XVI for option 3 will be the same, if not in certain respects, greater for option 4, e.g. fines might be even more homogenous, potentially meaning a more consistent level of deterrence across Europe.

Trade and investment flows

Same as for option 3: Greater competition enhances the ability of businesses to compete, both on their home markets and internationally. Making Europe's markets more open and competitive would make them more attractive to investors.

Position of SMEs

Same as for option 3, except that having uniform and detailed rules would result in a more level playing field. This is of benefit to all businesses, including SMEs.

Innovation and research

Same as for option 3: empowering NCAs to be more effective enforcers would boost competition. Businesses would compete more fairly on the merits, incentivising them to innovate and offer a better range of higher quality products and services that meet consumers' expectations.

Consumers and households

Same as for option 3: more effective competition enforcement protects European consumers from business practices that keep the prices of goods and services artificially high and ensures better quality, wider choice and innovative goods and services.

Public authorities

(1) The implementation of the legislative initiative: The implementation costs for public authorities in the Member States would be greater as it would imply a greater need for legislative change. This would vary to the extent that rules to ensure that NCAs are effective enforcers are already in place. However, by providing for detailed and uniform rules it would take limited account of national specificities, meaning that implementation costs would be higher. In particular, it would mean a system change for those 8 Member States which would have to move to a fully administrative model. As for option 3, these costs would be partly off-set, although to a lesser extent, by the benefits of having more effective enforcers which are 'better value for money', e.g. more enforcement would lead to welfare gains for consumers. The implementation costs would be estimated at overall 3 FTEs over 18 months for all Member States, with 1 extra FTE being needed for those Member States which would have to move to a fully administrative model. This option would also not necessarily imply an overarching need for NCAs to have more resources than option 3, although it would mean that Member States which previously had a judicial model for enforcing fines would have to allocate more staff to their administrative NCAs (at least 2 FTEs for 8 NCAs).

(2) Costs for NCAs: This would be similar as for option 3, but as the legislative changes would be greater, more training costs would be envisaged (up to 10 training days for 2 FTEs per NCA).

(3) Costs for the European Commission: the costs of having appropriate IT tools and platforms for NCAs to cooperate would be the same as for option 3.

Simplification and administrative burden on business

The costs for businesses involved in cross-border activities to adapt to different legal frameworks would ultimately be lower as uniform rules would be in place across Europe, meaning a more level playing field. Minimising/removing differences in national frameworks is also likely to lead to more predictable outcomes for business and increase legal certainty. This has to be balanced against the initial adaptation costs incurred by companies, which would be higher than for option 3, because it would lead to more legislative changes.

Social impacts

Employment and labour markets

Same as for option 3: greater competition stimulates employment growth in the long-term.

Effects on income, distribution

Same as for option 3: boosting competition leads to greater economic growth which in turn promotes greater economic prosperity for EU citizens.

Impacts on Fundamental Rights (EU Charter of Fundamental Rights)

Putting in place enforcement powers of NCAs may potentially interfere with a number of fundamental rights (see option 3), so it should only be done to the extent that this is necessary and proportionate. Companies would benefit from a more level playing field and greater legal certainty in terms of the protection of their rights. However, having uniform and detailed rules would prevent Member States from providing for further reaching procedural guarantees.

7How do the options compare?

7.1Comparison of the options

The options are compared against the baseline scenario based on their contribution to the general and specific objectives set out in section 4, as well as their main impacts as analysed in section 6.

7.1.1Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

The baseline scenario would not entail additional costs or obligations, but it is highly unlikely to achieve the policy objectives. Some Member States still may make some changes, even in the absence of EU law, however this is unlikely to take place on the scale needed. NCAs would continue to apply the same substantive EU rules on the basis of incomplete national means and instruments.

The baseline scenario would not be in line with stakeholders’ expectations given that 80% of respondents to the public consultation indicated that action should be taken to empower the NCAs to be more effective enforcers. 124  

7.1.2Option 2: further soft action 

Soft action would be most respectful of rules at national level and would carry negligible costs. However, soft action has all the drawbacks of option 1 and does not provide a sound legal basis to ensure that all NCAs have the necessary means and instruments to be effective enforcers.

Soft action has already been used extensively to address the problem and the four problem drivers. It has prompted a certain level of change and has been useful to illustrate to other stakeholders, including policy-makers, the consensus that exists among competition authorities in the EU on the means and instruments NCAs need. It may also lead to some further changes in certain Member States, although this will be limited given that the soft measures have been in place for a number of years, without achieving the aim of fully realising the potential of the decentralised system put in place by Regulation 1/2003 by making NCAs more effective enforcers of the EU competition rules (see section 6.1).

Soft law does not allow for converging EU law concepts to be clarified via the case law of the European Court of Justice, as national courts will continue to give different interpretations of issues such as the notion of undertaking. It also does not enable the Commission to take enforcement action (in the form of an infringement action) if soft measures are not respected.

Exclusive soft action would not be in line with the expectations of the broad majority of respondents to the public consultation, who prefer EU legislative action (79%) to be taken either exclusively or in combination with soft action (28% and 51% of respondents respectively). 125  

7.1.3Option 3: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments to be effective enforcers, complemented by soft action/detailed rules where appropriate 

Putting in place a minimum core set of means and instruments, if calibrated correctly, would allow NCAs to more effectively enforce the EU competition rules.

This calibrated approach would allow distinguishing between areas where only high-level principles need to be harmonised and those where, in view of the nature of the perceived gaps, more detailed rules are required to reap added value in terms of competition enforcement. This fine-tuning would limit interference in the Member States' legal systems to the extent that this is strictly necessary to boost effective enforcement, in line with the principles of proportionality and subsidiarity as laid down in Article 5 TEU.

For example, regarding the calculation of fines, establishing a minimum set of aspects that should be taken into account when determining a fine, such as the duration and gravity of an infringement, would go a long way towards ensuring deterrent fines across Europe, even if the more detailed methodology for their application were left for the NCAs. These measures could be complemented by soft measures on non-core aspects.

Another example is the nature of the fines imposed. In order to address the issue that there is little or no enforcement of the EU competition rules in (quasi) criminal systems for competition enforcement, particularly when it comes to fining abuses of dominance, it is necessary to grant NCAs the option of choosing another route than the (quasi) criminal route on a case-by-case basis. Attempts to address this through soft action have not succeeded and after 12 years it is highly unlikely Member States will act, meaning that safe havens from fines will continue to persist. This would directly contradict the decentralised system put in place by Regulation 1/2003 whereby the EU competition rules should be effectively enforced by NCAs in all EU Member States. Conversely, it does not seem necessary or proportionate to prescribe the alternative route to be chosen (administrative or civil courts) or to impose the abolition of the (quasi) criminal route altogether, which might still be appropriate and more deterrent for hard-core cartels in certain Member States. This approach also ensures that the choice of those Member States which have opted for a judicial model of competition enforcement is fully respected.

In some limited cases it may be necessary, however, to provide detailed and uniform safeguards to ensure NCAs are effective enforcers, e.g. to provide for full protection against the disclosure of leniency statements and settlement submissions to preserve incentives for companies to provide information to NCAs.

Such a calibrated approach would not be a radical departure from, but a logical evolution of, general EU law requirement that Member States must provide for effective procedures and sanctions for the enforcement of EU rules. According to the Court of Justice of the Europe Union, national law must ensure that EU competition law is fully effective. 126  The Court has also held that detailed national procedural rules for the functioning of NCAs must not jeopardise the attainment of the objective of Regulation 1/2003, which is to ensure that Articles 101 and 102 TFEU are applied effectively by those authorities. 127

In terms of the benefits it would bring, NCAs would become more effective enforcers. Only action at EU level can ensure that fines can effectively be imposed on companies by tackling national provisions which prevent the imposition of effective fines on companies for infringements of the EU competition rules. It is also the only means to address the wide variations in levels of fines imposed by different authorities and ensure that there are common core principles for imposing fines, thus, providing a more level playing field for business and ensuring deterrent fines across the EU. This is also the case for leniency programmes where companies regularly file applications to a number of EU jurisdictions and need guarantees of cross-border legal certainty. Such cross-border legal certainty cannot be sufficiently achieved by Member States individually.

It would also ensure that the necessary safeguards are in place to ensure that the NCAs enforce the EU competition rules without taking instructions from anyone and have the necessary resources to perform their tasks. All NCAs would have minimum powers needed to investigate and take decisions to effectively enforce the EU competition rules.

Having minimum rules would reduce divergent outcomes for companies and make the application of the EU competition rules by NCAs more predictable and consistent across the EU. The competition authorities in the EU would be able to cooperate better with each other, as it would ensure that they are all in a position to effectively assist each other, e.g. by gathering evidence. The credibility of the ECN would thus be reinforced.

Giving NCAs the means and instruments to be more effective enforcers would boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules. This would result in more open competitive markets, where companies compete more fairly on their merits and enabling them to generate wealth and create jobs. Greater competition boosts productivity - a key driver for economic growth, leading to greater prosperity for EU citizens, as well as long-term employment growth. Competition enforcement helps to remove barriers to enter markets. The single market would be reinforced and be fairer. Businesses would benefit from a more level playing field and consumers would profit from a more equivalent level of enforcement through-out the EU. More effective competition enforcement protects European consumers from business practices that keep the prices of goods and services artificially high and enhances their choice of innovative goods and services. As explained in more detail in Section 6.3 above, even a relatively small increase in the effectiveness of competition policy enforcement would give a significant boost to productivity. Option 3 thus actions two levers: First, it maximises the increase in effectiveness with a minimum of interference in national specificities by limiting the most detailed rules to the areas where they are most needed to improve effectiveness. Second, the effectiveness thus achieved translates into a significant increase in TFP, whose growth has been low in the EU over the last ten years. This approach is thus fully in line with the proportionality principle.

When it comes to costs, this would largely entail implementation costs of the legislative initiative for public administrations. These costs would be variable depending on the extent to which rules that NCAs are empowered to be effective enforcers are already in place, although all NCAs have the basic framework in place. It is therefore more a matter of filling certain gaps and removing specific limitations depending on the Member State concerned. The implementation costs for the public purse would be negligible compared to the benefits realised by making NCAs more effective enforcers, e.g. consumers pay lower prices for goods and services, and thus better 'value for money'.

Companies would face limited initial adaptation costs in terms of familiarisation with the new rules (which would vary depending on the Member State in which they operate). Overall, the costs for businesses involved in cross-border activities to adapt to different legal frameworks would reduce, reinforcing the single market.

7.1.4Option 4: EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

This option would aim at a higher level of harmonisation. It would bring limited additional benefits relative to option 3, but at the same time entail greater interference in national legal systems and traditions.

Providing for detailed and uniform means and instruments would create the best possible level playing field for the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by NCAs, and thereby strengthen the single market. This would be to the benefit of businesses operating cross-border: uniform rules means lower costs in terms of becoming aware of different laws in different national frameworks and is also likely to lead to more predictable outcomes and increase legal certainty.

However, it is not evident that giving NCAs more detailed and uniform means and instruments would necessarily result in significantly more effective enforcement of the EU competition rules than by giving NCAs minimum tools and safeguards. There is of course some added enforcement value in going for a high level of harmonisation. For example, the NCAs might receive even more leniency applications, leading to the detection of secret cartels, if the criteria leniency applicants must fulfil were fully convergent and applied by a central authority. Fines would be even more homogenous and deterrent if the more detailed methodology for fine-setting were regulated at European level. However, there is not a linear relationship between having more regulation and the effectiveness of the NCAs. The real step forward in terms of NCAs' effectiveness is between option 2 and 3, not between 3 and 4.

However, the main drawback of a high level of harmonisation is that it would take limited account of national specificities, and would mean greater interference in national legal systems and traditions than in option 3. For example, setting up a one-stop-shop for leniency applications would require the full harmonisation of the conditions and thresholds to be met for leniency to be granted across Europe. This would interfere in Member States' systems at a time when leniency programmes are still novel in some countries and have not reached a stage of sufficient maturity to merit a broader review. Similarly, having detailed and uniform rules on the parameters for setting fines would remove the flexibility NCAs need to adapt the rules to new developments. Allowing NCAs to only impose administrative fines, and thereby abolishing the criminal route in Member States where this is a deep-seated tradition would not respect the right of Member States to design their enforcement systems in light of their national specificities. Setting uniform rules, would also prevent Member States from providing for further-reaching powers or procedural guarantees.

On balance, since the advantages of option 4 in terms of creating a more level playing field and thus boosting effective enforcement are not substantial, especially not as compared to the real step forward made between option 2 and 3, option 3 and its calibrated approach are more in line with the proportionality and subsidiarity principles than option 4.

7.1.5Overview of how the options compare

The table below provides an assessment of options 2, 3 and 4 against the baseline scenario based on a number of criteria, namely effectiveness, coherency of the options with other EU policies, costs, benefits, subsidiarity and proportionality. Annex XI also contains a table containing an overview of how the different options compare with the baseline scenario in terms of achieving the general and specific objectives.



Summary table – Assessment of options

Option 1: no EU action (baseline scenario)

Option 2:

soft law measures

Option 3: 

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments, complemented by soft action and detailed provisions in confined cases

Option 4:

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

Effectiveness

None:

existing gaps and limitations would

prevent NCAs

from being more effective competition enforcers

Negligible/negative

High

High

Coherence with other EU policies including Charter on Fundamental Rights

None:

most NCAs will

continue to miss certain key tools or lack sufficient resources to enforce EU competition rules

Negligible/negative: NCAs would still face gaps and limitations that prevent them from being more effective competition enforcers, even though the EU competition rules are a defining feature of the single market

High:

would ensure that NCAs are effective competition enforcers while avoiding unnecessary interference in fundamental rights

Medium/high:

would ensure that NCAs are effective competition enforcers, but giving NCAs more powers by means of more detailed rules, to a level that is not necessary to achieve the general and specific objectives, would increase the risk of unnecessary interference in fundamental rights.

Costs

None

Negligible

Medium:

implementation costs for public authorities depending on extent to which NCA face gaps or limitations (they all have the basic framework in place). Companies would have limited initial adaptation costs depending on which Member States they are active.

Medium/high:

companies would ultimately benefit from lower costs as rules would be uniform, but implementation costs for public authorities and adaptation costs for companies would be higher as it would not leave room for national specificities.

Benefits

None

Negligible

High

High

Subsidiarity

High

High

High:

providing for primarily minimum means and instruments and limiting detailed rules to areas where this is strictly necessary to boost enforcement would ensure greatest possible respect for national procedures and traditions

Low:

would interfere in Member States' procedures and traditions even where this is not compensated by significant added value in terms of boosting enforcement

Proportionality

Low: would not address the problem drivers and fulfil the general and specific objectives

Low:

would not address the problem drivers and fulfil the general and specific objectives

High:

it would ensure a balance between meeting the general and specific objectives whilst not unduly interfering in national traditions

Low:

the measures would go further than is necessary to achieve the general and specific objectives

7.2Preferred policy option

The preferred policy option best suited to achieve the general and specific objectives without disproportional interference in the Member States’ legal systems and traditions is option 3. EU legislation is the only effective instrument to provide NCAs with the means and instruments necessary to boost their enforcement of the EU competition rules. Having primarily minimum rules as described in section 6.3 strikes the right balance by achieving the set objectives at the lowest possible cost, without unduly interfering with the national legal traditions and specificities.

Uniform and detailed safeguards would only be used in limited cases where minimum rules would not suffice to meet the objective of boosting effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by NCAs. For example, when it comes to protecting corporate leniency statements and settlement submissions, it may be better to follow the precedent of the Damages Directive 2014/104/EU and provide for full protection against their disclosure to preserve incentives for companies to provide the necessary information to competition authorities.

Soft action could be used in a number of areas where it is useful to build on basic provisions in the EU legislative instrument, while leaving sufficient flexibility to adapt to both national specificities and new developments. For example, soft action could be used to put 'meat on the bones' of minimum rules regarding fines set out in EU legislation. Such soft action has the benefit of allowing more detailed solutions to be put in place, which can easily be adjusted to new developments. Complementary soft action would ideally be developed in the ECN. This would entail little costs as one of the key roles of the ECN is to develop policy on the co-enforcement of the EU competition rules and foster a common approach across Europe. The ECN is a tried and tested forum for devising soft action which has the support and buy-in of all NCAs.

Option 3 would also best meet the expectations of stakeholders, including many key stakeholders such as NCAs, business and consumer organisations, of which the large majority (79%) in favour of EU action, expressed a clear preference for legislative action. It would also meet the majority view (51%) of stakeholders in favour of action at EU level as they preferred a mixture of EU legislative and soft action, as opposed to 28% in favour of exclusive legislative action (see section 7.1.2 for details per type of stakeholder). Such broad support for EU legislative action covers all four specific objectives. Moreover, stakeholders' backing for EU legislative action is often even higher when considering their replies for each specific objective. For example, on the competition toolbox, 89% opt for some type of EU legislative action. This option would be most in line with the initial feedback from Member State ministries, who did not object/were favourable to EU action to ensure a common competition enforcement area in Europe, provided it does not unduly interfere with national traditions. For example, when it comes to fines the main feedback from the Member States was that it would be useful to have common rules in place to ensure that effective fines can be imposed, provided there is room for further guidance to be given by the Court of Justice of the European Union on issues such as the notion of undertaking, parental liability and economic and legal succession. There should also be room for soft action, such as ECN Recommendations, to ensure further convergence in a flexible way on issues such as fining methodologies.

Stakeholders who favour taking action at EU level think that it would have a positive or very positive impact on: (i) the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules (92%) and (ii) legal certainty for businesses (85%). They consider that costs for businesses would decrease (52%) and cooperation in the ECN would be enhanced (83%). Taking action at EU level would have a positive impact on the legitimacy of decisions taken by NCAs (83%) and on the investment climate and economic growth (79%). 128  

Annex III sets out the practical implications of the preferred policy option for NCAs, business, consumers and public administrations.

The preferred policy option would boost effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by the NCAs by closing the gaps and remove the limitations that NCAs face which prevent them from enforcing more effectively. NCAs would have the capacity they need to fulfil their tasks under Regulation 1/2003. Putting guarantees in place that the NCAs can effectively enforce the EU competition rules would bolster public confidence in the national frameworks for ensuring compliance with the EU competition rules and enhance the legitimacy of the European system of competition enforcement as a whole.

The preferred policy option would achieve the specific policy objectives as follows:

7.2.1All NCAs would have an effective enforcement toolbox

All NCAs would have the tools they need to be able to investigate infringements and to take decisions to bring them to an end. NCAs would no longer be prevented from detecting infringements because of restrictions, for example, in their power to gather evidence. NCAs would be able to set their enforcement priorities in full and choose which cases to dedicate their scarce resources, e.g. to tackle cases which may bring significant consumer benefits or those which may have a strong precedent value for businesses. Their investigation and decision-making powers would be meaningful because they would be backed up by deterrent fines. Companies would think twice about not complying with a NCA decision. At the same time, it would be ensured that adequate procedural guarantees are in place in line with the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights.

7.2.2All NCAs would be able to impose (or seek) deterrent fines

All NCAs would be able to impose deterrent fines on companies for breaches of the EU competition rules. This would reduce wide variations in fines depending on which authority acts. It would also prevent companies escaping fines altogether, for example, by restructuring. NCAs would be able to impose (or seek) fines for the entire duration of an infringement and not just part of it, meaning that the fines better reflect the harm caused to competition. NCAs which currently can only impose primarily criminal fines, meaning that they have low levels of enforcement and fines imposed, particularly in abuse of dominance cases, would be given the option of imposing administrative fines or apply to civil courts for fines to be imposed, depending on the facts and circumstances of the case. Giving those NCAs this possibility means that they are no longer limited in terms of what cases they can take (now usually limited to the more straightforward cases such as hard-core cartels) and the fines they can impose or seek. This option would also improve criminal enforcement by enabling NCAs to bring and defend their cases in court. By making fines more deterrent and effective, companies contemplating breaking the EU competition rules would be much less likely to decide that the potential gains outweigh the risks. Complementary soft action could be taken on certain non-core aspects of the methodologies for imposing fines to develop an even more effective and coherent fining policy across the EU on a flexible basis. This could for example cover which aggravating/mitigating factors should be taken into account and how to assess the gravity of the offence.

7.2.3All NCAs would have effective leniency programmes which would encourage companies to come clean across the EU

All NCAs would have effective leniency programmes in place adapted to their needs, with a coherent EU system to deal with applications to multiple jurisdictions. This would increase legal certainty for companies as to their place in the leniency queue and would enable them to know whether they are eligible for immunity from fines or potentially no reduction in fines at all. With such a system in place, companies will be incentivised to apply for leniency. This will help NCAs to detect cartels which are often difficult to find out about due to their secret nature. Putting in place arrangements to ensure that employees of companies that make leniency applications to NCAs and/or the Commission are protected from sanctions will also ensure that companies are incentivised to apply for leniency. Without these guarantees, the legal risks for the individuals involved may have a chilling effect on the willingness of companies to come clean about their involvement in cartels. This prevents NCAs from becoming aware of the most pernicious forms of competition infringements.

7.2.4All NCAs would have guarantees of independence and resources

All NCAs would have guarantees that when they enforce the EU competition rules they act for the common good and they neither seek nor take instructions from any public or private body. This would give NCAs a shield to protect them from interference in their decision-making and allow them to act impartially on the basis on the facts and law. Trust in enforcement by NCAs would be enhanced. It would also mean that NCAs have a basic guarantee that they are not prevented from performing their tasks because of a complete lack of resources. This would best meet the views expressed by Member State ministries to date, who did not object to a basic hook, which does not prevent them from taking into account cyclical fluctuations.

7.2.5Nature of the instrument and legal basis

When taking EU legislative action, a choice has to be made between either a regulation or a directive. A regulation is directly applicable, and thus automatically deemed to be enshrined in Member State law, there is no need for implementing legislation. However, it leaves Member States very limited or no scope to adapt to their national specificities. A directive is only binding as to the result to be achieved, which gives Member States a choice as to the form/method to achieve this goal. Directives can set minimum standards which do not prevent Member States from having in place provisions which go further. It also allows for more uniform and detailed requirements to be put in place where appropriate.

The aim of the preferred policy option is to enhance effectiveness, while not imposing one size fits all so as to allow taking into account Member States’ legal traditions and institutional specificities. Accordingly, a regulation would not seem an appropriate instrument, but rather a directive would be the best way of ensuring that NCAs have the guarantees they need to be more effective enforcers, without unduly interfering in national specificities and traditions. A directive would also better reflect the expectations of stakeholders, 65% of whom in the public consultation said they prefer action to be taken at both EU and national level. In terms of the legal basis for a directive, Article 103 TFEU enables the EU to adopt legislation that gives effect to the EU competition rules. Article 114 TFEU allows for the adoption of legislation which supports the functioning of the internal market.

8Monitoring and evaluation

This section describes the monitoring and evaluation that could be applied to assess the impact of the preferred option, namely, a combination of EU legislative action in the form of a directive, complemented by soft action. The monitoring and evaluation is designed to cover the four specific objectives indicated in section 4.

As a first step, the Commission would try to refine and update the quantitative baseline at the moment when the new legislation has been adopted by the legislator.

As a second step, the monitoring would be focused on the implementation of the directive by the Member States in the run up to the date for transposition. The directive could require Member States to communicate to the Commission the preliminary text of the national provisions implementing the directive and any explanatory documents, thereby allowing the Commission to assess whether there has been adequate implementation. As a second step, the monitoring would be focused on both the transposition and the practical application by Member States and NCAs of the provisions of the legislative initiative, as well as the implementation of soft law measures, to see whether the four specific objectives have been achieved. The monitoring would also cover the impact of the initiative in monetary terms on NCAs.

The monitoring would be based mainly on indicators measuring the availability and application of the measures in the directive and, where possible, on quantitative/monetary indicators that could help to measure the impact of such measures and which can serve as basis for the evaluation. Annex XV provides an overview of the proposed indicators that could be used to assess whether each of the four specific objectives have been met. The sources of information for an assessment based on these indicators would range from fact-finding within the ECN to input received from stakeholders.

Complementary soft action would be developed within the current framework of the ECN, which has a successful track record for reaching consensus on such measures. This forum could also be used to discuss possible difficulties faced at national level in the implementation of the directive, learn from each other on potential solutions and exchange experience on the implementation of both the soft action and the legislative measures. The ECN framework would therefore be a key tool providing useful information to monitor the preferred option, which would complement the monitoring based on the core indicators.

During the first step of implementation of the Directive, monitoring would take the form of a report taking stock of the implementing measures adopted by each Member State. During the second step of application of the Directive, every two years there would be a monitoring of the values of the indicators and how they have evolved over time per Member State.

On the basis of the evidence gathered through the monitoring exercise, an evaluation would be carried out to assess the performance against each of the four objectives, as well as the possible existence of unintended/unexpected effects. While monitoring would be partly a continued process during the period of implementation of the directive, before carrying out a useful ex-post evaluation a reasonable period of time after its transposition would be needed to assess the impact of the changes in practice and whether the four objectives have been met. An ex-post evaluation would therefore be carried out after 5 years from the date of its transposition. This would also allow time for the complementary soft measures to be developed in the ECN and to be applied in practice.

The monitoring and evaluation process would provide useful information for any potential future modifications.

(1)  See the current priorities of the European Commission: https://ec.europa.eu/priorities/index_en.
(2)  Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty (OJ 2003, L 1, p.1).
(3)  EU citizens who have heard of a case being taken by a competition authority are more likely to think that it was their NCA who took the decision, see Flash Eurobarometer 403, "Citizens Perceptions about Competition Policy", March 2015.
(4)  The approach followed to benchmark the observable customer benefits from stopping a cartel (prevented harm) is broadly in line with the OECD Guide for assessing the impact of competition authorities' activities (April 2014), available at https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/Guide-competition-impact-assessmentEN.pdf. It consists of multiplying the assumed increased price brought about by the cartel (called the “overcharge”) by the value of the affected products or markets and then by the likely duration of the cartel had it remained undetected. A 10% to 15% overcharge is assumed. This is conservative when compared to the findings of empirical literature which report considerably higher median price overcharges for cartels. In order to estimate what the likely duration of the cartel would have been if it had continued undetected, a case-by-case analysis was carried out. This analysis focussed on the particular circumstances of each case and an assessment of key indicators, including the specific market conditions, the lifespan of the cartel, the ease of reaching and renewing cartel agreements as well as the potential reactions of outsiders (such as new entrants). The cartels are classified into three categories: "unsustainable", "fairly sustainable" "very sustainable". It is assumed that the cartels in the first category would have lasted one extra year in the absence of the Commission's intervention, the cartels in the second category 3 years, and the cartels in the third group 6 years. The assumptions concerning the likely duration of the cartels are made prudently to establish a lower limit rather than to estimate the most likely values. Finally, the estimates obtained are also conservative because other consumer benefits, such as innovation, quality and choice are not taken into account. The methodology followed by the Commission is not connected to the size of GDP but rather reflects the number of competition enforcement decisions taken per year. This explains the fluctuations in the Commission's yearly estimates. Similarly, the order of magnitude of customer benefits in a given year/period estimated by NCAs which carried out such an exercise is based on the number of competition enforcement decisions taken in that Member State.
(5)  Annual Activity Reports of the Directorate-General for Competition of the European Commission for the years 2010-2015.
(6)  See Dierx A., Heikkonen J., Ilkovitz F., Pataracchia B., Ratto M., Thum-Thysen A. and Varga J. (2015), "Distributional macroeconomic effects of EU competition policy – A general equilibrium analysis", paper to be published in a World Bank-OECD publication on Competition Policy, Shared Prosperity and Inclusive Growth. This paper tries to bridge the gap between the microeconomic estimates of the customer savings associated with important merger and cartel interventions and the longer term macroeconomic effects of these interventions. It also attempts to measure not only the direct effects of competition policy interventions but also their deterrent effects. Finally, it sheds some light on the distributional impact of competition policy. This objective is ambitious and the simulations are reliant on a chain of assumptions, going from the calculation of customer savings and the approximation of the deterrent effects to the specification and calibration of the general equilibrium model. However, these assumptions do not undermine the usefulness of the analysis in getting a better understanding of the role of competition policy in society.
(7)   https://www.acm.nl/en/publications/publication/14113/2014-ACM-Annual-Report/ . This assessment appears to rely on the amount of fines the authority imposed and/or collected as well as the remedies it imposed on certain merger plans in 2014 so it is expected to vary significantly from one year to the next.
(8)  See the Impact Assessment 2015/2016 of the UK Competition and Markets Authority, https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/537539/cma-impact-assessment-2015-16.pdf.
(9)  These estimates necessarily rely in part on assumptions. The UK competition authority explains that its impact estimations are conducted immediately after cases are completed and are therefore based only on information available during the case and on assumptions regarding the expected impact of its interventions. On this basis the estimates are considered to be "ex ante’ evaluations. The authority considers that in general, the assumptions it applies are cautious and hence the estimates are conservative. For example, it excludes impacts from a number of cases where consumer benefits were difficult to quantity in a sufficiently robust manner. Further, its estimates exclude its compliance work, international activities, and advocacy to government for policies that support competition because the benefits of these are difficult to quantify due to the nature of the work.
(10)  See https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/539987/cma-annual-report-and-accounts-2015-16-web-accessible-version.pdf . The authority undertakes these assessments itself, with subsequent review by external academics. Its methodology is based on that developed by the predecessor to the current UK competition authority (the Office of Fair trading), validated by successive independent academic reviewers. The current authority, the Competition and Markets Authority, considers that this is consistent with approaches now regarded by the OECD as international good practice.
(11)  European Parliament resolution of 19 January 2016 on the Annual report on EU Competition Policy (2015/2140(INI)), introduction, letter G. See further Mariniello, M. (2013) "Do European Union Fines Deter Price Fixing", breugelpolicybrief, Issue 2013/04.
(12)  Ormosi, P. L. (2014) "A tip of the iceberg? The probability of catching cartels", Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 29(4) 549.
(13)  A 15% probability of detection appears to correspond to the average of estimations by several researchers and is used by most authors in the relevant literature (see Combe, E and C Monnier (2009), “Fines against hard core cartels in Europe: the myth of over enforcement”, Cahiers de Recherche PRISM-Sorbonne Working Paper.
(14)  See Mariniello, M. (2013) "Do European Union Fines Deter Price Fixing", breugelpolicybrief, Issue 2013/04.
(15)  See Connor, J. M. & Bolotova, Y. (2006) "Cartel overcharges: survey and meta-analysis", International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 24(6), 1109-1137 and Smuda F. (2014), "Cartel Overcharges and the deterrent effect of EU competition law", Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 10(1), pp. 63-86.
(16)  London Economics (2011), "The impact of competition interventions on compliance and deterrence", OFT Report No. 1391, December, and SEO (2011), "Anticipating cartel and merger control", SEO-report.
(17)  See Dierx A., Heikkonen J., Ilkovitz F., Pataracchia B., Ratto M., Thum-Thysen A. and Varga J. (2015), "Distributional macroeconomic effects of EU competition policy – A general equilibrium analysis", paper to be published in a World Bank-OECD publication on Competition Policy, Shared Prosperity and Inclusive Growth.
(18)  See https://www.cnmc.es/Portals/0/Ficheros/download/cnmc_competition.pdf , p. 22.
(19)  Flash Eurobarometer 403, "Citizens Perceptions about Competition Policy", March 2015.
(20)  EU citizens have also experienced competition problems in the telecommunications and internet sector (18%), food distribution (14%) and financial services (12%).
(21) Consumer Market Scoreboards available at: http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/consumer_evidence/consumer_scoreboards/index_en.htm .
(22)  See the Digital Economy and Society Index (DESI) and in particular the connectivity dimension: https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/fixed-bb-price-desi-indicator-1d1.
(23)  See the Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, 2014 European Semester: Country-specific recommendations-building growth, COM(2014) 400 final, which states: "An efficient competition framework is a key aspect for the functioning of markets in goods and services. Progress has been mixed in this area".
(24)  In April 2015, the Commission sent a statement of objections to Gazprom over concerns that the latter is breaking EU antitrust rules by pursuing an overall strategy to partition Central and Eastern European gas markets (see press release in Case 39816 at http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-15-4828_en.htm). In December 2015, the Commission accepted commitments by Bulgarian Energy Holding to open up the Bulgarian wholesale electricity market (see press release in Case 39767 at http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-15-6289_en.htm ).
(25)  For example, following a complaint filed by Direct Energie, the French NCA adopted interim measures ordering the French incumbent gas operator GDF Suez to provide access to information contained in its database with respect to customers under the regulated gas tariffs which was considered to be essential for the successful entry of new operators and to allow them to make competitive non-regulated offers and therefore for the development of the energy market (Decision of the French NCA 14-MC-02 of 9 September 2014). In the UK, the UK NCA has been carrying out a detailed investigation of the supply and acquisition of energy in the British market (see final report of 24 June 2016 available at https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/5773de34e5274a0da3000113/final-report-energy-market-investigation.pdf ) and is now in the phase of implementing the remedies.
(26)  See the speech of Commissioner Vestager of 10 June 2016 in which she stated that all competition authorities in Europe have to play their part to make energy markets competitive: http://ec.europa.eu/commission/2014-2019/vestager/announcements/making-energy-markets-work-consumers_en.
(27)  OECD, 2014, Fact-sheet on how competition policy affects macro-economic outcomes.
(28)  For example, Taylor, J. E. (2002) "The output effects of government sponsored cartels during the New Deal", the Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(1), 1-10 and (2007).
(29)  Taylor, J. E. (2007) "Cartel Code Attributes and Cartel Performance: An Industry-Level Analysis of the National Industry Recovery Act", Journal of Law and Economics, 50(3), 597-624.
(30)  For all references to the public consultation, further information is provided in Annex II.
(31)  The European Court of Justice has ruled that procedural rules at national level should not jeopardize the attainment of the objective of Regulation 1/2003, which is to ensure that Articles 101 and 102 TFEU are applied effectively by the NCAs, Case C-439/08 Vebic ECLI:EU:C:2010:739.
(32)  European Parliament resolution of 19 January 2016 on the Annual report on EU Competition Policy (2015/2140(INI)), introduction, letter E.
(33)  See for example, Borrel, J-R and Jiménez, J. L., (2008) "The Drivers of Antitrust Effectiveness", Instituto de Estudios Fiscales.
(34)  Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G., Vitale, C., (2013) "Competition Policy and Productivity Growth: An Empirical Assessment, Review of Economics and Statistics", 95(4), 1324-1336. The study assessed 12 OECD countries, nine of which are EU Member States.Indicators developed in OECD Working Papers which measure the strength of competition law and policy include powers to investigate, powers to sanction and remedy and the independence of the institutions enforcing competition law, Alemani, E., Klein, C., Koske, I. Vitale, C. and Wanner, I. (2013). "New Indicators of Competition Law and Policy in 2013 for OECD and non-OECD countries", OECD Economics Department Working Paper no. 1104 See also Hoj, J. (2007) "Competition law and policy indicators for the OECD countries", OECD Economics Department Working Paper no 568.
(35)  Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, Ten Years of Antitrust Enforcement under Regulation 1/2003: Achievements and Future Perspectives, COM(2014) 453 and the accompanying Staff Working Documents: Ten Years of Antitrust Enforcement under Regulation 1/2003, SWD(2014)230 and Enhancing Competition by the Member States’ competition authorities: institutional and procedural issues, SWD(2014) 231, http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/regulations.html.
(36)  Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, Report on the functioning of Regulation 1/2003 COM(2009) final and the accompanying Staff Working Paper SEC(2009) 574 final, http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/regulations.html.
(37)  See, e.g. the Guidance of the International Competition Network on Investigative Process: http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/uploads/library/doc1028.pdf , and the Antitrust Enforcement Manual of the International Competition Network: http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/working-groups/current/cartel/manual.aspx.
(38)  In November 2012, the ECN made a detailed inventory of the investigation and decision-making procedures for competition enforcement which exist in the Member States: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/documents.html . The Reports provided a clear overview of the status quo for the first time. Further fact-finding was carried out in the ECN by way of follow-up to the 2014 Communication. Annex XVI illustrates that for a sample of 5 competition tools, 25 NCAs are lacking at least one of these powers.
(39)  The ECN Recommendation on Investigative Powers, Enforcement Measures and Sanctions in the context of Inspections and Requests for Information (available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/recommendation_powers_to_investigate_enforcement_measures_sanctions_09122013_en.pdf) recommends that all authorities have effective powers to inspect non-business premises.
(40)  For example, in a cartel among 15 commercial banks in Portugal, using forensic IT techniques was the only possible way to find evidence for the Portuguese NCA. Similarly an increasing number of Commission decisions rely on information which was exclusively exchanged by digital means.
(41)  The ECN Recommendation on the Power to impose Structural Remedies (available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/structural_remedies_09122013_en.pdf ) provides that is desirable that all authorities have the choice and the power to impose both behavioural and/or structural remedies.
(42)  The ECN Recommendation on Commitment Procedures ( http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/ecn_recommendation_commitments_09122013_en.pdf ) recommends that all authorities can impose effective fines for non-compliance with a commitment decision and have effective means to compel compliance, e.g. the imposition of periodic penalty payments set at an appropriate level.
(43)  The ECN Recommendation on the Power to set Priorities (available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/recommendation_priority_09122013_en.pdf) advocates for authorities to have greater flexibility to choose which cases to investigate. 8 NCAs are obliged to investigate cases which are not a priority and 15 NCAs cannot reject complaints which are not a priority without doing a detailed investigation on substance.
(44)  For the purpose of this impact assessment, references to fines imposed by NCAs is shorthand for fines imposed by the authorities designated by the Member States for the enforcement of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, whether of an administrative or a judicial nature.
(45)  Judgment in Inspecteur van de Belastingdienst v X BV, C-429/07, EU:C:2009:359, paragraphs 36-39. The case concerned the question whether fines imposed by the Commission can be wholly or partially deductible from Dutch taxes. The ECJ ruled that the effectiveness of the Commission’s decision by which it imposed a fine on a company might be significantly reduced if the fine could be deducted from tax. The Court stated: "To dissociate the principle of prohibition of anticompetitive practices from the penalties provided for … would therefore deprive of any effectiveness the action taken by the authorities responsible for monitoring compliance with that prohibition and punishing such practices. Thus, the provisions of Articles 81 EC and 82 EC [now Articles 101 and 102 TFEU] would be ineffective if they were not accompanied by enforcement measures provided for in Article 83(2)(a) EC [now Article 103(2)(a)]" (Article 103(2)(a) provides for the imposition of fines and penalty payments to ensure compliance with the EU competition rules).
(46)  No issues have arisen demonstrating that there would be a need to have a minimum level of fine that can be set. In some cases, e.g. in areas where the legal situation was unclear, competition authorities need to have the ability to impose symbolic fines, which would be prevented by having a minimum level of fine.
(47)  While many NCAs apply a percentage of 10%, in other Member States the percentages applied are lower (up to 5%) for less serious infringements. Similarly, in one Member State, a cap of 5% is imposed on the turnover of the direct infringer only for vertical anti-competitive practices between companies operating at different levels of the supply chain i.e. agreements between a manufacturer and its distributor and abuses of dominant position contrary to Article 102. In another Member State, the cap is generally set at 10% for competition infringements, but for the specific case of cartels, the cap is 10% for each year of infringement up to a maximum of 4 years: this means that the maximum can reach 40% for cartels lasting 4 or more years. Moreover, these amounts can be doubled for cartels in cases of recidivism (that is, if a company has already been found to have breached competition law), with the result that the legal maximum could potentially reach 80% of worldwide turnover.
(48)  Case C-97/08 P AkzoNobel NV v Commission [2009] ECR I-8237. It has to be shown that the parent company exercises decisive influence over the subsidiary that committed the infringement.
(49)  In 1 Member State it is not possible to fine associations of undertakings and in 9 Member States the fine can only be based on the turnover of the association, and not the turnover of its Members.
(50)  For the purpose of this impact assessment, the term “civil fines” is shorthand for fines imposed by a court in civil proceedings.
(51) The Irish NCA stated in the public consultation that criminal sanctions are neither appropriate nor practicable in relation to non-hard core competition law infringements (for which it considers civil procedures would be more suitable) and that it does not in practice pursue criminal prosecutions in such cases. Estonia also confirmed in its reply to the public consultation that the fact of having a criminal (misdemeanour) system makes competition enforcement more complicated.
(52)  There are other Member States that have reported a low number of cases, but these are small countries whose NCAs had insufficient resources.
(53) Regarding criminal fines, 56% of the respondents consider that it is a problem that some NCAs impose only/primarily criminal fines vs. 9% that disagree with this conclusion. Regarding civil fines, the percentage of respondents considering that it is a problem that some NCAs impose only/primarily civil fines decreases to 45%, vs. 21% that disagree with this conclusion. In both cases, the support to the conclusion that there is a problem tends to be higher amongst companies/SMEs and consultancy/law firms, and lower amongst public authorities and industry associations.
(54)  DAF/COMP(2015)1/FINAL.
(55) Issues Paper on Regulatory and Corporate Offences: www.lawreform.ie.
(56)  Government committee of inquiry on enhanced decision-making in the Swedish Competition Authority, ("En utökad beslutanderätt för Konkurrensverket, Betänkande av Utredningen om en utökad beslutanderätt för Konkurrensverket", June 2016) which concluded that moving to an administrative system would make the Swedish competition enforcement system more effective through fast high-quality decisions of the NCA, greater certainty for potential leniency applicants and better cooperation by the Swedish NCA in the ECN.
(57)  The Swedish NCA issued a report in December 2013 advocating for a change from its civil system to an administrative system (Konkurrensen i Sverige 2013, Rapport 2013:10).
(58)  A study has shown that the introduction of the leniency programme in the US resulted in a 40% reduction in the number of detected cartels: Miller, N. H. (2009) "Strategic Leniency and Cartel Enforcement, American Economic Review", Vol. 99(3) 750. The number of cartel discoveries increases around the date of the introduction of the leniency programme and then falls below pre-leniency programme levels, consistent with enhanced cartel detection and deterrence.
(59)  Rather than having to file complete leniency applications with all NCAs with (potential) jurisdiction to take actions against the cartel, a summary application system allows companies to file a leniency application to these NCAs on the basis of more limited information where a full application has been given to the Commission.
(60)  In the judgment in DHL Express (Italy) S.r.l. and Others v Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato and Others, Case C-428/14, EU:C:2016:27, the Court held that soft instruments adopted in the context of the ECN are not binding. As a result, Member States are not required to incorporate provisions of the ECN Model Leniency Programme in their leniency systems and, they are not precluded from adopting rules not present in that model programme or which diverge from it.
(61)   http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/documents.html . The Model Leniency Programme was revised in 2012.
(62)  A formal settlement is a simplified procedure which results in the faster handling of the case and in a reduction of the fines. In order to benefit from this procedure, the companies involved have to acknowledge their participation in the infringement.
(63)  In 2013, the OECD presented its new competition law and policy indicators which measure the strength and scope of competition regimes. Independence of competition authorities is one of the indicators as there is broad consensus among OECD countries that it constitutes good practice for competition regimes. See E. Alemani and others, "New Indicators of Competition Law and Policy in 2013 for OECD and non-OECD Countries" (2013) OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1104, OECD Publishing. In an OECD survey on competition policy, “greater independence” was the factor most frequently identified as likely to lead to better promotion of competition law’s objectives. OECD, Global Forum on Competition, "The Objectives of Competition Law and Policy: Note by the Secretariat" (2003) Session 1, Doc. No. CCNM/GF/COMP(2003)3, 8.
(64)  See UNCTAD, "Independence and accountability of competition authorities" (2008), Note by the UNCTAD secretariat referring to other international organizations including the World Trade Organization, World Bank, International Monetary Fund and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
(65)  A. Mateus, "Why should national competition authorities be independent and how should they be accountable?" (2007) 3(1) European Competition Journal 17; and G. Monti, "Independence, Interdependence and Legitimacy: The EU Commission, National Competition Authorities, and the European Competition Network" (2014) EUI Working Paper No. 2014/1, 4-5.
(66)  The European Court of Justice has also recognised the link between guaranteeing the independence of national supervisory authorities and ensuring the effectiveness of such supervision. See judgment in Commission v Germany, C-518/07, EU:C:2010:125, para 25.
(67)  Ibid., para 18.
(68)  European Parliament Resolution of 11 December 2013 on the Annual Report on EU Competition Policy (2013/2075 (INI)); European Parliament resolution of 10 March 2015 on the Annual Report on EU Competition Policy (2014/2158 (INI)); European Parliament resolution of 16 January 2016 on the Annual Report on EU Competition Policy (2015/2140 (INI)).
(69)  Austria, Latvia, Luxemburg, Malta and Slovenia, see http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/index_en.htm .
(70)  96 respondents supported the importance of this measure, which was considered as the first most important measure by 50%, the second by 28%, and the third for the remaining 22%. This support was particularly strong amongst consumer and non-governmental organisations, and public authorities (both NCAs and particularly ministries), while it was somehow lower amongst companies/SMEs, industry associations and consultancy/law firms.
(71)  GDP is used as a proxy for the size of markets.
(72)  For example, on 12 May 2016, the Latvian Parliament adopted amendments to the Competition Law which among others enable the NCA to impose penalties on undertakings which do not provide information requested by it or provide false or misleading information.
(73)  In 2009, a Report was made assessing the level of convergence with the ECN MLP. Similarly, ECN Reports of 2012 provided an EU-wide overview of the different procedures for enforcing the EU competition rules. The reports are available at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/documents.html .
(74)  See Country Specific Recommendations addressed to Austria (2013 – 2015) and Slovenia (2012 – 2014), http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/index_en.htm .
(75)  Commission Guidelines on the effect on trade concept contained in Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, OJ 2004, C 101, p.81, para. 50.
(76)  Commission Notice on Agreements of Minor Importance, OJ 2014, C 291, p.1.
(77)  The ECN endorsed Recommendations on (1) Investigative Powers, Enforcement Measures and Sanctions in the context of Inspections and Requests for Information; (2) The Power to collect Digital Evidence, including by Forensic Means; (3) Assistance in Inspections conducted under Article 22(1) of Regulation 1/2003; (4) The Power to set Priorities; (5) The Power to grant Interim Measures; (6) Commitment Procedures and (7) The Power to Impose Structural Remedies. The Recommendations are available at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/documents.html.
(78)  http://www.autoritedelaconcurrence.fr/doc/eca_principles_uk.pdf.
(79)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/ncas.pdf.
(80)  Article 6(6) of the Directive 2014/104/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 November 2014 on certain rules governing actions for damages under national law for infringements of the competition law provisions of the Member States and of the European Union, OJ 2014, L 349, p.1.
(81)  Where NCAs have other competences, such as consumer protection or regulatory functions, Member States have to ensure that sufficient budget and staff be assigned to competition enforcement.
(82)  See Commission's "White paper on modernisation of the rules implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty" and the explanatory memorandum of the proposal for the Regulation implementing Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty (OJ C 365 E, 19/12/2000 P.0284-0296).
(83)  A formal settlement is a simplified procedure which results in the faster handling of the case and in a reduction of the fines. In order to benefit from this procedure, the companies involved have to acknowledge their participation in the infringement.
(84)  Instead of civil fines, the Government proposed legislation in September 2011 to double jail terms for cartel offences from five to ten years., see "Boom, Bust and Bailout: A Tale of Modern Irish Competition Law" by Philip Andrews, available at http://kluwercompetitionlawblog.com/2012/07/12/boom-bust-and-bailout-a-tale-of-modern-irish-competition-law/.
(85)  Judgment in DHL Express (Italy) S.r.l. and Others v Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato and Others, C-428/14, EU:C:2016:27.
(86)  See DHL Express (Italy) S.r.l. and Others v Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato and Others, Case C-428/14, EU:C:2016:27.
(87)  The results were in general similar also per type of stakeholder, with smaller support coming normally only from non-governmental organisations and industry associations. However, even for these two groups of stakeholders, the most frequent alternative replies were that the effects would be neutral or that they had no opinion, (very) negative effects being supported generally by less than 7%.
(88)  The best evidence for the effectiveness of competition law enforcement tends to be that based at the level of the enforcement itself. Competition authorities and academics have published a large number of ex-post studies of the results of enforcement actions, which were surveyed by the OECD in 2013: "Evaluation of competition enforcement and advocacy activities: The results of an OECD survey".There are also meta-studies which have sought to measure the effectiveness of competition enforcement across a large number of cases. For example, Dutz, M. & Vagliasindi, M. (2000), "Rules versus implementation: determinants of competition policy effectiveness in transition countries", EBRD, London used data on a number of transition economies to show that better implementation of competition law leads to better competition. In a previous study Dutz and Hayri had also found a positive link between measures of competition law effectiveness and GDP growth (Dutz M. & Hayri, A. (1999). "Does More Intense Competition Lead to Higher Growth?", Policy Research Working Paper No.2320. World Bank).
(89)  Keith N. Hylton and Fei Deng, (2007) Antitrust Around the World: An Empirical Analysis of the Scope of Competition Laws and Their Effects.
(90)  Arnold, J. M., Nicoletti, G., & Scarpetta, S. (2011) Regulation, Resource Reallocation and Productivity Growth. European Investment Bank Papers,16(1), 90-115; OECD’s project of 2013 on Supporting Investment in Knowledge Capital, Growth and Innovation.
(91)  A number of surveys suggest that the deterrent effect of antitrust enforcement may be substantial. See Baarsma B., Kemp R., van der Nol, R., and Seldeslachts J. (2012), " Let's not stick together: anticipation of cartel and merger control in the Netherlands ", De Economist, which estimated on the basis of a survey of lawyers and other advisors that for every sanction decision taken by the Dutch competition authority there are almost 5 other cases in which a prohibited act has been terminated or modified in response to advice on competition law. A study commissioned by the former UK competition authority, the Office of Fair Trading (OFT): London Economics (2011), "The impact of competition interventions on compliance and deterrence", OFT Report no 1391, found, based on a survey of more than 800 companies and a small number of law firms, that for each abuse of dominance case, 12 potential infringements are deterred. For cartels 28 potential agreements were deterred and for commercial agreements (anti-competitive agreements between companies which are not cartels), the ratio was 1:40.
(92)  See Nickell, S. (1996) "Competition and Corporate Performance", Journal of Political Economy 104(4), 724-746 which found that the most competitive firms experienced productivity growth rates 3.8-4.6% higher than the least competitive. See also Disney, R., Haskel, J., & Heden, Y. (2003). "Restructuring and productivity growth in UK manufacturing". The Economic Journal, 113(489), 666-694; Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & van Reenen, J. (1999). "Market Share, Market Value and Innovation in a Panel of British Manufacturing Firms. Review of Economic Studies", 66(3), 529-54; Januszewski, S. I., Köke, J. & Winter, J. K. (2002). "Product market competition, corporate governance and firm performance: an empirical analysis for Germany". Research in Economics, 56(3), 299-332. 
(93)  See OECD, 2014, Fact-sheet on how competition policy affects macro-economic outcomes.
(94)  See Ahn, S. (2002). "Competition, Innovation and Productivity Growth: A Review of Theory and Evidence". OECD Economics Working Paper No. 317. A study carried out by Petit L., Kemp R. and van Sinderen J. (2015) "Cartels and productivity growth: an empirical investigation of the impact of cartels on productivity in the Netherlands", assessed the impact of cartels on total factor productivity (TFP). TFP is a measure of the output of a company, sector or total economy that cannot be explained by the amount of inputs used in production and whose level is determined by how efficiently and intensely the inputs are utilized and is an indicator of competitiveness. The results showed that the entry and presence of a cartel had a negative impact on TFP and it was estimated that cartels had a negative impact on TFP of between 2% to 3% during the period covered.
(95)  Bucirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G. & Vitale, C. (2011) "Measuring the deterrence properties of competition policy: the competition policy indices" Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7(1), 165-204.
(96)  Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G., Vitale, C., (2013) "Competition Policy and Productivity Growth: An Empirical Assessment", Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1324-1336. Similarly, Dutz, M. & Hayri, A. (1999), "Does more intense competition lead to higher growth?" Policy Research Working Paper No. 2320, World Bank, found a strong correlation between long-run GDP growth, and effective enforcement of competition rules, on the basis of a cross-section of 52 countries.
(97)  The figure is illustrative to make concrete the effects of the elasticity between total factor productivity growth and the aggregate Competition Law and Policy Index the authors of the study constructed.
(98)  To put it simply, if an economy is able to produce more with the same amount of inputs, its TFP increases. To illustrate the importance of TFP, an annual growth of TFP of 1% would mean that an economy using the same amount of input resources would increase its production with around 10.5% over ten years. If the growth of TFP is only 0.5% the increase in production would only be 5.1% higher.
(99)  The authors recognise that there is scope for further refinements, such as expanding the study to more countries, to a longer period, and that the CPI could also be improved if more detailed information would be available (such as the sanctions actually imposed). On the other hand, econometric tools have been used to support the conclusion that the link between competition policy and TFP growth is of a causal nature, and the findings prove to be robust to several checks such as the use of various measures of productivity, different aggregation techniques of the CPI and the use of several subsamples. (see Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G., Vitale, C., (2013) "Competition Policy and Productivity Growth: An Empirical Assessment", Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1334-1335.
(100) 0.004976 x 0.09 = 0.0004478 ~0.0448%.
(101)

     See Clougherty, J. A. (2010), "Competition Policy Trends and Economic Growth: Cross-National Empirical Evidence", International Journal of the Economics of Business, 17(1), 111-127. The study found that increasing competition policy funding by about €60 million would result in economic growth of 0.84%.

(102) For example, this work relies, amongst other, on estimates regarding customer savings from important 2012 merger and cartel decisions by the European Commission, on estimates regarding the reduction in prices resulting from competition policy enforcement decisions in the market concerned and also on estimates regarding the duration of the price reduction.
(103)  See Dierx A., Heikkonen J., Ilzkovitz F., Pataracchia B., Ratto M., Thum-Thysen A. and Varga J. (2015), "Distributional macroeconomic effects of EU competition policy – A general equilibrium analysis", paper to be published in a World Bank-OECD publication on Competition Policy, Shared Prosperity and Inclusive Growth.
(104)  Barone and Cingano demonstrate that productivity growth in manufacturing is harmed by regulations that reduce competition in services (especially financial services and energy provision). (Barone, G., & Cingano, F. (2008). "Service Regulation and Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries", Bank of Italy Temi di Discussione (Working Paper) No, 675).Studies carried out by Bourlès, R., Cette, G., Lopez, J., Mairesse, J., & Nicoletti, G. (2013). "Do product market regulations in upstream sectors curb productivity growth? Panel data evidence for OECD countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(5), 1750-1768", and Forlani, E. (2010). "Competition in the Service Sector and the Performances of Manufacturing Firms: Does Liberalization Matter? CESifo Working Paper No. 2942", reaches similar results.
(105)  Gutmann, J., & Voigt, S. (2014). "Lending a Hand to the Invisible Hand? Assessing the Effects of Newly Enacted Competition Laws", (February 8, 2014).
(106)  Borrell, J. R., & Tolosa, M. (2008). "Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity". Applied Economics Letters, 15(11), 827-831. The authors found that the impact of antitrust enforcement on total factor productivity is positive and statistically significant, implying that competition policy effectiveness raises productivity. The estimates suggest that increasing the average antitrust effectiveness in one standard deviation would increase average total factor productivity by 28%. The study assesses the combined effect of both competition and trade policy, as examining competition law alone over-states its effect on productivity growth.
(107)  Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2005). "Competition and Innovation: an Inverted-U Relationship". The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701-728. Other studies showing the relationship between competition and innovation are Polder, M. and Veldhuizen, E. (2010), Grünewald, O. (2009) or Carlin, W., Schaffer, M., & Seabright, P. (2004). On empirical work, see Aghion, Philippe, Stefan Bechtold, Lea Cassar and Holger Herz (2014), "The causal effects of competition on innovation: Experimental evidence", Harvard University Working Paper, February.
(108)  Ahn, S. (2002), "Competition, Innovation and Productivity Growth: A Review of Theory and Evidence". OECD Economics Working Paper No. 317, Gilbert, Richard J. (2007), "Competition and innovation", Competition Policy Centre, UC Berkeley.
(109)  Ahn, S. (2002), op. cit. See also for example, a study by the Directorate-General for Competition of the European Commission on "The Economic Impact of enforcement of competition policies in the functioning of EU energy markets" (2015), which found that the Commission's decision finding an abuse of dominance by E.ON lead to a reduction in prices for both wholesalers and retailers to the benefit of consumers. See also the Note by the UNCTAD Secretariat (2014) "The benefits of competition policy for consumers".
(110)  See Connor, J. M. & Bolotova, Y. (2006) "Cartel overcharges: survey and meta-analysis", International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 24(6), 1109-1137, Oxera and a multi-jurisdictional team of lawyers led by Dr Assimakis Komninos (2009) "Quantifying antitrust damages", (Study prepared for the European Commission) available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/actionsdamages/quantification_study.pdf , p. ix, and Smuda F. (2014), "Cartel Overcharges and the deterrent effect of EU competition law", Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 10(1), pp. 63-86. A study by Connor, J.M. (2014), "Price-fixing overcharges", found that the median average long-term overcharge for all types of cartels over all time periods is 23%.
(111)  Connor, J. M. & Bolotova, Y. (2006) "Cartel overcharges: survey and meta-analysis", International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 24(6), 1109-1137.
(112)   http://ec.europa.eu/atwork/synthesis/amp/doc/comp_sp_2016-2020_en.pdf .
(113)  See the Impact Assessment2015/2016 of the UK Competition and Markets Authority (https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/537539/cma-impact-assessment-2015-16.pdf) , which estimated the benefits of the Competition and Markets Authority’s work averaged over a 3-year period and the ratio of these benefits to costs. The above estimates do not include many other benefits stemming from competition law enforcement, such as better product quality and wider choice, the deterrent effect of the enforcement actions, or other effects of competition policy such as productivity gains or impact on jobs.
(114)  The UK competition authority explains that its impact estimations are conducted immediately after cases are completed and are therefore based only on information available during the case and on assumptions regarding the expected impact of its interventions. On this basis the estimates are considered to be "ex ante’ evaluations. The authority considers that in general, the assumptions it applies are cautious and hence the estimates are conservative.
(115)  "Does competition kill or create jobs?", OECD Global Forum on Competition, DAF/COMP/GF(2015)9.
(116)  See also Dierx A., Heikkonen J., Ilzkovitz F., Pataracchia B., Ratto M., Thum-Thysen A. and Varga J. (2015), "Distributional macroeconomic effects of EU competition policy – A general equilibrium analysis", paper to be published in a World Bank-OECD publication on Competition Policy, Shared Prosperity and Inclusive Growth, who estimate that enforcement of the EU competition rules by the European Commission has a sizeable impact on the creation of new jobs (they estimate around 650 000 after ten years).
(117)  "Does competition kill or create jobs?", OECD Global Forum on Competition, DAF/COMP/GF(2015)9, paragraph 78.
(118)  See Dierx A., Heikkonen J., Ilkovitz F., Pataracchia B., Ratto M., Thum-Thysen A. and Varga J. (2015), ibid, whose simulations show that competition policy has important redistributive effects. This supports the view that competition policy interventions, by lowering prices and increasing the quality and variety of products, are particularly beneficial for the poorest in the society.
(119)  Hausman, J. A., & Sidak, J. G. (2004). "Why Do the Poor and the Less-Educated Pay More for Long-Distance Calls?" Contributions in Economic Analysis & Policy, 3(1).
(120)  Urzúa, C. M. (2013), "Distributive and regional effects of monopoly power", Economia Mexicana NUEVA EPOCA, 22(2), 279-295.
(121)  "Market power and wealth distribution", John Davies and Sean Ennis, OECD, presentation at the conference on "Looking beyond the direct effects of the work of competition authorities: deterrence and macroeconomic impact", Directorate-General for Competition of the European Commission, Brussels, 17/18 September 2015.
(122)  For example, some NCAs cannot issue binding and enforceable requests for information to get the data they need.
(123)  See for example, Article 3 of Directive 2002/21 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on a common regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services, OJ 2002, L 108, p.33 as amended by Directive 2009/140 of the European and of the Council of 25 November 2009, OJ 2009, L 337, p.37; Article 35 of Directive 2009/72 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54, OJ 2009, L 211, p.55; and Article 55 of Directive 2012/34 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 establishing a single European railway area, OJ 2012, L 343, p.32. Recently, detailed independence safeguards have been enacted in the new General Data Protection Regulation, see Articles 51 - 54 of Regulation (EU) 2016/679 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 April 2016 on the protection of natural persons with regard to the processing of personal data and on the free movement of such data, and repealing Directive 95/46/EC, OJ 1995, L 281, p.31. The Commission also proposes to introduce a legal EU requirement of independence of audio-visual regulatory bodies, see Commission proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2010/13/EU on the coordination of certain provisions laid down by law, regulation or administrative action in Member States concerning the provision of audio-visual media services in view of changing market realities, COM(2016) 287 final.
(124)  8% of respondents (strongly) disagreed, 10% had a neutral opinion, and 2% indicated that they did not know/not applicable. Per group of stakeholders, the (strongly) disagree option was supported by higher percentages in the case of companies/SMEs (11%, but there was still more than 77% support) and industry associations (28%, but still 61% support).
(125)  At the level of the individual groups of stakeholders, a lower level of support come mainly from non-governmental organisations and industry associations, which nevertheless still gave a total support to EU legislative action (either alone or combined with soft action) of around 50%. Regarding the rest of the stakeholders, the support was in all cases above 70-75%, although with some differences regarding the preference between exclusively legislative action and legislative combined with soft action. For example, NCAs preferred exclusive EU legislative action (56%), with 40% favouring legislative combined with soft action), and Ministries preferred EU legislative action combined with soft action (50%) over exclusive EU legislative action (25%).
(126)  Case C-557/12, Kone AG v. ÖBB-Infrastruktur AG, EU:C:2014:1317, at para. 32.
(127)  Case C-439/08, Vlaamse federatie van verenigingen van Brood- en Banketbakkers, Ijsbereiders en Chocoladebewerkers (VEBIC) WZW, EU:C.2010:739, at paras 56 and 57.
(128)  As already indicated in section 6.3, these results were in general similar also per type of stakeholder, with lower levels of support coming normally only from non-governmental organisations and industry associations. However, even for these two groups of stakeholders, the most frequent alternative replies were that the effects would be neutral or that they had no-opinion, (very) negative effects being supported generally by less than 7%.
Top

Brussels, 22.3.2017

SWD(2017) 114 final

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

IMPACT ASSESSMENT

Annexes

Accompanying the document

Proposal for a

DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

to empower the competition authorities of the Member States to be more effective enforcers and to ensure the proper functioning of the internal market

List of Annexes

{COM(2017) 142 final}
{SWD(2017) 115 final}
{SWD(2017) 116 final}





List of Annexes

Annex I - Procedural information

Annex II - Stakeholder consultation

Annex III - Who is affected by the initiative and how

Annex IV - Problem tree

Annex V - Replies of stakeholders on the tools NCAs need to effectively enforce

Annex VI - Issues related to legal maximum, fines calculations and who can be fined

Annex VII - Results of hypothetical cartel case for a duration of 3.75 years

Annex VIII - Article in German press

Annex IX - Imposition of sanctions in civil and criminal procedures

Annex X - Policy options

Annex XI - Achievement of objectives

Annex XII - Number of leniency and summary leniency applications submitted before NCAs

Annex XIII – Divergences between leniency programmes

Annex XIV - Budget and staff of NCAs

Annex XV - Core indicators

Annex XVI – Costs/benefits analysis of the preferred option

Annex XVII – Glossary of terms



Annex I - Procedural information

1. Initiative key information

Leading DG: DG Competition

Agenda planning reference: 2017/COMP/001

Initiative title: Legislative proposal - Enhancing competition in the EU for the benefit of businesses and consumers – Reinforcement of the application of EU competition law by national competition authorities

Expected adoption of legislative proposal: 1st quarter 2017

2. Reports on the functioning of Council Regulation 1/2003

During 2013 and 2014 DG Competition conducted an assessment of the functioning of Council Regulation 1/2003.

As part of this new assessment, DG Competition examined a range of areas that either were not addressed by Regulation 1/2003, were addressed in a general way but a need for a detailed response has subsequently arisen in practice, or have emerged as new issues.

Based on the results of this assessment, the Commission adopted in July 2014 the "Communication from the Commission - Ten Years of Antitrust Enforcement under Regulation 1/2003: Achievements and Future Perspectives" 1 ("the Communication"). The Communication concluded that the enforcement of the EU competition rules had considerably increased as a result of the achievements of the Commission, the ECN and the national competition authorities (NCAs). The guidance provided by the Commission to stakeholders, NCAs and national courts and the cooperation within the ECN had favoured the coherent application of the EU competition rules throughout the EU and boosted the enforcement of EU competition rules. However, the Communication also concluded that it was important to build on these achievements to create a truly common competition enforcement area in the EU, in particular by:

- further guaranteeing the independence of NCAs in the exercise of their tasks and that they have sufficient resources;

- ensuring that NCAs have a complete set of effective investigative and decision making powers at their disposal;

- ensuring that powers to impose effective and proportionate fines are in place in all Member States;

- ensuring that well-designed leniency programmes are in place in all Member States and consider measures to avoid disincentives for corporate leniency applicants.

This exercise built on the previous "Report on the functioning of Regulation 1/2003" 2 of 2009 which had found that the new competition enforcement system had positively contributed to a stronger enforcement of the EU competition rules, but that some aspects merited further evaluation, in particular, with respect to making NCAs' enforcement tools and fining powers more effective.

3. Evidence used to support the Impact Assessment

By way of follow-up to the Communication, extensive fact-finding has been carried out by DG Competition in cooperation with NCAs on all the objectives identified by the Communication in order to have a detailed picture of the status quo.

In addition to the Communication on ten years of Regulation 1/2003 and the Report on five years of Regulation 1/2003, noted above, the fact-finding built on the following Reports:

- Investigative Powers Report (31 October 2012), which provides an overview of investigative procedures within the ECN. 3  

- Decision-Making Powers Report (31 October 2012), which provides an overview of decision-making powers within the ECN. 4  

- Report on the Assessment of the State of Convergence with the ECN Model Leniency Programme (15 October 2009). 5

- Several publications on the impact of competition, such as the OECD report "Fact-sheet on how competition policy affects macro-economic outcomes" (October 2014)

Fact-finding within the ECN

For the preparation of this Impact Assessment, DG Competition relied on fact-finding carried out by three ECN working groups: the Working Group on Cooperation Issues and Due Process, the Cartels Working Group and the ad-hoc Working Group on Fines and Related Issues. Detailed questionnaires have been sent on the different issues raised in the Communication.

Moreover, the fact-finding done at the level of the respective working groups was further discussed and reviewed at a higher level in the context of the ECN Plenary meetings, and finally at the highest level during the ECN Directors-General meetings, attended by the Heads of the NCAs and DG Competition.

On the basis of all the information gathered, the Commission has decided to carry out an Impact Assessment in order to define in more detail the scope of the identified problems and the objectives to be achieved and assess the different policy options to address them.

4. Organisation and timing

4.1. Inter-Service Steering Group

An Inter-Service Steering Group (ISSG) was set up in October 2015. In total four meetings have been held on the following dates: 22 October 2015, 19 May 2016, 23 June 2016 and 14 July 2016.

The following Directorates-General and services participated: BUDG, CNECT, ECFIN, ENER, ENV, FISMA, GROW, JUST, MARE, MOVE, OLAF, TRADE, LS and SG.

The feedback received from these Directorates-General and services has been taken into account in the draft Impact Assessment Report.

The ISSG approved the Inception Impact Assessment that was published in November 2015 and the draft Impact Assessment Report.

The minutes of the meeting held on 14 July 2016 were submitted to the Regulatory Scrutiny Board.

4.2. Consultation of the Regulatory Scrutiny Board

This draft Impact Assessment Report was submitted to the Regulatory Scrutiny Board on 31 August 2016 and a meeting took place on 28 September 2016.

The table below provides an overview on, and, where necessary, brief explanations about, the changes introduced in the revised draft Impact Assessment Report after the meeting on 28 September 2016 and the main recommendations for improvements of the Regulatory Scrutiny Board.

Main Recommendations for improvements

Overview of changes in the revised draft IA Report & explanations

(1) Demonstrate relevance of identified problems. The report should go beyond the general statement that more competition enforcement is better and present further evidence to demonstrate the untapped potential of more effective NCA enforcement of competition rules. It could achieve this by adding anecdotal evidence (i.e. examples of cases that NCAs were not able to deal with), comparing Member States' performances, or using other relevant facts drawn from the 10 years of cooperation between the Commission and Member States on enforcement.

Section 2 of the revised draft Impact Assessment report includes all relevant facts and anecdotal evidence available at the time of drafting to illustrate the four problem drivers. The main difficulty in determining the untapped potential of more effective enforcement of the competition rules lies in estimating undetected anti-competitive practices which necessarily companies try to keep secret.

(2) Clarify the policy options. The report should explain in more detail the proposed provisions to ensure Member States have the right investigative tools, deterrent fines, better leniency programs, more resources, and strong independence. The choice of parameters should be based on more evidence. On this basis, the report should clarify the differences between the preferred option 3 and option 4. The report also needs to reflect on a possible redistribution of work between the Commission and NCAs, or explain why this approach is discarded.

Sections 5.3 and 5.4 of the revised draft Impact Assessment report include more details on the envisaged options for each specific objective. Where available, references to evidence have been added or highlighted compared to the previous draft. Equally, the differences between option 3 and option 4 have been brought out and further explained in the revised draft. A new section 5.5 explains why a possible redistribution of work between the Commission and the NCAs has been discarded.

(3) Strengthen subsidiarity and proportionality aspects. The report should strengthen the analysis of the options against the subsidiarity and proportionality principles. In doing so, the report should better explain to which degree EU law could and should restrict Member States' choices as to their administrative/civil/judicial procedures. In terms of proportionality, possibly a "lighter" option "2.5" with more limited regulatory changes could be included.

Section 7 of the revised Impact Assessment report clarifies the analysis of the options against the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality as well as the degree to which the envisaged options could and should restrict the procedural choices of Member States.

Regarding the possibility of a "lighter" option "2.5" with more limited regulatory changes: as explained in the report, soft action is not considered effective because it has already been used extensively to address all four problem drivers, and, based on this experience, it is expected to lead only to at most very limited change without achieving the overall aim. The regulatory changes envisaged by the preferred option include only the minimum means and instruments necessary to ensure that NCAs are effective competition enforcers while carefully avoiding undue interference. Leaving out any of these means and instruments would risk failing to meet the overall aim of making NCAs more effective enforcers.

(4) Estimate costs and impacts. The report should give indications on the cost of implementing the new requirements for Member States. The impact analysis should more clearly establish how the additional instruments and resources would yield the expected benefits in individual Member States.

The new Annex XVI provides an analysis of the costs and benefits of the preferred option. The methodology, main arguments, and results presented in this Annex have been summarised in sections 6.3 and 6.4 of the revised draft Impact Assessment report.

The Regulatory Scrutiny Board issued a subsequent opinion on 9 December 2016, giving a positive opinion, with a recommendation to improve the following aspects:

Main Recommendations for improvements

Overview of changes in the revised draft IA Report & explanations

(1) Provide more evidence to support the argument that some NCAs do not have enough resources.

Section 2.2.4 of the revised draft Impact Assessment report includes additional explanations on the correlation between the level of resources and the level of enforcement of NCAs of comparable GDP.

(2) Disaggregate stakeholder's views according to stakeholder categories.

Annex II summarising the results of the public consultation now contains now a more detailed description of the stakeholder's views disaggregated according to stakeholder categories.

(3) Elaborate on the limitations and uncertainties of the quantitative estimates.

Sections 2.1 and 6.3 include additional explanations about the limitations and uncertainties of the quantitative estimates. Section 6.3 and Annex XVI also include additional explanations about how the competition policy indicators are built.

The Regulatory Scrutiny Board also recommended the addition of a glossary of acronyms, issues and expressions used. A glossary of terms has been added in Annex XVII.

Annex II - Stakeholder consultation

I.    Report on the Contributions to the Public Consultation on Empowering the national competition authorities to be more effective enforcers of the EU competition rules

Introduction

A public consultation 6 on empowering the national competition authorities to be more effective enforcers of the EU competition rules was launched on 4 November 2015 and ran until 12 February 2016.

The public consultation follows up the Commission's Communication on Ten Years of Regulation 1/2003 7 , which identified a number of areas of action to boost the powers of national competition authorities ("NCAs") to enforce the EU competition rules. The objective of the public consultation was to get feedback from a broad range of stakeholders on their experience/knowledge of issues that NCAs may face having an impact on their ability to effectively enforce the EU competition rules and what action, if any, should be taken in this regard.

The public consultation followed the Commission's minimum standards and has taken the form of an EU Survey which was split into two parts, a first one with general questions seeking input from non-specialised stakeholders, and a second one for stakeholders with a deeper knowledge/experience of competition matters. This second part addresses four key issues:

A.resources and independence of the national competition authorities;

B.enforcement toolbox of the national competition authorities;

C.powers of national competition authorities to fine undertakings; and

D.leniency programmes.

The public consultation page and the general questions were available in the following EU official languages: bg   cs   da   de   el   en   es   et   fi   fr   hr   hu   it   lt   lv   mt   nl   pl   pt   ro   sk   sl   sv   to encourage input by consumers and SMEs and to allow the public at large to contribute. The detailed sections of the open public consultation questionnaire were only available in English but answers could be provided in all EU official languages.

Validity of the public consultation: assessment of its weaknesses and strengths

The main weakness of the questionnaire, which has been raised by some stakeholders, is that it is rather long. This, together with the inherent complexity of the issues it tackles, might have dissuaded some stakeholders from replying. To address this issue, the questionnaire contains a shorter section with general questions aimed at all (including non-specialised) stakeholders.

Another weakness is that it was not possible to translate the entire questionnaire in all official languages. To encourage wide participation in the public consultation the introductory sections and the section with the general questions, which covered the essence of the main issues covered by the questionnaire, were translated into all official languages. Over 40 participants opted to exclusively use this option.

The public consultation had however several features that counterbalanced, at least partially, the weaknesses referred to above.

First, although the public consultation has been officially open for participation for about 12 weeks, in practice stakeholders could provide input for around 16 weeks. This has allowed stakeholders willing to participate ample time to do so.

Moreover, respondents had for almost every question the possibility to add additional comments clarifying or expanding their replies and to attach supporting documents. Replies in the form of a position paper as opposed to through the questionnaire were also accepted.

Finally, in order to promote participation as much as possible, we encouraged NCAs to bring the the public consultation to the attention of their respective national consumer and business associations. This was complemented by initiatives by the Commission to promote awareness of the public consultation by reaching out to organisations with a pan-European dimension such as the European consumer organisation BEUC and Business Europe, as well as through participating in conferences at national level.

Summary of the general questions

There have been 181 replies from a wide variety of stakeholders, ranging from private individuals, law firms and consultancies, companies and industry associations, consumer organisations, academics, non-governmental organisations, think tanks and trade unions to public authorities, including a number of Ministries and NCAs, from within and outside the EU. This is a very good response rate for a public consultation in the competition field.

The results show that for the majority of respondents NCAs are effectively enforcing EU competition rules. There is however a 31% of respondents that considers that this is not the case.

Are EU competition rules effectively enforced by NCAs?

However, a wide majority of respondents consider that NCAs could do more to enforce EU competition rules than they currently do:

Could NCAs do more to enforce EU competition rules?

Respondents also consider that the following measures would help NCAs to be more effective:

Degree of support for measures to help NCAs to be more effective enforcers. Number of replies =165 8

Having guarantees that they enforce the EU competition rules in the general interest of the EU and do not take instructions when doing so

Strongly Agree

Agree

Neutral

Disagree

Strongly disagree

No opinion

Consumer associations

29%

71%

Non-governmental organisations

14%

29%

29%

14%

14%

Public Authority

70%

24%

6%

Business

26%

50%

6%

18%

Industry Association

26%

53%

11%

5%

5%

Consultancy/Law firm

23%

46%

31%

Other

33%

56%

11%

Having sufficient resources to perform their tasks

Strongly Agree

Agree

Neutral

Disagree

Strongly disagree

No opinion

Consumer associations

43%

57%

Non-governmental organisations

14%

57%

14%

14%

Public Authority

77%

17%

6%

Business

44%

35%

6%

6%

3%

6%

Industry Association

37%

42%

5%

16%

Consultancy/Law firm

77%

15%

8%

Other

44%

56%

Having effective enforcement tools to detect and investigate infringements

Strongly Agree

Agree

Neutral

Disagree

Strongly disagree

No opinion

Consumer associations

71%

29%

Non-governmental organisations

14%

71%

14%

Public Authority

68%

32%

Business

23%

51%

9%

17%

Industry Association

32%

37%

16%

11%

5%

Consultancy/Law firm

31%

46%

15%

8%

Other

33%

33%

33%

Having effective powers to fine companies for breach of competition law

Strongly Agree

Agree

Neutral

Disagree

Strongly disagree

No opinion

Consumer associations

86%

14%

Non-governmental organisations

14%

71%

14%

Public Authority

76%

24%

Business

34%

43%

9%

6%

3%

6%

Industry Association

37%

37%

11%

11%

5%

Consultancy/Law firm

31%

23%

38%

8%

Other

33%

33%

22%

11%

Having effective leniency programmes to encourage companies to come clean about infringements

Strongly Agree

Agree

Neutral

Disagree

Strongly disagree

No opinion

Consumer associations

71%

29%

Non-governmental organisations

14%

71%

14%

Public Authority

68%

32%

Business

23%

51%

9%

17%

Industry Association

32%

37%

16%

11%

5%

Consultancy/Law firm

31%

46%

15%

8%

Other

44%

56%

Other issues raised by stakeholders

A majority of stakeholders (59%) also consider that other actions should be taken to boost the effectiveness of the NCAs. There is in particular a consistent demand from lawyers, business and business organisations that any enhancement of NCAs' enforcement powers is counter-balanced by increased procedural guarantees, including ensuring that rights of defence can be effectively exercised by having greater transparency of investigations and effective judicial review (e.g. companies should receive a Statement of Objections and have effective rights of access to file).

Other issues raised are the request of greater coherency within the ECN in the application of the EU competition rules, the recognition of Legal Professional Privilege (LPP) for in-house lawyers and of compliance programmes as a mitigating factor for fines, that NCAs should be able to defend their cases in court, a more consistent application of the effect on trade criterion or the abolition of the power of NCAs to apply stricter rules on unilateral conduct.

The questionnaire has also sought views from stakeholders on whether action to boost enforcement by NCAS should be taken and, if so, who should take action. The graphs below show the results which indicate that a wide majority of stakeholders supports that action should be taken and that such action should preferably be a combination of EU and Members States action. 9

Should action be taken? Who should take action?

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Should action be taken?

(Strongly) agree

Neutral

(Strongly) disagree

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

100%

0%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

100%

0%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

86%

14%

0%

0%

NCA

100%

0%

0%

0%

Ministries

60%

40%

0%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

77%

6%

11%

6%

Industry association

61%

11%

28%

0%

Think tanks

67%

33%

0%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

84%

8%

8%

0%

Trade Unions

100%

0%

0%

0%

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

100%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

29%

14%

43%

14%

NCA

0%

40%

60%

0%

Ministries

0%

25%

50%

25%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

9%

12%

66%

12%

Industry association

13%

27%

40%

20%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

8%

8%

84%

0%

Trade Unions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Respondents also consider that, if EU action were to be taken, it should preferably take the form of a mix of legislative and non-legislative action.

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

17%

50%

0%

33%

NCA

4%

40%

56%

0%

Ministries

0%

50%

25%

25%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

7%

50%

23%

20%

Industry association

25%

37%

12%

25%

Think tanks

0%

50%

50%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

17%

75%

8%

0%

Trade Unions

0%

100%

0%

0%

Finally, the overall view of stakeholders is that taking action at EU level would have a (very) positive impact on various aspects, as shown in the table below:

Impact of EU action

(Very) Positive

Effective enforcement of the EU competition rules

92%

Legal certainty for businesses

85%

Cooperation within the European Competition Network

83%

Legitimacy of national competition authorities' decisions

83%

Investment climate/economic growth

79%

Costs for businesses

52%

Summary of results of the detailed questions

A. Resources and independence of the national competition authorities

A wide majority of stakeholders agree with the findings of the Commission's Communication on Ten Years of Regulation 1/2003 that it is necessary to further guarantee the independence of NCAs and that they have sufficient resources when enforcing the EU competition rules.

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Is it necessary to further guarantee the independence of NCAs and that they have sufficient resources when enforcing the EU competition rules?

(Strongly) agree

Neutral

(Strongly) disagree

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

100%

0%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

100%

0%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

86%

14%

0%

0%

NCA

100%

0%

0%

0%

Ministries

40%

20%

0%

20%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

71%

5%

10%

14%

Industry association

71%

12%

17%

0%

Think tanks

100%

0%

0%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

100%

0%

0%

0%

Trade Unions

100%

0%

0%

0%

Many respondents consider that the following measures are needed to ensure NCAs' independence when they enforce the EU competition rules (stakeholders were asked to identify and rank the three measures they considered to be of most importance): 

Importance

Supported by:

(# respondents)

1

2

3

Guarantees ensuring that NCAs are endowed with adequate and stable human and financial resources to perform their tasks

96

50%

28%

22%

Guarantees that NCA's top management/board or decision-making body are not subject to instructions from any government or other public or private body

97

45%

37%

18%

Guarantees ensuring that dismissals of members of the NCA's top management/board or decision-making body can only take place on objective grounds unrelated to its enforcement activities

67

13%

31%

55%

Rules on conflicts of interest for the NCA's top management/board or decision-making body

46

20%

39%

41%

Rules on accountability of the NCA (e.g. requiring that NCAs report annually on their activities

37

19%

43%

38%

Other measures (*)

7

43%

0%

57%

(*)e.g. budgetary autonomy and transparent appointment procedures for NCAs' management

The majority of stakeholders prefer action to be taken at both EU and national level on resources (59%) and on independence (54%).

In terms of those who consider that EU action is appropriate, approximately 43% consider that a mixture of legislative and soft action is the best solution.

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Ind*.

Res.*

Ind.

Res.

Ind.

Res.

Ind.

Res.

Academic institutions

0%

0%

0%

0%

100%

100%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

33%

0%

67%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

20%

33%

20%

17%

40%

50%

20%

0%

NCA

0%

0%

40%

36%

60%

64%

0%

0%

Ministries

20%

20%

20%

20%

60%

60%

0%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

19%

10%

14%

5%

52%

70%

14%

15%

Industry association

25%

38%

19%

6%

50%

56%

6%

0%

Think tanks

50%

50%

0%

0%

50%

50%

0%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

17%

25%

33%

25%

50%

50%

0%

0%

Trade Unions

0%

0%

100%

100%

0%

0%

0%

0%

Ind = Independence and **:Res = Resources

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

17%

33%

17%

33%

NCA

4%

25%

70%

0%

Ministries

20%

0%

60%

20%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

15%

55%

15%

15%

Industry association

7%

27%

47%

20%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

9%

64%

18%

9%

Trade Unions

0%

0%

100%

0%

B. Enforcement toolbox of the national competition authorities

A lack of effective powers for NCAs is considered by stakeholders to be a problem, firstly, in terms of the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules (e.g. NCAs may refrain from taking action/carry out more limited action/take action which does not meet the desired objective), and secondly, for cooperation within the ECN (e.g. it can impinge on the ability of NCAs to carry out inspections etc. on each other's behalf under Article 22 of Regulation 1/2003).

Divergences in NCAs' powers is seen as a problem in terms of legal certainty for business (63%), costs for business (62%) and for cooperation in the ECN, e.g. different rules on what evidence can be gathered on behalf of another NCA (57%).

The table below shows the investigation and decision-making tools stakeholders think that NCAs need to have in order for them to be effective enforcers of the EU competition rules.

Tool

% of support

Power to inspect business premises

92

Power to inspect non-business premises

63

Power to issue requests for information

93

Power to effectively gather digital evidence

89

Power for the officials of one NCA (NCA A), which requests another NCA (NCA B) to carry out an inspection on its behalf, to assist in the inspection carried out by NCA B (e.g. to be present during the inspection, to have investigative powers)

80

Power to conduct interviews

90

Power to conduct sector inquiries

89

Power to adopt prohibition decisions

87

Power to adopt formal settlement decisions (formal decision and reduced fine)

86

Power to adopt commitment decisions

91

Power to issue interim measures

87

Power to impose dissuasive fines for non-compliance with investigative and decision-making powers

83

Power to compel compliance with investigative and decision-making powers, e.g., power to impose effective periodic penalty payments

76

Power to fully set enforcement priorities, including the power to reject complaints on priority grounds

75

Power for NCAs to act within a certain time period (limitation periods)

77

Power for one NCA (NCA A) to ask another NCA (NCA B) to notify acts (e.g. a Statement of Objections) on its behalf in the territory of NCA B (e.g. if NCA A cannot notify acts to a company in its own territory because it does not have a subsidiary/other legal representation there)

71

Power for one NCA (NCA A) to ask another NCA (NCA B) to enforce fining decisions on its behalf in the territory of NCA B (e.g. if NCA A cannot fine a company in its own territory because it does not have a subsidiary/other legal representation there)

61

A majority of stakeholders consider that ensuring that the NCAs have an effective toolbox should be addressed by a combination of EU and national action.

Those who consider EU action appropriate prefer a mixture of legislative and non-legislative action (48%), with a smaller number opting for exclusive legislative action (41%).

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

100%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

33%

0%

67%

0%

NCA

0%

48%

52%

0%

Ministries

25%

25%

50%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

6%

6%

76%

12%

Industry association

36%

36%

21%

7%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

25%

75%

0%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

75%

0%

25%

NCA

4%

20%

76%

0%

Ministries

0%

0%

100%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

14%

43%

36%

7%

Industry association

14%

57%

29%

0%

Think tanks

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

73%

27%

0%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

C. Powers of national competition authorities to fine undertakings

The public consultation has covered three main issues: the nature of the fines imposed by NCAs (criminal, civil or administrative); who can be fined (concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession); and fines methodologies/legal maximum of the fines.

The graphs below show to what extent stakeholders considered that there are problems in the three areas identified:

Is it a problem that some NCAs impose only/primarily criminal / civil fines?

       Criminal fines                    Civil fines

Regarding the measures which could be taken to address the issues identified in those Member States where no administrative fines are available, stakeholders' views are approximately evenly split between those proposing the introduction of a pure administrative system (27%), introducing administrative fines as a complement to the current criminal/civil systems (27%), or to take measures to make the current criminal/civil systems more effective (23%).

Who can be fined: is it a problem that some NCAs do not apply the concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession in line with the ECJ case law?

Are differences in legal maximum of the fines/fines methodologies a problem?

Legal maximum                Fines methodologies

With respect to who should take action on all of these three areas, stakeholders generally support either a combination of EU and Member States action or EU action alone.

Nature of fines

Who can be fined

Legal maximum and fines methodologies

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?(1: Member States; 2: EU; 3: EU & Member States; 4: Do not know/not applicable)

Nature of fines

Who can be fined

Legal maximum

1

2

3

4

1

2

3

4

1

2

3

4

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

33%

0%

67%

0%

60%

20%

0%

20%

0%

33%

33%

33%

NCA

5%

27%

36%

32%

0%

44%

44%

13%

0%

57%

35%

13%

Ministries

0%

0%

25%

75%

0%

25%

50%

25%

0%

25%

50%

25%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

14%

29%

43%

14%

14%

21%

43%

21%

7%

43%

29%

21%

Industry association

36%

14%

21%

29%

10%

30%

10%

50%

15%

31%

31%

23%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

50%

0%

50%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

27%

45%

27%

11%

22%

33%

33%

30%

50%

10%

10%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

Finally, the majority of stakeholders considering that EU action should be taken have the view that such action should be either a mixture of legislative and non-legislative action or pure legislative action. In general, non-legislative action is supported by a minority of respondents.

What type of action is most appropriate?

Nature of fines

Concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession

Legal maximums and fines methodologies

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

(1: Non-legislative; 2: Mix legislative & non-legislative; 3: Legislative; 4: Do not know/not applicable)

Nature of fines

Who can be fined

Legal maximum

1

2

3

4

1

2

3

4

1

2

3

4

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

100 %

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

0%

0%

100%

0%

60%

20%

20%

NCA

0%

21%

79%

0%

10%

25%

65%

0%

4%

25%

63%

8%

Ministries

100%

0%

0%

0%

33%

0%

67%

0%

25%

25%

25%

25%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

11%

44%

44%

0%

11%

44%

44%

0%

0%

29%

50%

21%

Industry association

25%

50%

25%

0%

0%

100%

0%

0%

0%

67%

11%

22%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

-

-

-

-

0%

0%

50%

50%

Consultancy/Law firm

20%

40%

40%

0%

0%

60%

40%

0%

0%

20%

40%

40%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

D. Leniency programmes

The public consultation has addressed four main topics: the need of a legal basis for leniency and divergences in leniency programmes; facilitating multiple applications for leniency; the protection of leniency and settlement material; and the interplay between leniency programmes and sanctions on individuals.

Legal basis for leniency and divergences in leniency programmes

The majority of respondents consider that the lack of a legal basis in EU law for leniency programmes is a problem:

Is the lack of EU legal basis for national leniency programmes a problem?

Moreover, 43% consider that the existence of divergences in the leniency programmes could have an impact on who can benefit from leniency and under which conditions (10% not sharing this view and 46% answering “do not know” or “not applicable”). This is considered to be a problem in terms of effective and consistent enforcement of EU competition law and legal certainty for business.

40% of respondents consider that the ECN Model Leniency Programme ensures a sufficient degree of alignment of Member States' leniency programmes. However 61% finds a lack of implementation of the ECN Model Leniency Programme by Member States, and 44% consider that additional rules are needed.

With respect to potential action, there is wide support for EU action either alone or combined with action by Member States. The type of EU action should be either a mix of legislative and non-legislative action or purely legislative.

   Who should take action        What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

100%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

17%

67%

17%

NCA

0%

68%

27%

5%

Ministries

0%

25%

25%

50%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

0%

40%

40%

20%

Industry association

17%

17%

50%

17%

Think tanks

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

54%

23%

23%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

80%

20%

0%

NCA

5%

33%

62%

0%

Ministries

0%

50%

50%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

8%

42%

50%

0%

Industry association

0%

100%

0%

0%

Think tanks

0%

50%

50%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

44%

56%

0%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

Multiple applications

Summary applications is a system set up by the ECN Model Leniency programme under which leniency applicants make a full application for leniency to the Commission and can make short form "summary applications" to NCAs on the basis of limited information, to protect their place in the leniency queue if the Commission decides not to take up, a part of, or the entire case. Only 19% of stakeholders consider they have experience or knowledge of the system of summary applications.

Divergences in the way summary applications are applied are considered to be a problem by nearly half of respondents in terms of the effective and consistent application of EU rules, legal certainty for business and incentives to apply for leniency.

With respect to taking action, the majority supports EU action either combined with action by Member States, or exclusively by the EU action. The type of EU action should mainly be either a mix of legislative and non-legislative action or purely legislative.

Who should take action?        What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

50%

50%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

17%

50%

33%

NCA

10%

35%

25%

30%

Ministries

0%

0%

25%

75%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

0%

33%

25%

42%

Industry association

10%

0%

40%

50%

Think tanks

0%

50%

50%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

20%

30%

50%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

0%

100%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

75%

25%

0%

NCA

8%

50%

42%

0%

Ministries

0%

100%

0%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

14%

43%

43%

0%

Industry association

0%

75%

25%

0%

Think tanks

0%

50%

50%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

60%

40%

0%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

Protection of leniency and settlement material

About half of the respondents are in favour of extending the protection provided for by the Damages Directive (protection from use/disclosure in civil damages actions before EU courts) to other types of proceedings (another 48% replied that they "do not know"). A broad majority of these stakeholders support extending such protection to the following types of proceedings:

Civil proceedings other than damages actions (for example injunctive relief)

79%

Administrative proceedings (such as proceedings before tax authorities or regulators)

72%

Criminal proceedings

69%

Proceedings under the "transparency" rules/public access to documents

69%

They consider that measures to protect leniency and settlement materials should be addressed through a combination of EU and Member State action or through EU action alone. In terms of EU action, a majority is in favour of legislative action.

Interplay of corporate leniency programmes with sanctions on individuals

A majority of stakeholders considers it a problem that only a few Member States have arrangements to protect employees of companies cooperating under a leniency programme from individual sanctions.

Is it a problem that only a few MS protect employees of companies applying for leniency from individual sanctions?

Also a majority is in favour of establishing safeguards to protect such employees, mainly regarding the ones detailed in the table below:

Current employees

74%

Former employees

64%

Protection from administrative sanctions in all MS (director disqualification orders)

60%

Protection from criminal sanctions in all MS (imprisonment)

62%

Employees of companies which obtain immunity

72%

Employees of companies which benefit from a reduction in fines

60%

Employees of leniency applicants with any NCA

67%

Employees of leniency applicants with the Commission

64%

They consider that the interplay between corporate leniency programmes and sanctions on individuals should be addressed through a combination of EU and Member State action or through EU action alone. In terms of EU action, a majority favours a mix of legislative and soft action.

Per group of stakeholder, the replies are as follows:

Who should take action?

Member States

EU

EU & Member States

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

100%

0%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

0%

50%

50%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

20%

60%

20%

NCA

5%

33%

33%

29%

Ministries

25%

25%

25%

25%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

23%

15%

31%

31%

Industry association

10%

10%

50%

30%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

10%

10%

30%

50%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

What type of EU action is most appropriate?

Non-legislative

Mix legislative & non-legislative

Legislative

Do not know/not applicable

Academic institutions

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consumer organisations

0%

100%

0%

0%

Non-governmental organisation

0%

100%

0%

0%

NCA

0%

14%

86%

0%

Ministries

0%

0%

100%

0%

Company/SME/micro-enterprise/sole trader

0%

67%

33%

0%

Industry association

0%

83%

17%

0%

Think tanks

0%

0%

100%

0%

Consultancy/Law firm

0%

50%

50%

0%

Trade Unions

-

-

-

-

II.    Public Hearing co-organised by the ECON Committee of the European Parliament and the Commission

On 19 April 2016, the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON) of the European Parliament and DG Competition of the European Commission co-organised a Public Hearing. The purpose of the Public Hearing was to provide experts and stakeholders an additional opportunity to share their views on the Commission's public consultation on empowering national competition authorities to be more effective enforcers.

At the hearing, Commissioner Vestager presented the results of the Public Consultation.

It was followed by two panel discussions on the four topics covered by the Public Consultation. The two panels consisted of experts from different areas, including the business and legal community, consumer associations, academics and the judiciary. The first panel addressed the enforcement powers and independence of NCAs while the second panel discussed sanctions and leniency in the Member States.

The presentations by panellist were followed by an exchange of views with Members of the ECON Committee and a broad range of stakeholders (around 150 attended the public hearing including, academia, business (large and small), consultancy, industry associations, law firms, press, private individuals and public authorities).

The objectives of the initiative were widely agreed with and supported. Overall, it was considered that the goal is not just to strengthen the powers of individual NCAs, but to reinforce the EU enforcement system as a whole.

III.    Further consultation of stakeholders

The initiative is developed in continuous cooperation and consultation with the NCAs and the relevant national Ministries.

Two meetings have already been held with relevant Ministries to get their preliminary feedback. On 12 June 2015, Ministries were informed about the main issues that had been identified by the Commission. A second meeting with the Ministries and NCAs was held on 14 April 2016 in which they were informed about the results of the Public Consultation.

The Commission has also engaged in regular dialogue with other stakeholders, in particular, consumer organisations (e.g. BEUC) and the business including SMEs (e.g. BusinessEurope) and legal communities (e.g. European Competition Lawyers Forum (ECLF)), through conferences and bi- or multilateral meetings and will continue to do so.



Annex III - Who is affected by the initiative and how

The following stakeholders would be affected by the initiative as set out in the preferred policy option 3:

National competition authorities

NCAs would be the first stakeholders affected by the initiative, and together with businesses, the most directly affected. NCAs play a key role in making sure that the single market works well and fairly to the benefit of both businesses and consumers throughout Europe. NCAs would be affected by the initiative as it aims precisely at removing the gaps and limitations which they currently face in their means and instruments to enforce the EU competition rules and that mark their ability to be more effective enforcers. However, not all NCAs would be affected in the same way, since the changes required would be dependent on the precise starting point of each national legal framework, most of them would need to undertake changes to address the problems as identified in section 2.2 of the Impact Assessment.

Once implemented, the initiative would provide all NCAs with the minimum means and instruments to find evidence of infringements, to fine companies which break the law, to act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and to have the resources they need to perform their tasks, and to have at their disposal leniency programmes that are more effective. This will allow the NCAs to take effective enforcement action and enable them to cooperate better with other competition authorities in the EU leading to more competition on markets. More particularly, it will ensure that the system of cross-border information gathering and exchange put in place by Regulation 1/2003 works effectively. This might create some additional costs for some public authorities, if for example new tools need to be provided, but these costs are expected to be negligible.

Practically all NCAs have replied to the public consultation, showing their strong interest and confirming the impact that the initiative could have on them. The public consultation has also shown their support for the initiative: 100% think that action should be taken to empower NCAs to be more effective enforcers of EU competition rules, and that this action should be taken either by the EU alone (40%) or in combination with the Member States (60%). NCAs also consider that EU action should be either exclusively legislative (56%) or combined with soft action (40%).

Support for taking action not only comes from NCAs; 60% of ministries from Member States that have replied to the questionnaire consider that action should be taken to empower NCAs to be more effective enforcers (vs 40% with a neutral position. They consider, that action should be taken either by the EU alone (25%) or in combination with Member States (50%), and that in case of EU action, it should be exclusively legislative (25%) or combined with soft action (50%).

Business

Businesses would be, together with NCAs, the group of stakeholders mostly affected by the initiative.

Firstly, like consumers, businesses also suffer from the consequences of diminished competition enforcement, as they equally face the negative impact of higher prices from their suppliers and the lower levels of innovation and choice, as well as from attempts of competitors infringing competition rules to foreclose them from the market. The initiative would boost competition enforcement by NCAs in Europe and create a more level playing field in which a competition culture prevails. This would be to the benefit of all companies, both large and small, as it would enable them to compete more fairly on their merits and grow throughout the single market. This would also incentivise them to innovate and offer a better range of higher quality products and services that meet consumers' expectations.

Secondly, the initiative would also benefit businesses subject to investigations for alleged infringements of EU competition rules in several respects. The introduction of common minimum means and instruments for NCAs would reduce divergent outcomes for companies, making the application of the EU competition rules more predictable and increasing legal certainty across the EU. Companies may also benefit from enhanced procedural rights particularly in those jurisdictions in which there is room for improvement, as well as more legal certainty when applying for leniency. Companies would face initial adaptation costs in terms of familiarisation with possibly new procedural rules. However, overall, the costs for businesses involved in cross-border activities in the single market to adapt to different legal frameworks would be reduced or even fall.

On the other hand, for those businesses infringing the law in some jurisdictions it would become more difficult to conceal evidence or to escape fines, or to benefit from low fines.

The public consultation has also shown the strong interest of this group of stakeholders (companies and industry associations, forming the second group with the highest number of replies after public authorities) in this initiative: more than 60% think that action should be taken to empower NCAs to be more effective enforcers of EU competition rules, and that this action should be taken either by the EU alone (12% for companies and 27% for industry associations) or in combination with the Member States (66% for companies and 40% for industry associations). They also consider that EU action should be either exclusively legislative (23%/12%) or combined with soft action (50%/37%).

In addition, the initiative would not disproportionately impact SMEs compared to larger companies. While in principle all companies are subject to the EU competition rules provided there may be an effect on trade between Member States, many agreements/behavior of SMEs fall outside the scope of the EU competition rules as they not necessarily have such an effect on trade between Member States or appreciably restrict competition. SMEs are also unlikely to hold dominant positions, that is, substantial market power, the abuse of which would be caught by the EU competition rules.

Consumers

Although consumers would not be strictly speaking directly affected by the initiative, they would benefit directly from the benefits that stronger competition would bring to the market. EU competition policy aims at making markets work better to the benefit of consumers across the EU. It encourages companies to compete fairly by creating a wide choice of products for consumers at lower prices and with better quality. For consumers, the lack of means and instruments and capacity of national competition authorities (NCAs) to un-leash their full potential to enforce the EU competition rules means that they miss out on these benefits of competition enforcement. By making sure that NCAs have all the minimum means and instruments and adequate resources they need to be effective enforcers of the EU competition rules, consumers will get the same level of protection across Europe from business practices that keep the prices of goods and services artificially high and enhances their choice of innovative goods and services at affordable prices.

The importance of the initiative for consumers is reflected by the replies of eight consumer organisations to the public consultation. They consider that action should be taken to empower NCAs to be more effective enforcers of EU competition rules (100%), and that this action should be taken by the EU in combination with the Member States (100%). They also believe that EU action should therefore be a combination of EU action and soft action (100%).

Untapped potential for more effective enforcement of EU competition rules by NCAs

Annex IV - Problem tree

Consequences

Not all NCA have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to carry out their work

Risk of undermining legitimacy and credibility of NCAs

More distortions of competition in single market as well as in national and regional markets (energy, telecom, etc.)

Infringements not detected/addressed/partially tackled

Legal uncertainty and costs for companies operating cross-border

Less incentive for leniency applications

Not all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox

Loss of 180-320 billion Euro (up to 3% GDP) per year in EU through cartels

Untapped potential for innovation, productivity, growth, jobs, etc.

No level playing field for businesses

Problem drivers

Cooperation within ECN is hindered, e.g. NCAs cannot effectively gather evidence located in other MS

Divergences between leniency programmes

Consumers do not benefit from lower prices, more choice and better quality (and general quality of life of EU citizens)

Fines not reflecting harm to competition / Shelters from sanctions

Not all NCAs can impose deterrent fines

Annex V - Replies of stakeholders on the tools NCAs need to effectively enforce

Tool

Percentage of stakeholders who agree/strongly agree

Power to inspect business premises

92

Power to inspect non-business premises

63

Power to issue requests for information 

93

Power to effectively gather digital evidence

89

Power for the officials of one NCA (NCA A), which requests another NCA (NCA B) to carry out an inspection on its behalf, to assist in the inspection carried out by NCA B (e.g. to be present during the inspection, to have investigative powers)

80

Power to conduct interviews

90

Power to conduct sector inquiries

89

Power to adopt prohibition decisions

87

Power to adopt formal settlement decisions (formal decision and reduced fine)

86

Power to adopt commitment decisions

91

Power to issue interim measures

87

Power to impose dissuasive fines for non-compliance with investigative and decision-making powers

83

Power to compel compliance with investigative and decision-making powers, e.g., power to impose effective periodic penalty payments

76

Power to fully set enforcement priorities, including the power to reject complaints on priority grounds

75

Power for NCAs to act within a certain time period (limitation periods)

77

Power for one NCA (NCA A) to ask another NCA (NCA B) to notify acts (e.g. a Statement of Objection) on its behalf in the territory of NCA B (e.g. if NCA A cannot notify acts to a company in its own territory because it does not have a subsidiary or other legal representation there)

71

Power for one NCA (NCA A) to ask another NCA (NCA B) to enforce fining decisions on its behalf in the territory of NCA B (e.g. if NCA A cannot fine a company in its own territory because it does not have a subsidiary or other legal representation there)

61

Annex VI - Issues related to legal maximum, fines calculations and who can be fined

Legal Maximum

The legal maximum is calculated as a percentage of a given turnover in most Member States. There are however significant differences between Member States in the way the legal maximum is calculated in terms of the percentages applied, and the turnover to which such percentages are applied.

oPercentages applied: While many NCAs apply a percentage of 10%, in other Member States the percentages applied are lower (up to 5%) for less serious infringements. Similarly, in one Member State, a cap of 5% is imposed on the turnover of the direct infringer only for vertical anti-competitive practices between companies operating at different levels of the supply chain i.e. agreements between a manufacturer and its distributor and abuses of dominant position contrary to Article 102. In another Member State, the cap is generally set at 10% for competition infringements, but for the specific case of cartels, the cap is 10% for each year of infringement up to a maximum of 4 years: this means that the maximum can reach 40% for cartels lasting 4 or more years. Moreover, these amounts can be doubled for cartels in cases of recidivism (that is, if a company has already been found to have breached competition law), with the result that the legal maximum could potentially reach 80% of worldwide turnover.

oTurnover to which percentages are applied: Most NCAs when calculating the legal maximum use the worldwide turnover of the corporate group that has been held liable for the infringement, but some base it solely on the national turnover or the turnover of the direct infringer. In at least one case there are also absolute maximum amounts. The entities for which the turnover is considered (the undertaking or the direct infringer) and whether the geographic scope of such turnover is worldwide or national make a big difference to the maximum level of the fine.

For example, in a Member State, only the direct turnover of the infringer is used and fines are limited to €16 million. For breaches of Article 102 TFEU, maximum fines of only €400 000 can be imposed. Such low legal maximums are highly unlikely to reflect the harm caused to competition and fines are likely to be under-deterrent, particularly for large multinational groups.

The table below gives an overview of how NCAs calculate the legal maximum of the fines.

Basis for calculation of legal maximum for fines

Geographic scope of the turnover

Entity's turnover:

Worldwide

National

Undertaking

11 NCAs

3 NCAs

Direct infringer

9 NCAs

4 NCAs

Fines calculation

Most Member States apply methodologies based on common parameters, such as the sales achieved by the infringer and the gravity and duration of the infringement. Some Member States however do not have clear rules on how fines are calculated. For those NCAs which do apply fining parameters, there are a number of issues:

oFines risk being unrelated to the infringement: while many NCAs use sales related to the infringement/market affected, others use the total turnover of the undertaking which can include sales of other unrelated products.

oFines risk being unrelated to the harm caused to competition: there is a wide range of percentages between NCAs for taking into account the gravity of the infringement 10 and in one NCA the fine is based on fixed amounts.

oThe actual duration of the infringement is not always reflected in the fine and consequently does not reflect the harm to competition: many Member States base the fine on the sales over the entire infringement period – as a way to reflect as accurately as possible the harm caused to competition 11 – some Member States apply reduction factors so that each year of infringement counts less, and others apply still other methods based on single increases of the fine regardless of the exact number of years of infringement. 12

These issues can have a significant impact on the level of fines. The amount of the fine may not reflect the harm caused to competition and be below the amount of gains improperly made as a result of the infringement. Very different fines may be imposed for the same infringement, meaning that the deterrent effect of fines differs widely across Europe.

Who can be held liable for paying the fine

Another aspect which may mean that fines do not reflect the harm to competition is limitations regarding who can be held liable for paying the fine. Not all NCAs can hold parent companies liable for infringements committed by subsidiaries under their control despite the long-established case law of the European Court of Justice according to which parent companies can be held responsible for infringements of their subsidiaries. 13 This sends a clear signal to the entire corporate group that the absence of good corporate governance and compliance with competition law will not remain unpunished. It allows the legal maximum of the fine to be set on the basis of the overall economic strength of the corporate group, instead of only that of the subsidiary.

In addition, several NCAs cannot hold legal and economic successors of an infringer liable for fines or there is uncertainty about whether national courts would uphold the application of these principles, which means that companies can escape fines simply by merging with other companies or through corporate restructuring. The table below provides an overview of the application of parental liability and succession by NCAs:

Application of parental liability and succession by NCAs

Can parent companies be held liable?

Can legal succession be applied?

Can economic succession be applied?

YES

17

21

14

YES

(with certain restrictions) 14

2

-

-

YES

(limited practice)

2

5

6

NO

5

2

8

Moreover, there are NCAs that cannot effectively fine associations of undertakings, such as trade associations, either because national legislation prevents this possibility or because NCAs cannot impose fines that take into account the turnover of their members. 15 This is a problem as trade associations typically have very little turnover, compared to the turnover of their members. NCAs need to be able to also fine the members of the association benefitting from the infringement. The fines imposed by NCAs without this power are often symbolic and do not reflect the harm to competition.



Annex VII - Results of hypothetical cartel case for a duration of 3.75 years

To assess the impact of divergences in fining methodologies, the NCAs were asked to calculate the fine that they would impose in a hypothetical case.

The case was a simple cartel with several types of companies, ranging from companies with sales focussed at national level or worldwide sales, companies specialised in the manufacture of one product or multiproduct companies, and small single companies or large groups.

The two tables below show the different types of companies considered in the hypothetical in terms of geographic scope, product scope and corporate structure (first table), and the hypothetical sales attributed to each company/group (second table).

Companies involved in the infringement

Direct infringer

Geographic scope, product scope and corporate structure

Direct infringer

Geographic scope, product scope and corporate structure

A

National focus

Production focussed on Product X

Single company

F

Worldwide presence

Producer of several products

Single company

B

National focus

Producer of several products

Single company

G

Worldwide presence

Production focussed on Product X

Belongs to a group with parent G*

C

National focus

Production focussed on Product X

Belongs to a group with parent C*

H

Worldwide presence

Producer of several products

Belongs to a group with parent H*

D

National focus

Producer of several products

Belongs to a group with parent D*

I

Worldwide presence

Producer of several products

Belongs to a large group with parent I*

E

Worldwide presence

Production focussed on Product X

Single company

J

Worldwide presence

Producer of several products

Belongs to a very large group with parent J*

Sales affected by the infringement and turnovers (Million EURO)

Affected sales

Total turnover of the direct infringer

Total turnover of the Undertaking (EU meaning)

Company

National

Worldwide

National

Worldwide

National

Worldwide

A

20

20

20

20

20

20

B

20

20

60

60

60

60

C

20

20

20

20

80

80

D

20

20

60

60

250

250

E

20

40

20

40

20

40

F

20

40

60

120

60

120

G

20

40

20

40

80

650

H

20

40

60

120

200

2000

I

20

40

60

120

750

7500

J

20

40

60

120

3250

32500

The hypothetical case also covered a range of different durations, from short durations of some months up to long durations of almost 9 years.

The results showed that the fines imposed by the different NCAs could range from small differences to significant variations depending on the specific scenario considered.

For example, while the differences in the fines are not very high in the case of a company with sales at national level only, producing one product and that does not belong to a wider corporate group (company type "A"), the differences between the fines increase with companies that, although also having a national focus, produce other products or belong to a corporate group (type "D"), and become significant with large multiproduct and multinational groups (type "I" in the example).

As shown in the example below, differences in the fines are also significant in the cases of smaller groups, such as type "C" companies.



Annex VIII - Article in German press

Annex IX - Imposition of sanctions in civil and criminal procedures

In the majority of Members States fines are administrative.

Civil fines are imposed in three Member States: Austria, Finland and Sweden.

Criminal or quasi-criminal fines are imposed in five Member States:

-Ireland

-Denmark,

-Estonia, where fines are imposed by criminal courts for infringements of Article 101 (and until 2014 also for Article 102). As from 1 January 2015 fines for infringements of Article 102 are imposed by the NCA instead of a criminal court but according to misdemeanour procedures (criminal offences of minor importance).

-Slovenia, where fines are imposed by the NCA instead of a court but according to misdemeanour (quasi-criminal) procedures.

-Germany, where fines are initially administrative, imposed by the NCA, but if they are appealed, the case is brought to court where it is reassessed according to criminal standards.



Annex X - Policy options

Specific Objectives

Option 1:

No EU action at all (baseline scenario)

Option 2:

Further soft action

Option 3:

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments, complemented by soft action where appropriate. For certain confined aspects detailed rules may be provided for where minimum rules would not suffice

Option 4

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

Ensuring all NCAs have an effective competition toolbox to investigate and take decisions

No EU action

Further soft action on issues not covered by set of seven ECN Recommendations on key enforcement powers of 2012-2013, e.g. new ECN Recommendations on issues such as the use of behavioural remedies to ensure a return to competitive conditions on markets and formal settlement procedures.

Minimum rules to ensure that:

(1) NCAs have a minimum core set of operational investigative tools (that is effective powers to inspect business and non-business premises, to issue requests for information and to gather digital evidence) and decision-making tools (the power to adopt prohibition decisions (including the power to impose structural and behavioural remedies), to issue interim measures and to adopt commitment decisions). These tools would be backed up by effective sanctions for non-compliance with them, e.g. the payment of a fine for failure to comply with an inspection and. the power of NCAs to set their priorities in full. Tools could also be put in place to address limitation periods and the inability of NCAs to enforce fining decisions cross-border.

(2) the increase in the powers of the NCAs would be counter-balanced by ensuring that key procedural guarantees are in place in line with the EU Charter on Fundamental Rights, such as the obligation of NCAs to notify companies of the objections against them and by providing for effective judicial review of enforcement decisions.

Build on option 3 to have uniform and detailed (as opposed to minimum) rules so that NCAs have identical investigation and decision-making powers backed up by uniform sanctions for non-compliance. This would mean, for example, having detailed rules such as on how NCAs consult market players about the appropriateness of proposed commitments. This option would also provide for a more complete competition toolbox, meaning that, for instance, the power to carry out sector inquires would also be included. It would also provide for detailed procedural guarantees, such as detailed and uniform rules on access to an authority's case file and rules on the ability of complainants and third parties to intervene in proceedings.

Ensuring that all NCAs can impose deterrent fines

(a) Ensuring that fines reflect the harm caused to competition by addressing differences in methodologies for calculating fines which lead to wide variations in fining levels; and limitations in who can be fined

(b) Tackling under- enforcement in primarily criminal systems

No EU action

(a) ECN soft measures could be contemplated to convince Member States of the need to apply the EU concepts of undertaking, parental liability and succession in line with the ECJ case law, to ensure that associations of undertakings can be effectively fined.

(b) ECN soft measures could be contemplated to convince Member States with primarily criminal enforcement systems of the need to allow the imposition of administrative fines or the imposition of fines by civil courts.

(a) Minimum rules to ensure that:

(1) The legal maximum of fines is set at a level which ensures deterrence; and that fines take into account a minimum set of core parameters. To ensure that the fine is related to the infringement and to the harm caused to competition, it would be based on key elements widely recognised as essential for calculating a fine: the gravity and duration of the infringement, and the potential application of aggravating and mitigating circumstances. To ensure deterrence, the legal maximum of the fine would be set as a percentage of the total worldwide turnover of the undertaking.

(2) When applying EU competition rules, the concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession are applied in line with ECJ case law, and that associations can be effectively sanctioned.

(3) Soft action on non-core aspects such as aggravating/mitigating factors to be taken into account and how to assess the gravity of the infringement.

(b) There exists the possibility either to impose administrative fines or to apply to a civil court for the imposition of fines. This would mean that NCAs which currently operate within a primarily (quasi-) criminal system would be given the option of deciding depending on the facts and circumstances of the case, whether to follow an administrative track/seize a civil court or to follow the existing criminal route. It would also be ensured that all NCAs would have the power to defend their cases in court (most already can do so).

(a) A uniform fines methodology, setting out all the parameters that are to be taken into account and prescribing how fines should be calculated and who can be fined.

(b) A uniform fining model so only administrative fines can be imposed.

Making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with authorities in the fight against cartels

(a) Reducing divergences on core principles of substance and procedure between national leniency programmes (for instance on the availability and treatment of summary applications)

(b) Ensuring protection of leniency and settlement materials beyond civil damages actions

(c) Ensuring better interplay between corporate leniency programmes with sanctions on individuals

No EU action

(a) The ECN MLP already provides for core principles of substance and procedure for efficient leniency programmes, for example a system of summary applications to facilitate multiple applications for leniency.

(b) The ECN MLP already contains rules on the protection of leniency materials.

c) Encourage the introduction of arrangements to protect employees of companies which apply for leniency from individual sanctions at national level through an extension of the ECN MLP or a separate ECN Recommendation.

(a) Translate the core principles of the ECN MLP into law in light of experience with their application, thereby introducing binding minimum rules for leniency programmes. This would reduce the current divergences between national programmes and ensure, for example, that summary applications are available in all Member States and are applied in the same way.

In particular, NCAs would have in place leniency programmes that enable them to grant immunity from fines and reduction of fines to undertakings and companies would have to satisfy core common conditions in order to qualify for leniency.

Further, it would be ensured that applicants that have applied for leniency to the European Commission can file summary applications in relation to the same cartel with the NCAs and that NCAs accept summary applications with the same scope as the leniency application filed with the Commission.

(b) Uniform binding rules to fully protect leniency and settlements materials against disclosure outside the context of civil damages actions (already being addressed by the Damages Directive). EU legislative action to this end would expand the protection granted by the Damages Directive to other procedures.

(c) Minimum rules to protect employees of leniency applicants to either the Commission or NCAs from sanctions at national level.

(a) Maximum requirements beyond the ECN MLP to ensure, amongst others, a one-stop shop for leniency applicants (meaning they can file a single application with one authority that issues an immunity decision which is binding in all MS and before the Commission) and fully harmonized leniency programmes.

(b) Same as for option 3.

(c) Uniform and detailed rules to protect employees of leniency applicants to either the Commission or NCAs from sanctions at national level.

Ensuring that all NCAs have safeguards they can act independently when enforcing the EU competition rules and have the resources they need to perform their tasks

No EU action

The 2010 ECN Resolution on the continued need for effective institutions already calls for NCAs to be adequately equipped and to be able to act independently and impartially. Soft action could provide for more detailed provisions on the independence and resources of NCAs.

Minimum rules to ensure independence of NCAs when they enforce the EU competition rules, including for example the following requirements:

(1) NCAs perform their tasks and exercise their powers independently and are not subject to any instructions from any other body when enforcing the EU competition rules. In particular, it would be ensured that NCAs can take decisions independently from any political and business influence and that the staff and the members of a NCA's decision making body refrain from actions and occupations that are incompatible with the performance of their duties during their term of office and for a reasonable period thereafter.

(2) NCAs’ board/management cannot be dismissed for reasons related to the proper performance of their powers in the application of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU;

(3) NCAs have adequate human and financial resources to perform their tasks. This would simply provide that NCAs should have sufficient financial, human and technical resources to perform their tasks and would include a list of these tasks (e.g. conducting investigations, taking decisions and cooperating with other authorities in the ECN).

In addition to the minimum requirements foreseen under option 3, this option would foresee uniform and detailed rules to also ensure the institutional and financial autonomy of NCAs when they enforce the EU competition rules, including for example the following requirements:

(1) NCAs should be legally distinct from any other public or private body (structural independence);

(2) full authority over the recruitment and management of staff;

(3) separate annual budget/full budgetary autonomy;

(4) appointment of board/management through a transparent procedure on the basis of merit.

Annex XI - Achievement of objectives

Objectives

Option 1:

Baseline scenario – no EU action

Option 2:

soft law measures

Option 3:

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with minimum means and instruments

Option 4:

EU legislative action to provide NCAs with detailed and uniform means and instruments

General objective: boost enforcement of the EU competition rules by the NCAs and the functioning of markets in Europe 

0

0/+

+++

+++

Specific objective: Ensuring all NCAs have effective investigation and decision-making tools

0

0/+

+++

+++

Specific objective: Ensuring that all NCAs are able to impose effective fines

0

0

+++

+++

Specific objective: Making leniency programmes and their interplay more attractive to encourage companies to cooperate with the authorities in the fight against cartels across multiple jurisdictions

0

0

+++

+++

Specific objective: Ensuring that NCAs have sufficient resources and they can enforce the EU competition rules independently

0

0

+++

+++

Key:    (-):    option would have a detrimental effect

   (0):    option does not meet the objective

   (+):    partially meets the objective

   (++):    option meets the objective to a reasonable extent

   (+++):    option meets the objective in full

Annex XII - Number of leniency and summary leniency applications submitted before NCAs

The figures below show the total number of leniency and summary leniency applications submitted before NCAs in the period 2004(2006)-2014. It is apparent from these figures that the number of (summary) leniency applications varies widely across NCAs and some NCAs are much more successful in attracting such applications. A number of authorities attracted none or only up to 10 applications during the 8-10 years of the survey:



It is interesting to compare the number of leniency application as stated above with the overall level of enforcement activity per NCA (for the period 2010-2015, as indicated by the number of competition cases, both under national law only and under national and EU law in parallel). Some NCAs can rely to a significant extent on leniency applications to feed their enforcement work stream whereas others generate none or much less of their overall enforcement activity with leniency applications. However, where both the number of leniency applications and the number of overall enforcement cases is comparatively high, the low share of leniency cases in the overall enforcement of a NCA might also be the result of special efforts deployed over the period to detect cartels and other infringements by other means.

Annex XIII – Divergences between leniency programmes

Divergences in the treatment of summary leniency applications and in core leniency features

In 2006 the ECN endorsed the ECN Model Leniency Programme (ECN MLP) that sets out the main features that an effective leniency programme should have. To facilitate making applications for leniency to multiple jurisdictions in cross-border cartel cases, the ECN MLP also provides for a system of summary applications. Under this system companies make a full application to the Commission, but can submit summary applications (which contain very limited information) to NCAs which may become active later if the Commission does not take up (a part of) the case. This is intended to protect companies' place in the leniency queue before these NCAs, so that they can still benefit from immunity or a reduction in fines if (parts of) the case would ultimately be pursued by the NCA(s). 16

However, although the ECN has achieved a degree of convergence through the non-binding 17 ECN MLP, important divergences remain both in the treatment of summary applications and on core leniency features.

For example, summary applications are still not available before a number of NCAs. Even where the possibility to make summary applications exists, there are often restrictions, for instance, in some Member States, the protection provided by summary applications is only given to immunity applicants and not to companies who are eligible for a reduction of fines. Moreover, NCAs assess summary applications differently. For example, not all programmes clarify that when the summary application is perfected at the NCA's request, the NCA will consider that the information was submitted on the date when the summary application was submitted. Also on core leniency features, divergences continue to exist between NCAs regarding which companies can benefit from leniency and under which conditions. For example, NCAs apply different thresholds for granting leniency reductions and different rules for excluding certain cartel members from leniency altogether.

These divergences have two main consequences: (1) they hamper the interplay between leniency programmes across the EU because they lead to different outcomes for leniency beneficiaries; and (2) they may also undermine the effectiveness of national leniency programmes where such programmes contain diverging rules compared to other ECN members. This may reduce incentives for cartel members to cooperate with the NCAs concerned.

These issues are borne out by the majority of respondents to the public consultation: 66% of respondents consider that divergences in the features of Member States' leniency programmes are a problem in terms of legal certainty for business 18 and 61% believe that this hampers the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules by the NCAs 19 . 59% of the respondents with sufficient knowledge about and experience with summary leniency applications find that the ECN Model Leniency Programme does not ensure a sufficient degree of alignment. 75% consider that this is a problem in terms of the effective enforcement of the EU competition rules and 77% believe that this impacts on incentives to apply for leniency.

Lack of protection of leniency and settlement material

Companies that choose to cooperate under leniency programmes are required to disclose their participation in a secret cartel and provide self-incriminating leniency material. In case of formal settlements, parties to the investigation are required to acknowledge their participation in, and liability for, the infringement. 20 In this framework, companies provide NCAs with leniency statements and settlement submissions which, if disclosed and used outside the context of the investigation in which they have been provided, could seriously harm their commercial interests, by exposing them to liability to other proceedings being brought against them.

The Damages Directive 21 harmonises the protection of leniency statements and settlement submissions in the context of civil damages actions before national courts in the EU. However, this Directive does not address other scenarios, such as the use of such leniency statements or settlement submissions in other civil, administrative or criminal proceedings or in case of access by the public at large through "transparency" rules/public access to documents.

The level of protection granted for such material varies significantly between Member States:

Level of protection of leniency statements

Level of protection of settlement submissions

Accessible to parties before NCA without limitation to their use

7 MS

6 MS

Accessible to civil courts in proceedings other than actions for damages

12 MS

13 MS

Accessible to public prosecutors and/or the police

20 MS

13 MS

Accessible through general transparency rules

5 MS

6 MS

Companies considering applying for leniency or contemplating settling a case may consider that there is not sufficient legal certainty about the protection of their commercial interests and decide not to cooperate with NCAs. 22 Indeed, the public consultation shows that only 33% of respondents consider that leniency statements and settlement submissions are sufficiently protected from disclosure and use outside proceedings before NCAs. 49% of respondents are in favour of extending the protection foreseen by the Damages Directive to other types of proceedings including civil, administrative, criminal and transparency procedures.

This lack of protection can undermine cartel members' incentives to apply for leniency or to settle cases under the national leniency programmes concerned.

Lack of effective interplay between corporate leniency programmes with sanctions on individuals

Another challenge is the lack of arrangements in place to protect employees of companies which make leniency applications to NCAs and/or the Commission from individual sanctions. Individual sanctions are foreseen by many Members States for their involvement in certain types of anticompetitive behaviour. 23  

The mere threat of sanctions on individuals can have a stifling effect on the willingness of companies to report cartels to NCAs or the Commission. The legal risks for the individuals involved may discourage a company's management from deciding to apply for corporate leniency. Individuals who may be subject to criminal proceedings may be deterred from helping their employers to collect the evidence required for a successful corporate leniency application, unless they are protected from sanctions. This issue also has cross-jurisdictional implications: if a company considers applying for leniency in two Member States, but its employees could be exposed to criminal sanctions in one of these countries, this prospect may deter that company from applying from leniency at all. However, only two Member States 24 provide for arrangements to protect employees from individual sanctions if their company cooperates under the leniency programme of another NCA or the Commission.

This issue has been repeatedly signaled to the ECN by stakeholders as one of the main concerns which, if not resolved, would have a chilling effect on leniency applications. In the public consultation, 63% of respondents consider it a problem that only a few Member States have arrangements in place to protect employees from sanctions if the companies they work for cooperate under the leniency programmes of a NCA or the Commission. Most stakeholders (71%) are in favour of establishing safeguards to protect such employees. 25

Annex XIV - Budget and staff of NCAs

Examples: Inadequate human and financial resources

Several NCAs had to stop or refrain from conducting certain investigations due to inadequate budget or limited staff.

Certain NCAs cannot pursue several large cases at the same time or have to separate the proceedings against the undertakings in the same case.

Some NCAs do not have sufficient staff to conduct simultaneous inspections of all members of a suspected cartel but have to limit the search for evidence of anticompetitive conduct to key targets in the investigation with the risk of missing out on key evidence.

Many NCAs do not have the resources to invest in advocacy activities 26 and they face difficulties in cooperating closely in the context of the ECN.

Others lack the appropriate forensic IT tools to find digital evidence of cartel infringements or cannot offer attractive salaries in order to attract or retain staff with experience in competition law.

Some NCAs are less inclined to enforce abuses by companies in a dominant position given the lack of economic expertise to conduct the complex economic assessment required by the case law in Article 102 cases.

The two tables below show significant differences in budget and staff between NCAs in Member States with a similar GDP.

Significant differences can also be observed regarding staffing levels. The below table shows that two NCAs have staff levels which are less than half those of other NCAs in Member States with a similar GDP.

 

Annex XV - Core indicators

(Key - Availability/Ability: NCAs have the power to do something - Application: NCAs in practice apply certain rules/power or they are put in place)

Objectives

Core indicators

Ensuring all NCAs have effective investigation and decision-making tools.

Legislative action

1. Availability of the core investigation and decision-making tools per NCA.

2. Availability of the key procedural guarantees per NCA.

3. Use of new investigation tools per NCA.

4. Number of enforcement decisions per type of decision (e.g. prohibitions, commitments, interim measures).

Soft action:

1. Application by NCAs of recommended practices/guidance to be endorsed by the ECN (e.g. to reinforce basic procedural guarantees, such as on modalities for granting effective access to the NCAs case file).

Ensuring that all NCAs are able to impose effective fines.

Legislative action:

1. In MS currently imposing criminal fines:

- Availability of administrative/civil fines.

- Ability of NCAS to bring/defend cases before courts.

- Number of fines vs. number of cases compared to previous period when primarily criminal fines were imposed.

2. Application of the prescribed legal maximum for the level of fines per NCA.

3. Changes in the level of fines compared to the situation prior to the entry into force of the Directive.

4. Total amount of fines imposed.

5. Application/non-application by national courts of the concept of undertaking, parental liability and succession.

Soft action:

1. Application by NCAs of recommended practices/guidance to be endorsed by the ECN (e.g. on aggravating/mitigating circumstances, assessment of gravity, use of guidelines etc.).

Guaranteeing that all NCAs have a well-designed leniency programme in place which facilitates applying for leniency in multiple jurisdictions.

Legislative action:

1. Availability per NCA of effective guarantees that leniency applicants can safeguard their place in the leniency queue.

2. Availability per NCA of rules to protect employees of leniency applicants from sanctions.

3. Number of leniency applications per NCA.

Soft action:    

1. Application by NCAs of recommended practices/guidance to be endorsed by the ECN (e.g. on practical issues for dealing multiple leniency applications.

Ensuring that NCAs have sufficient resources and they can enforce the EU competition rules independently.

Legislative action:

1. Availability per NCA of rules ensuring that NCAs do not receive instructions from public or private bodies.

2. Survey of whether NCAs have been subject to attempts to undermine their independence.

3. Survey of whether NCAs have adequate human and financial resources to perform their tasks, including trend and comparison of levels of staff and budget.

Extra costs for NCAs

1. Additional costs incurred as a result from enhanced powers (training, etc.)

4. Cost of NCAs' antitrust enforcement activity (costs vs. amount of fines imposed)

Annex XVI – Costs/benefits analysis of the preferred option

A) Costs assessment

Total costs arising from the legislative initiative can be (1) Direct costs, (2) Enforcement Costs, or (3) Indirect costs. The three categories of costs are assessed in more detail below.

(1) Direct costs

Types of direct costs

Assessment

Quantification

Regulatory charges 27

The initiative would not give rise to any additional regulatory charges on stakeholders.

0

Substantive compliance costs 28

There could be adaptation costs for businesses in terms of familiarisation with the new rules, which would vary depending on which Member States they operate in. These costs would be in any case rather limited and more than off-set by the benefits of operating in a more level playing field with greater legal certainty.

Apart from these potential costs, the initiative would not introduce additional obligations on businesses or citizens and therefore it would not be expected to give rise to any additional substantive compliance costs.

Low

Administrative burdens 29

The initiative would not introduce information obligations and therefore it would not be expected to give rise to any additional administrative burdens.

0

Hassle costs 30

The initiative would not be expected to give rise to any additional hassle costs.

0

(2) Enforcement Costs 31

Types of enforcement costs

Assessment

Quantification

Implementation of the legislative initiative

This is expected to be the higher cost and is to be borne by the public administration. It would include:

1) adaptation of legal framework, which would include the costs of national civil servants and politicians involved in assessing the new requirements of the initiative, the changes needed to be done in their national legal frameworks and the drafting of the necessary changes; and

2) costs linked to the adoption of the legal changes by national parliaments.

These costs are however not expected to be “additional costs” in general 32 , since the costs of civil servants, politicians and of the normal functioning of national parliaments would be incurred anyway, regardless of the initiative.

These costs are also difficult to quantify ex-ante, and could also vary significantly depending on the Member State: while for some Member States the changes would be minimal, for others more extensive legal changes could be required.

In any event, even if not additional costs, these are public resources that, absent the initiative, could be devoted to other projects. We have therefore tried to at least estimate the order of magnitude of what these costs could represent.

For the adaptation of the legal framework, the cost of the staff/politicians working in the assessment of the legal changes that are needed and drafting the proposals, taking as a basis experience in the implementation by Members States of the Damages Directive 2014/104/EU, a realistic estimate would be a maximum of 2 FTE for 18 months.

-Adaptation of the legal framework would involve at most: 2 FTE x 18 months per Member State

Costs of actual enforcement of the initiative

Within the enforcement costs, for most of the measures it is not expected that they would in general entail per se additional costs for NCAs. All NCAs already have the basic framework in place for enforcing the EU competition rules. Moreover, filling in gaps in NCAs' means and instruments is primarily an implementation cost which is not borne by the NCAs directly (see above).

NCAs would also need to get familiarised with the changes introduced by the initiative, and therefore training cost could be expected. These training costs would however be limited because they would partly be offset by the mechanisms of cooperation/training possibilities that are currently in place: through the ECN meetings NCAs' officials would be able to exchange experience and know-how about the application of the new measures; and NCAs' officials could also participate in the one month training programme organised annually by DG Competition. The cost of this training can be estimated to be about 5 training days, for 2 FTE per day

The main cost for Member States would be related to the measures to ensure a sufficient level of financial and staff resources. The envisaged provision in this respect is however very basic and essentially it is aimed at preventing NCAs from being in a situation where they cannot effectively enforce the EU competition rules. This would mean that a limited number of Member States may need to increase their staff of their NCAs to ensure that they can effectively carry out simultaneous inspections of all/most members of a cartel. This cost is difficult to estimate accurately ex-ante, but in order to obtain an approximation of its order of magnitude, we have estimated these needs to range between 4 to 10 FTEs for 5 NCAs to allow them to conduct simultaneous inspections of all/most members of a cartel.

Finally, the Commission is responsible for ensuring that appropriate IT platforms and tools are in place to ensure that authorities can cooperate effectively in the ECN. This is currently fit for purpose. These IT platforms and tools have to be updated continuously and any challenge resulting from the initiative would have to be integrated in this process. These costs are however difficult to estimate ex-ante and in any case they would not be significant.

-Training 5 days x 2 FTE per Member State

-Total increase of staff: ~ 35 FTE (4 to 10 FTEs for 5 NCAs)

Monitoring costs

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any additional monitoring costs on top of those each Member State may already incur to monitor the application of national competition rules.

Adjudication costs

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any adjudication costs.

(3) Indirect costs 33

Types of indirect costs

Assessment

Quantification

Costs incurred in related markets or experienced by stakeholders not directly targeted by the initiative

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any indirect costs in related markets or for stakeholders not targeted by the initiative.

0

Indirect compliance costs

As a result of more effective enforcement, more companies could be subject to antitrust investigations, which could in turn lead to costs for these companies in terms of legal advice, administrative procedures with the NCA, and potential sanctions. These are however costs that are inherent to ensuring compliance with the law and would therefore not amount to additional costs.

0

Costs related to substitution

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any costs related to substitution.

0



B) Benefits assessment

Benefits arising from the legislative initiative could be (1) Direct regulatory benefits, (2) Indirect regulatory benefits, and (3) ultimate impacts of the initiative. The three categories of benefits are assessed in more detail below.

(1) Direct regulatory benefits

Types of direct regulatory benefits

Assessment

Quantification

Improvement of the well-being of individuals 34

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any direct benefit in terms of health, environmental and safety improvements.

NA

Efficiency improvements 35

The initiative is expected to give rise to significant benefits derived from more competitive markets in terms of lower prices and greater innovation, choice and quality of products and services.

Although difficult to quantify at EU level, some Member States and the Commission have estimated the benefits for consumers derived from their respective enforcement actions as follows:

Dutch NCA: €260 million (2014, and including merger control).

UK NCA: £73 million (2015) (~ €100 million)

Commission: €0.99-1.49 billion (2015, and only from cartel prohibition decisions)

The cost of under-enforcement (uncovered cartels) has been estimated at around €181-320 billion.

Quantification not available

(2) Indirect regulatory benefits

Types of indirect regulatory benefits

Assessment

Quantification

Indirect compliance benefits 36

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any indirect compliance benefits, in addition to the wider effects for the economy assessed under ultimate impacts.

See “Economic goals” under “Ultimate impacts of the initiative”

Macroeconomic benefits 37

Assessed under ultimate impacts.

See “Economic goals” under “Ultimate impacts of the initiative”

Other non-monetizable benefits 38

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any other non-monetizable benefits.

NA

(3) Ultimate impacts of the initiative

Types of ultimate impacts

Assessment

Quantification

Well-being, happiness and life satisfaction

The initiative is expected to give rise to benefits derived from more competitive markets: lower prices and greater innovation, choice and quality of products and services. These features could have a positive impact on the level of satisfaction of citizens.

It is however difficult to quantify these specific benefits.

Not quantified

Environmental quality

The initiative is not expected to give rise to any benefit in terms of environmental quality, beyond the fact that more competitive markets make a better use of the scarce resources available.

Not quantified

Economic goals (such as GDP growth and employment)

See section B.1

See section B.1

B.1) Economic goals (such as GDP growth and employment)

Giving NCAs minimum means and instruments to address the problems identified would enable them to be more effective enforcers, boosting the application of the EU competition rules. According to a report from the OECD there is solid evidence from numerous empirical studies that enforcement of competition law leads to more competition on markets, which in turn results in higher productivity growth in affected industries, which translates into economic growth. 39 In a survey carried out by Ahn S. it was concluded that "A large number of empirical studies confirm that the link between product market competition and productivity growth is positive and robust. […] Empirical findings from various kinds of policy changes […] also confirm that competition brings about productivity gains, consumers’ welfare gains and long-run economic growth". 40

It is, however, difficult to give estimates of the expected benefits of the preferred option since the proposed changes are of a nature that is not easily quantifiable. This is because more effective competition enforcement is likely to give rise to general benefits to society and to the economy as a whole rather than to specific and quantifiable savings or benefits. In addition, economic literature trying to measure those benefits is scarce.

Despite these obstacles, in two articles published in the Journal of Competition Law & Economics 41 and The Review of Economics and Statistics 42 P. Buccirossi and co-authors developed a methodology to measure the impact that competition policy enforcement has on the economy. To our knowledge, this is the only available econometric approach trying to quantify the benefits of various detailed aspects of competition policy enforcement on the economy.

Using the articles of Buccirossi et al. we have tried to calculate (or at least give some orders of magnitude) the impact that the preferred option would have on the level of competition enforcement, and hence on growth in Total Factor Productivity ("TFP").

Quantification of the relationship between level of competition enforcement and TFP growth

Buccirossi et al. constructed so-called "Competition Policy Indicators" (CPIs) that are intended to measure the quality of competition policy enforcement in various countries. They then estimated the effect of competition policy enforcement on efficiency and productivity as measured by TFP.

TFP is a widely used measure of productivity in an economy. It basically describes how efficient the economy is in the use of all (hence "total") relevant inputs. To put it simply, if an economy is able to produce more with the same amount of inputs, its TFP increases.

To illustrate the importance of TFP, an annual growth of TFP of 1% would mean that an economy using the same amount of input resources would increase its production with around 10.5% over ten years. If the growth of TFP is only 0.5%, the increase in production would only be 5.1% higher.

The fact that TFP growth has slowed down in Europe has therefore raised concerns. For instance, the Commission devoted about half of its April 2016 Quarterly Report on The Euro Area to issues related to TFP growth. 43 The Report states that "[i]n the current setting of low GDP growth, inflation and interest rates, all of which are legacies of the global financial crisis, a decline in productivity and a deterioration in demographic trends could weaken Europe's resilience in facing additional adverse shocks in the region". 44

Before moving on to our calculations, it may be useful to explain why we would expect a connection between competition policy and TFP growth. One part of the explanation is actually given in the Buccirossi articles mentioned above in a section focusing on the drivers of TFP growth in the EU. The section stresses the role of "business dynamics" by which it intends market entry and exit of firms. The section presents empirical analysis done by the Commission but first explains that "[a]ccording to economic theory, there is a link between these firm dynamics and productivity developments. Various channels proposed in the literature may explain this link. These include Schumpeterian creative destruction (replacement of less efficient firms by more efficient ones through the process of innovation), the disciplining effect of market entry on existing firms, and reallocation of productive resources towards more efficient uses facilitated by the process of market entry and exit." 45

This quote explains well why we would expect effective competition policy enforcement to influence TFP growth. Effective competition policy enforcement helps keeping markets open, thereby ensuring that new innovative and more productive firms are not foreclosed from the market, at the same time putting pressure on incumbents to either improve or lose market share. At the same time, effective competition policy ensures that prices for inputs in the productive process are not inflated by activities of cartels and anticompetitive mergers.

It would, of course, be interesting to know how large the contribution of competition policy actually is. This is the question that Buccirossi and his co-authors attempted to answer. To this end, the authors collected data on seven features of competition policy for 12 OECD countries for the period 1995-2005, 9 of which are EU Member States. 46 .

Although not all these features are directly targeted by the current initiative (e.g. issues such as having effective merger control and private enforcement are already tackled by other EU legislative measures 47 ), many of them match its specific objectives. Furthermore, the spirit of what Buccirossi et al. try to measure, the effectiveness of the enforcement of competition policy in improving efficiency and productivity, is obviously very close to what this initiative is trying to achieve. We therefore consider that we can use the effects estimated by Buccirossi et al. of competition policy on TFP to illustrate the magnitude of the effects that can be expected from our proposal.

For each of the 12 countries Bucirossi et al. constructed yearly indicators with values between 0 and 1 for each of the seven features of competition policy. They then used the seven indicators to calculate an aggregate CPI incorporating all the information on the competition policy regime in a jurisdiction. 48   49

The aggregate CPI, which also is between 0 and 1, has an average value (over the 12 countries and the 11 years) of 0.4976 with a standard deviation of 0.1019. The minimum value is 0.3167 and the maximum 0.7035. This means that improving the performance of a country with the lowest CPI value to the average would be an increase of the CPI of 57%. As we will see below, managing to cover just a part of that would have a significant impact on TFP growth.

In Bucirossi et al. the CPI, together with several other variables, is used to explain growth in TFP within an econometric framework. In the basic estimations (using basic OLS regressions), the estimated coefficient of the CPI index is around 0.09. 50 This means that an increase in the CPI index of 0.1 is estimated to lead to an increase in TFP growth of 0.009, that is, 0.9 percentage point.

One way to look at what this means is to consider the elasticity of TFP with respect to the CPI that emerges from the estimations. Using the estimated coefficient of 0.09 mentioned above, Buccirossi et al. calculate this elasticity to be 4.48 at the average values for TFP and CPI (over the 12 countries and 22 industries considered). This implies that a 1% increase in CPI leads to a 4.48% increase in the growth rate of TFP. A 10% increase in the CPI might therefore be associated with an increase in the growth rate of TFP of almost 50%. As the average TFP growth across the countries and industries considered by Buccirossi et al. was about 1% over the period 1995-2005, for the average country an increase in the CPI of 10% would have led to an average TFP growth of 1.5% (instead of 1%).

Another way to look at this is to concentrate on countries with low CPI indices, since it could be argued that it may be easier to raise the CPI from a low level, rather than increasing an already relatively high CPI. An increase of the smallest value of CPI in the data set from 0.3167 to 0.3484 (equivalent to a 10% increase) would result in an increase TFP growth of 0.29 percentage point (e.g. from 1% to 1.29%, using again a coefficient of 0.09).

Given that TFP growth in the EU as a whole has been below 1% for the last ten years (see Graph 1), the results of Buccirossi et al. indicate that even a relatively small increase in the effectiveness of competition policy enforcement would give a significant boost to productivity. In fact, as shown in Graph 1 below, over the last decade TFP growth has had an impact on total GDP as important as increases in labour and capital, and it has become the most important factor during the last five years.

Graph 1 - TFP and non-TFP contributions to EU Potential Growth: 2000-15 51

It should be noted that for several countries in the data set the variation in the values of the CPIs over the period considered is more than 10%. In fact, the average CPI increases from around 0.45 to around 0.52 over the period, equivalent to an increase of more than 15%. Increases in the CPI of the magnitude we are discussing are therefore not unusual.

Taking into account that the EU28 GDP has been within the range 13 000 000 - 15 000 000 million euro during the past 5 years 52 , very small changes in GDP have a huge impact in terms of absolute value. Even taking a very conservative approach and considering that the real impact would be a fraction of what would be expected, these results indicate that achieving even a relative small increase in the value of CPI would increase productivity growth in a manner that in all likelihood would dwarf the costs of implementing the proposals in the preferred option which, as explained in section A dealing with the cost assessment, are expected to be modest.

In the next section, an attempt will be made to relate the proposals in the preferred option 3 to the CPI, that is, to see what changes in the CPI these proposals can be expected to have. Following that, the corresponding increases in TFP growth will be calculated.

Effect of the preferred option on competition enforcement and on TFP growth

Once the relationship between the level of competition enforcement - in terms of CPI - and TFP growth has been established and quantified, the next steps are to assess, first, whether the Member States have scope to improve their level of competition enforcement (i.e. the CPI) and, if so, assess the effect of the preferred option on such a level of enforcement (i.e. on the CPI).

Scope for the improvement of competition enforcement

One approach to estimate by how much competition enforcement could be improved in each Member State would be to estimate their respective CPIs. This would allow us to estimate the margin of improvement of such index (which can be between 0 and 1), and hence of TFP growth that could be achieved in each Member State as a result of changes in the CPI induced by option 3.

This exercise is, however, very difficult to carry out because the CPI estimates available in the study by Buccirossi et al. only relate to 9 Member States, and the study does not provide the information that would be needed to replicate the results for the remaining Member States or even to update the results for the 9 Member States for the period after 2005. Moreover, the results cannot be replicated either on the basis of the information that we have collected for the preparation of this Impact Assessment. 53

Nevertheless, there is scope for improvement which can be inferred from the results of the Buccirossi study.

As mentioned above, the average CPI provided by the study is 0.4976 for the twelve countries considered, nine of which are EU Member States. The minimum value is 0.3167 and the maximum 0.7035. Taking into account that the CPI ranges between 0 and 1, these results show that, on average, there is a significant margin of improvement of the CPI for every country in the study.

A criticism of this approach could be that the CPI gives a value to some aspects of enforcement that are not pursued by the present initiative, so that in the Commission's view the optimum CPI level could probably be a CPI below 1. In any case, there is still significant scope for improvement (up to around 0.8217). 54

Another potential criticism could be that the data in the Buccirossi study are for 2005, and that the enforcement level of the Member States could have improved in the meantime so that there is no longer scope for improvement. However, as explained in section 6.2. of the Impact Assessment, despite the significant efforts to address the gaps in the means and instruments of the NCAs that have been made since 2004 when Regulation 1/2003 entered into force, these problems still persist after more than ten years, and many jurisdictions still have a number of loopholes which leave room for significant improvements in the level of enforcement.

Effect of the preferred option on competition enforcement

As indicated above, replicating the study of Buccirossi et al. and estimating the quantitative changes that all the measures proposed by option 3 would induce in the CPI, and hence in TFP growth, of each Member State, is not feasible.

It is, however, possible to carry out a qualitative assessment of the effects that option 3 would have on the CPI of the Member States by assessing how the proposed measures will affect each of the features that form the CPI. In addition, we have also tried to illustrate some quantitative estimates of the impact that some of the measures of option 3 would have on CPI and TFP growth for those Member States affected by that particular measure.

How CPI is constructed – weights of the different factors

In their study, Buccirossi et al explain the construction of the CPI. As indicated above, they used seven features to assess the competition policy of a given jurisdiction. These features included aspects such as independence, investigative powers, sanctions policy, the availability of private damages and resources. Five of the seven features are labelled "institutional", and other two are called "enforcement" features. These features are used to measure different aspects of competition enforcement regarding the four "limbs" of enforcement: abuses of dominant positons, hard-core cartels, other anticompetitive agreements, and mergers. Each feature is in turn formed by two or three "low-level indicators". See examples of these "low-level indicators" in Table 2 below.

The CPI is calculated by aggregating the values (between 0 and 1) assigned to each low-level indicator according to different weights given to each of the "low-level indicator", type of feature and "limb" of enforcement. Table 1 of Bucirossi's study 55 provides details on the weights given to each "low-level indicator". These weights are generally 1/6 for each of the "institutional" features, except in some cases in which it is 1/3, while for each of the "enforcement" features they can take the values 1/3, 2/3 or 1, depending on the case. The weights given to the groups of "institutional" and "enforcement" features as a whole, and to each of the "limbs" of competition are shown in Table 1 below: 56

Table 1 – Weights

Antitrust

(3/4)

Mergers

(1/4)

Abuses

(1/3)

Hard-core cartels

(1/3)

Other agreements

(1/3)

Mergers

Institutional features

(2/3)

Institutional features

Institutional features

Institutional features

Institutional features

Enforcement features

(1/3)

Enforcement features

Enforcement features

Enforcement features

Enforcement features

Qualitative assessment of the impact of option 3 on the CPI

First, it is necessary to identify the features and low-level indicators on which option 3 will have an impact. Option 3 would impact, depending on the antitrust enforcement "limb" considered (abuses of dominant positons, hard-core cartels and other anticompetitive agreements) between four and six features, and ten out of the seventeen low-level indicators. Table 2 shows the features and the low-level indicators (with their corresponding scores) that would be affected by option 3.

Table 2 - Low-level indicators forming the CPI affected by option 3

Affected by measures in Option 3

Impact on low-level indicators

Scores

Scope (*)

Effective competition toolbox

Fines

Independence and resources

Leniency programmes and interplay

Powers during the investigation

-Ability to impose/request interim measures

-Yes: 1

-No:0

(a)(c)

X

-Combination of powers: power to inspect business and/or non-business premises

-Two powers available: 1

-One power to inspect business premises available: 0.5

-None available: 0

(a)(b)(c)

X

Sanction policy and damages

-Sanctions to firms

(2/3)

-If legal maximum of fine set as a percentage of turnover: 1

-If legal maximum of fine is left to discretion of adjudicator: 0.66

-If legal maximum fine set as an absolute value: 0.33

-If no fines envisaged: 0

(1/3)

-Monetary sanctions + structural remedies: 1

-Only monetary sanctions: 0.75

-Neither: 0

(a)

X

X

X

-If legal maximum of fine set as a percentage of turnover: 1

-If legal maximum of fine is left to discretion of adjudicator: 0.66

-If legal maximum fine set as an absolute value: 0.33

-If no fines envisaged: 0

(b)(c)

X

Independence

- Body performing the investigation

-Total statutory independence (court or independent agency): 1

-Ministerial agency/department: 0

-If both can perform the investigation: intermediate value

(a)(b)(c)

X

- Body making the decision and role of the government

-Total statutory independence and government cannot overrule the decision: 1

-Total statutory independence but government can overrule the decision: 0.5

-Ministerial agency/department: 0

(a)(b)(c)

X

Resources

-Budget

-Scores=[Budget/GDP country X]/[highest budget/GDP of sample]

(a)(b)(c)(d)

X

-Staff

-Score=[Staff/GDP country X]/[highest staff/GDP of sample]

(a)(b)(c)(d)

X

-Stall skills

-Score=[Number of economists with Ph.D and qualified lawyers /total staff country X]/[ highest number of economists with Ph.D and qualified lawyers/total staff of sample]

(a)(b)(c)(d)

X

Quality of the law

-Leniency programme

-There is a leniency programme: 1

-There is no leniency programme: 0

(b)

X

Sanctions and cases

(Tries to measure the effectiveness of sanctions also on the basis of (i) the strictness of jail terms for employees and (ii) the credibility of CA by looking at their level of investigation activity)

-Number of cases opened

-Score=[number cartel invest. initiated/GDP]/[highest number cartel invest. initiated/GDP]

(b)

X

X

(*) Scope: (a) dominant positons, (b) hard-core cartels, (c) other anticompetitive agreements, (d) mergers

It is important to underline that the impact of option 3 on the effective enforcement of competition rules by NCAs would be much wider than what it could be concluded from Table 2. This is because Table 2 only shows the impact of option 3 on the pre-selected indicators chosen by the authors of the study, which for practical reasons need to be limited to make the study manageable. However, there are many other aspects of competition enforcement which are as important as those shown in Table 2 and which would be also affected by option 3 as is illustrated below. For example, the pre-selected indicators do not cover the power to gather digital evidence, even though this is an indispensable tool to investigate infringements nowadays.

a) Effects of option 3 on the degree of "independence" and "resources"

The CPI attaches great relevance to the independence and the resources of CAs, which account respectively for about 15% and 28% of the overall index.

Option 3 will have a significant impact on several of the indicators considered in the CPI regarding both independence and resources:

-The measures to ensure that NCAs are not subject to any instructions from any other public or private body when enforcing the EU competition rules would ensure a protection of the independence of the bodies performing the investigations and making the decision equivalent to that of an independent agency, having, therefore, a positive impact on the two antitrust low-level indicators on independence. The additional measures to ensure that NCAs’ board/management cannot be dismissed in relation to its decision-making would reinforce the level of independence.

- The measures to ensure that NCAs have adequate and stable human and financial resources to perform their tasks would also have a direct positive impact on the three antitrust low-level indicators on resources.

Table 3 shows that most Member states would be affected by the proposed measures on independence:

Table 3 – Provisions on independence in Member States

Qualitative Indicators →

Availability of explicit prohibition to seek or take instructions from government or other public or private bodies

Explicit requirement to act independently and impartially in the exercise of their duties

Member States lacking the provision

18

11

On resources, section 2.2.4 of the Impact Assessment contains a graph showing the relationship between decisions adopted by NCAs and budget for a single group of Member States with similar GDP. The strong link observed between the available budget and the level of enforcement is, however, not limited to this group of Member States, but an overall trend. This is shown in Graphs 2 to 6 below for all the groups of countries:

Graph 2 - Member States with GDP 7.9-24 Billion Euro

Graph 3 - Member States with GDP 36-75 Billion Euro

Graph 4 - Member States with GDP 102-256 Billion Euro

Graph 5 - Member States with GDP 329-650 Billion Euro

Graph 6 - Member States with GDP 1057-2903 Billion Euro

Regarding staff, Graphs 7 -11 below also tend to confirm the relationship between available staff and level of enforcement:

Graph 7 - Member States with GDP 7.9-24 Billion Euro

Graph 8 - Member States with GDP 36-75 Billion Euro

 

Graph 9 - Member States with GDP 102-256 Billion Euro

Graph 10 - Member States with GDP 329-650 Billion Euro

Graph 11 - Member States with GDP 1057-2903 Billion Euro

Moreover, the fact that the lack of sufficient resources has actually caused enforcement problems has been corroborated by many NCAs which have indicated that they have been forced to refrain or reduce their activities due to budgetary/staffing constraints:

Quantitative estimate

In an attempt to determine the impact of some of the proposed measures regarding powers on the CPI, we have estimated the change in the CPI attributing the following values to the budget low-level indicators:

a) Budget, Staff and Staff skills: an improvement in 10% in these indicators for a NCA with a value of 0.3 57 (therefore increasing from 0.3 to 0.33) would lead to an increase in the CPI of 0.0083, which in turn would translate into an increase of the TFP growth of 0.0083 x 0.09 = 0.000747 or ~0.075 percentage points (from 1% 58 to 1.075%). 59

In order to illustrate the order of magnitude of the changes required, we can take a real example. According to the data on GDP and budget dedicated to competition enforcement of 2014, the normalised low-level indicators "budget/GDP" of all Member States would have an average value of around 0.3677. For a Member State with a real budget of 2 million Euro and a low-level indicator of 0.3064, an increase in 10% of this indicator would require a real budget increase of around € 200 000, which is a very low cost compared to the benefits brought in terms of TFP growth.

b) Effects of option 3 on the "powers during investigations"

The CPI also attaches great relevance to the powers of CAs (around 9% of the overall index) even if only a few of them, and with limited scope, are considered.

Option 3 will have a significant direct impact on the indicators considered in the CPI regarding powers during the investigation:

-The measures to ensure that NCAs can inspect business and non-business premises and to issue interim measures would have a positive impact on the two low-level indicators related to powers during the investigation.

-In addition, the power to impose structural remedies would have a positive impact on another CPI indicator ("Sanctions to firms" under "Sanction policy and damages").

The real impact would, however, be much more significant in real terms, because option 3 would tackle a much larger number of powers and also their scope, making them decidedly effective. For example, relying solely on the power to inspect business premises, as the CPI does, is not enough. Since 2005 (year of the study), there has been an unprecedented development in communication and storage by digital means making the possibility of gathering digital evidence crucial (as explained in section 2.2.1 of the Impact Assessment). Likewise, the CPI relies very much on the power to impose interim measures, while the Commission's experience over the last years has shown that many other powers are equally or even more important. During the public consultation we assessed the relevance of 17 powers for the effective enforcement of EU competition. The results, shown in Annex V, demonstrate a broad consensus on the tools NCAs need to be effective enforcers.

Table 4 shows the availability in the NCAs of a sample of 5 of these 17 powers, which cover both investigative and decision making powers and include the ones that are considered as CPI indicators. Almost all NCAs (25) are lacking at least one of these 5 powers.

Table 4 – Availability of powers in NCAs

Feature b): the scope of the investigative powers

Qualitative Indicators

Full power to set their priorities and decide which cases to dedicate their (often scarce) resources

Fundamental power to inspect the homes of business people for evidence of infringements

Power to impose structural remedies to restore competition on markets

Effective power to gather digital evidence (following specific aspects only: access to data on clouds, servers located in third countries, ability to carry out continued inspection procedure, ability to access mobile phones used for cartels etc.)

Power to impose effective sanctions, pecuniary sanctions and periodic penalty payments in case of non-compliance with a commitment decision/compel compliance

# NCAs lacking the power

15

3

8

11

14

These results therefore show that the changes introduced by option 3 would have a significant impact in most, if not all, NCAs, as they ensure that all NCA have a minimum set of powers compared to the current situation in which practically all NCAs are lacking some or several of them.

Quantitative estimate

In an attempt to determine the impact of some of the proposed measures regarding powers on the CPI, we have estimated what would be the change in the CPI attributing the following values to the low-level indicators:

a) Combination of powers: change from 0.5 to 1. A NCA lacking one of the two powers covered by this indicator would have as a result of option 3 an increase in the CPI of 0.0347, leading to an increase of the TFP growth of 0.0347 x 0.09 = 0.0031 or 0.31 percentage points (from 1% to 1.31%). 60

b) Availability of interim measures: change from 0 to 1. A NCA lacking this power would have as a result of option 3 an increase in the CPI of 0.0139, leading to an increase of the TFP growth of 0.0139 x 0.09 = 0.001251 or 0.12 percentage points (from 1% to 1.12%). 61

c) Effects of the measures of option 3 related to fines and leniency on the "sanctions policy and damages" and on "sanctions and cases"

The CPI attaches great relevance to the sanctions systems of competition authorities – such as the size of the sanction and the level of activity - and their level of activity, as shown by the features measuring the performance in these areas which account for around 22% of the overall CPI.

Sanctions

Regarding sanctions, Option 3 will have a significant direct impact on some of the areas that the indicators considered in the CPI try to capture, and in some cases they will directly impact the specific indicators:

-The measures to ensure that NCAs can impose deterrent fines (such as a legal maximum of fines set as a percentage of the total turnover) would have a positive impact on the level of sanctions and on the low-level indicators related to "sanctions to firms".

-In addition, the measures aimed at ensuring that NCAs would be able to impose fines through an administrative or civil route (without prejudice to their current criminal systems) would also have a positive impact on the indicator measuring the "number of cases opened".

The real impact would, however, be much more significant because the deterrent level of the fines would be reinforced by the additional measures to ensure the consistent application of the concept of "undertaking" so that parent and successor companies are fined (instead of escaping fines) and to establish a set of core fining parameters.

With respect to "sanctions to firms", the indicator used only takes into account if the legal maximum is based on a percentage of total turnover of the firm, if it is left to discretion of the adjudicator, if it is an absolute value, or if there are no fines. The indicator, however, does not enter into the details of how the legal maximum is calculated (e.g. what exact turnover is considered). This makes the assessment of how option 3 could impact this indicator very difficult to carry out. It is however clear that Option 3 would significantly affect the way NCAs calculate their respective fines legal maximums. Annex VII shows that there is an important scope for improvement in many Member States. Currently, many Member States calculate the legal maximum, not on the basis of the turnover of the group, but of the direct infringer, and/or not on the basis of the total worldwide turnover but of the national turnover. This is shown in Table 5 below.

Table 5 - Basis for calculation of legal maximum for fines

Geographic scope of the turnover

Entity's turnover:

Worldwide

National

Undertaking

11 NCAs

3 NCAs

Direct infringer

9 NCAs

4 NCAs

In addition, one NCA has also limits based on absolute values (€16 million for Art 101 infringements and €400 000 for Art. 102 infringements).

With respect to the level of activity ("number of cases opened"), option 3 would likewise have a positive impact on some NCAs which are currently facing some issues preventing them from achieving their full potential.

An assessment of the cases and the fines imposed per Member State shows that when fines are primarily criminal, the level of enforcement/sanctions is low. This is for example the case for Ireland, where there has been practically no enforcement of EU competition law (only one case) between 2004 and 2014. Similarly, in Denmark, only one fine was ever imposed for breach of the EU competition rules in the same period, despite a large number of cases (40) being undertaken by the NCA and several infringements being found. In Germany there have been no fines for infringements of Art. 102 despite having dealt with a large number of cases (for Art. 101 infringements the NCA has imposed 41 fines in 60 decisions, whereas for infringements of Art. 102 in has not imposed any fine despite having taken 24 decisions). 62

Option 3 would allow NCAs to opt for a complementary administrative/civil route for imposing sanctions and would, therefore, significantly increase the number of both findings of infringements and sanctions in those Member States that are now facing this type of issues.

Leniency

With respect to leniency, the CPI only accounts for the fact of having or not having a leniency programme, which currently all Member States except one have in place. It does not capture, however, more detailed information which is very important to assess whether or not a leniency programme is really effective, or the inter-link between national leniency programmes at EU level. Although for these reasons it is very difficult to assess the direct effect that option 3 would have on the CPI, we consider that option 3 would have a clear positive and significant effect in the area of leniency programmes. Probably this effect would end up by also having a positive effect on TFP growth, even if not captured by a change in the CPI, as it would likely lead to more attractive leniency programmes, increasing the number of leniency applications and therefore of enforcement activity across the EU.

The positive impact on the level of activity of NCAs would however not be achieved only by these measures (sanctions and leniency). The level of activity would also be reinforced and therefore multiplicative effect of the other option 3 measures. The enhanced investigative and decision making powers and having adequate and stable financial and human resources would allow NCAs to engage in cases that are currently out of their reach.

Quantitative estimate

In an attempt to determine the impact of some of the proposed measures regarding sanctions on the CPI, we have estimated what would be the change in the CPI attributing the following values to the low-level indicators:

a) Sanctions to firms: a modest improvement in 10% in this indicator as a result of option 3 would mean that a NCA with an average value for these indicators of 0.75 63 would have an increase in the CPI of 0.00416, leading to an increase of the TFP growth of 0.00416 x 0.09 = 0.00037 or ~0.04 percentage points (from 1% to 1.04%). In the extreme case of a NCA which in practice does not impose sanctions, option 3 would lead to an increase in the CPI of 0.0555, and therefore an increase of the TFP growth of 0.0555 x 0.09 = 0.00499 or ~0.50 percentage points (from 1% to 1.50%). 64

Annex XVII – Glossary of terms

Antitrust

Field of competition law and policy. In the EU context, ‘antitrust’ refers both to the rules prohibiting anti-competitive agreements and practices (such as cartels, other cooperation agreements, distribution agreements, etc.) based on Article 101 TFEU, and to the rules prohibiting abuses by dominant companies based on Article 102 TFEU.

Abuse of a dominant position

Anti-competitive business practices (including improper exploitation of customers or exclusion of competitors) which a dominant company may use in order to maintain or increase its position in the market. Competition law prohibits such behaviour, as it damages competition between firms, exploits consumers, and makes it unnecessary for the dominant company to compete with other companies on merit. Article 102 of the TFEU lists some examples of abuse, namely unfair pricing, restriction of production output and imposing discriminatory or unnecessary terms in dealings with trading partners.

Cartel

Agreement and/or concerted practice between two or more competitors aimed at coordinating their competitive behaviour on the market and/or influencing the relevant parameters of competition, through practices such as the fixing or coordination of purchase or selling prices or other trading conditions, the allocation of production or sales quotas, the sharing of markets and customers including bid-rigging, restrictions of imports or exports and/or anti-competitive actions against other competitors.

Commitment decision

When a competition authority pursues a competition law case, companies may offer commitments (for example, the removing of anticompetitive clauses in an agreement) that are intended to address the competition concerns identified by the competition authority. If the competition authority accepts these commitments, it adopts a commitment decision making them binding and enforceable on the parties, without taking position on whether an infringement has been committed.

Dominant position

A company is in a dominant position if it has the ability to behave independently of its competitors, customers, suppliers and, ultimately, the final consumer.. Article 102 TFEU prohibits firms that hold a dominant position on a given market from abusing that position, for example by charging unfair prices, by limiting production, or by refusing to innovate to the prejudice of consumers.

Effect on trade between Member States

Articles 101 and 102 TFEU are only applicable if there may be a direct or indirect, actual or potential influence on the flow or pattern of trade between at least two Member States of the EU. An effect on trade exists in particular where national markets are partitioned or the structure of competition within the common market is affected. Anti-competitive agreements or conduct which have no effect on trade, therefore, fall outside the scope of EU competition rules and may only be dealt with by national legislation.

European Competition Network (ECN)

The network formed by the competition authorities of the Member States (NCAs) and the European Commission. This network is a forum for discussion and cooperation in the application and enforcement of EU competition policy. It provides a framework for European competition authorities to cooperate in cases where Articles 101 and 102 TFEU are applied, and for flexible allocation of cases between the authorities. The European Competition Network was created on the basis of Regulation No 1/2003.

ECN Model Leniency Programme

A document endorsed by the ECN members aligning the key elements of leniency policies within the ECN in order to increase the effectiveness of leniency programmes in the EU and simplify the burden for applicants and authorities in case of multiple filings. The Model Leniency Programme sets out the essential procedural and substantive elements that ECN members believe every leniency programme should contain. The ECN authorities made a commitment to use their best efforts to align their leniency programmes with the ECN Model Leniency Programme or to introduce aligned programmes. However, this document is not a legally binding programme.

Fine

A monetary penalty imposed by a competition authority on a company for a violation of the EU competition rules.

Hard-core infringement

Restrictions of competition by agreements or business practices, which are seen by most jurisdictions as being particularly harmful for competition and which normally do not produce any beneficial effects. They therefore almost always infringe competition law. Under EU law, the most prominent examples on the horizontal level include agreements between competitors that fix prices, allocate markets or restrict the quantities of goods or services to be produced, bought or supplied. Examples of hard-core restrictions in vertical relationships (i.e. between companies operating at different levels of the production or distribution chain) are resale price maintenance and certain territorial restrictions.

Interim measures

Conservatory measures imposed on companies by a competition authority in a competition case, to avoid damage to the marketplace.

Leniency statement

A voluntary presentation by, or on behalf of, a company to a competition authority, describing the company’s knowledge of a cartel and its role therein, which was drawn up specifically for submission to the authority with a view to obtaining immunity or a reduction of fines under a leniency programme concerning the application of Article 101 of the Treaty or the corresponding provision under national law.

Leniency programme

A programme on the basis of which a participant in a cartel, independently of the other companies involved in the cartel, co-operates with the investigation of the competition authority by voluntarily providing presentations of its knowledge of the cartel and its role therein, in return for which such participant receives immunity from, or a reduction in, the fine for its involvement in the cartel.

National Competition Authority (NCA)

National competition authorities (NCAs) are the authorities designated by the Member States pursuant to Article 35 of Regulation 1/2003 as responsible for the application of Article 101 and 102 TFEU in their territories. EU law obliges Member States to ensure that NCAs are set up and equipped in such a way that the provisions of Regulation No 1/2003 are effectively complied with. Together with the Commission, the competition authorities from Member States form the European Competition Network (ECN).

Periodic penalty payment

A monetary penalty imposed by a competition authority on a company, in order to compel such company to comply with an earlier decision or order.

Statement of Objections

Form of communication addressed by a competition authority to a company which contains its preliminary concerns and conclusions with respect to such company's alleged anti-competitive behaviour on which the competition authority intends to rely upon in its final decision. This allows the addressee to make its point of view known on any objection in accordance with its rights of defence.

Summary application

A summary application system allows companies to file a leniency application to NCAs on the basis of more limited information where a full leniency application has been given to the Commission. This entails that they avoid having to file complete leniency applications with all NCAs with (potential) jurisdiction to take actions against the cartel.

Regulation No 1/2003

A Council Regulation setting out the main rules for the enforcement of EU antitrust rules (Articles 101 and 102 TFEU). This Regulation, which took effect on 1 May 2004 modernised the rules governing how EU antitrust rules are enforced. Regulation 1/2003 entrusts, in parallel with the Commission, competition authorities of the Member States (NCAs) and national courts with the role of applying Article 101 and 102 TFEU. Regulation 1/2003 also forms the basis for the European Competition Network (ECN) which provides a framework for the Commission and NCAs to cooperate.

Remedies

Measures adopted by a competition authority requiring behavioural or structural changes on the part of the company to whom the measures are directed.

Formal settlement procedure

A simplified procedure which results in the faster handling of the case and in a reduction of the fines. In order to benefit from this procedure, the companies involved have to acknowledge their participation in the infringement.

(1)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/antitrust_enforcement_10_years_en.pdf http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/swd_2014_230_en.pdf http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/swd_2014_231_en.pdf.
(2)  http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52009DC0206&from=EN and http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52009SC0574&from=EN.
(3)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/investigative_powers_report_en.pdf.
(4)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/decision_making_powers_report_en.pdf. 
(5)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/model_leniency_programme.pdf. 
(6)  http://ec.europa.eu/competition/consultations/2015_effective_enforcers/index_en.html
(7)  COM(2014) 453 final, 9 July 2014.
(8) Although the total number of replies was 181, only 165 replied to the online questionnaire, while the other 16 provided their replies in the form of a position paper. The percentages indicated in the table are based on the replies to the online questionnaire only.
(9)  The figures used will not necessarily add up to 100% because some respondents may have answered "do not know" or "not applicable".
(10)  Gravity is normally accounted for as a percentage of the sales that are used as the basis for the calculation of the fine. The Commission applies a percentage of up to 30%. Most Member States have the same range, but some have lower percentages. For Member States using the sales related to the infringement, four apply a percentage up to 10%, and another one up to 3% in the relevant market. For the Member States using the total turnover of the undertaking, two apply a percentage up to 7%/8% and another one up to 3%.
(11)  This is normally done by calculating the fine for the first year of infringement (starting amount) and multiplying it by number of years of duration of the infringement.
(12)  One NCA multiplies the starting amount of the fine by 1 for durations of 1 year or less, by 3 for durations of more than 10 years, and by a coefficient between 1 and 3 for intermediate durations. Another NCA increases the fine by 0.5% of total turnover for up to five years durations, and by between 0.5%-1% for longer durations. Another NCA, if the durations are longer than 1 year, increases the fine by 100% for abuses and by 200% for agreements.
(13)  Case C-97/08 P AkzoNobel NV v Commission [2009] ECR I-8237. It has to be shown that the parent company exercises decisive influence over the subsidiary that committed the infringement
(14)  One NCA cannot apply the principle of "presumption" (meaning that in cases of 100% ownership it is presumed that the parent company has exercised decisive influence on the subsidiary and can be held liable), while two others can hold liable only one legal entity, either the direct infringer or its parent, but not both.
(15)  In one Member State it is not possible to fine associations of undertakings, and in nine Member States the fine can only be based on the turnover of the association, and not on the turnover of its members.
(16)  It also ensures that companies and NCAs do not invest a disproportionate amount of resources in filing and checking parallel leniency applications for cases that are likely to be dealt with by the European Commission.
(17)  Judgement in DHL Express (Italy) S.r.l. and Others v Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato and Others, C-428/14, EU:C:2016:27
(18)  Only 6% of respondents disagree with this proposition; 78% of the responding business organisations agree with it.
(19)  Only 7% of respondents disagree with this proposition; 74% of the responding NCAs agree with it.
(20)  A settlement is a simplified procedure which results in the faster handling of the case and in a reduction of the fines. In order to benefit from this procedure, the companies involved have to acknowledge their participation in the infringement.
(21)  Directive 2014/104/EU on certain rules governing actions for damages under national law for infringements of the competition law provisions of the Member States and of the European Union, OJ L349/1 of 5.12.2014.
(22)  In order to ensure effective protection of leniency statements and settlement submissions in Commission investigations, the Commission adapted the provisions in Regulation 773/2004 and the four Notices concerning the disclosure and use of information in the Commission's investigative file (Access to the File, Leniency, Settlements, Cooperation with National Courts), to the rules of the Damages Directive 2014/104/EU on disclosure and use of information obtained from competition authorities in antitrust damages actions.
(23)  Only three Member States do not foresee any sanctions on individuals. 19 Member States foresee criminal sanctions on individuals for certain types of competition offences and 12 Member States have administrative or civil sanctions for individuals involved in certain antitrust infringements.
(24)  In Austria, the prosecution against individuals will be closed if their employers have filed for leniency in Austria, any EU Member State or with the Commission, subject to the individual's continuing cooperation. In the UK, criminal immunity is not only available for UK immunity recipients, but also for immunity recipients under the Commission's leniency notice.
(25)  The remainder of the respondents replied do not know/not applicable, the latter probably because they have no experience with Member States where such arrangements already exist.
(26) Many respondents value competition advocacy as important as individual case enforcement.
(27)  Fees, levies, taxes, etc.
(28)  Investments and expenses that are faced by businesses and citizens in order to comply with substantive obligations or requirements contained in a legal rule.
(29)  Costs borne by businesses, citizens, civil society organizations and public authorities as a result of administrative activities performed to comply with information obligations included in legal rules.
(30)  Costs for businesses/consumers associated with waiting time and delays, redundant legal provisions, corruption etc.
(31)  These costs are associated with activities linked to the implementation by the Member States of new legal rules such as monitoring (compliance with the new rules), enforcement (cost of applying the new legal rules) and adjudication (using the legal system, or an alternative dispute resolution mechanism, to solve controversies generated by the new legal rules).
(32)  Additional costs might arise for example in cases where external studies are commissioned for the assessment of certain aspects of the implementation. This is, however, not possible to foresee at this stage.
(33)  These costs are incurred in related markets or experienced by consumers, government agencies or other stakeholders that are not directly targeted by the initiative/regulation. These costs are usually transmitted through changes in the prices and/or availability and/or quality of the goods or services produced in the regulated sector. Changes in these prices then ripple through the rest of the economy changing prices in other sectors and ultimately affecting the welfare of consumers. The category also includes so-called “indirect compliance costs” (i.e. costs related to the fact that other stakeholders have to comply with legislation) and costs related to substitution (e.g. reliance on alternative sources of supply), transaction costs and negative impacts on market functioning such as reduced competition or market access, or reduced innovation or investment.
(34)  Health, environmental and safety improvements.
(35)  Notably, cost savings but also information availability and enhanced product and service variety and quality for end consumers.
(36)  Spill-over effects related to third-party compliance with legal rules.
(37)  Including GDP improvements, productivity enhancements, greater employment rates, improved job quality etc.
(38)  Protection of fundamental rights, social cohesion, reduced gender discrimination or international and national stability.
(39)  See OECD, 2014, Fact-sheet on how competition policy affects macro-economic outcomes.
(40)  See Ahn, S. (2002). "Competition, Innovation and Productivity Growth: A Review of Theory and Evidence". OECD Economics Working Paper No. 317. A study carried out by Petit L., Kemp R. and van Sinderen J. (2015) "Cartels and productivity growth: an empirical investigation of the impact of cartels on productivity in the Netherlands", assessed the impact of cartels on total factor productivity (TFP). TFP is a measure of the output of a company, sector or total economy that cannot be explained by the amount of inputs used in production and whose level is determined by how efficiently and intensely the inputs are utilized and is an indicator of competitiveness. The results showed that the entry and presence of a cartel had a negative impact on TFP and it was estimated that cartels had a negative impact on TFP of between 2% to 3% during the period covered.
(41)  Bucirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G. & Vitale, C. (2011). "Measuring the deterrence properties of competition policy: the competition policy indexes ". Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7(1), 165-204.
(42)  Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G., & Vitale, C. (2013). Competition policy and productivity growth: an empirical assessment. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1324-1336.
(43)  http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/eeip/pdf/ip024_en.pdf.
(44)  Quarterly Report on the Euro Area, April 2016, p. 19.
(45)  Quarterly Report on the Euro Area, April 2016, p. 25.
(46)  Canada, the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom and the United States.
(47)  See Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between undertakings (the Merger Regulation ) Official Journal L 24, 29.01.2004, p. 1-22, and Directive 2014/104/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 November 2014 on certain rules governing actions for damages under national law for infringements of the competition law provisions of the Member States and of the European Union, OJ 2014, L 349, p.1. .
(48) Details on these features, their components and the specific weights given to each of them used to calculate the aggregate final CPI can be found in Bucirossi, et al (2011). "Measuring the deterrence properties of competition policy: the competition policy indexes", Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7(1), 165-204, tables 1, 2 and 3.
(49)  To aggregate the seven components they experiment with different weighting choices and show that the results are robust with the chosen weights.
(50)  In the basic estimations, the authors use Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regressions. In more sophisticated estimations using instrumental variables (IV) methods, the estimated coefficient of the CPI index is around 0.2. As the authors use the coefficient from the OLS regressions when explaining their results, we do the same in our calculations. Using the IV coefficient, the effects would be roughly twice as large.
(51)  European Economic Forecast, Winter 2014, Box I.2. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2014/pdf/ee2_en.pdf.
(52)  http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/tgm/refreshTableAction.do?tab=table&plugin=1&pcode=tec00001&language=en.
(53)  Although the information collected covers a wide range of topics, it does not cover certain aspects that are necessary to estimate some of the indicators (such as qualifications of staff or detailed information on sanctions to individuals).
(54)  This value for the CPI is obtained by assuming that under the present initiative the scores of some low-level indicators would not reach 1 because not all aspects are addressed by the current initiative or are relevant. Re-calculating the CPI on the basis of the maximum values for the indicators addressed by the current initiative and the corresponding weights provided by the Buccirossi study, the maximum CPI would still be 0.8217, therefore still leaving significant scope for improvement.
(55)  Bucirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G. & Vitale, C. (2011). "Measuring the deterrence properties of competition policy: the competition policy indexes". Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7(1), 165-204.
(56)  Bucirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G. & Vitale, C. (2011). "Measuring the deterrence properties of competition policy: the competition policy indexes". Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7(1), 165-204, Tables 2 and 3.
(57)  These indicators are "normalised", which means that the value assigned to each CA is the result of dividing its resources by the highest value of the sample.
(58)  In this and the other examples, we use a value of the TFP growth of 1% for the base line scenario, which is the average value found by Buccirossi et al. for the period they studied. The current TFP growth is now lower, as shown in Graph 1, with an average of around 0.5-0.6% for the past 5 years and closer to 1% if the last 15 years are considered. The order of magnitude of the results would, however, not be substantially different.
(59)  The calculation has been done as follows: on the basis of the weights given to each low-level indicator and the way they are aggregated to form the final CPI provided in the Buccirossi study, and assuming that a change in the resources of a NCA is evenly split amongst the four limbs of competition enforcement, it results that a change "X" in the "Resources" low-level indicator (comprising Budget, Staff and Staff skills) produces a change in the final CPI of  * X. A change in the "Resources" low-level indicator from 0.3 to 0.33 (e.g. a 10% increase) results therefore in a change in the CPIs of  * 0.03 = 0.00833.
(60)  Following the same methodology used for the example with the "Resources" low-level indicator, it results that a change "X" in the "Combination of powers" low-level indicator produces a change in the final CPI of 5/72* X. A change in the low-level indicator from 0.5 to 1 as a result of gaining the lacking power would therefore result in a change in the CPIs of  * 0.5 = 0.0347.
(61)  Following the same methodology used for the example with the "Resources" low-level indicator, it results that a change "X" in the "Availability of interim measures" low-level indicator produces a change in the final CPI of 1/72* X. A change in the low-level indicator from 0 to 1 as a result of gaining the lacking power would therefore result in a change in the CPIs of  * 1 = 0.013888 ~ 0.0139.
(62)  In the case of Germany, fines follow a quasi-criminal procedure only in case of the fine being appealed.
(63)  As explained, the indicator used only takes into account if the legal maximum is based on the percentage of total turnover of the firm, if it is left to discretion of the adjudicator, if it is an absolute value, or if there are no fines. Since option 3 affects the legal maximum in the details of how it is calculated (e.g. what exact turnover is considered), the current indicator may not capture the real effect of option 3, making an assessment of option 3 difficult in this respect. We have, however, provided this indication to give an estimate of the order of magnitude of the effects that an improvement in the sanctioning systems could have on the TFP growth.
(64)  Following the same methodology used for the example with the "Resources" low-level indicator, a change "X" in the "Sanctions to firms" low-level indicator produces a change in the final CPI of 1/18* X. A change of 10% in the low-level indicator from 0.75 to 0.825 as a result of option 3 would therefore result in a change in the CPIs of 1/18 * 0.075 = 0.00416. In the extreme case, a change from 0 to 1 would result in a change in the CPIs of 1/18 * 1 = 0.0555.
Top